SSRN Id2085476 Code708923
SSRN Id2085476 Code708923
EFFICIENT FRONTIERS
WORKING PAPER
By
Malcolm Athaide
Electronic
Electroniccopy
copyavailable
availableat:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2085476
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2085476
ABSTRACT
This study focuses on the background and relationship of asset pricing, optimal portfolios and
efficient portfolio frontiers. This has been discussed in light of multiple crisis; right from the Asian
Crisis of 1997, dotcom of 2001 till the financial crisis of 2008. This study tracks the changes in
asset portfolio frontiers based on changes in asset prices in the background of a business cycle. By
applying the portfolio model for an efficient frontier, the paper shows that efficient portfolios are
ones where asset pricing is done with a tactical approach. The efficient portfolio contribution to
asset allocation over cycles uses equity prices to validate the study. The results were obtained,
assuming asset returns to be independent and multivariate normally distributed.
Key words
BACKGROUND
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) was first expressed by French mathematician Louis
Bachelier (1900) and emerged as a prominent theory in the 1960s when Bachelier’s work
began to circulate among contemporary academics. Eugene Fama is generally given
credit as the father of modern EMH as his work provided evidence for the hypothesis,
while he extended and refined the theory. An efficient market is a market that is efficient
in processing information. In an efficient market, prices ‘fully reflect’ available
information (Fama 1970). Fama classified EMH into three forms of efficiency: weak,
strong and semi-strong. The three forms of EMH are commonly distinguished:
Market prices incorporate all information, both publicly available and also that available
only to insiders. If the strong form of the EMH holds, then insider trading is ineffective,
in the sense that its application should not enable investors to obtain higher investment
returns through information that is known only to themselves and not to the general
public.
Market prices incorporate all publicly available information. If the semi-strong form of
the EMH holds, then fundamental analysis based upon such information should not be
able to generate higher investment returns for the investor. Fundamental analysis uses
information concerning the issuer of the security (e.g. turnover, profitability, liquidity,
level of gearing) and general economic and investment conditions (e.g. real interest rates
and inflation) in order to determine the “true” or “fundamental” value of a security and
hence whether or not it is cheap or dear.
Electronic
Electroniccopy
copyavailable
availableat:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2085476
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2085476
Weak form EMH
The market price of an investment incorporates all information contained in the price
history of that investment. If the weak of the EMH holds, then trading rules based only on
historical price data should not be able to generate higher investment returns for the
investor. Such trading rules form the basis of technical analysis. Studies on market
efficiency suggest that the weak and the strong form efficiency hold but there is
significant debate about the semi-strong form efficiency.
LITERATURE REVIEW
In the 1960s and early 1970s, the controversy focused on the extent to which successive
changes in prices of the stocks were independent of each other or whether stock prices
followed a random walk. The early tests to answer this question were conducted by Fama
(1965) and Samuelson (1965), in which they concluded that most of the evidence seems
to have been consistent with the efficient market hypothesis (EMH). Stock prices
followed a random walk model and the predictable variations in equity returns, if any,
were found to be statistically insignificant. Other studies in the US with similar findings
included those of Sharpe (1966), Friend et al. (1970), and Williamson (1972).
Throughout the 1980s, EMH has provided the theoretical basis for much of the research,
and most empirical studies during these years focused on predicting prices from historical
data, while also attempting to produce forecasts based on variables such as P/E ratios
(Campbell and Shiller 1987), dividend yield (Fama and French 1989) and term structure
variables (Harvey 1991)
Efficiency of equity markets has important implications for the investment policy of the
investors. If the equity market in question is efficient researching to find miss-priced
assets will be a waste of time. In an efficient market, prices of the assets will reflect
markets best estimate for the risk and expected return of the asset, taking into account
what is known about the asset at the time. Therefore, there will be no undervalued assets
offering higher than expected return or overvalued assets offering lower than the expected
return. All assets will be appropriately priced in the market offering optimal reward to
risk. Hence, in an efficient market an optimal investment strategy will be to concentrate
on risk and return characteristics of the asset and/or portfolio. However, if the markets
were not efficient, an investor will be better off trying to spot winners and losers in the
market and correct identification of miss-priced assets will enhance the overall
performance of the portfolio Rutterford (1993). EMH has a twofold function - as a
theoretical and predictive model of the operations of the financial markets and as a tool in
an impression management campaign to persuade more people to invest their savings in
the stock market (Will 2006).
The efficiency of stock markets is one of the most controversial and well studied
propositions in the literature. Even if there have been a number of researches and journal
articles, economists have not yet reached a consensus about whether capital markets are
efficient or not. The wide range of studies concerning the efficient market hypothesis in
the literature provides mixed evidences. The studies by Prusty (2007) supports the weak
form efficiency of Indian capital market. There have been some studies (Gupta and Basu
2007; Mishra 2009; Mishra and Pradhan 2009) which do not support the existence of
weak form efficiency in Indian capital market.
Electronic
Electroniccopy
copyavailable
availableat:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2085476
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2085476
Price Expectations
The EMH for the equity market is a statement about the theory that equity prices reflect
the true value of stocks; the absence of arbitrage opportunities in an economy populated
by rational, profit-maximizing agents; and the hypothesis that market prices always fully
reflect available information (Fama 1970). In Jensen (1978), an efficient market is
defined with respect to an information set t if it is impossible to earn economic profits
by trading on the basis of t . Fama (1970) presented a general notation describing how
investors generate price expectations for stocks. This could be explained as (Cuthbertson
1996):
E ( p j ,t 1 | t ) [1 E (r j ,t 1 | t )] p jt (1)
where E is the expected value operator, p j ,t 1 is the price of security j at time t+1, r j ,t 1
is the return on security j during period t+1, and t is the set of information available to
investors at time t.The left-hand side of the formula E ( p j ,t 1 | t ) denotes the expected
end-of-period price on stock j, given the information available at the beginning of the
period t . On the right-hand side, 1 E (r j ,t 1 | t ) denotes the expected return over the
forthcoming time period of stocks having the same amount of risk as stock j.
Under the efficient market hypothesis (EMH), investors cannot earn abnormal profits on
the available information set t other than by chance. The level of over value or under
value of a particular stock is defined as:
x j ,t 1 p j ,t 1 E ( p j ,t 1 | t ) (2)
where x j ,t 1 indicates the extent to which the actual price for security j at the end of the
period differs from the price expected by investors based on the information available
t . As a result, in an efficient market it must be true that:
E ( x j ,t 1 | t ) 0 (3)
This implies that the information is always impounded in stock prices. Therefore the
rational expectations of the returns for a particular stock according to the EMH may be
represented as:
Pt 1 E t Pt 1 ε t 1 (4)
where Pt is the stock price; and t 1 is the forecast error. Pt 1 E t Pt 1 should therefore
be zero on average and should be uncorrelated with any information t . Also
E ( x j ,t 1 | t ) 0 when the random variable (good or bad news), the expected value of
the forecast error is zero:
E t t 1 E t ( Pt 1 E t Pt 1 ) E t Pt 1 E t Pt 1 0 (5)
Tests of the EMH fall under three major categories, tests for random walk in asset prices,
event studies and performance of professional investors. All these tests compare observed
asset returns against returns predicted by the EMH, controlling for systematic risk. One
first need to understand what any assets normal returns should look like; based upon its
level of risk. Therefore, tests of the EMH are joint tests of market efficiency and the asset
pricing model (e.g. the CAPM or APT) used to estimate systematic risk.
Despite the many advances in the statistical analysis, databases, and theoretical models
surrounding the EMH, the main result of all of these studies is to harden the resolve of the
proponents of each side of the debate. Are stock prices too volatile because markets are
inefficient, or due to risk aversion, or dividend smoothing? All three inferences are
consistent with the data. Moreover, new statistical tests designed to distinguish among
them will no doubt require auxiliary hypotheses of their own which, in turn, may be
questioned. More importantly, tests of the EMH may not be the most informative means
of gauging the efficiency of a given market. The Efficient Market Hypothesis is based on
a simple assumption that risk is defined by volatility. According to the theory, investors
are risk adverse: they are willing to accept more risk for higher payoffs and will accept
lower returns for a less volatile investment. It has always been assumed that volatility is
risk which may not be always true.
In reality, the premises listed above are not real: investors don’t always show aversion to
risk, they don’t react promptly to information, their guided by trend (built on past
information) in present strategies. Because of this, the premises that investors are rational,
rate modification is independent and markets are “random walk” can’t be accepted. The
irregular assimilation of information, as it is in reality, can lead to the tendency of random
movement- “biased random walk”, named fractal time series. On the reverse side, the
hypothesis of random movement is supported by the following aspects:
The distribution of outputs isn’t perfectly normal;
The risk of some extreme events is greater than the one supposed by the theory of
efficient markets;
The output has the same distribution regardless of the horizon of time chosen;
Volatility rises with a greater rate than T but after a sufficient period of time it
drops suddenly.
During the 1970s and 1980s, assessment of the EMH was largely confined to econometric
studies. The process of financial deregulation, beginning with the breakdown of the
5
The evidence of financial crisis was not long in coming. A number of developing
countries experienced severe financial crises in the 1990s, even though their governments
had done their best to follow the policy prescriptions of economic liberalism, in particular
by deregulating financial markets and encouraging private investment. The experience of
the US itself provided plenty of evidence against the EMH. The near-collapse and
government-orchestrated rescue of hedge fund LTCM provided a preview of the massive
bailouts of 2008 and 2009, undermining some key assumptions of the EMH in the
process. Even more significantly, the boom and bust in the shares of ‘dotcom’ companies
that promised to generate vast profits from the Internet showed that all the sophistication
and complexity of modern financial markets only served to make possible bigger and
better bubbles.
Asian economies had enjoyed decades of strong growth through policies of export-
oriented industrialisation, rejecting the ‘import replacement’ policies, aimed at economic
self-sufficiency that had been tried and failed elsewhere. From the early 1990s onwards,
they had been engaged in a process of financial deregulation. The Asian financial crisis
cast doubt on the idea that globalization was both inevitable and beneficent, as did the
failure of Washington consensus policies in Argentina. In the dotcom asset bubble,
previous bubbles might have been dismissed on the basis that the markets concerned
weren’t fully informed and transparent, or that speculators were prevented from betting
against the bubble assets and thereby bringing prices back to earth. Although the dotcom
bubble and bust was spectacular, the 2000-01 crash was at least equally significant for the
exposure of corporate fraud on a scale unparalleled (at the time) since the 1920s. The two
biggest frauds, Enron and WorldCom offered a sharp contrast. The Enron frauds relied on
a complex network of trading schemes, special purpose vehicles and elaborate accounting
devices. By contrast, the managers of WorldCom simply invented revenue numbers that
made the company look massively profitable when it was actually losing money hand
over fist.
OPTIMAL PORTFOLIOS
Over the last 50 years, Markowitz' modern portfolio theory (Markowitz 1952) has
become one of the cornerstones of finance theory and is still the most important guide to
constructing portfolios with an optimal trade-off between risk and return. Classical mean
variance optimization, in Markowitz' theory, assumes that an investor will always choose
a portfolio with maximum expected future return given a specific level of portfolio risk,
measured as portfolio variance or standard deviation. Often, the portfolio optimization
algorithm is subject to further constraints like short-selling restrictions or maximum
allocations to a single asset class. Uncertainty about future asset returns is taken into
account by assuming that the asset returns are drawn randomly from a normal
distribution, where the mean and standard deviation are known as well as the paired
correlations between different assets. It is this uncertainty about future returns that
compels us not to put all our eggs in one basket. If one knew future returns exactly, it
would suffice to invest in the single asset with the highest positive future return. But since
one does not know the best performing asset in advance, mean variance optimization
shows us how to allocate our wealth to different assets in order to maximize future return
expectations.
Portfolio Optimisations
According to the CAPM theory, a portfolio that lies in the efficient frontier and combined
with certain proportion of risk free investment, and given a desired risk level, maximizes
the return of the combined portfolio. This definition is valid even if the desired risk level
is less than the minimum defined by the efficient frontier. Given the risk free rate of
return, how to determine the optimal risky portfolio? That optimal risky portfolio is just
the point of tangency between the Capital Market Line and the efficient frontier. As this
optimal portfolio has to lie along the efficient frontier; the point of tangency is located at
the line with the maximum tangent between that line and the horizontal line. It is not
necessary to generate indifference curves or even the efficient frontier given the
Separation Theorem posited by Tobin. According to the CAPM theory, the investor will
prefer a position in the “market portfolio” either levered or unlevered. Then, the optimal
portfolio is given by this optimization problem (Vélez-Pareja 2001)
s.t. (6)
where i is the weight of stock i in the portfolio, is the covariance between stocks k
and j, Rm is the portfolio return, r is the risk-free rate of return and m is the number of
stocks in the analysis. The restriction that the s be positive might be included. In that
case there is no short position. This can be seen in the next figure
Asset Allocation
The figure below shows the efficient frontier which is a set of risk and return for the
portfolio at different combination of the assets. This hyperbola is called the opportunity
set as it represents all the possibilities, however only the upper half above the minimum
variance point represents the efficient set as it gives the maximum return for a given risk.
According to CAPM(Capital asset pricing model), the maximum return for any investor
can be obtained by a combination of the risky portfolio represented by the efficient
frontier and the risk free portfolio which are the Government bonds.The capital market
line which represents the different combinations will be a tangent to the efficient frontier
as it gives the investor the maximum utility.Selection of these proportions will depend on
the risk aversion of the investor.
For a risk averse investor his portfolio will lie on the line which is a tangent to the
efficient frontier on the left side half of the tangency point whereas in the case of a risk
taking investor this will lie on the right half which suggests that a risk taking investor will
borrow at the risk free rate and invest in the risk portfolio. It is found that the risky
portfolio giving the maximum portfolio return is the market portfolio consisting of all
risky assets in proportions of their market capitalizations.
Most asset allocation analyses use the mean-variance approach for analyzing the trade-off
between risk and expected return. Analysts use quadratic programming to find optimal
asset mixes and the characteristics of the capital asset pricing model to determine
reasonable optimization inputs (Sharpe 2007).
Many institutional investors periodically adopt an asset allocation policy that specifies
target percentages of value for each of several asset classes. Typically, a policy is set by
the fund manager within a specified range around the policy target level. Most asset
allocation studies include at least some analyses that use standard mean-variance
optimization procedures and incorporate at least some of the aspects of equilibrium asset-
pricing theory based on mean-variance assumptions— typically, a standard version of the
Mean-Variance Analysis
Much of modern investment theory and practice builds on the Markowitz (1952)
assumption that an investor need be concerned in many cases solely with the mean and
variance of the probability distribution of his or her portfolio return over a specified
future period. Given this assumption, only portfolios that provide the maximum mean
(expected) return for given variance of return warrant consideration. One can hence
consider a representative set of such mean-variance-efficient portfolios of asset classes in
an asset allocation study and choose the one that best meets the investor’s preferences in
terms of the range of relevant future outcomes over one or more future periods.
A focus on only the mean and variance of portfolio return can be justified in one of three
ways. First, if all relevant probability distributions have the same form, mean and
variance may be sufficient statistics to identify the full distribution of returns for a
portfolio. Second, if an investor wishes to maximize the expected utility of portfolio
return and considers utility a quadratic function of portfolio return, only mean-variance-
efficient portfolios need be considered. Thirdly, over the range of probability distributions
to be evaluated; a quadratic approximation to an investor's true utility function may
provide asset allocations that supply expected utility adequately close to that associated
with a fully optimal allocation (Levy and Markowitz 1979).
Asset allocation studies often explicitly assume that all security and portfolio returns are
distributed normally over a single period (for example, a year). If this were the case, the
focus on mean-variance analysis would be appropriate, no matter what the form of the
investor's utility function. But there is increasing agreement that at least some return
distributions are not normally distributed, even over relatively short periods, and that
explicit attention needs to be given to "tail risk" arising from greater probabilities of
extreme outcomes than those associated with normal distributions. In comparison
quadratic utility functions are characterized by a satiation level of return beyond which
the investor prefers less return to more—an implausible characterization of the
preferences of most investors. To be sure, such functions have a great analytical
advantage and may serve as reasonable approximations for some investors' true utility
functions. Although mean-variance analysis may provide a sufficient approximation in a
given setting to produce an adequate asset allocation, it would seem prudent to evaluate
the efficacy of the traditional approach by at least conducting an alternative analysis
based on detailed estimates of possible future returns and the best possible representation
of the investor's preferences. Given such a set of forecasts, one can show below how an
optimal portfolio would be chosen if one used a traditional mean-variance analysis; then,
present the more general approach that can take into account an alternative form of an
Mean-Variance Optimization
Quadratic programming algorithms can be used to find the portfolio that provides the
maximum expected return for a given level of standard deviation of return (Markowitz
1952). Solving such a quadratic programming problem for each of several different levels
of standard deviation of return or variance (standard deviation squared) can provide a set
of mean-variance-efficient portfolios for use in an asset allocation study.
Solving the above for various levels of risk tolerance provides a set of mean-variance-
efficient portfolios. For any given risk tolerance, a mean-variance optimization requires
the following inputs:
forecasts of asset return standard deviations,
forecasts of correlations among asset returns,
expected asset returns,
the investor's risk tolerance, and
any relevant constraints on asset holdings.
The goal is thus to maximize the equation . The first step in a mean-variance
optimization is to compute the expected returns, standard deviations, and correlations of
the assets from the forecasted returns (Table I) and probabilities of states. Table II
provides these expected returns and standard deviations; and shows the correlations.
In this example, there are no constraints on asset holdings other than that the sum of the
proportions invested in the assets equals 1. The resulting mean-variance-optimal portfolio
is composed as shown in the first column of Table IV.
Efficient Frontiers
Merton (1972) showed that the efficient frontier in the mean-variance space is the upper
part of the parabola given by
(16)
where the coefficients a = μ’ Σ-1μ, b = 1’ Σ−1μ and c = 1’ Σ−11 fully define the location
of the vertex and the slope coefficient. The set (a, b, c) is known as the efficient set
constants. Rewriting (16) one obtains
with (9)
11
Investment committees can decide to modify the long-term strategic asset allocation in
the medium term – say 5 years – following the eruption of factors which have an impact
on asset expected returns precisely in the medium-term. These factors can be structural
changes in the investment environment and/or economic cycles. For example, a long-term
strategic international equity portfolio may have a proportion of 20% of its stocks
invested in the Chinese market. However, if there are structural reforms in the Chinese
banking system with a likely negative influence on domestic activity in the medium-term
may have a negative impact on the Chinese expected equity returns for that time horizon.
As a result, investment managers could decide to significantly reduce the strategic
proportion of Chinese stocks for the medium-term horizon (i.e. 5 years).
At the end of the expansion period/beginning of the contraction period, interest rates will
usually reach a relative maximum, while stock markets should start to turn bearish for a
while, as profit expectations become less optimistic. Accordingly, at this moment of the
cycle, it would be wise to raise the bond proportion with respect to stocks in a diversified
portfolio. Conversely, at the end of a contraction period/beginning of the expansion
period, interest rates are at their lows, following the weak level of activity and lower
inflation. Concerning the stock market, after a long period of stagnation or fall, company
profits should start to recover, while the required risk premium of market participants is at
its highest, as people do not yet have a clear view of profit prospects. The conditions are
established for starting a period of high equity returns and relatively low bond returns.
Thus, during these times, it is convenient to raise the proportion of stocks to bonds.
Tactical asset allocation is commonly defined as the change in the proportion of assets of
a portfolio in response to significant expected returns which should be partly materialized
in a relative short period of time, say, three to six months. Typically, these tactical
expected returns are the result of a sudden and often a large change in the required risk
premium of investors (translating into a large change in market prices), who may be
overreacting to a particular piece of information arriving to the market. For instance, the
Russian default in August 1998, followed by the September crisis of the huge hedge fund
Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) resulted in a sharp increase of the required risk
premium of European markets, which fell by 20% during those two months. At that
period, the economic situation in Europe was quite favourable, with company profits
growing soundly. Eventually, it turned out that the market had overestimated the impact
of the crisis on the European financial system and equity markets recovered significantly
in October, though helped by the reduction of the US Fed Funds rate. If the deviation
12
We construct a market portfolio consisting of only 3 Securities ‐ RIL, L&T and ONGC.
2001
2007
Return 13.60% 8.50% 12.70% 6.70% 63.90% 36.10%
Std devn 6.20% 5.10% 5.70% 0%
Market cap 0.34 0.27 0.39
Rtn 0.11872
Std Devn 11% Std devn 9.07%
2010
Return 12% 7.50% 13.10% 7.50% 70.00% 30.00%
Std Devn 5% 4.70% 6.70% 0%
Market Cap 41% 0.28 0.31
Rtn 11%
Std Devn 11% Std devn 9.30%
13
CONCLUSIONS
Since last few decades many researchers and analysts have been trying to examine the
efficient market hypothesis in the asset portfolio pricing and capital market. Despite their
novel attempt, the EMH hypothesis remains a controversial issue. During any bubble,
many believe that “this time it’s different and the old rules no longer apply”. Such an
attitude was certainly true of the Asian bubble, dot com bubble, LTCM and Financial
Crisis of 2008. I believe that EMH is a model that is ideal in nature and good to start with
when evaluating market behaviour. However, it is not bulletproof and do not believe that
it rationally explains market behaviour in many instances. The concepts within
behavioural finance shed some light on the human biases that may explain the
breakdowns in EMH. I believe these inefficiencies can be exploited by long-term
investing in high quality, sustainable businesses.
Most asset allocation analyses use the mean-variance approach for analyzing the trade-off
between risk and expected return. Analysts use quadratic programming to find optimal
asset mixes and the characteristics of the capital asset pricing model to determine
reasonable optimization inputs. This article also presents a view on asset allocation and
an optimal portfolio. The goal of asset allocation is to maximize expected utility, where
the utility function may be more complex than that associated with mean-variance
analysis. This can be done by an active approach of active portfolio management or a
passive approach of through-the-door approach.
14
Different levels of asset allocation can be defined, which will depend mainly on the
information used in the allocation decision process. More precisely, we made the
distinction between long-term asset allocation and fundamental-driven asset allocation,
conditional on the equilibrium expected returns in the medium term. Typically defined for
a period of around 5 years, these returns are the mirror of the “normal” expected
premiums of the financial assets, consistent with the economic cycle and/or structural
changes of the economic/financial environment.
REFERENCES
Bachelier, L. (1900). "Theorie de la Speculation." Cambridge : MIT 1964: Paul Cootner : The Random nature
of Stock Market Prices.
Black, F. (1972). "Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing." Journal of Business 45(July):
444-455.
Campbell, J. Y. and R. J. Shiller (1987). "Cointegration and tests of present value models." Journal of
Political Economy 95: 1062-1088.
Cuthbertson, K., Ed. (1996). Quantitative financial economics: stocks, bonds, foreign exchange. John Wiley
and Sons. London.
Fama, E. (1965). "The Behavior of Stock Market Prices." Journal of Business 38(34-105).
Fama, E. (1970). "Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work." Journal of Finance
25: 383-417.
Fama, E. and K. R. French (1989). "Business conditions and expected returns to stocks and bonds." Journal of
Financial Economics 25: 23-50.
Friend, I., M. Blume, et al., Eds. (1970). Mutual funds and other institutional investors: a new perspective
McGraw-Hill. New York.
Gupta, R. and P. K. Basu (2007). "Weak Form Efficiency in Indian Stock Markets." IBER Journal 6(3): 57-
64.
Harvey, C. R. (1991). "The world price of covariance risk." Journal of Finance 46: 111-157.
Jarrow, R. A., Ed. (1988). Finance Theory. New Jersey.
Jensen, M. (1978). "Some anomalous evidence regarding market efficiency." Journal of Financial Economics
12: 33-56.
Levy, H. and H. Markowitz (1979). "Approximating Expected Utility by a Function of Mean and Variance."
American Economic Review 69(3): 308-317.
Markowitz, H. (1952). "Portfolio selection." Journal of Finance 7: 77-91.
Merton, R. C. (1972). "An analytical derivation of the efficient frontier." Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 7: 1851-1872.
Mishra, P. K. (2009). "Indian Capital Market - Revisiting Market Efficiency." Indian Journal of Capital
Markets II(5): 30-34.
Mishra, P. K. and B. B. Pradhan (2009). "Capital Market efficiency and Financial Innovation - A Perspective
Analysis." The Research Network 4(1): 1-5.
Prusty, S. (2007). "Market Efficiency and Financial Markets Integration in India." Indian Journal of
Economics and Business
Rutterford, J. (1993). Introduction to Stock Exchange Investment. London.
Samuelson, P. A. (1965). "Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly." Industrial Management
Review 6: 41-50.
Sharpe, W. F. (1966). "Mutual fund performance." Journal of Business January
Sharpe, W. F. (1985). "Asset Allocation Tools." Scientific Press.
Sharpe, W. F. (2007). "Expected Utility Asset Allocation." Financial Analysts Journal 63(5).
Vélez-Pareja, I. (2001). Optimal Portfolio Selection Bogotá, Colombia, Department of Management,
Universidad Javeriana: 8.
Will, M. (2006). The Role of Performances in an Accounting Scandal: An Insiders Perspective on How
Things Went Wrong. 5th Global Conference on Business & economics, Cambridge University,
Paper 152.
Williamson, J. (1972). "Measuring mutual fund performance." Financial Analysts Journal November /
December.
15