0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views8 pages

Sectors': Export and Economic Growth in Ethiopia: (VECM Causality Approach)

Uploaded by

habtamu beharu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
23 views8 pages

Sectors': Export and Economic Growth in Ethiopia: (VECM Causality Approach)

Uploaded by

habtamu beharu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 8

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.

org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

Sectors’ Export and Economic Growth in Ethiopia: (VECM


Causality Approach)
Tesfa-Amlak Gizaw (M.sc.) Tasew Tadesse(Phd)
Economics Department, Dilla University, Dilla Ethiopia

Abstract
The link between export and economic growth has been interesting and rich source of debates among economists
and many other scholars. Particularly looking depth into the logical disagreement of the scholars; it is revolves
mainly around whether export-led growth hypothesis or growth-led export hypothesis hold true in the explicit
circumstances for different countries. And this divergence is also the foremost purpose of this work in that the
causal relationship between sectors’ export and output growth in Ethiopia examined using secondary time series
data collected from national bank of Ethiopia, ministry of finance and economic development and World Bank
development indicator data base. VECM model used and its result reveal, in the long run the existence of
unidirectional causality which run from economic growth to agriculture, industry and service export disjointedly
however in the short run it reveal the existence of unidirectional causality which runs solely from economic
growth to service export, in other word growth-led export hypothesis supported in case of Ethiopia. Therefore,
to further develop and diversify export in Ethiopia, economic growth needs to be strengthening and diversified.
Keywords: export, economic growth, econometrics, VECM model and causality.
DOI: 10.7176/JESD/11-3-04
Publication date: February 29th 2020

1. INTRODUCTION
Countries of the world are interdependent. And one of the means by which countries relay one up on another is
trade. International trade has an element of export and import in it. Despite the fact that a country is not self
sufficient to meet the total demand of its society with what it produced in the home economy, it may import
foreign goods and services from other countries. However to import foreign product, the country must export
goods and services to foreigners and get foreign currencies in return. And hence exporting goods and services
means acquiring foreign currencies, encouraging economic specialization, rising the productivity of non-export
sector, promoting investment, creating employment opportunity, increasing intra trade, reducing the impact of
external shocks on domestic economy and then promote economic growth. (Balassa, 1978; Feder, 1982; Smith,
2001; Hock, 2006)
Despite export trade is believed to play crucial role in promoting economic growth for both developed and
developing countries. Still there is an increasing interest on the relationship between export and economic
growth. In such way for long period of time there has been considerable debate regarding the relationship
between the two variables. And five possible relationships had been identified between export and economic
growth: viz export driven growth, growth led exports, two way causality, no causal effects and negative
connection between them. And theoretically all five results are supported (Pack, 1988; Thornton, 1996).
The export-led hypothesis suggests a sharp growth in output through various avenues. First, an increase in
exports facilitates more imports into a country. If these imports include capital and intermediate goods, they
would act as a catalyst for higher output growth. Second, export development tends to concentrate investment in
the most efficient sectors of the economy where comparative advantage lies. Specialization in these improves
productivity in the economy leading to higher output growth. Third, the totaling of international markets to
already existing domestic market, gives scope for economies of scale in the export sector. This also pushes up
the growth in output. Fourth, export growth represents an increase in aggregate demand, which can serve to
increase output. Fifth, exchange control relaxation and the export growth induce lower allocative inefficiencies
in the economy, yielding higher output growth. Sixth, higher export growth can lead to higher investment – both
local and foreign. Finally, international spread of technology and market innovation which exports capture can
have output effects. In general, all these characteristics of export growth tend to reinforce each other stimulating
further expansion of exports, investment and consumption. And the final result is a significant rise in the rate of
growth of output. (Chu, 1988; Khalafalla and Webb, 2000; Anwar and sampath, 2000; and Dawson, 2005)
The direction of causality from output growth to exports is also plausible. In a growing LDC it is possible
that there are some dynamic industries which are expanding rapidly. It is unlikely that domestic demand in these
countries will rise as rapidly as output of these industries. Consequently, these domestic producers will explore
foreign markets for sales. If this were the case, it is increased output that causes increased exports. Also, higher
output growth can stimulate higher investment, part of which can be for increasing the capacity to export.
(Ewetan and Okudua, 2012; Ugwuegbe and Uruakpa, 2013; Armand Gilbert, et al 2013)
A feedback relationship between exports and output can also hold under certain cases. Countries exporting

43
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

a large share of their output seem to grow faster than other countries. Putting together the two hypotheses;
exports may rise from the realization of economies of scale due to productivity gains; the rise in exports may
further enable cost reductions, which may result in further productivity gains. (Idowu, 2005; Rahmaddi, 2011)
With this setting, we are interested to note the link between export and output growth in Ethiopia. The
country has been formulating different strategies and undertaking policy changes in different sectors of the
economy. Among such changes export promotion strategy occupies the prominent place. And following this
strategy the country’s economy and its export tangibly had been increasing overtime. For instance according to
(world bank, 2016) report “over the past decade Ethiopian’s economy has been growing twice the rate of Africa
regions, averaging 10.6 percent GDP per year between 2004 and 2011 compared to 5.2 percent in sub-Sahara
Africa(SSA). Similarly during the same period export grew by 20 percent with the dominance of primary
commodities in general and coffee with 26.4 percent in particular. Despite these figures give evidence regarding
the existence of some link relationship between export and economic growth in Ethiopia they can’t give surety
about whether the export sector has been backing up Ethiopian economy in its double digit growth rate. To this
end some authors had examined over the relation between export and growth in the case of Ethiopia. For
instance (Tegenu, 2011) examined export- led or domestic demand- led growth policy in Ethiopia. He argued
that the current stage of the country’s structural transformation requires policy agenda of domestic demand-led
growth. (Hailegiorgis, 2012) empirically examined the effects of export led growth (ELG) on Ethiopian
economy with the application of Granger (1969) causality test using annual data for the period 1974-2009 and
find unidirectional causality from export to economic growth in Ethiopia. (Soressa, 2013) examined relationship
between exports, domestic demand and economic growth in Ethiopia using time series data over the period 1960
to 2011. The result revealed a dynamic relationship between export and economic growth and between domestic
demand and economic growth. Exports and domestic demands are important for economic growth and economic
growth has an impact on exports and domestic demand in Ethiopia.
However empirical studies which have been conducted during the last four decades to investigate the role of
exports on economic growth they were conducted along a number of divergent lines. Thus all of the above work
is not free from gaps. Loosely speaking the early studies on this issue examined the simple correlation
coefficient between export growth and economic growth. The second group of studies took the approach of
whether or not exports are driving output by estimating output growth regression equations based on the
neoclassical growth accounting techniques of production function analysis, including exports or export growth as
an explanatory variable. A third group of, relatively recent, studies have their emphasis on causality between
export growth and economic growth. Finally, there have been relatively new studies which involve the
application of techniques of co-integration and error-correction models. This relatively new methodology does
not suffer from the shortcomings found in methodologies of previous studies. But since these studies which
conducted in this method highly concentrated on aggregate export band failed to show the relationship between
disaggregate export and economic growth. And hence this study, using VECM causality technique, mainly
examined the causal link between disaggregate export and economic growth in Ethiopia.

2. METHODOLOGY
2.1. Type and Source of Data
A time series secondary data from 1974/75 to 2016/17 is collected from National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE),
Ethiopia Revenue and Custom Authority (ERCA), Central Statistics of Authority (CSA), Ministry Finance and
Economic development (MoFED) and World Bank (WB) development indicators database

2.2. Methods of Data Analysis


The analytical framework of the study is more empirical. Specifically, we employed vector error correction
model. This is because the model has gained reputation or ability to guarantee stationarity and to make available
extra channels through which bi-directional causality can be examined when two variables are co-integrated.

2.3. Model specification


To examine the effect of export on economic growth some theoretical models are considered in this study. The
factors of production and the production technology that determine the level of output in an economy can be
given as:
Yt = f ( At K t Lt ) = At Kt b1 Lt b 2 ------------------------------------------------------------------ (1)
Where Yt is the production of the economy which is real GDP at time t; At , K t , Lt , are the total factor
productivity, the stock of capital, the stock of labor in the given country respectively.
The second theoretical model considered in this work is the neo-classical growth model modified and suggested
by (Balassa, 1978):
Y = A f (L, K, X) ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- - (2)

44
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

Where Y is aggregate real output, K, L and X represent capital, labor and export respectively.
b b b b b
Thus,Yt = K t 1 Lt 2 RAX t 3 RIX t 4 RSX t 5 Et ---------------------------------------------- (3)
Where b1 , b 2 , b 3 , b 4 and b 5 are constant elasticity coefficients of output with respect to K, L, RAX, RIX
and RSX is exogenous components of growth. That means it consists of any variable that affect growth but not
included in the model as explanatory variable.
From the equation above after taking log in both sides, the equation now becomes:
lnYt= b 0 + b1 ln K t + b 2 ln Lt + b 3 ln RAXt + b 4 ln RIXt + b 5 ln RSXt + e t ------------------- (4)
Where, LRGDP = Real GDP at time t in log form is the dependent variable.
LRAX = log of real agricultural export at time t
LRIEXP = log of real industry export at time t
LRSX = log of real service export at time t
Where e t is the white noise error term that is the error term which satisfies the assumption of Classical linear
Regression Model (CLRM)

2.4. Estimation Technique


2.4.1. Unit root test
Working with non-stationary variables lead to spurious regression results, from which further inference is
meaningless. Thus, it is better to distinguish between stationary and non-stationary variables. The most common
example of a stationary series is the white noise which has a mean of zero, a constant variance and a zero
covariance between successive terms.
The ADF test assumes that the errors are statistically independent and have a constant variance. Thus, an
error term should be uncorrelated with the others, and has a constant variance. The test is first carried out with a
constant and trend on the variable in level form. Secondly, it is carried out with a constant only and finally
without constant or trend, on the differenced variable depending on which was significant in the level form.
p
D y t
= d 0 + d1 y t -1
+ åq i D y t -i
+ et
i =1 ------------------ (5)
p
D y t
= d1 y t -1
+ å i =1
qi D y t -1
+ et
------------- (6)
Where, δ0 and t are the constant and the time trend, respectively. If dependent and independent variables
failed the stationarity test, the data generating process of these variables are non-stationary. These tests are
performed on both level form and first differences of both variables. In a situation where all the variables are
stationary at I (0), the OLS method is used in the estimation. Implications of the unit root test result on the
estimation procedures are; if all variables in the equation are found to be non-stationary at level form but
stationary at first difference I (1), then co-integration test is conducted to find the existence of a long-run
equilibrium relationship.
2.4.2. Co-integration Test
The theory of co-integration can be used to study series that are non-stationary but a linear combination of which
is stationary. Co integration is the statistical implication of the existence of long run relationship between the
variables which are individually non-stationary at their level form but stationary after difference (Gujarati, 1995).
Two main procedures can be used to test for co-integration: The (Engle and Granger, 1987) test and the
(Johansen, 1988) co-integration test. Johansen procedure of co integration gives two statistics. These are the
value of LR test based on the maximum Eigen – value and on the trace value of the stochastic matrix. The
Johansen test uses the likelihood ratio to test for co-integration. And up to (r-1) co-integrating relationships may
exist between a set of r variables. The decision rule compares the likelihood ratio to the critical value for a
hypothesized number of co-integrating relationships. If the likelihood ratio is greater than the critical value, the
hypothesis of co-integration is accepted.
Besides if two variables Y and X are cointegrated, then the long term or equilibrium relationship that exists
between the two can be expressed as ECM (Gujarati, 2004). This means one will go for the construction of an
error correction model if and only ly if the two variables are cointegrated. The ECM can be given by:
------------------------------------------------------------------- (7)
Where Δ denotes the first difference operator, is a random error term, and
( ), that is, the one-period lagged value of the error term from the cointegrating regression.
This ECM equation states that ΔYt depends on ΔXt and also on the equilibrium error term. If the latter is
nonzero, the model is out of equilibrium. Suppose ΔXt is zero and ut-1 is positive. This means Yt-1 is too high

45
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

[above] to be in equilibrium. Since α2 is expected to be negative, the term is negative and, therefore,
ΔYt will be negative to restore the equilibrium. That is, if Yt is above its equilibrium value, it will start falling in
the next period to correct the equilibrium error; hence the name ECM. By the same token, if is negative
(i.e Yt is below its equilibrium value), will be positive, which will cause ΔYt to be positive, leading Yt
to rise in period t. The absolute value of α2 determines how quickly the equilibrium is restored. In practice
Ù Ù Ù
will be estimated by u t -1 = Yt - b 1 - b 2 X t (Gujarati, 2004).
2.4.3. VECM and Causality
In a setting where the variables are non-stationary at level, as is the case with most economic time series (Engle
and Granger, 1987) argue that the conventional Granger causality tests could provide misleading results. This is
because the conventional Granger causality test ignores the long run equilibrium relationships implied by the co-
integration properties of the time series, and hence omits an important channel through which causality may be
detected. In this case the recommended approach to testing for the Granger causality is the Co-integration and
Error-Correction framework. As opposed to the conventional Granger causality test, an error-correction model
combines the short run dynamics with the long run properties of the data and thus provides a convenient tool for
investigating short run as well as long run causal patterns. The error-correction models are formulated as follows:
p h
(1 - L) yt = c1 + d1 e t -1
+ å di (1 - L) yt -i + åqi (1 - L) xt -i + mt
i =1 i =1 ---------- (8)
m n
(1 - L) xt = c2 + d 2 e' t -1
+ å gi (1 - L) xt -i + å li (1 - L) yt -i + vt
i =1 i =1 ---------- (9)
Where, L is the lag operator and the error-correction terms ε and ε′ are the stationary residuals from the co-
integration equations. These terms re-introduce the long run information in the levels of the variables that is lost
in first differencing, and thus provide an additional channel, the adjustment of variables towards a long run
equilibrium, through which causality can be detected. For instance, in equation (8), y is said to Granger-cause x,
not only if the θi’s are jointly significant, but also if d1 is significant. Therefore, in contrast to the standard
Granger test, as long as the error-correction term has a significant coefficient, the error-correction model allows
for the possibility that y Granger-causes x even if the θi’s are not jointly significant.

3. RESULT and DISCUSSION


3.1. Unit Root Test Results.
Table 1: Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) stationarity test results
ADF test statistics
Variables Intercept Critical Intercept Critical prob. Remarks

No trend value And trend value

LRGDP -2.020151 -3.621023 -6.635440 -4.219126 0.0000 I(1)


LRAX -6.540730 -3.610453 -6.549601 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
LRIX -6.240128 -3.610453 -6.151209 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
LRSX -7.381334 -3.610453 -7.390909 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
LRIM -8.285444 -3.610453 -8.451934 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)

PP test statistics

LRGDP -4.453935 -3.610453 -6.229825 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)


LRAX -6.538141 -3.610453 -6.573942 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
LRIX -6.409869 -3.610453 -6.284100 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
LRSX -7.530092 -3.610453 -7.559470 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
LRIM -8.201386 -3.610453 -8.694209 -4.211868 0.0000 I(1)
Notes: A variable is stationary when ADF and PP test statistics are greater than the CV at a given level.
Source: E-views version 7 outputs
Table 1 displays the results of ADF and PP unit root test at both intercept with and without trend. At their
levels all-time series have a stochastic trend and indicate that the null hypothesis cannot be rejected for any of
the variables under scrutiny. However, when taking their first differences the tests strongly reject the unit root,
which means that they are integrated of order one i.e. I (1).

46
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

3.2. Co-integration Test Result


3.2.1. Optimal Lag Length Determination.
To determine optimal lag length in this study, the Likelihood Ratio test statistics (LR), the Final Prediction Error
(FPE), the Akaiki Information Criterion (AIC), the Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC)], and the Hannan-Quinn
Information Criterion (HQ) statistics are employed and all them suggest lag length one as maximum lag.(see
table 2)
Table 2: Optimal Lag Order Selection Criteria
Lag LogL LR FPE AIC SC HQ
0 -73.49199 NA 3.85e-05 4.025230 4.238508 4.101752
1 82.22218 263.5163* 4.79e-08* -2.678061* -1.398398* -2.218929*
2 105.7490 33.78216 5.51e-08 -2.602515 -0.256467 -1.760773
Note: * indicates lag order selected by the criterion

Table 3: VAR Wald Lag-Exclusion Test


LRGDP LRAX LRIX LRSX LRIM Joint
5265.412 223.7582 230.6686 689.8812 984.0292 6053.455
Lag 1 [ 0.000000] [ 0.000000] [ 0.000000] [ 0.000000] [ 0.000000] [ 0.000000]
df 5 5 5 5 5 25
Note: The values are chi-squared test statistics for lag exclusion: Numbers in [ ] are p-values
The Wald Lag-Exclusion Test results in table 3 further confirm the lags with significant information content
are not disembodied from the VAR system and portrays that the first lag which is chosen by all lag selection
criterions as maximum lag is valid. This implies that the fist lags of all variables, individually and jointly, are
significant in the system VAR.
3.2.2. Johansen Co-integration Test Results
Since both the trace test statistic and Max-Eigen statistic are greater than the critical values at zero co-
integrating vector in their respective tests, the null hypothesis of no co-integration(r=0) among the variables is
rejected at the 5% level of significance. In other words, both test statistics indicate the existence of one co-
integrating relationship among variables (see table 4 and table 5)
Table 4: Johansen co-integration tests (Trace)
Null hypothesis Alternative Eigen value Trace Critical Prob.**
hypothesis statistic Value(5%)
r=0* r≥0 0.832604 88.08627 69.81889 0.0009
r≤1 r≥1 0.383785 29.10237 47.85613 0.7635
r≤2 r≥2 0.200912 13.12510 29.79707 0.8858
r≤3 r≥3 0.128374 5.723726 15.49471 0.7279
r≤4 r≥4 0.035409 1.189702 3.841466 0.2754
Source: E-views 7 output. Trace test indicates 1 co-integration equation(s) at the 0.05 level, * denotes rejection
of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level, **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values and r denotes the rank of long
run matrix
Table 5: Johansen co-integration tests (Max-Eigen)
Null hypothesis Alternative Eigen value Max-Eigen Critical Prob.**
hypothesis statistic value (5%)
r=0* r=1 0.832604 58.98389 33.87687 0.0000
r=1 r=2 0.383785 15.97728 27.58434 0.6678
r=2 r=3 0.200912 7.401369 21.13162 0.9364
r=3 r=4 0.128374 4.534025 14.26460 0.7991
r=4 r=5 0.035409 1.189702 3.841466 0.2754
Source: E-views 7 output. Max-Eigen test indicates 1 co-integration equation(s) at the 0.05 level, * denotes
rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level, **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values and r denotes the
rank of long run matrix

3.3. VECM Short Run and Long Run Causality Results


In the previous co-integration analysis the variables under consideration are found to be co-integrated, this
suggests the existence of at least unidirectional causality between the variables but it does not provide the
direction of causality (Engel and Granger, 1987). However, since the lagged residuals which are constructed
from co-integrated equations provide an additional channel through which causality might revealed and also
direct us to differentiate between short run and long run causality, the inclusion of error correction term in testing

47
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

causal relationship among variables is very much important.


Table 6 presents the results of causality based on error correction models. Accordingly it provides direction
of causation, the t-statistics for the error-correction terms and Chi-square statistics for the joint significance of
the lagged independent variables based on Wald test respectively in the causality equations. The statistical
significance of the error-correction term and the Ch-square statistic respectively indicate the presence of long-
run and short-run causality.
Table 6: Causality Results Based on Error Correction Models
Direction of causation Error correction Ch-square Prob.
Term t. Statistic Prob. statistic
From Agricultural Export to GDP -1.147654 0.2534 1.242655 0.2650
From GDP to Agricultural Export -3.131421* 0.0045 0.731530 0.3924
From Industrial Exports to GDP -1.147654 0.2534 0.333324 0.5637
From GDP to industrial Export -3.744876* 0.0010 2.915668 0.0877
From service Exports to GDP -1.147654 0.2534 0.218550 0.6401
From GDP to service Export -5.885740* 0.0000 9.465248* 0.0021
Note: * indicates significance at 5% level
The result in the above table 6 indicates the presence of short run and long run causal relationships between
economic growth, agriculture export, industry export and service export. Owing agriculture export and economic
growth there is no causality between them in the short. Similarly there is no causality between industry and
growth in the short run. However there is unidirectional causality between service export and growth which run
from growth to service export. In the long run it is evident that the results support the hypothesis of long run
causality from economic growth to agriculture export but the reverse causality from agricultural export to
economic growth is not supported. It is also evident the results strengthen the hypothesis of long run causality
from economic growth to industry export and service export but failed to reject the null hypothesis of industry
and service export does not granger cause economic growth in the long run.
Uni-directional causality from economic growth to export is accordance with the advocate of the opposite
causality channel, in which the self-propelled growth of the domestic economy leads to improved
competitiveness and eventually to the expansion of exports. Therefore, this finding is also consistent with the
findings of (Thornton, 1996; Ewetan and Okudua, 2012; Ugwuegbe and Uruakpa, 2013; Armand Gilbert, et al
2013).

3.4. Variance Decompositions


Variance decomposition equipped us with information regarding the magnitude of relationship and the direction
of causation both in the short run and long run. For instance, if disaggregate exports are important for economic
growth; the impact of the shocks on disaggregate exports should be significant on growth and conversely if the
growth in GDP is important to disaggregate exports; the impact of the shocks on GDP should be significant on
disaggregate exports.
The result portrays how much an economic growth own shock is explained by movements in its own
variance and the other variable. Both in the short run and long run the variation in the fluctuation in economic
growth is explained significantly by its own shock. In the short run, after three periods, 97.61 percent of
variation in the fluctuation of LRGDP explained by its owns shock and after eighteen periods 89.76 percent of
forecast error variance of LRGDP explained by owns shock but during this period 3.98 percent, 3.03 and 3.12
percent of forecast error variance of LRGDP explained by the innovations of agriculture, industry and service
export respectively.
Table 7: Variance decomposition of LRGDP:
Period S.E. LRGDP LRAX LRIX LRSX LRIM
1 0.041753 100.0000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000
3 0.072121 97.60950 0.157245 1.105051 0.905631 0.222569
9 0.138427 93.01850 2.092483 2.864758 1.912946 0.111312
18 0.225277 89.75860 3.978720 3.025086 3.124723 0.112868
21 0.253699 89.35760 4.232875 2.923405 3.354383 0.131740
24 0.282468 89.11110 4.393936 2.827676 3.520634 0.146652
28 0.321878 88.91532 4.526203 2.724409 3.674025 0.160047
32 0.363037 88.79610 4.609015 2.649074 3.777638 0.168176
36 0.406450 88.71343 4.666944 2.595112 3.851222 0.173289
40 0.452563 88.65044 4.710905 2.555759 3.906098 0.176794
43 0.464562 88.63685 4.720346 2.547583 3.917704 0.177514
Source: calculation by author using Eviews 7

48
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

In such way compared with industry export the shock in agriculture and service export explained important
variation of fluctuation in GDP. However, since the shock in disaggregate export explained insignificant
variation of fluctuation of economic growth both in the short run and long run, it does not encourage saying
agriculture, industry and service export plays more important role in forecasting and accelerating economic
growth in Ethiopia separately.
Alternatively the variance decomposition of LRAX and variance decomposition of LRIX signify the shock
in economic growth explained significant variation in the forecast error variance of LRAX and of LRIX in the
long run and also variance decompositions of LRSX shows the innovation in economic growth explained
significant variation in the forecast error variance of LRSX both in the short run and long run. Thus, it
encouraged to say economic growth promotes agriculture, industry and service export in Ethiopia separately.

3.5. Impulse Response Function


An impulse response functions signify the response of the system over time to a shock to each of the variables in
the system and measure the importance of next period shocks for future values of a time series. It also provides
information concerning the sign of the causal relationship among the variables and how long would the effect of
the shocks persist in the system.
Table 8 presents the result of impulse response function of economic growth (LRGDP) to a one-standard
deviation shocks in GDP, agriculture export, industry export, service export and import over a 10 years period. A
one standard deviation innovation of disturbance originating from real GDP, future LRGDP increases by 0.04
percent in the first year and further rise in the fifth year to 0.044 and reaches to 0.05 at the end of time horizon.
Table 8: Impulse responses to generalized One S.D innovation response of LRGDP:
Period LRGDP LRAX LRIX LRSX LRIM
1 0.041753 0.018423 0.011011 0.007345 0.023574
2 0.039754 0.017734 0.005542 0.009124 0.022026
3 0.041874 0.021035 0.005442 0.009367 0.024538
4 0.042919 0.022931 0.004087 0.010070 0.026222
5 0.044181 0.024905 0.003313 0.010858 0.028081
6 0.045415 0.026692 0.002758 0.011749 0.029869
7 0.046665 0.028343 0.002443 0.012684 0.031599
8 0.047915 0.029851 0.002308 0.013630 0.033244
9 0.049164 0.031226 0.002317 0.014562 0.034798
10 0.050410 0.032480 0.002433 0.015463 0.036258
Source: calculation by author using Eviews 7
One standard deviation innovation of disturbance coming from agriculture export leads to 0.018 percent
increase in real GDP in the first year and further increases to 0.02 percent in the fifth year and bit by bit reaches
to 0.03 percent at the end of time horizon. Likewise a one-standard deviation shocks disturbance originating
from industry and service export leads to 0.01 percent and 0.007 percent increase in real GDP respectively in the
first period, 0.003 percent and 0.01 rise in real GDP respectively in the fifth years period and 0.002 percent and
0.015 percent increase in real GDP respectively at the end of time horizon.

4. CONCLUSION AND IMPLICATION


To accomplish the objectives of the study econometrics methods of analysis has been employed over the period
1974/75 to 2016/17. Specifically after Johansen co-integration test witnessed the variables are co-integrated;
VECM employed to examine the causality between sectors export and economic growth both in the short run
and long run. The findings reveal in the long run the existence of unidirectional causality which runs from
economic growth to agriculture, industry and service export separately. In the short run economic growth does
cause service export however, it does not cause agriculture and industry export separately. That is there is
unidirectional causal relation only between service export and economic growth and the direction of causation
runs from economic growth to service export. And hence the reason for the existence of positive and significant
long run link between sectors’ export and economic growth is not as a result of export leaded growth rather it is
the economic growth caused export to grow. In sum this finding is quite supportive to the ideas of growth lead
export (GLE) hypothesis and against the ideas of export lead growth (ELG) hypothesis. And hence to expand
and diversify export economic growth should be Strengthen and diversifying in Ethiopia.
Declarations
Acknowledgements
The authors are thankful to almighty God. We are also grateful to national bank of Ethiopia and ministry of
finance and economics development of Ethiopia, with their all staff members of them, for their valuable
assistance during data collection.

49
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development www.iiste.org
ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)
Vol.11, No.3, 2020

Funding
Not applicable
Availability of data and materials
The data that support the findings of this study can be obtained from the authors based on request.
Authors’ contributions
The first author generates idea, formulate methodology, undertaken the data collection, analyzed and interpreted
it up. The second author read and revised the manuscript. Both authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Competing interests
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

REFERENCE
Anwar, Muhammad S. and R. K. Sampath (2000) “Exports and Economic Growth.” Indian Economic Journal.
January – March 1999-2000. Vol. 47, No.3. pp. 79-88.
Balassa, B.(1978), “Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence”; Journal of Development Economics 5:
181-189.
Chu, W., (1988), “Export-led growth and import dependence”, Journal of Development Economics 28, 265-276.
North-Holland
Dawson, P.J. (2005), “Agricultural exports and economic growth in less developed Countries”.
AgriculturalEconomics, No.33, pp. 145 - 152.
Dickey, D. and Fuller W. (1981), “Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit
root”.Econometrica, No.49, pp.1057 - 1072.
Engel,R.F. and C.W.J. Granger. (1987), “Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and
Testing”; Econometrica 55(2):251-276.
Ewetan and Okodua (2013), “Econimetric Analysis of Exports and Economic Growth in Nigeria”. E-mail:
HYPERLINK "mailto:banji.ewetan@covenantuniversity.edu.ng" banji.ewetan@covenantuniversity.edu.ng
Feder, G. (1982), “On Exports and Economic Growth”; Journal of Development Economics 12:5973.
Fernando, U.F.N. (1988), “The Relationship between Exports and Economic Growth in Sri Lanka:an Empirical
Investigation”, Central Bank Staff Studies, Vol.18, No. 1 & 2. pp. 97-126.
Granger, C.W.J. (1969), “Investigating causal relations by econometric and cross-spectral
Method”.Econometrica, 37(3), pp. 424 - 438.
Gujarati, D. (1995), “Basic Econometrics”, 3rd Edition, New York: McGraw-Hill
Hailegiorgis B.(2012),“Export-Led Growth in Ethiopia”: America Journal of Economics. P-ISSN 2166-4951.
Idowu, K.O. (2005), “A Preliminary Investigation into the Causal Relationship between Exports and Economic
Growth in Nigeria”; CBN Economic and Financial Review 43(3): 29-50.
Johansen, S. (1988), “Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors”. Journal of Economic Dynamics andControl,
No.12, 231 - 254.
Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990), “Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on Co-integration with
application to the demand for money”. Oxford Bulletin of Economic and Statistics, No.52, pp. 169 - 210.
Khalafalla, K.Y. and Webb, W.J., 2000, “Exports and Economic Growth UnderStructural Change”: A
Cointegration Analysis of Evidence from Malaysia. International Agricultural Trade and Research,
Working paper 00-1.
Mohamed, Yee Liew and Mzee (2012), “Export Trade and Economic Growth in Tanzania”. Journal of
Economics and Sustainable Development. Vol.3, No.12.
Soressa (2013) “Exports, Domestic Demand and Economic Growth in Ethiopia”. Journal of Economics and
International Finance. Vol. 5(9), pp. 357-372
Tyler, W. (1981), “Growth and export expansion in developing countries”, Journal of Development Economics 9,
pp 121- 30
Ugwuegbe and Uruakpa(2013) , “The Impact of Export Trade on Economic Growth In Nigeria”. International
Journal of Economics, Business and Finance. Vol. 1 PP: 327-34166.
Wong Hock (2006), “Exports, Domestic Demand and Economic Growth in China”: Granger causality analysis,
Some Empirical Evidence, J. Econ. Cooperation.
World Bank (2016), “www.ethiopiainvestor.com-ethiopia-economic”.

50

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy