Micro-Chapter2 and Chapter3
Micro-Chapter2 and Chapter3
A firm’s profit is the difference between the revenues it receives from selling its output and its cost
of producing that output. Algebraically; profit is defined as
π = T R −TC
The above equation tells us that what happens to profit depends on what happens to revenue and
costs. The cost of production depends on quantity and quality of factors of production that the firm
employs in the production process.
On the other hand a variable input is an input whose quantity can be changed during the period
under consideration. For example, the number of workers hired to perform job like construction can
often be increased or decreased on short notice. Both fixed and variable inputs are generally classified
into four groups: land, labor, capital and entrepreneurship or management.
2.2.1 Land
Land as a factor of production includes minerals, forests, water, and all other natural resources as well
as soil used in agriculture and a site upon which economic activities take place. Land as a factor of
production has three main features; it is fixed in supply; it is a gift of nature; and it varies in quality.
2
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 3
2.2.2 Labor
Labor in its simplest term describes the human effort or other work done by human beings. Labor is
so important in production activities that some radical economists like Karl Marx and other socialist
oriented economists believe that labor is the only embodiment in production. Labor as a factor of
production can be classified into skilled and unskilled labor, as well as technicians and professionals
like engineers, doctors, lawyer etc. Labor can be more productive through training and education.
2.2.3 Capital
Capital can be defined as man - made wealth that is used in the production of goods and services. It
is defined as a “produced means of production” and it includes raw materials, machinery, buildings,
factories, tools and other manufactured inputs.
2.2.4 Entrepreneurship
It is the entrepreneur who coordinates all the factors of production by bringing them together in the
production process. It involves the use of initiatives, skills as well as the willingness and ability of the
decision-maker to take risk.
2.2.5 Production
Production in economics refers to the process of transforming inputs (such as labor, capital, land, and
raw materials) into outputs (goods and services) that can be sold in the market. The aim of production
is to create value by producing goods and services that satisfy human wants and needs.
Q x = f (L, K )
Where;
• L= labor
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 4
Short run is that period of time over which the input of at least one factor of production cannot be
varied.
Assumption
For example, a factory may be able to hire more workers or reduce the number of working hours for
existing employees in response to fluctuations in demand for its products. However, it cannot easily
expand or reduce its physical capital, such as machinery and equipment, in the short run.
Nonetheless, this assumption is often made in economic models for analytical simplicity and to focus
on the core relationships between inputs and outputs.
However, the degree of substitutability between inputs may vary across industries and firms. Some
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 5
industries may have more flexibility to substitute between labor and capital inputs than others, de-
pending on factors such as the nature of production technology, labor market conditions, and capital
intensity.
While technological change is a pervasive feature of modern economies, the short-run assumption
of constant technology allows economists to isolate the effects of changes in input quantities on out-
put levels without complicating the analysis with changes in production methods. However, in reality,
firms often innovate and adopt new technologies over time, which can influence their production pro-
cesses and efficiency.
Production function is an important starting point in the analysis of theory of the firm. But we need
to know more about the average and marginal product of labour. The average product of labor (APL)
is defined as total product (TP) divided by the number of units of labor used. Algebraically, it can be
expressed as:
TP
AP L = (2.1)
L
Where; APL is the average product of labor; TP is the total product and L is the labor. The marginal
product of labor (MPL) is given by the change in TP per unit change in the quantity of labor used.
Algebraically, it can be expressed as:
∆T P
M PL = (2.2)
∆L
Where; ∆T P is the change in the total product and ∆L is the change in labor input. The shapes of
the APL and MPL curves are determined by the shape of the corresponding TP curve. The APL at any
point on the TPL curve is given by the slope of the line from the origin to that point on the TPL curve.
the MPL curve also rises at first, reaches a maximum (before the APL reaches its maximum) and then
declines. The MPL becomes zero when the TP reaches maximum and it becomes negatives as TP falls.
The falling portion of the MPL curve illustrates the law of diminishing returns.
The law of diminishing marginal returns states that, as additional units of a variable
factor are added to a given quantity of fixed factors, with a given state of technology, the
marginal product of the variable factor will eventually decline.
Several things should be noted about this law. First, it assumes that technology remains fixed. The
law of diminishing marginal returns cannot predict the effect of an additional unit of input when
technology is allowed to change. Second, it is assumed that there is at least one input whose quantity
is being held constant. The law of diminishing marginal returns does not apply to cases where there
is a proportional increase in all inputs.
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 6
Output
Total Product
Stage II
Stage I Stage III
Maximum MP
Maximum AP (MP=AP)
MP=0
Average product
Labour
Marginal Product
Exercise
Exercise 1. The short run production function of ABC company is represented by the following equa-
tion:
Q = 6L 2 − 0.2L 3
. Where L denotes the number of workers.
1. Determine the size of the workforce which maximizes output (Hint: where MPL=0)
2. Determine the size of the workforce, which maximizes the average product of labour.
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 7
3. Compute MPL and APL at this value of workforce at AP L is maximum ?
2.4.1 Isoquant
An isoquant shows the different combinations of labor (L) and capital (K) with which a firm can pro-
duce a specific quantity of output. A higher isoquant such as Q2 in following figure indicates greater
quantity of output and a lower one such as Q1, indicates smaller quantity of output. In the Figure
, point B on the isoquant labeled Q1, represents just one possible combination of capital and labor
(0K1 units of capital and 0L1units of labor) with which a firm can produce Q1units of output. There
are in fact an infinite number of other points on the isoquant Q1 all of which represent different com-
binations of capital and labor which can be used to produce output Q1. An output of Q2 units bigger
than Q1 can be produced using any of the combinations of capital and labor represented by points
along the isoquant labeled Q2, such as point D and E.
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 8
negatively sloped. If both capital and labor have positive marginal products (so that the employment
of extra units increases total output), then it follows that to maintain a given level of output when
the quantity of one of factors is reduced, the quantity of other must be increased. Thirdly, isoquants
are convex to the origin. As units of capital are given up, successively bigger quantities of labor must
be employed to keep the output level unchanged. This makes the isoquants convex to the origin
as shown in Figure above. Note that the slope of isoquant is called the Marginal Rate of Technical
Substitution. The Figure shows that the movement from point A to point B requires more K to be
sacrificed. However, the movement from point B to point C requires less of K to be sacrificed, i.e.
∆K > ∆K ∗.
The marginal rate of technical substitution of labor (L) for capital (K), (i.e., MRTSLK) refers to the
amount of capital that firm can give up by increasing the amount of labor by one unit and still remain
on the same isoquant. The MRTSLK is also equal to the ratio of marginal product of labor (MPL) to the
marginal product of capital (MPK) or MPL /MPK. As the firm moves down an isoquant the MRTSLK
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 9
diminishes.
MPL
M RT S LK = (2.3)
MPK
C = P L (L) + P K (K ) (2.4)
Where;
• C is Total outlay
C PL L
K= − (2.5)
Pk PK
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 10
dK PL
Slope = =−
dL PK
MPL PL
= (2.6)
M P K PK
Where; MPL denotes the marginal product of labor, MPK denotes the marginal product of capital, PL
denotes the price of labor and PK denotes the price of capital. Equation 9.9 tells us that at equilibrium,
the marginal product of the last money spent on labor is the same as last money spent on capital. The
same would be true for other factors, if the firm had more than two factors of production.
Exercise
Exercise 2. Assume that the production function for ABC product is given by Q = 100K L. What is the
minimum cost of producing 1000 pairs of shoes if the price of capital and labor per day are Birr 120 and
30 respectively?
Exercise 3. Given the production function and price of labour and price of capital
that a firm now hires more unit of labor than before (i.e., 0L2>0L1). This result is obtained by drawing
a parallel isocost (i.e., TO/PK2, TO/PL2), which is just below the new isocost TO/PK1, TO/PL1*. The
scale effect on the other hand shows that a firm would employ both labor and capital where the new
isocost TO/PK1, TO/PL1* is tangent to the new isoquant (i.e. Q2). Thus, the movement from E2 to E3
is called the scale effect. The total effect is denoted by movement from E1 to E3.
In practical terms, constant returns to scale suggest that the firm is operating at an optimal size, where
scaling up or down does not affect its efficiency. This situation can occur in industries where tech-
nology and production processes are well understood and standardized, allowing firms to expand
without significant changes in per-unit costs. It reflects a scenario where there are no significant
economies or diseconomies of scale.
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 13
This phenomenon often occurs due to inefficiencies that arise as the scale of production increases.
These inefficiencies can stem from factors such as increased complexity in management, difficulties
in coordination, and potential resource constraints. As a firm grows, it might face challenges like
overcrowded production facilities or a diluted managerial effectiveness, leading to lower marginal
productivity of inputs. This scenario is indicative of diseconomies of scale, where the cost per unit of
output increases as the scale of production expands.
This situation often occurs due to efficiencies gained through larger scale production, such as spe-
cialization of labor, better utilization of capital, and technological advancements. Increasing returns
to scale are typically associated with economies of scale, where the cost per unit of output decreases
as the scale of production increases. This can be seen in industries with high fixed costs but low
marginal costs, such as manufacturing and technology sectors, where spreading the fixed costs over a
larger output reduces the average cost per unit.
Homogeneity helps in understanding how changes in scale affect output and allows for the simpli-
fication of production analysis. It provides a framework for analyzing production processes and for
understanding how firms can adjust their input combinations to achieve desired output levels effi-
ciently. Homogeneous production functions are often used in economic modeling to derive implica-
tions about firm behavior, cost structures, and the impact of scaling on productivity.
The concept of returns to scale is closely related to the concept of homogeneity in the neo-classical
production function. One of the most commonly used production functions in applied economics
work is the Cobb-Douglass production function, put forth by Cobb and Douglass in 1928. In its sim-
plest form, Cobb-Douglass production function can be written as:
Q = AK α L β (2.7)
CHAPTER 2. THEORY OF PRODUCTION 14
Where: Q=output; A=Constant; L=Labour; and K =Capital. The coefficients α and β can be interpreted
as the elasticities of output with respect to the labour and capital inputs respectively. The important
feature of Cobb-Douglass production function is that (α + β) measures returns to scale. For example,
suppose we double L and K by λ. Then the new output Q is given by
The production function Q = AK α L β is said to be homogeneous of degree (α+β), if given any positive
A, doubling inputs by λ, raises output by λα+β . When
Economists define cost in terms of opportunities that are sacrificed when a choice is made. Hence,
economic costs are defined in terms of opportunity costs—the cost associated with opportunities
that are foregone by not putting the firm’s resources to their best use. Economic costs are subjective
as seen from the perspective of a decision maker not a detached observer. Moreover, economic costs
are prospective in the sense that economists are concerned with what costs are expected to be in the
future, and with how the firm might be able to lower its costs and improve its profitability. Economic
cost estimates are used for making decisions about pricing, output levels, buying or making, alterna-
tive marketing tactics/strategies, product introductions, etc.
However, both accountants and economists include explicit costs, in their calculations. Explicit costs
refers to contractual payments made by the firms to factor owners in the process of acquiring inputs
required in production or provision of services. These includes among others, wages and salaries,
payments for raw materials, payment for utilities, rent, taxes, and interest rate. Economists are thus
concerned with both explicit and implicit costs (i.e., opportunity cost).
15
CHAPTER 3. THE THEORY OF COST 16
economic transaction that parties "external" to the transaction bear. Externalities can be either posi-
tive, when an external benefit is generated, or negative, when an external cost is imposed upon others.
Social cost of producing a commodity is equal to the private cost of producing it plus the cost to other
people. It is the cost of production borne by all members of the society at large when a commodity is
produced. A good example of social cost is that of a cement factory polluting air in the neighboring
townships, which harms human health. Thus, social costs are the private costs of resources that the
firm uses plus any additional costs imposed on society by the firm’ s operation.
WL W W
AV C = = =
Q Q/L AP L
∆W L ∆L W W
MC = =W = =
∆Q ∆Q ∆Q/∆L M P L
Characteristics:
• All Inputs Variable: In the long run, firms can adjust the quantities of all inputs, such as labor,
capital, and raw materials. This flexibility allows firms to choose the optimal production scale.
• Economies of Scale: The long-run cost function often exhibits economies of scale, where in-
creasing the scale of production leads to a lower average cost per unit. This happens due to
factors like specialization, bulk purchasing, and more efficient use of capital.
CHAPTER 3. THE THEORY OF COST 19
• Diseconomies of Scale: Beyond a certain point, firms may experience diseconomies of scale,
where increasing the scale of production raises the average cost per unit. This can occur due to
factors like management inefficiencies, increased complexity, and resource constraints.
Shape of the Long-Run Average Cost (LRAC) Curve: The LRAC curve is typically U-shaped due to
economies and diseconomies of scale. Initially, costs decrease with increased production, reach a
minimum point, and then start to increase as diseconomies of scale set in.
The Long run Average Total Cost (LRATC) is illustrated in Figure 3.2. It indicates the minimum possi-
ble average cost of production for each level of output, given that the plant of the appropriate capacity
has been constructed. Figure 3.2 shows that as the firm changes its level of output with the plant ap-
propriate for minimum long run average cost of production at output OQ1, it moves along SRAC1, at
output OQ2 it moves along SRAC2 and so on. In fact, at every point of tangent on the LRAC, there is
an SRAC curve. Since each SRAC curve lies above the LRAC curve except at the point at which it is at a
tangent, the LRAC curve is sometimes called and envelope curve.