Macro Chapter 4
Macro Chapter 4
Second, Keynes posited that the ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity
to consume, falls as income rises. He believed that saving was a luxury, so he expected the rich
to save a higher proportion of their income than the poor.
Third, Keynes thought that income is the primary determinant of consumption and that the
interest rate does not have an important role. This conjecture stood in stark contrast to the
beliefs of the classical economists who preceded him. The Classical economists held that a
higher interest rate encourages saving and discourages consumption. Keynes admitted that the
interest rate could influence consumption as a matter of theory. Yet he wrote that "the main
conclusion suggested by experience, I think, is that the short-period influence of the rate of
interest on individual spending out of a given income is secondary and relatively unimportant.''
Figure 1.1
On the basis of these three conjectures, the Keynesian consumption function is often written as
As Y rises, /Y falls, and so the average propensity to consume C/Y falls. And finally, this
consumption function satisfies Keynes's third property because the interest rate is not included in
this equation as a determinant of consumption.
4.1.2 Irving Fisher and Inter-temporal Choice
The consumption function introduced by Keynes relates current consumption to current income.
This relationship, however, is incomplete at best. When people decide how much to consume
and how much to save, they consider both the present and the future.
The economist Irving Fisher developed the model with which economists analyze how
rational, forward-looking consumers make Intertemporal choices— that is, choices involving
different periods of time.
To keep things simple, we examine the decision facing a consumer who lives for two periods.
Period one represents the consumer's youth, and period two represents the consumer's old age.
The consumer earns income Y1 and consumes C1 in period one, and earns income Y2 and
consumes C2 in period two. (All variables are real—that is, adjusted for inflation.) Because
the consumer has the opportunity to borrow and save, consumption in any single period can be
either greater or less than income in that period.
For example, if the interest rate is 5 percent, then for every $1 of saving in period one, the
consumer enjoys an extra $1.05 of consumption in period two. Because there is no third period,
the consumer does not save in the second period.
Note that the variable S can represent either saving or borrowing and that these equations
hold in both cases.
If first-period consumption is less than first period income (C1<Y1), the consumer is
saving, and S is greater than zero.
If first-period consumption exceeds first-period income(C1>Y1), the consumer is
borrowing, and S is less than zero. For simplicity, we assume that the interest rate for
borrowing is the same as the interest rate for saving.
To derive the consumer's budget constraint, combine the two preceding equations. Substitute the
first equation for S into the second equation to obtain
C1 Y 1
This equation relates consumption in the two periods to income in the two periods. It is the
standard way of expressing the consumer's intertemporal budget constraint.
hypothesis.
The Hypothesis
One important reason that income varies over a person's life is retirement. Most people plan to
stop working at about age 65, and they expect their incomes to fall when they retire. Yet they do
not want a large drop in their standard of living, as measured by their consumption. To maintain
consumption after retirement, people must save during their working years. Let's see what this
motive for saving implies for the consumption function.
Consider a consumer who expects to live another T years, has wealth of W, and expects to earn
income Y until he/she retires R years from now. What level of consumption will the consumer
choose if he/she wishes to maintain a smooth level of consumption over his/her life?
The consumer's lifetime resources are composed of initial wealth W and lifetime earnings of R
Y. (For simplicity, we are assuming an interest rate of zero; if the interest rate were greater than
zero, we would need to take account of interest earned on savings as well.) The consumer can
divide up his/her lifetime resources among her T remaining years of life. We assume that He/she
wishes to achieve the smoothest possible path of consumption over his/ her lifetime. Therefore,
he/she divides this total of W RY equally among the T years and each year consumes
C (W RY )/T.
We can write this person's consumption function as
C (1/T )W (R/T )Y.
For example, if the consumer expects to live for 50 more years and work for 30 of them, then T
50 and R 30, so his/ her consumption function is
C 0.02W 0.6Y.
This equation says that consumption depends on both income and wealth. An extra $1 of income
per year raises consumption by $0.60 per year, and an extra $1 of wealth raises consumption by
Haftom, who has a law degree, earned more this year than yohannes, who is a high-
school dropout. Haftom's higher income resulted from higher permanent income, because
his education will continue to provide him a higher salary.
Kasim, a Harar orange grower, earned less than usual this year because a freeze destroyed
his crop. Ali, an awash orange grower, earned more than usual because the freeze in
Harar drove up the price of oranges. Ali's higher income resulted from higher transitory
income, because he is no more likely than Kasim to have good weather next year.
These examples show that different forms of income have different degrees of persistence. A
good education provides a permanently higher income, whereas good weather provides only
transitorily higher income. Although one can imagine intermediate cases, it is useful to keep
things simple by supposing that there are only two kinds of income: permanent and transitory.
Friedman reasoned that consumption should depend primarily on permanent income, because
consumers use saving and borrowing to smooth consumption in response to transitory changes in
income.
For example, if a person received a permanent raise of $10,000 per year, his consumption would
rise by about as much. Yet if a person won $10,000 in a lottery, he would not consume it all in
one year. Instead, he would spread the extra consumption over the rest of his life. Assuming an
interest rate of zero and a remaining life span of 50 years, consumption would rise by only $200
per year in response to the $10,000 prize. Thus, consumers spend their permanent income, but
they save rather than spend most of their transitory income.
Friedman concluded that we should view the consumption function as approximately
CY P,
where is a constant that measures the fraction of permanent income consumed. The
permanent-income hypothesis, as expressed by this equation, states that consumption is
proportional to permanent income.