Bitcoin
Bitcoin
net/publication/327571604
CITATION READS
1 1,385
2 authors:
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Md SAJJAD Hosain on 11 September 2018.
ABSTRACT
Bitcoin is a digital cryptocurrency that has attracted substantial interest in recent
years from the general public, profit seekers, risk takers, academic practitioners,
and, last but not least, economists. Although it is referred to as new, Bitcoin has
existed since 2009 and is rooted in technology that goes back even farther. It was
the first established cryptocurrency, with the first trade in 2010. Since 2015,
Bitcoin has attracted even more attention because of its increase in value and
volume of exchange. The Bitcoin system maintains a global, distributed
cryptographic ledger of transactions, or blockchain, through a consensus algorithm
running on hardware scattered around the world. This paper discusses the nature
of cryptocurrency and blockchain, how it works, and the present status of Bitcoin
blockchain in different countries around the world. The paper also includes a
review of literature on Bitcoin engineering, Bitcoin as currency and the
cryptocurrency system, related work on queuing theory, and work on competition
and monopoly. The paper explores three possible outcomes with regard to the
future prospects of Bitcoin. The various aspects of this technology are yet to be
revealed in detail, but the authors hope that this simple, basic, and narrative paper
will be helpful to those seeking basic references regarding this newest issue.
1. INTRODUCTION TO BITCOIN
Bitcoin is a peer-to-peer cryptocurrency used mainly for monetary
transactions on the Internet (Nakamoto, 2014). It is intended to be similar to flat
money and commodities. Bitcoins are inherently valueless, their worth being
determined by those trading in them (O’Dwyer & Malone, 2014). Though it was
established in 2009, Bitcoin has generated a massive amount of interest in the
media recently and has inspired a wave of copycat currencies (Litecoin, Gaelcoin,
etc.) and even a fully working parody currency (dogecoin). It has also generated
interest in intellectual circles because of issues it creates regarding user privacy
(Androulaki et al., 2013), because of attempts to gain insight into its use in
transactions (Meiklejohn et al., 2013), and because of attempts to better understand
its implications as a payment system (Karame et al., 2012).
Bitcoin is a kind of digital currency in which encryption techniques are used
to control the generation of units of currency and to verify the transfer of funds,
operating independently of a central bank. Bitcoins are produced by users who
“mine” them by lending computing power to verify other users’ transactions. They
are stored in a “digital wallet,” which exists either in the cloud or on a user’s
computer. The wallet is a kind of virtual bank account that allows users to send or
receive bitcoins, pay for goods, or save their money (Anderson et al., 2017). The
major difference between physical currency (e.g., GBP or US dollar) and bitcoins
or between bank accounts and Bitcoin wallets is that physical currency and bank
accounts insured by the Financial Services Compensation Scheme (FSCS) in the
United Kingdom or the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) in the
United States, whereas bitcoins and Bitcoin wallets are not.
Fundamental to Bitcoin is a public ledger, acknowledged as the blockchain.
At the beginning, a new “block” was added to this chain or ledger every 10 minutes
(although it can take more than an hour today). This ledger records all of the
transactions that have occurred, as well as the quantities of bitcoins that are in
possession at singular public addresses, each having a related classified key. The
owner of the private key has the authority to transfer the digital coins that are held
at that specific address only. Each key is 51 characters long, in the same format as
a public address. To spend an amount of bitcoins, one must use his or her private
key to cryptographically sign the transaction, sending the bitcoins to another
address. This message or transaction is then transmitted to the network, and the
computers in the network begin to record that the address no longer has the amount
that was sent, but that it is now held at the receiving address. All of the computers
that are working to write new blocks to the blockchain are known as miners. These
computers are all racing to solve a cryptographic puzzle, which is required to write
the new block. The computer that solves the algorithm and writes the new block
receives an award of newly created bitcoins, now worth more than $7,000 each
(Anderson et al., 2017).
chain on top of his or her block. Other miners will build on top of his or her block
only if they consider it legally incentivizing to assemble and create legal blocks.
Consensus forms on a ledger that includes the new block. The process continues
in the same manner for the following 10 minutes, on average, and so on (Eyal &
Sirer, 2014)
The miner who produces a block is paid from two sources. One consists of
newly minted coins, the exact number of which is protocol-determined and
decreases with time. Crediting successful miners with newly minted coins moves
the system early on from having zero balances to having positive ones. The second
source consists of the fees offered by the transactions in the mined block
(Huberman et al., 2017).
According to Huberman et al., (2017), this system will have the following
desired properties:
1. All miners are synchronized to hold the same ledger of processed
transactions.
2. No single miner controls the system, because every 10 minutes the ability
to process transactions is given to a randomly chosen miner.
3. Balances change only with a legal transaction because any transaction that
is added is vetted by other miners to be valid, and transactions cannot be
deleted from the ledger.
4. RELATED LITERATURE
As relatively new concepts, Bitcoin and blockchain are the subject of only a
few previous studies. Very recently, however, they began attracting the curiosity
of researchers and continue to do so. This section reviews the studies that have
been completed on the engineering of Bitcoin (Table 1) and the use of bitcoins as
currency and the cryptocurrency market (Table 2), and discusses related work in
queuing theory, as well as work on competition and monopoly.
Table 1
Literature on Bitcoin Engineering
Table 2
Literature on Bitcoin Use as a Currency and on the Cryptocurrency Market
queuing system with batch service inspired by Bitcoin, but do not consider user
incentives or equilibrium considerations.
4.2. Work on Competition, Monopoly, and Its Regulation
The social welfare implications of monopolistic versus competitive provision
of a goods or service is of utmost concern to economic analysis, often leading to a
debate regarding the extent to which regulation is desired and the best means
through which to accomplish it (Huberman et al., 2017). According to Posner
(1975), a model of the social cost of monopoly and monopoly-inducing regulation
(Narayanan et al., 2016) assumes that competition to obtain a monopoly results in
a conversion of monopoly profits into social costs. A major conclusion is that
public regulation is perhaps a larger source of social cost than private monopoly.
A Posner-inspired explanation of mining is that, when a block is completed (i.e.,
the hard riddle has been solved by one of the miners), the solving miner is a
monopolistic winner who takes all the revenues associated with the completion of
that block. The social cost of one miner’s winning is the amount spent by the
community of miners to try to solve the hard puzzle. Noteworthy is that the
monopolist is not a price-setter, in contrast with standard monopoly models,
including Posner’s (Huberman et al., 2017).
Table 3
Reactions to Bitcoin Around the World
--Continued
Table 3 (Cont’d)
6. FUTURE PROSPECTS
The future of Bitcoin is unknown. This means that the progression of Bitcoin
can go in any direction, which is currently and slowly evolving before our eyes.
There are too many speculations and opinions regarding its future. So far, when
cataloging the possibilities, three dissimilar outcomes rise to the top (Andersson &
Wegdell, 2014):
1. Bitcoin becomes a globally recognized currency used all over the place,
possibly even eliminating cash and credit cards.
2. Bitcoin remains active and fine, but performs in the background. Rather
than being a major currency, it could function as an attribute and an
accompaniment to the global financial sector. Just as the English language
has spread around the world without eliminating existing languages,
Bitcoin could spread around the world as a global payment system, co-
existing with other world currencies.
3. Bitcoin prices collapse to their inherent value. The collapse could take the
form of a sudden fizz or a slow fade over time. Either way, it ceases to
survive in the public eye and is ultimately forgotten as the years pass.
Although priced identically (in bitcoins) for two consecutive days, the price of the
cup of coffee during day two (in USD) could be half the price, twice the price, 10
times the price, or whatever the currency happens to be on that day. This means
that sellers who accept bitcoin payments must constantly adjust the prices of their
goods in order to represent their current value in USD (Yermack, 2013).
Many people around the globe are using Bitcoin as anticipated, hoping that
one day it will be acknowledged as a globally accepted currency. For Bitcoin to
function as a currency, it is also essential that its velocity increase and that more
people start using it to purchase goods and services. At present, however, the
typical users do not. So far, the majority of users are speculative investors who
have recently seen the possibilities of an investment profit as media coverage
increased and the price skyrocketed (Andersson & Wegdell, 2014). According to
Fred Ersham, co-founder of the digital wallet service Coinbase, about 80% of
transaction activity is related to speculation (Goldman Sachs, 2014).
6.2. Possibility 2: Complementary and Attributive Currency
If Bitcoin could by some means become a more controlled and stable
currency, this way of transferring money globally has the prospect of entirely
knocking out its present competition (i.e., cash offices). In 2013, remittances sent
by immigrants to 33 developing countries amounted to $401 billion, and this
amount was projected to increase to $515 billion by 2015 (The World Bank, 2013).
This money usually flows through third parties such as MoneyGram or Western
Union. In the first quarter of 2014, the global average total price of remittances
was 8.36%, which was a lifetime low (The World Bank, 2014). For this reason,
Bitcoin has a huge advantage over cash offices as a medium of exchange. In this
case, its volatility would not be a very big obstacle either. Money could be
exchanged to bitcoins, cheaply sent around the world, and exchanged back to a
regular currency. To do this, however, the recipient would have to have an account
on an exchange platform in order to sell the bitcoins and receive the money. The
exchange used must also be able to provide withdrawals in the currency wanted,
and, at present, many developing countries do not provide this service (Andersson
& Wegdell, 2014).
In addition to having a wide range of applications, Bitcoin could also give rise
to new lines of products and services such as micro-payments. Until now,
micropayments of less than $1 have had little success because of the
impracticalities inherent in a transaction of this kind. Bitcoin enables extremely
small payments at a reasonable cost, making the market for micro-payment
services very much alive in a way they have not been before. It would enable a
more convenient “pay-as-you-go” world where people could pay very small
amounts for very small services or goods. Present transaction fees (using, for
example Visa, MasterCard, or PayPal) make these types of purchases impractical
as they easily could equal or even exceed the purchase price itself (Andersson &
Wegdell, 2014). One example of a micro-payment like this could be paying for
Wi-Fi access by the kilobyte when one passes a Wi-Fi hotspot (Bitcoin.org.).
Besides micro-payments and cost efficiency, other positive characteristics of
Bitcoin are its global accessibility, the possibility of multi-signature accounts, and
simplification of donations/crowd-funding. Its global accessibility allows
everyone with an Internet connection to take part in the network, thereby
increasing global access to commerce and possibly helping international trade to
flourish. Multi-signature accounts allow accounts to be shared by 34 groups of
people and do not allow any transactions to take place unless all the members are
unanimous about it. This could be of great value to, for example, a board of
directors, to make sure that no company money is spent without the knowledge of
all (Bitcoin.org.).
Crowd-funding is a type of fund raising in which members of a group each
contribute a small amount of money and collectively work toward a unanimous
economic goal. The goal could be a project such as a non-profit, political, or
philanthropic campaign (Canada Media Fund, 2012) With the help of Bitcoin
technology, there is a possibility of even pledging money to a project, but not
collecting it from anyone until the main economic target is reached (Andersson &
Wegdell, 2014).
When the website WikiLeaks announced that it needed donations to continue
its work, both Visa and MasterCard denied donations by the general public
(because of political pressure), causing donations in bitcoins to skyrocket
(Matonis, 2012). The reason is that a Bitcoin transaction cannot be stopped by any
authority. Also, in case of a catastrophe such as a natural disaster, Bitcoin
donations could be very useful in quickly and cheaply organizing an international
response, with the money arriving long before any normal currency could
(Andersson & Wegdell, 2014).
The fact that money can be programmable opens a world of possibilities. It
could be regarded as an extrinsic value; that is, the value assigned to an object
through external factors. Activities such as “earmarking” money could become
common in the future. Earmarking would make it impossible to spend the money
unless it is spent in the way intended. Earmarking could be used, for example, to
program economic support to Third World countries so the money can be used
only for medical treatment or food and not for weapons, or it could be used by
parents to program their children’s allowances so that they cannot buy cigarettes
or alcohol, but only school lunches (Andersson & Wegdell, 2014). In this way, it
would be similar to the U.S. system of food stamps for people on public assistance.
Other applications for programmed money are cloud services. Money can be stored
in clouds and programmed to be released, piece by piece or all at once, at a certain
point. This could be, for example, on a child’s 18th birthday or even after one’s
death (Wilhelm, 2013).
6.3. Possibility 3: Fading Away or Crashing
In the event that Bitcoin becomes extinct, it seems that there are two possible
ways it might do so. One way is for it to die gradually as people lose hope and
interest. The second way is for something extreme to happen that makes public
interest change overnight from great to non-existent. In either way, this event
would have to be something so major that Bitcoin cannot fight back against it
(Andersson & Wegdell, 2014).
7. BITCOIN: A PONZI SCHEME?
A Ponzi scheme (sometimes called a Ponzi game) is a fraudulent investment
operation in which the operator provides fabricated reports and generates returns
for prior investors through revenue paid by new investors, rather than from
legitimate business activities or the profit of financial trading. Operators of Ponzi
schemes can be either individuals or corporations. In either case, they grab the
attention of new investors by offering short-term returns that are either abnormally
high or unusually consistent (Frankel, 2012).
Among the many theories in circulation about why Bitcoin was formed is the
suspicion that it may, in fact, be a Ponzi scheme or some other trick in disguise.
Some skeptics, such as American economist Nouriel Roubini, have emphasized
the view that the whole system could be a Ponzi scheme (Andersson & Wegdell,
2014). Another theory is that Bitcoin was formed, not as a fraud, but as a reaction
to the global financial crisis in 2008, when there was great malcontent concerning
the present financial system. The idea of a decentralized currency may have many
positive sides, but it also has some downsides such as instability and the lack of a
safety net for users.
A Ponzi scheme is an unsustainable business model that promises the investor
great profit opportunities. It is made possible in the short run because the profit
returns are, in fact, money collected from new investors and given to earlier
investors. The new investors, in turn, receive returns paid by even newer investors.
In this manner, the pyramid grows, creating the illusion that all participants are
profiting from a legitimate business (FBI, n.d.).
In the long run, a Ponzi scheme is unsustainable because it can operate only
as long as more people join and supply a steady, new flow of money. In other
words, it is dependent on an ever-growing supply of enthusiastic participants and
will, in time, collapse. The collapse happens for two reasons: because the original
operator disappears with all the money, or because no new participants can be
found to supply previous investors with the money promised to them. (FBI, n.d.)
There is a risk that people like Bitcoin founder Satoshi Nakamoto and the
early adopters, who have accumulated millions of dollars, might one day start
selling their bitcoins and pulling out of the system. This scenario can happen
without the rest of the world being aware of it or realizing that the “scammers” are
deserting. Soon after, the fairy tale is likely to be over. The price could fall
precipitously, and there would be no regulations whatsoever to help innocent third-
party investors who have exposed themselves to the risks. The similarities with a
classic “pump and dump” strategy would become obvious and hard to ignore.
Attempts have been made to estimate how many bitcoins founder Satoshi
Nakamoto is sitting on, and the number is expected to be around 1 million BTC,
making him worth approximately $1 billion in December 2013 (Andersson &
Wegdell, 2014).
8. CONCLUSIONS
We have observed gold became cash and cash became credit cards. Is the next
step cryptocurrencies? It would be interesting to see whether Bitcoin finds a place
in our financial world today. It is very unlikely that it will become a real currency.
Its properties are poorer on all aspects of being a performing currency besides
acting as a medium of exchange. In theory, one solution to solve the store of value
problem could be to nail it to, for example, the US dollar, making it more stable
and predictable. Also, the unit of account difficulties would grasp to exist as people
could more easily measure and compare prices and goods in bitcoins. But, in
reality, this will never happen since the Bitcoin network is programmed to be
decentralized and unmanageable. The whole idea of Bitcoin is that it is
independent from a central entity and the price will go wherever the market drives
it. Legislation cannot solve the issue this since it would entail a comprehensive
conformity.
REFERENCES
Anderson, T.; Scanlon, L.; & Smith, C.C. (2017). Bitcoin, Blockchain & Initial Coin
Offerings: A Global Review, Pinsent Masons.
Andersson, G., & Wegdell, A. (2014). Prospects of Bitcoin: An evaluation of its future,
Master Thesis presented on Spring 2014 at the Department of Economics, School of
Economics and Management, Lund University.
Androulaki, E.; Karame, G.O.; Roeschlin, M.; Scherer, T.; & Capkun, S. (2013).
Evaluating user privacy in bitcoi, In: Proceedings of the International Conference
on Financial Cryptography and Data Security, Springer, Heidelberg, 34–51.
Athey, S.; Parashkevov, I.; Sarukkai, V.; & Xia, J. (2016) Bitcoin pricing, adoption, and
usage: Theory and evidence, Stanford University Graduate School of Business
Research paper No. 16-42. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2826674.
Babaioff, M.; Dobzinski, S.; Oren, S.; & Zohar, A. (2012). On bitcoin and red balloons, In:
Proceedings of the 13th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, ACM, 56–73.
Bitcoinfees. (2014). Retrieved March 31, 2017. Available at: http://bitcoinfees.com/
Bitcoin.org. (n.d.). Retrieved April 5, 2017. Available at: http://bitcoin.org/
Canada Media Fund. (2012). Crowdfunding in a Canadian context. Retrieved April 16,
2017. Available at: http://www.cmf-
fmc.ca/documents/files/about/publications/CMF-CrowdfundingStudy.pdf
Carlsten, M.; Kalodner, H.; Weinberg, S.M.; & Narayanan, A. (2016). On the instability
of bitcoin without the block reward, In: Proceedings of the 2016 ACM SIGSAC
Conference on Computer and Communications Security, ACM, 154–167.
Catalini, C., & Gans, J.S. (2016). Some simple economics of the blockchain, NBER
Working Paper 22952, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
DOI: 10.3386/w22952
Chiu, J., & Koeppl, T. (2017). The economics of cryptocurrencies – Bitcoin and beyond.
Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3048124 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3048124
Croman, K.; Decker, C.; Eyal, I.; Gencer, A.E.; Juels, A.; Kosba, A.; Miller, A.; Saxena,
P.; Shi, E.; & Gu¨n, E. (2016). On scaling decentralized blockchains, In: Proceedings
of 3rd Workshop on Bitcoin and Blockchain Research.
Easley, D.; O’Hara, M.; & Basu, S. (2017). From mining to markets: The evolution of
bitcoin transaction fees, SSRN Working Paper Series. Available at SSRN:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3055380 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3055380
Eyal, I.; Gencer, A.E.; Sirer, E.G.; & Van Renesse, R. (2016). Bitcoining: A scalable
blockchain protocol, In: 13th USENIX Symposium on Networked Systems Design and
Implementation (NSDI 16), 45–59.
Eyal, I., & Sirer, E G. (2014). Majority is not enough: Bitcoin mining is vulnerable, In:
International Conference on Financial Cryptography and Data Security, Springer,
436–454.
Federal Bureau of Investigation. (n.d.). Common fraud schemes. Retrieved April 28, 2017.
Available at: http://www.fbi.gov/scams-safety/fraud/
Frankel, T. (2012). The Ponzi Scheme Puzzle: A History and Analysis of Con Artists and
Victims, USA: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0199926611.
Gans, J.S., & Halaburda, H. (2015). Some economics of private digital currency,
Economic Analysis of the Digital Economy, University of Chicago Press, 257–276.
Gandal, N., & Halaburda, H. (2014). Competition in the cryptocurrency market, CEPR
Discussion Paper No. DP10151. Available at SSRN:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2501640
Glazer, A., & Hassin, R. (1986). Stable priority purchasing in queues, Operations Research
Letters 4(6), 285–288.
Goldman Sachs Global Investment Research. (2014). All about bitcoin: Top of Mind,
21, 8. March 11.
Hassin, R. (2016). Rational Queueing, 1st ed., Chapman & Hall/CRC Series in Operation
Research, Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press, Taylor & Francis Group.
Hassin, R., & Haviv, M. (2003). To Queue or Not to Queue: Equilibrium Behavior In
Queueing Systems, Vol. 59 of International Series in Operations Research and
Management Science, Springer Science & Business Media.
Hassin, R. (1995). Decentralized regulation of a queue, Management Science 41(1), 163–
173.
Huberman, G.; Leshno, J.D.; & Moallemi, C.C. (2017). Monopoly without a monopolist:
An economic analysis of the Bitcoin payment system, Columbia Business School
Research Paper No. 17-92, Columbia University.
Karame G.O.; Androulaki, E; & Capkun, S. (2012). Double-spending fast payments in
bitcoin, In: Proceedings of the 2012 ACM Conference on Computer and
Communications Security, ACM, 906–917
Kroll, J.A.; Davey, I.C.; & Felten, E.W. (2013). The economics of bitcoin mining, or
bitcoin in the presence of adversaries, In: Proceedings of WEIS, 2013.
Kasahara, S., & Kawahara, J. (2017). Effect of Bitcoin fee on transaction-confirmation
process, Working Paper Series.
Lui, F.T. (1985). An equilibrium queuing model of bribery, Journal of Political Economy
93(4), 760–781.
Matonis, J. (2012). WikiLeaks bypasses financial blockade with bitcoin, Forbes
Magazine, August 20. Available at:
http://www.forbes.com/sites/jonmatonis/2012/08/20/wikileaks-bypasses-
financialblockade-with-bitcoin/
Meiklejohn, S.; Pomarole, M.; Jordan, G.; Levchenko, K.; McCoy, D.; Voelker, G.M.; &
Savage, S. (2013). A fistful of bitcoins: characterizing payments among men with no
names. Paper presented in IMC, 2013, October 23–25, 2013, Barcelona, Spain.
Nakamoto, S. (2014). Bitcoin: A peer-to-peer electronic cash system.
http://fastbull.dl.sourceforge.net/ project/bitcoin/Design\%20Paper/
bitcoin.pdf/bitcoin.pdf
Narayanan, A.; Bonneau, J.; Felten, E.; Miller, A.; & Goldfeder, S. (2016). Bitcoin and
Cryptocurrency Technologies, Princeton University Press.
O’Dwyer, K.J., & Malone, D. (2014). Bitcoin Mining and its Energy Footprint, Hamilton
Institute, National University of Ireland Maynooth Press, ISSC 2014 / CIICT 2014,
Limerick, June 26–27.
Posner, R.A. (1975). The social costs of monopoly and regulation, Journal of Political
Economy 83(4), 807–827.
Ron, D. & Shamir, A. (2013). Quantitative analysis of the full bitcoin transaction graph,
In: Proceedings of International Conference on Financial Cryptography and Data
Security, Springer, 6–24.
Sapirshtein, A.; Sompolinsky, Y.; & Zohar, A. (2016). Optimal selfish mining strategies in
bitcoin. In: Proceedings of International Conference on Financial Cryptography and
Data Security, Springer, 515–532.
Tanenbaum, A.S., & Van Steen, M. (2007), Distributed Systems: Principles and
Paradigms, Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
The Economist. (2014). Money from nothing. The Economist, March 15. (Retrieved May
3, 2017). Available at: http://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-
economics/21599053-chronicdeflation-may-keep-bitcoin-displacing-its-fiat-rivals-
money
The World Bank. (2013). World Bank Launches Initiative on Migration, Releases New
Projections on Remittance Flows. The World Bank, April 19. (Retrieved April 16,
2017) Available at: http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-
release/2013/04/19/world-bank-launchesinitiative-on-migration-releases-new-
projections-on-remittance-flows
The World Bank. (2014). An analysis of trends in the average total costs of migrant
remittances services, The World Bank, Issue no. 9. (Retrieved April 16, 2017)
Available at: https://remittanceprices.worldbank.org/sites/
default/files/RPW_Report_Mar2014.pdf
Wilhem, A. (2013). Inside Bitcoin, the programmable currency for our digital future,
Techcrunch, September 10. (Retrieved April 4, 2017). Available at:
http://techcrunch.com/2013/09/10/disrupt-sf-13-bitcoin-panel/>
Yermack, D. (2013). Is Bitcoin a real currency? An economic appraisal, NBER Working
Paper No. 19747, National Bureau of Economic Research. DOI: 10.3386/w1947
Zohar, A. (2015). Bitcoin: Under the hood, Communications of the ACM 58(9), 104–113.