The document discusses demand analysis and consumer behavior theories, focusing on the indifference curve analysis as an alternative to the Marshallian utility approach. It explains the assumptions of consumer preferences, the properties of indifference curves, and how they represent combinations of goods that provide equal satisfaction. Additionally, it addresses unusual shapes of indifference curves when goods are considered 'bad' and the implications for consumer choice.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF or read online on Scribd
0 ratings0% found this document useful (0 votes)
29 views10 pages
Consumer Behaviour
The document discusses demand analysis and consumer behavior theories, focusing on the indifference curve analysis as an alternative to the Marshallian utility approach. It explains the assumptions of consumer preferences, the properties of indifference curves, and how they represent combinations of goods that provide equal satisfaction. Additionally, it addresses unusual shapes of indifference curves when goods are considered 'bad' and the implications for consumer choice.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 10
DEMAND ANALYSIS AND THEORY.
fei Seesitute goods
ssncrease in the price of rice,
sises and the demand curve
DD, (Fig, 2.7), a fall in price
OP, increases the quantity
= OX, to OX,. On the otherhand,
curve is D,D,, a rise in price
) causes a movement upward
e demand curve. As a result, the
three approaches in economic
the behaviour of a consumer.
attempt to explain the
25
0 Quantity of pen
(b) Complementary goods
Fig. 28; Shits ofthe Demand Cuve
negative sloping demand curve, The fistapproach
is known as introspective cardinal approach or
Marshallian utility approach, after the name of
its inventor. A. Marshall—the great neo-classical
economist—tefined the utility approach developed
by W. S, Jevons, Carl Menger, and L. Walras,
independently, Marshall just perfected their
analyses. The send approach evolved in the 1930s
‘out of the criticisms levelled against the utility
approch. This approach came to Le known as
introspective ordinal approach. Sir] R. Hicks and
R. G.D.Allen—two great British economists—
employed the tool of indifference curve to explain
this ordinal approach to consumer behaviour
‘The third appraoch was invented by the US
economist P. A. Samuelson in 1938, His approach
came to be known as behaviouristic ordinal
approach. In this book, we will concetrate on
indifference curve analysis only.
An alternative approach to Marshall’ utility
approach is Hicks-Allen’s indifference analysis.
This alternative approach is also known as
‘introspective ordina? approach as contrasted to
Marshall's ‘introspective cardinal’ approach.
According to Marshall, utility obtained from the
consumption of a commodity can be measured
in cardinal numbers, just as we can measure the
body temperature or the day temperature. ButHicks and Allen argued that utility, being a psycho-
logical concept, can never be measured in cardinal
numbers, like 1, 2, 3, ete. Utility is intrinsic in
character and, hence, not quantifiable.
Further, utility varies from person to person.
Hence, utility is a relative as well as a subjective
concept hardly amenable to measurement. If it
can be measured, it can be measured in ordinal
numbers, like, I, II, III, etc. Different levels of
utility derived from the consumption of
commodities can.only be ranked ot ordered. A
consumer can only rank or order his preference
pattern. He cannot say that commodity A gives
utility of 10 while B gives a utility of 13, He can
only compare between A and B and say that A
is preferable to B or B is preferable to A. But
how much utility is obtained from A or from B
cannot be quantified by the consumer. Hence,
the name ‘ordinal approach’ to demand analysis,
2.4.1, INDIFFERENCE CURVE
The indifference curve analysis aims at analysing
the choice between different combinations of
» two goods, without meduring utility in physical
units. The indifference curve analysis argues that
utility is not measurable but comparable. If a
‘Consumer is presented with a number of various
combinations of two goods (say A, B,C, etc..) he
can rank them in a scale of preferences, A is
pteferable to B (or in short APB) or BPA. But,
he cannot say that from A he gets better utility
measured in cardinal numbers.
+ Assumptions: Before defining indifference
curve, we must make the following assumptions:
@ completeriess, i) non-satiety, and (ii) consis-
tency or transitivity,
For simplicity’s sake, let us assume that there
are two goods, X and Y, containing various
quantities of these two goods, We also assume
that preferences are complete. This means that
@ consumer can determine which combination
of X and Yis preferable or which combinations
‘of X and Y yield the same level of satisfaction.
Since the consumer knows the ‘utility value of
all possible choices’ economists say that pre-
ferences are complete.
The assumption of non-satiety states that a
consumer always prefers ‘more of a commodity
to less’, Let situtation A contain more of good
X and good ¥ than the situation B. Obviously,
A.would be preferred to situation B since more
is preferred to less.
The consumer is also expected to behave
consistently If a consumer prefers A to B in any
situation then he must not choose B over A in
other situation. If he chooses, however, B, then
his behaviour is said to be contradictory and
inconsistent.
Further, preferences must be transitive. This
means that if a consumer chooses A over B and
BoverC, then he chooses A over C. If that were
not true, then consumer preferences would not
be transitive. Thus, the assumption of consistency
is related to the assumption of transitivity
0 Good X
Fig. 29: Combinations ofX and ¥
These three assumptions enable us to represent
consumer preferences in a graphic form. As a
result, we obtain indifference curve.
+ Meaning: An indifference curve
represents various combinations of two goods
that yield an equal amount of satisfaction. To
show how such a curve can be constructed, we
consider Fig. 2.9. In this figure we measure good=". suis and good Y on the
ssseng these combiriations.
en of rationality states that
m pecferred to less. Thus, C is
net purchases various
and Y shown in Table 2.4.
esamelevelof consumption
whether he purchases
exBorCorD. This table shows
of ¥ (or X) are consumed,
the use of more of X and less
these points we get a curve
race curve. Our consumer is
es all these points, He cannot
Nia
1 23 4 5 & Goodx
Fig. 210: lnditference Cue
saywhich point is giving him the maximum
satisfaction. As he cannot say which combination
of the two goods gives him the highest
satisfaction he is, therefore, indifferent between
different combinations.
A set of indifference curves plotted on a
graph is called an indifference map. A consumet
is indifferent on an indifference curve and not
between two indifference curves. Higher indiffe-
tence curve represents higher satisfaction and
lower indifference curve represents lower
satisfaction. Hence, utility or satisfaction is
‘comparable. i
‘The indifference curve that we have drawn
is not a straight line. Normally, it slopes
downwards from left to the right.
Now we present important properties of an
indifference curve.
2.4.2. PROPERTIES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVE
An indifference curve has three important
properties:
+ Property 1: It slapes downwards rom left to
right. In other words, it bas a negative slope.
Proof: On an indifference curve, as we move
from one point to another point, an increase in
the consumption of one good will lead to a
decline in the consumption of another good,
so that satisfaction remains the same. This
implies a negatively sloped indifference curve.)
Fig, 211: Unikely shapes
Proof of this negatively sloped indifference
curve can also be made with the help of the
above three figures:
In Fig 2.11(@) IC is parallel to the vertical
axis, indicating that as a consumer moves from
Ato B to C, his consumption of Y rises while
that of X remains the same. The consumer is
indifferent between having mote or less of good
X, Thus, X is a ‘neuter’ good. This means that
if we take 1 unit of X away at point A, then we
need not compensate the consumer his loss of
X with any amount of Y to keep him on the
same indifference curve. In Fig 2.11(b),as [Cis
parallel to the horizontal axis, consumption of
X rises and that of Y remains unchanged. Here
Yis a ‘neuter’ good. To have a negatively sloped
indifference curve, consumption of one good
must rise while that of another must decline,
Indifference curve can never be upward rising,
as drawn in Fig, 2.11(c). Movement from point
‘A to B to C implies that consumption of both
X and Y are rising. Again, this sort of
Table 2.5: Diminising MRS
Combinations —_X ¥ URS y
A 1 6 is
8 2 3
Pat
c 3 24 :
1 i
D 4 BH
Good X
ct indiference Curves:
indifference curve is ruled out because of th
non-satiety assumption: more is preferred t
less, Thus, indifference curve must b
downwand sloping:
+ Property 2: An indifference curve is conve
to the origin, or concave. from above.
Proof: An indifference curve is convex t
the origin due to diminishing marginal rate c
substitution (MRS) between two goods, MR
of X for Y is the rate at which Y must b
sacrificed (o get an additional unit of X so as t
maintain the same level of satisfaction, As th
rate is a diminishing one, an indifference cury
is convex to the origin. This we can prove wit
the aid of Table 2.5
When our consumer gives up combinatio
Ato obtain combination B, he sacrifices 3 uni
of Y to getan additional 1 unit of X. Thus, th
marginal rate of substitution of X for ¥ is 3:
Again, a movement from combination B to
suggests that the consumer now gives up 1 un
of Y to obtain another unit of X. Heno
the MRS becomes 1 : 1. Similarly, this ra
declines to 1:4 when a consumer moves fros
combination C to D. As MRS is diminishin
the indifference curve must be convex to th
origin.
Diagrammaticaly, convexity of an indifferent
curve has been shown in Fig, 2.12. Along t
indifference curve, our consumer is indiffere
between points D, C and B. As the consumfs willing to substitute X,X,
¥. The marginal rate of
DE . CF
Tt is obvious that EC > FB’ This means
that initially our consumer was willing to give
up larger amount of ¥ for an additional unit of
X. Ashe possessed larger quantity of Y, marginal
significance of ¥ to the consumer is less while
that of X is more. But as substitution goes on,
‘marginal significance of Y rises while that of X
declines since the consumer gets more of X and
less of ¥. That is why willingness to sacrifice Y
to get more of X along an indifference curve
declines. This means that MRS declines, for
which IC is convex to the origin. ,
It is to be remembered here that the slope
of an indifference curve is tht MRS. The slope
is -#--8. Thus, the slope is negative.
Slope at a point on an indifference curve ean
be measured by drawing a tangent to that
particulat point. At points D, C and B on an
indifference curve, we have drawn three tangents
in Fig 2.13(a). As we move downwards,
steepness of the tangent declines. Slope of the
tangent at D is steeper than the tangent at C or
B. This means that the slope or MRS declines
So, an indifference curve must be convex to the
origin, Or simply, if an indifference curve liesabove a tangent line drawn atany point on the
Curve, the curves said to be convex to the origin
Fig, 2.13@)),
Again, if a straight line connecting any two
Points (say AA’ or BB’) on the curve lies above
the curve IC (Fig, 2.13(b) the curve is convex to
the origin,
On the other hand, if the tangents lie above
the curve, and a chord ing two points on
the curve lies below the curve, the indifference
curve becomes concave to the origin.
+ Property 3: No two indifference curves tan
Intersect or touch each other,
Proof: If the indifference curves intersect
or touch each other, one will encounter an
absurd result. In Fig, 2.14, we have drawn two
interescting indifference curves that cut each
WC=Kand O= B then
|A=B ButB>A
Good ¥
y
%
By Me
% Good x
Fig. 2.14 ntereectng Indiference Curves
other at point C. Points C and A lie on IC, and
points C and B lie on IC,. As points C and’A lie
on IC, the consumer gets the same level of
satisfaction. Similarly, the consumer gets the
same satisfaction along points C and B on IC,.
Thus, along points C and A on IC,, we have
OX, + OY, = OX, + OY,
Similarly, on points C and B on IC, we have
OX, + OY, = OX, + OY,
Equating the R.H.S. of the above two
equations, we get OX, + OY, = OX, + OY,
ee nO
and subtracting OY, from both sides, we obtain
OX, = OX,
But it is clear from the figure that OX, is
definitely preferable to OX, So the two curves
cannot intersect each other.
This property can also be explained in the
following way. One of the important assump-
tions of indifference curve analysis is theassump-
tion of transitivity. This assumption states that
if X is preferable to Y and Y is preferable to Z,
then X is preferable to Z. Or if X is equivalent to
Y and Y is equivalent to Z, then X is equivalent
toZ. In Fig. 2.14 we, have two points Cand A on
IC, and C and Bon IC, AsC = A, and C= B,
then A =B. But the figure shows that B is
preferable to A. This happ ens since twoindifference
Curves cut each other. Thus, indifference curves
must be non-intersecting,
2.4.3. Some UNusuat SHAPES oF
INDIFFERNCE CuRVE
We have drawn negatively sloped indifference
curve for two goods X and ¥. These goods are
treated as ‘good! as they ate deemed to be fit for
consumption. In other words, when goods are
‘good; indifference curve is negative sloping and
convex to the origin. But, sometimes, to a
consumer some of the goods may become ‘bad?
or unfit for consumption. This means that a
Consumer gets less satisfaction by consuming
‘mote of that (‘bad’) commodity. Thus, the ‘good’
becomes a ‘bad’. Ih this case, the consumer will
get more satisfaction if he consumes less and
less of the ‘bad’ commodity. An example of such
‘bad’ good is pollution.
‘Bad’ good is measured on the horizontal
axis, while a ‘good” commodity is measured on
the vertical axis in Fig. 2.15(a). Now the
indifference curve is upward sloping, A consumer
would get higher satisfaction if he consumes less
Of the ‘bad’ good. If the consumer consumes
mote of a ‘bad’ good then the consumer needs
more of the ‘good’ good to stay on the same
indifference curve. In Fig, 2.15(b), an indifferenceon
‘offending’ commodity: This is shown in Fig. 2.16
where Of, amount of a commodity, say food, is
consumed. At point A, the slope of the
indifference curve becomes zero and, hence, MRS
is zero, As consumption of food beyond Of,
Yields negative utility, the indifference curve
becomes positive sloping.
In Fig. 2.17, another unusual shaped indiffe-
fence curve has been drawn. At point A on this
curve marginal utility of X is zero and, at point
5B, marginal utility of Y is zero. Consumption
beyond point A implies negative utility for X
and consumption beyond point B yields negative
utility for Y. Between points A and B, marginal
utilities for both X and ¥ are positive.
™ 2.5, BUDGET LINE OR PRICE LINE
OR CONSUMPTION-
POSSIBILITY LINE
Range of preferences of an individual for two
‘goods is represented by indifference curves Thus,
Psychic element is involved in an indifference
curve, But it does not tell anything about the
Purchasable combinations of two goods from
the limited money income. Such purchase plan
is determined by money income, prices of the
goods that a consumer buys, tastes and
Preferences, etc. A consumer always tries to
mamimise satisfaction from the consumption
of commodities. But in this pursuit, he is
hampered by his limited income, ie. his budget.
How does consumer dis ibute his fixed
income in the purchase of two goods X and Y
whose prices are fixed can be known from the
budget line or the consumption-possiily line,
Assume that a consumer has a fixed money
income, M, to purchase two goods, X and Y,
whose prices are P,, and P,, respectively. It is
also assumed that the prices of X and Y are
also fixed. Thus, the total expenditure on X and
Y can be zeptesented by the following equation:
M2X.P.+Y.P, ww-(2:1)
This non-equality equation suggests that
money income may equal or exceed total
expenditure. However, we will consider the
equality form of equation (2.1) ie,
M=X.P.+¥.P, + (22)
This is the equation of a steaight line. If the
consumer spends his entire income on good X
then the budget equation becomes
M=X.P, +0 BY
Or if the entire income is spent on Y, the
budget line equation becomes
M=O+Y.P: G4)
From equation (2.2), solving for X, we obtain
M-Y.P,
ial a . @5)
wy Py
Cee - (25a)
Here, p shows the amount of X that a
consumer can purchase, if no Y'is bought. This
is indicated by the distance OB in Fig 2.18, Thus,
Fplivwhetnentisnaetenney equation
ee Banke! ee the slope of the budget
Similasly, solving for ¥, one obtains
yesh 26)
¥
o y=M_ Ry
PR Py . Co
Here = is the vertical intercept of the
equation (262).Itshows the maximum purchasable
amount of Y, if no X is bought at all. This is
represented by the distance OA. ~Biistheslope
of the budget line, .
Thus, the two points A and B are the two
extreme points in Fig 2.18. Now if these two
points are joined together we obtain the budget
line AB which shows different purchasable
combinations of ‘two goods X and Y if thefeasible or attainable
m Point C or any other point on
= (em, point E). Though point E is
ot feasible or attainable since
Budget Line due to a change in Income
= Odamoune sf ¥ _/ oM/P,
“mere Omr,
OA. ot Bee
PE ee OBi tiie
Thus, the budget line is defined as the
purchasable combinations of two goods if the
entire money income is spent. The slope of this
straight line boundary is given by the negative
of the price ratio, It is to be noted here that as
long as prices of two goods are fixed and
independent of the quantities purchased, the
budget line is necessarily linear.
2.5.1. SHirrinG or THE BuGeT Line—
Errects or CHANGES IN INCOME
AND PRICE
The position and slope of the budget line
depends on money income and prices of two
goods that a consumer can purchase. In other
words, if there is a change in money income or
a change in the price of a good there will be a
shift in the budget line.
Letus consider an increase in money income
from M to 2M, while P, and Py remain fixed.
Thus the budget line equation changes to
2M=X,Py +¥,P,
‘Obviously, both the horizontal and vertical
intercepts will change from OB to OB, and
Fig, 219(b): Shits in Budget Line de to a Change in pcefrom OA to OA,. Thus, the new budget line
becomes A,B, [Fig.2.19(a)]- So, when-money
income increases, budget line shifts parallely
from AB to A,B,. Since Py and Py do not
change, the slope of the budget line does not
change. Or as there is a parallel shifting of the
budget line following a changein money income,
the slope of the budget line remains unchanged.
Now, suppose Py, declines to Px, , while
money income and price of good Y remain
fixed.
This means that horizontal intercept of Fig
2.19(b) changes from OB to OB, while vertical
intercept remains anchored at OA. Thus, when
price of X falls, the budget line shifts from AB
to AB, As a result the slope of the budget line
A | P, P,
changes’ from (R)o(#). Since
P< a(R) -(#) In other words, the
Py Py
slope of the new budget line AB, is less steep
than the slope of the original budget line AB.
If ptice of ¥ changes, holding P,, and M
constant, only the vertical intercept of the
budget line would change. And the slope of the
budget line would also change.
Further, assume that the prices of both the
goods change proportionately, money income
remains constant. This is equivalent to an
increase in money income. In such a situation,
budget line would shift parallel and the slope
would remain unchanged. 3
Finally, if both money income and prices of
two goods X and Y change in the same propor-
tion and in the same direction, budget line would
remain unchanged.
=2.6. CONSUMER EQUILIBRIUM—
MAXIMISING SATISFACTION
By equilibrium of a consumer we mean
maximisation of satisfaction. The basic goal of
a consumer is the maximisation of satisfaction
from the consumption of the two goods. Such
maximisation goal can be represented by
indifference map and budget line.
‘An indifference map represents the ranking
of choices of two goods. An indifference curve
shows the willingness to purchase different
combinations of ‘two goods which yield equal
satisfaction. The budget line shows the purrhasable
combinations of two goods that a consumer can
buy from his fixed money income.
Let us assume that a consumer, with his
limited income, purchases two goods X and Y
whose prices are fixed. The purchasable
combinations are represented by the budgetline
- AB of Fig, 2.20. In this figure, we have drawn
three indifference curves IC,, IC, and IC, to
represent rank or ordering of all combinations
of X and Y that a consumers is willing to buy.
To explain equilibrium, we bring together the
indifference map and the budget line. A
consumer would reach equilibrium if the
following assumptions hold:
+ money income of the consutner does not
change;
«» prices of the two goods remain unchanged;
«+ tastes and preferences of the consumer
also remain fixed; ;
+ goods and preferences of the consumer
also remain fixed;
+ the consumer is consistent in his choice,
and
+ the consumer is rational.
With these assumptions in mind, a consumer
would reach equilibrium when the budget line
becomes tangential to the highest as well as
attainable indifference curve. This condition
holds at point E on IC, Though IC,—a higher
order indifference curve—is desirable to
consumer, it is not attainable because the fixed
income will not pexinit him to climb on to IC,,
IC, is within the feasible area but this lower order
indifference curve cuts the budget line at two
points, C and D. Ths, points Cand D (.e.,non-
tangency points) on IC, are not equilibrium
points since a consumer moves to a lower= carve and, thus, detives lower level
When the consumer stays at
aims at moving towards point
higher satisfaction and when
stays on point D on IC,, he tries
és point E on IC, so that higher
& derived. Thus, point E is the
cist. Corres-ponding to this point,
purchases OX, of X and OY, of
ES optimum satisfaction.
Eessative explanation may also be of-
- sumer would reach equilibrium
Sf difference curve analysis, when
= conditions are fulfilled simul-
ef the budget line must be equal to
of the indifference curve, This
a is known as the necessary
‘Mathematically, this is called
- condition for equilibrium,
islope of the budget line is the
‘of the price ratio (ie, Pp )and
of the indifference curve is the
rate of substitution between X
‘Ge, MRS,,) and its sloy
Symbolically this con
difference curve must be convex
‘exigin at the point of equilibrium,
‘condition is known as sufficient
8 or mathematically, second-
condition. :
E the necessary condition as well as
are being fulfilled (called
a’). Thus, point E is the
point where he gets maximum
Butat points C and D, though the
condition is satisfied, first-order
nothold hence these are inferior
C, the slopes of budget line and
sSarve are unequal. In fact, at point
ok. Now the consumer can
,y
>
Goood ¥
9 % $
Fig. 2.20: Consumer Equilibrium
increase his satisfaction, without spending more,
by purchasing mote of X and less of Y. Doing
this, the consumer, along the budget line, moves
to point E which lies on a higher indifference
curve—indicating a higher level of satisfaction,
The opposite is true at point D where
E> MRS qq. So the consume, inorder 15 get
higher satisfaction, will go on purchasing more
of ¥ and less of X, of course, without incurring
any additional expenditure. Anyway, the optimum
point is reached at the tangency point where
MRS = 2 Thus the festoeder condition for
equilibrium is satisfied at point E. Further, at point
E, the second-order condition is also satisfied.
Point Eis thus, called ‘interior solution’ where the
consumer buys both the goods.
(Good K
1. A demand function is estimated to be
= —30P + 0.05M + 2P, + 4A
where P is the own price, M the money
income, P, the prices of related goods and
Ais the advertisement expenditure.
(@) Assuming M = Rs, 5,000, P. = 25, and A
= Rs. 30, draw the graph for the demand
function.