Policy Design Primer - Choosing The Right Tools For The Job
Policy Design Primer - Choosing The Right Tools For The Job
‘How might governments choose the most appropriate tool for a chieving
desired policy goals and objectives? How might they uncover innovative
and durable solutions? Howlett’s The Policy Design Primer: Choosing the
Right Tools for the Job provides, in one place, the critical theoretical,
conceptual and analytical tools for making informed decisions in a highly
complex and globalized world. The book is must reading for government
and bureaucratic officials seeking to manage complex problems that
often demand, and can benefit from, drawing on procedural tools that
integrate key stakeholders into public management design and practice,
and substantive instruments that can steer policy subsystems towards
meaningful results. A tour de force in its integration of conceptual
breadth, analytical scope and practical insights’.
– Professor Benjamin Cashore, Yale University, USA
The Policy Design Primer
Michael Howlett
First published 2019
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
52 Vanderbilt Avenue, New York, NY 10017
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2019 Michael Howlett
The right of Michael Howlett to be identified as author of this work
has been asserted by him in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of
the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or
reproduced or utilised in any form or by any electronic, mechanical,
or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including
photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or
retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks
or registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and
explanation without intent to infringe.
British Library Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Howlett, Michael, 1955– author.
Title: The policy design primer: choosing the right tools for
the job / Michael Howlett.
Description: Abingdon, Oxon; New York, NY: Routledge, 2019. |
Series: Routledge textbooks in policy studies | Includes bibliographical
references and index.
Identifiers: LCCN 2018059423 (print) | LCCN 2019006616 (ebook) |
ISBN 9780429401046 (master ebook) | ISBN 9780429684517 (web pdf ) |
ISBN 9780429684500 (ePub) | ISBN 9780429684494 (mobipocket/kindle) |
ISBN 9780367001612 (hbk: alk. paper) | ISBN 9780367001650
(pbk: alk. paper) | ISBN 9780429401046 (ebk)
Subjects: LCSH: Political planning. | Policy sciences.
Classification: LCC JF1525.P6 (ebook) | LCC JF1525.P6 H7 2019 (print) |
DDC 320.6—dc23
LC record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2018059423
List of figures xi
List of tables xii
Preface xiii
Acknowledgements xiv
Part I
Policy design in the modern state 1
Part III
Principles for designing policies and programmes 113
Index 133
Figures
The book could not have been written without the pioneering work
of the many scholars and colleagues who individually and collectively
spent a great deal of time and effort developing the empirical cases and
carefully building the many frameworks and models used throughout
the text. A special debt is owed to Rebecca Raglon for her patience,
support and encouragement.
Part I
Policy level
High Low
Packaging
Tense
(“Pure Patching Drift Stretching Non-Design
Layering
Design”)
References
Bobrow, Davis. “Policy Design: Ubiquitous, Necessary and Difficult.” In
Handbook of Public Policy, edited by Guy Peters, B. and Jon Pierre, 75–96.
Beverly Hills, CA: SAGE, 2006.
Carey, Gemma, Adrian Kay, and Ann Nevile. “Institutional Legacies and ‘Sticky
Layers’: What Happens in Cases of Transformative Policy Change?” Admin-
istration & Society 51, no. 3 (2019): 491–509. doi:10.1177/0095399717704682.
Chindarkar, Namrata, Michael Howlett, and M. Ramesh. “Conceptualizing
Effective Social Policy Design: Design Spaces and Capacity Challenges.”
Public Administration and Development 37, no. 1 (February 1, 2017): 3–14.
May, Peter J. “Policy Design and Implementation.” In Handbook of Public
Administration, edited by Guy Peters, B. and Jon Pierre, 223–33. Beverly
Hills, CA: Sage, 2003.
14 Policy design in the modern state
Feindt, Peter H., and Andrew Flynn. “Policy Stretching and Institutional
Layering: British Food Policy between Security, Safety, Quality, Health
and Climate Change.” British Politics 4, no. 3 (2009): 386–414.
Goldsmith, S., and W. D. Eggers. Governing by Network: The New Shape of the
Public Sector. Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 2004.
Goodin, Robert E. Manipulatory Politics. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press, 1980.
Hood, Christopher. The Tools of Government. Chatham: Chatham House
Publishers, 1986.
Howlett, Michael. “Governance Modes, Policy Regimes and Operational
Plans: A Multi-Level Nested Model of Policy Instrument Choice and Policy
Design.” Policy Sciences 42, no. 1 (2009): 73–89.
Howlett, Michael. Designing Public Policies: Principles and Instruments. New
York: Routledge, 2011.
Howlett, Michael, and Ishani Mukherjee. “Policy Design and Non-Design:
Towards a Spectrum of Policy Formulation Types.” Politics and Governance
2, no. 2 (November 13, 2014): 57–71.
Howlett, Michael, M. Ramesh, and Anthony Perl. Studying Public Policy: Policy
Cycles & Policy Subsystems. Toronto: Oxford University Press, 2009.
Howlett, Michael, and Jeremy Rayner. “Patching vs Packaging in Policy
Formulation: Assessing Policy Portfolio Design.” Politics and Governance 1,
no. 2 (2013): 170–82.
Klijn, Erik-Hans, Joop Koppenjan, and Katrien Termeer. “Managing Networks
in the Public Sector: A Theoretical Study of Management S trategies in
Policy Networks.” Public Administration 73 (1995): 437–54.
Lasswell, Harold D. “The Policy Orientation.” In The Policy Sciences: Recent
Developments in Scope and Method, edited by Daniel Lerner and Harold D.
Lasswell, 3–15. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1951.
Linder, Stephen H., and B. Guy Peters. “From Social Theory to Policy
Design.” Journal of Public Policy 4, no. 3 (1984): 237–59.
Linder, Steven H., and B. Guy Peters. “The Logic of Public Policy Design:
Linking Policy Actors and Plausible Instruments.” Knowledge in Society 4
(1991): 125–51.
Salamon, Lester M. “Rethinking Public Management: Third-Party Govern-
ment and the Changing Forms of Government Action.” Public Policy 29,
no. 3 (1981): 255–75.
Salamon, Lester M. The Tools of Government: A Guide to the New Governance.
New York: Oxford University Press, 2002.Vedung, Evert. “Policy Instru-
ments: Typologies and Theories.” In Carrots, Sticks and Sermons: Policy Instru-
ments and Their Evaluation, edited by Marie-Louise Bemelmans-Videc, Ray
C. Rist, and Evert Oskar Vedung, 21–58. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
Publishers, 1997.
Wildavsky, Aaron B. Speaking Truth to Power: The Art and Craft of Policy Analysis.
Boston, MA: Little-Brown, 1979.
2 Systematically studying
policy design
The logic of tool use
Even more complex design challenges exist when both the level
of ‘objective’ knowledge of problems and the relative nature of
decision-makers’ knowledge of that ‘fact-base’ are taken into account;
or if there is little agreement on the choice of variables to be included
in models (Chow and Sarin 2002) (see Table 2.3).
Figure 2.2 Links in the design chain – individual and group levels.
Systematically studying policy design 21
Resources are used and tools deployed in order to secure better com-
pliance or adherence of populations to government aims and ambitions,
be it in the promotion of public safety and security or in the provision
of effective healthcare and social welfare. If perfect compliance with
governments’ aims existed automatically, of course, there would be lit-
tle need to undertake state activity beyond information provision in
that a government would only have to inform citizens of its ambitions
for perfect compliance to occur. But, of course, it does not. Desired
changes can be large or small, and the expectation of compliance can
be rapid or gradual, but in all cases, some changes in behaviour in a
direction congruent with government aims are expected to require the
utilization of other kinds of state resources.
Traditionally, much compliance theory in economics and elsewhere
has been based on a fairly superficial concept of target behaviour in-
volving ‘deterrence’ (Kaine et al. 2010) in which the primary type of
tool to be deployed to acheive a policy goal is a penalty. This is based
upon the hedonic idea that narrow self-interest and calculable utility
in enhancing pleasure and avoiding pain are the primary motivators of
compliance behaviour on the part of policy actors, with governments
enhancing pain through penalties (and often pleasure through subsidies)
in efforts to deter or encourage specific kinds of activity.
In practice, this means that compliance of policy targets with
government intentions is often viewed as a problem equated with the
exercise of authority on the part of governments in the form of laws and
regulations designed to deter certain kinds of activity, sometimes cou-
pled with other kinds of incentives – often financial – that encourage
other kinds. Compliance-deterrence utility considerations can then be
extended to the calculation of the more precise calibration of such tools,
with incentives and disincentives set at such a level as to punish those
who might contest the legitimacy of such actions or seek to free-ride on
compliers and/or reward those who comply.
As suggested earlier, however, the situation is more complex than
a purely utilitarian perspective would have it, as even the most basic
activities of governance such as paying taxes and obeying rules involve
not just individual hedonic behaviour but also considerations on the
part of targets and the public concerning the legality and normative
‘appropriateness’ of government’s levying and collecting such taxes
(March and Olsen 1989). Moreover, different kinds of target groups and
individuals exist (and are perceived to exist) and can be and are treated
differently by governments in terms of government expectations of the
nature of their compliant or non-compliant behaviour (Schneider and
Ingram 1994).
22 Policy design in the modern state
Some targets, for example, such as businesses may be thought to
be influenced through means such as financial incentives or penali-
ties while others, such as parents, may be thought to respond better
to efforts at moral suasion and education. But the compliance situ-
ation is made even more complex by the fact that different targets
have different resources and capabilities and attitudes when it comes
to determining whether or not they will comply, and how, and to
what extent, they will not. These attitudes can be quite complex and
rooted in historical and culturally specific views of government inten-
tions and the moral and other aspects of compliant and non-compliant
behaviour (Wan et al. 2015). These can include, for example, consid-
erations of the legitimacy and illegitimacy of government actors and
actions in specific fields such as constitutional, religious or privacy-
related ones, but can also run into and involve desires on the part of
individuals and groups to earn praise, or avoid shame, or to avoid guilt
and social opprobrium for their actions.
This variation in target motivation and compliance behaviour makes
policy design a much more challenging activity than that surmised
from either a bounded-rationality perspective on policy knowledge or
a simple hedonic utilitarian perspective. Whether a proposed action
triggers behaviour linked to ‘affiliation’ or ‘conformity’ with govern-
ment wishes or results in ‘boomerang’ effects (encouraging the action
it is aimed at discouraging, or vice versa, such as sometimes happens
from, for example, the increased prominence or normalizing of smok-
ing or unsafe sexual activity featured in government anti-smoking and
public health campaigns) is critical but not well understood. And nei-
ther is the effect of the manner in which compliance can be affected
by the type of ‘message’ sent, urging compliance and its negative or
positive nature, the way it has been framed, as well as other factors
linked to the character of the underlying norm itself (see also Schultz
et al. 2007). What works with one individual or group may not work
with another, and it is not unusual for a range of governing resources
and tools to have to be deployed in order to deal with such complex,
‘target-rich’ environments.
In such circumstances, governments must determine not only
whether or not a target is likely to comply with government ac-
tions and intentions but also whether or the extent to which com-
pliance will be reluctantly or freely given. As Table 2.4 shows,
estimations and diagnoses about likely compliance behaviour can
usefully be linked to coercive versus persuasive actions on the part
of governments.
Systematically studying policy design 23
Table 2.4 Nature of compliance of policy targets
Likelihood of compliance
High Low
Table 2.5 Perceptions of policy targets after Schneider and Ingram (1993)
Positive Negative
Good/Success Poor/Failure
Capacity Brokers/Advisors
Outcomes (Implementation)
Functional/Technical ad hoc
Designs (Formulation)
Replacement Non-Designing/
Process/Designing (Formulation)
Log-rolling
Figure 2.3 P
olicy effectiveness as the relationship between process, design and
outcome.
References
Azuela, Gabriela Elizondo, and Luiz Augusto Barroso. Design and Performance
of Policy Instruments to Promote the Development of Renewable Energy: Emerging
Experience in Selected Developing Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank
Publications, 2012.
Bhatta, Gambhir. “Evidence-Based Analysis and the Work of Policy Shops.”
Australian Journal of Public Administration 61, no. 3 (2002): 98–105.
Chow, Clare Chua, and Rakesh K. Sarin. “Known, Unknown, and Unknow-
able Uncertainties.” Theory and Decision 52, no. 2 (March 1, 2002): 127–38.
Colebatch, H. K. “The Idea of Policy Design: Intention, Process, Outcome,
Meaning and Validity.” Public Policy and Administration 33, no. 4 (October 1,
2018): 365–83.
Hood, C. “Using Bureaucracy Sparingly.” Public Administration 61, no. 2 (1983):
197–208.
Howlett, Michael. “Policy Analytical Capacity: The Supply and Demand
for Policy Analysis in Government.” Policy and Society, Special Issue on the
D ynamics of Policy Capacity, 34, no. 3 (September 1, 2015): 173–82.
Howlett, Michael. “Matching Policy Tools and Their Targets: Beyond Nudges
and Utility Maximisation in Policy Design.” Policy & Politics, 46, no. 1
( January 18, 2018): 101–24.
Ingraham, Patricia W. “Towards More Systemic Consideration of Policy
Design.” Policy Studies Journal 15, no. 4 (1987): 611–28.
Kaine, Geoff, Helen Murdoch, Ruth Lourey, and Denise Bewsell. “A
Framework for Understanding Individual Response to Regulation.” Food
Policy 35, no. 6 (December 2010): 531–37.
Linder, S. H., and B. G. Peters. “The Logic of Public Policy Design: Linking
Policy Actors and Plausible Instruments.” Knowledge in Society 4 (1991):
125–51.
Manski, Charles F. “Policy Analysis with Incredible Certitude.” The Economic
Journal 121, no. 554 (August 1, 2011): F261–89.
Maor, Moshe. “The Implications of the Emerging Disproportionate Policy
Perspective for the New Policy Design Studies.” Policy Sciences 50, no. 3
(September 1, 2017): 383–98.
Systematically studying policy design 29
March, J. G., and J. P. Olsen. Rediscovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis
of Politics. New York: The Free Press, 1989.
May, Peter J. “Compliance Motivations: Affirmative and Negative Bases.” Law &
Society Review 38, no. 1 (2004): 41–68.
Pierce, Jonathan J., Saba Siddiki, Michael D. Jones, Kristin Schumacher,
A ndrew Pattison, and Holly Peterson. “Social Construction and Policy
Design: A Review of Past Applications.” Policy Studies Journal 42, no. 1
(February 1, 2014): 1–29.
Redström, Johan. “Persuasive Design: Fringes and Foundations.” In Persuasive
Technology, edited by Wijnand A. IJsselsteijn, Yvonne A. W. de Kort, Cees
Midden, Berry Eggen, and Elise van den Hoven, 112–22. Lecture Notes in
Computer Science 3962. Berlin and Heidelberg: Springer, 2006.
Rittel, H. W. J., and M. M. Webber. “Dilemmas in a General Theory of
Planning.” Policy Sciences 4 (1973): 155–69.
Schneider, A., and H. Ingram. “Social Construction of Target Populations:
Implications for Politics and Policy.” American Political Science Review 87, no. 2
(1993): 334–47.
Schneider, A., and H. Ingram. “Social Constructions and Policy Design:
Implications for Public Administration.” Research in Public Administration 3
(1994): 137–73.
Scholz, J. T. “Cooperative Regulatory Enforcement and the Politics of
Administrative Effectiveness.” American Political Science Review 85, no. 1
(1991): 115–36.
Schultz, P. Wesley, Jessica M. Nolan, Robert B. Cialdini, Noah J. Goldstein,
and Vladas Griskevicius. “The Constructive, Destructive, and Reconstruc-
tive Power of Social Norms.” Psychological Science 18, no. 5 (May 1, 2007):
429–34.
Simon, Herbert A. Models of Man, Social and Rational: Mathematical Essays on
Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting. New York: Wiley, 1957.
Simon, Herbert A. “The Structure of Ill Structured Problems.” Artificial Intel-
ligence 4, no. 3–4 (Winter 1973): 181–201.
Torgerson, D. “Between Knowledge and Politics: Three Faces Of Policy
Analysis.” Policy Sciences 19, no. 1 (1986): 33–59.
Wan, Calvin, Geoffrey Qiping Shen, and Ann Yu. “Key Determinants of
Willingness to Support Policy Measures on Recycling: A Case Study in
Hong Kong.” Environmental Science & Policy 54 (December 2015): 409–18.
Weaver, R. Kent. “Getting People to Behave: Research Lessons for Policy
Makers.” Public Administration Review 75, no. 6 (2015): 806–16.
Part II
Direct government
The direct use of government agencies for substantive policy purposes
involves the ‘delivery of a good or service by government employees,
funded by appropriations from government treasury’ (Leman 1989;
Leman and Salamon 2002). This is what is sometimes referred to as ‘the
forgotten fundamental’ within policy instrument studies, as its ubiq-
uitous nature is often ignored in studies which take it for granted and
focus instead on more esoteric kinds of tools.
Within this general type of direct government organizational tool,
there are several common forms or subtypes found in many jurisdic-
tions. These include the following.
Line departments
In most countries, government agencies undertake a very wide variety
of tasks on a direct basis. These services are provided at all levels of
government (central or federal, provincial, state or regional, as well as
urban or local) in slightly different configurations in different countries
but often through core departments or what are sometimes referred to
as ‘line’ departments in order to distinguish them from ‘staff’ agencies
which typically co-ordinate rather than deliver services themselves.
Unemployment, welfare or social security payments, for example, can
be the task of central governments in some countries and eras, and of
provincial or local governments in others but are commonly adminis-
tered by line departments or their functional equivalents.
Typically, these kinds of government agencies follow what is known
in the public administration literature as a Weberian ‘monocratic bureau-
cracy’ form of organization (Rudolph and Rudolph 1979). This is a type
Organizational implementation tools 35
of organizational structure first systematically described and analyzed by
the German political sociologist Max Weber (1978) in his early twentieth-
century work, Economy and Society. Weber argued that although bureau-
cratic forms of organization had a long history in ancient and medieval
empires and kingdoms, a significant change had occurred in the modern
era – roughly corresponding to the start of the French Revolution in the
late eighteenth century – when such organizations came to be viewed
as providing services to the public rather than being the property of a
monarch or emperor to do with as he or she pleased (Albrow 1970). The
main characteristics of these modern government agencies, in Weber’s
view, were:
Task Examples
many for many different purposes, from railways, airlines and regional
development initiatives of various kinds to energy security and defence.
There are many different definitions of public enterprises, with dif-
ferent levels of public ownership ascribed to each. Hence, for example,
in Canada, the Ontario Auditor’s Act defines ‘public enterprise’ as
Commissioning
Commissioning is the most recently recognized collaborative tech-
nique which, as Taylor and Migone (2017) put it:
As they note, however, in some cases, the new relationship will modify
established sets of interactions, such as when increased competitiveness
Organizational implementation tools 45
of non-profit organizations results in decreased cooperation amongst
the providers or when service provision becomes the central focus of
NGO activity, replacing other kinds of membership activity, including
those devoted to recruitment and retention of members.
Contracting
Contracting is probably the most well-known organization-based
activity which involves government. All government contract for
services of course, from provision of military equipment to office
stationary. However in recent years many efforts have been made to
reduce the level of direct state involvement in the provision of public
services and the number of government personnel deployed to do so,
through the replacement of civil servants and internal procure-
ment processes with contractual arrangements with, usually, non-
governmental organizations, primarily private businesses (Vincent
Jones 2006). Various forms of contracting out exist, such as the PPPs or
public-private partnerships discussed earlier. However other less rig-
orous forms of contracting exist in areas such as healthcare, education
and prisons, in which contracts may not involve large investments
and profit sharing, but rather simply remove major expenditure ar-
eas, such as penitentiaries, or minor ones such as janitorial services,
from government books, budgets and payrolls (Roehrich et al. 2014;
Thadani 2014). These activities are often undertaken in order to
avoid sub-optimal production of services by relatively expensive gov-
ernment workers and also to avoid payments of benefits and superan-
nuation to civil servants.
In the case of contracting, however, many supporters of the concept
have noted significant limitations which can prevent contracting from
functioning effectively. The 2016 Nobel Prize in Economics, for ex-
ample, was awarded to two economists who specialize in detailing the
significant flaws and limits of contracting in areas such as prisons and
healthcare (Holmstrom and Milgrom 1991). Their concern was with
the difficulty encountered by governments in enforcing quality con-
trol in such contracts when the nature of the service provided (i.e. its
quality) was dependent on difficult-to-monitor interactions between,
for example, patients and doctors or prisoners and prison guards. These
and other criticisms highlight the need to carefully negotiate realistic
contracts and deal with the information asymmetries and knowledge
gaps linked to public services, as well as other issues such as difficul-
ties encountered in cancelling contracts or preventing contractees from
simply reneging on their contracted obligations.
46 Policy tools
Non-state and society-based tools: co-production
and certification
Efforts at policy reform around substantive organizational tools have
been omnipresent in many developed and developing countries over
the past several decades and have often featured efforts to reduce the
number of state-based tools and shift their activities either towards hy-
brid instruments or, in some cases, away from state-based organizations
altogether. Many of these efforts have featured waves of management
reforms and administrative re-structuring, including privatizations,
de-regulation and re-regulation and the other activities cited above
(Ramesh and Howlett 2006). These efforts have also led to the artic-
ulation and promotion of several alternative modes of governing to
more traditional ‘hierarchical’ or state-led ones which still nevertheless
include governments as key organizational actors.
Many of these techniques are ‘market-based’ and constitute efforts
to replace government activity with private sector actions. However,
others are focused less on zero-sum notions of state-market relations,
but include more complex ideas about involving ‘civil society’ actors
more directly in ‘collaborative’ policy-making, administration and im-
plementation (Brudney 1987). These kinds of activities come in many
forms, but two which have received a great deal of attention in recent
years are ‘co-production’ and ‘certification’.
Certification
Certification is a term used to capture the activities of many non-state
actors involved in areas such as forestry, fisheries, organizing foods and
other similar areas in which quality control and enforcement of stand-
ards are accomplished less directly than is the case with traditional gov-
ernment supplied command and control regulation and government
agencies (Cashore et al. 2004). In these cases, for a variety of reasons,
from cost to ideology, ‘certification’ of standards is undertaken by civil
society organizations, such as the Forestry Stewardship Council or the
Marine Stewardship Council, which lack the formal authority to com-
pel business and industries to abide by regulatory standards but which
utilize (often negative) publicity, boycotts and other actions to encour-
age compliance of firms with set standards of behaviour, from netsize
and type in the case of the fishery to sustainable logging practices in the
forest sector.
These tools are often referred to as non-state market-based (NSMD)
tools (Cashore 2002) since they do not rely upon state authority for
Organizational implementation tools 47
their power and legitimacy to regulate private sector activity, but rather
do so through market activities such as product labelling and producer
certifications which affect consumer behaviour and preferences, for
example, for organic produce or sustainably harvested timber, fish or
coffee, amongst others. It is debatable, however, if these kinds of efforts
could work without the ‘iron-fist’ of a threat of government regulation
lurking in the background.
It is also the case that such schemes rely heavily on the reputation
of the certifier for honesty, accuracy and precision. Certification only
functions effectively if trust exists between the public and the certifiers
and between the certifiers and the certified companies and govern-
ments. Concerns about second-class regulation or corrupt standards can
easily undermine years of work building up a certified brand. Similarly,
competing or dueling certifiers can also undermine existing schemes
and impede their effectiveness. If their reputation is damaged, as has
happened from time to time with products such as wine or olives in
which additives were added or cheaper products substituted for ex-
pected ones, such schemes can collapse and require either substantial
reform or government takeover, revealing their dependence on gov-
ernment organizations, ultimately, to serve as the guarantor of quality.
Co-production
Co-production is a short-hand term for a variety of governance ar-
rangements which involve citizens in the production and delivery of
public services, some of which have already been discussed above, such
as ‘co-design’ or ‘co-management’ (Brandsen and Honingh 2016). In
the USA, these ideas generated interest amongst public administration
scholars in the 1970s and the 1980s in areas such as storefront policing,
and experienced a revival in the decades after the turn-of-the-century
in many areas from education to environmental protection and high-
way beautification and litter control (Pestoff et al. 2006).
Originally, co-production was narrowly defined as the ‘involvement
of citizens, clients, consumers, volunteers and/or community organ-
izations in producing public services as well as consuming or oth-
erwise benefiting from them’ (Alford 1998: 128). Many governance
arrangements, even those thought to be purely hierarchical, such as
public schooling and policing, in fact combine aspects of hierarchical or
state-based governance with elements of civil society mobilization in
the form of activities such as neighbourhood watches or parent-teacher
associations. This involvement is often voluntary, meaning it existed as
a positive externality, reducing production and delivery costs of public
48 Policy tools
services. This made it very attractive to governments seeking cost re-
ductions in public service delivery, especially ones favourable to notions
of ‘social enterprise’ and enhanced community participation as an end-
or good-in-itself (Parks et al. 1981).
Like all other tools, however, co-production also has a downside as
a policy tool. In the case of co-production, it has long been recognized
that expectations of free labour from co-producers may not material-
ize (Sorrentino et al. 2018), and schemes to incentivize co-producers
through payments are susceptible to all of the usual harms of public
expenditures, including corruption, clientelism and goal displacement,
amongst others (Howlett et al. 2017).
Laws
Law is an important tool of modern government and the very basis of
legal modes of governance (Ziller 2005). Several different types of laws
exist, however. These include distinctions often drawn by legal scholars
Authoritative implementation tools 63
Table 4.1 Six types of legal instruments
1. Statutes
2. Delegated legislation between levels of government
3. Decisions of regulatory bodies and courts
4. Contracts or treaties
5. Quasi-legislation such as tax notices and interpretative bulletins
6. Reference documents such as background papers, other legislation and
standing orders
between private and public law; private, civil or tort law and common
law; public, criminal and administrative law and hybrids such as class
action suits which combine features of public and private law. These
different types of law vary substantially in terms of what kinds of situa-
tions they can be applied to, by whom and to what effect (see Table 4.1).
All of these laws can be thought of as ‘regulations’, since all involve
the creation of rules governing individual behaviour. However, in the
form it is usually discussed by policy scholars, ‘regulation’ is typically
thought of as a form of public law; although even then it can also involve
criminal and individual or civil actions (Kerwin 1999).
While laws can prohibit or proscribe many kinds of behaviour (and
encourage others either by implication or overtly), in order to move
beyond the symbolic level, they all require a strong enforcement mech-
anism, which includes various forms of policing and the courts. And
even here, a considerable amount of variation and discretion is possible
since inspections and policing can be more or less onerous and more
or less frequent, can be oriented towards responding to complaints or
actively looking for transgressions (‘police patrols’ vs ‘fire alarms’) and
can be focused on punishment of transgressions or prevention, in the
latter case often with a strong educational component designed to per-
suade citizens and others to adopt modes of behaviour more congruent
with government aims and objectives rather than punish them for each
transgression that occurs (McCubbins and Schwartz 1984). A desire for
100 per cent compliance on the part of governments requires a high
level of scrutiny, and thus some kind of ongoing, institutionalized gov-
ernment organization or agency: typically a line department such as a
police department or some other similar administrative bureau with
investigatory and policing powers.
All laws are intrusive, and many are highly visible. A significant prob-
lem with the use of laws in policy designs, however, pertains to cost and
precision of targeting. With respect to the first, while passage of a law is
usually not all that costly, the need for enforcement is. Laws have a low
64 Policy tools
degree of automaticity, as they rely upon citizen’s goodwill and per-
ceptions of legitimacy for them to be obeyed. Inevitably, this will not
ensure 100 per cent compliance and will thus require the establishment
of an enforcement agency, such as the police, customs agencies, immi-
gration patrols, coast guards and the courts. Precision of targeting is an
issue since most laws have general applicability and often cannot single
out specific groups or targets for differential treatment. These problems
have led to the use of alternate forms of regulation expected to reduce
these costs and allow for improved targeting of specific actors.
Source: Wu (2008).
IRCs are quasi-judicial in the sense that one of their main activi-
ties is adjudicating disputes over the interpretation and enforcement of
rules – a task taken away from the courts in order to ensure that exper-
tise in the specific activities regulated is brought to bear on a case in
order to have more expert, timely and predictable results. Decisions of
independent regulatory commissions are still subject to judicial review,
although often this is only in terms of issues relating to procedural fair-
ness, rather than the evidentiary basis of a decision.
IRCs are relatively inexpensive, specialized bodies that can remove
a great deal of the routine regulatory burden in many areas of social
and economic life from government departments and the courts, and
are quite popular with governments wishing to simplify their agendas
and reduce their need to supervise specific forms of social behaviour on
a day-to-day basis (Wonka and Rittberger 2010). In the contemporary
period, independent regulatory commissions are involved with all as-
pects of market behaviour, production, distribution and consumption,
as well as many areas of social life. Many specialized forms of IRCs
exist, such as the use of ‘marketing boards’, or arm’s-length regulatory
bodies often staffed by elected representatives of producers and granted
specific rights to control prices and/or supply in areas from chicken pro-
duction to organ donations, thereby creating and enforcing pricing and
supply regimes on producers (Royer 2008). This has occurred primarily
in areas affected by periodic bouts of over- or under-supply and can be
found in areas such as bulk agricultural commodities like wheat or milk
whose supply is very sensitive to price fluctuations, and in areas such as
liver and heart transplants, which are subject to chronic supply shortages
(Weimer 2007). These boards typically act as rationing boards charged
with allocating supply quotas and setting prices in order to smooth out
supply fluctuations in the activity involved. They are very common,
66 Policy tools
for example, in wartime when many goods are in short supply and
rationing goods from fuel to food often is a necessity.
IRCs, like more direct government regulation, have been the subject
of efforts at deregulation, as some governments attempted to move some
sectors towards more open market modes of operation. Some high-
profile privatization and deregulation in transportation, telecommunica-
tion and financial industries in many countries occurred in the 1980s and
1990s as a result of these efforts however there has been no across-the-
board reduction in the use of more directive tools. Like privatization,
deregulation is nowhere as widespread as claimed by both enthusiasts
and critics. Even in banking, the most globalized business sector, there is
little or no evidence of an overall decline of regulation, and the market
and credit crises of 2008 have rather led to increased moves in a re-
regulatory direction in many countries, from Iceland to the USA, as well
as at the international level. Indeed, regulations have been expanded in
many sectors to compensate for the loss of state control following privat-
ization of public enterprises ( Jordana and Levi-Faur 2004).
There are still some concerns about the use of this instrument in policy
designs, however, linked to considerations of cost and visibility. The cost
of enforcement by regulatory commissions can be quite high, depend-
ing on the availability of information, and the costs of investigation and
prosecution in highly legalistic and adversarial circumstances can also be
very large. Regulations also are often inflexible and do not permit the
consideration of individual circumstances, and can result in decisions and
outcomes not intended by the regulators. They can distort voluntary or
private sector activities and promote economic inefficiencies. Price reg-
ulations and direct allocation, for example, restrict the operation of the
forces of demand and supply and affect the price mechanism, thus causing
sometimes unpredictable economic distortions in the market. Restrictions
on entry to and exit from industrial sectors, for example, can reduce
competition and thus have a negative impact on prices. Regulations can
also inhibit innovation and technological progress because of the market
security they afford to existing firms and the limited opportunities for
experimentation they might permit. For these and other reasons, they are
often labelled as overly intrusive by many firms and actors (Dyerson and
Mueller 1993) and efforts to avoid them through other forms of regulation
(see below) are very common, though, not always successful.
Table 4.3 T
ypes of voluntary regulation
Table 4.4 A
ctions undertaken by procedural
authoritative instruments
Problem identification
Mobilizing interest
Spanning and bridging activities
Claims-making
Knowledge acquisition
Convening and deliberating
Community capacity-building
Transparency, evaluation and feedback
1. Source of advice
2. A source of support for regulators
3. A means of popularizing a regulatory regime
4. A ‘listening post’ for industry and government to listen to each other
5. A means of reaching agreement and resolving conflicts between
government and interests
6. A n agency for special inquiries
7. A device for patronage
8. A set of ambassadors for an administrative agency
1. From the point of view of publicity: how private and secret these
consultations are, versus public, open and transparent.
2. From the point of view of official status: whether consultations are
unofficial, semi-official or official.
3. From the point of view of origin: whether the consultations are ‘organic’
(traditional) or ‘inorganic’ (imposed).
4. From the point of view of imperiousness: whether participation is
optional or compulsory.
References
Abelson, Julia, Pierre-Gerlier Forest, John Eyles, Patricia Smith, Elisabeth
Martin, and Francois-Pierre Gauvin. “Deliberations about Deliberative
Methods: Issues in the Design and Evaluation of Public Participation Pro-
cesses.” Social Science and Medicine 57 (2003): 239–51.
Ajzen, Icek. “The Theory of Planned Behavior.” Organizational Behavior and
Human Decision Processes 50, no. 2 (1991): 179–211.
Averch, Harvey. Private Markets and Public Interventions: A Primer for Policy
Designers. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1990.
Baldwin, Robert, and Martin Cave. Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy
and Practice. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.
Brockman, Joan. “‘Fortunate Enough to Obtain and Keep the Title of Profes-
sion’; Self-Regulating Organizations and the Enforcement of Professional
Monopolies.” Canadian Public Administration 41, no. 4 (1998): 587–621.
Brown, David S. “The Public Advisory Board as an Instrument of Government.”
Public Administration Review 15 (1955): 196–201.
Brown-John, C. Lloyd. “Advisory Agencies in Canada: An Introduction.”
Canadian Public Administration 22, no. 1 (1979): 72–91.
Cushman, Robert Eugene. The Independent Regulatory Commissions. London:
Oxford University Press, 1941.
Dion, Leon. ‘The Politics of Consultation.’ Government and Opposition 8, no. 3
(1973): 332–53.
Dyerson, Romano, and Frank Mueller. “Intervention by Outsiders: A Strate-
gic Perspective on Government Industrial Policy.” Journal of Public Policy 13,
no. 1 (1993): 69–88.
Edley, Christopher F. J. Administrative Law: Rethinking Judicial Control of Bureau-
cracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1990.
Elgie, Robert. “Why Do Governments Delegate Authority to Quasi-Autonomous
Agencies? The Case of Independent Administrative Authorities in France.”
Governance 19, no. 2 (2006): 207–27.
Fligstein, Neil. “Markets and Politics: A Political-Cultural Approach to
Market Institutions.” American Sociological Review 61, (August 1996): 656–73.
Gibson, Robert B. Voluntary Initiatives: The New Politics of Corporate Greening.
Peterborough, ON: Broadview Press, 1999.
Gilardi, Fabrizio. “Policy Credibility and Delegation to Independent Regula-
tory Agencies: A Comparative Empirical Analysis.” Journal of European Public
Policy 9, no. 6 (2002): 873–93.
Glicken, Jessica. “Getting Stakeholder Participation ‘Right’: A Discussion of
Participatory Processes and Possible Pitfalls.” Environmental Science and Policy
3 (2000): 305–10.
Authoritative implementation tools 77
Gunningham, Neil, and Joseph Rees. “Industry Self-Regulation: An Institu-
tional Perspective.” Law Policy 19, no. 4 (1997): 363–414.
Haas, Peter M. “Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International
Policy Coordination.” International Organization 46, no. 1 (1992): 1–36.
Hall, Thad E., and Laurence J. O’Toole. “Shaping Formal Networks through
the Regulatory Process.” Administration & Society 36, no. 2 (2004): 186–207.
Heinmiller, B. Timothy. “The Poltiics of ‘Cap and Trade’ Policies.” Natural
Resources Journal 47, no. 2 (2007): 445–67.
Heinrichs, Harald. “Advisory Systems in Pluralistic Knowledge Societies: A
Criteria-Based Typology to Assess and Optimize Environmental Policy Ad-
vice.” In Democratization of Expertise? edited by Sabine Maasen and Peter
Weingart, 24, 41–61. Berlin and Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, 2005.
Hendriks, Carolyn, and Lyn Carson. “Can the Market Help the Forum?
Negotiating the Commercialization of Deliberative Democracy.” Policy
Sciences 41, no. 4 (December 1, 2008): 293–313.
Heritier, Adrienne, and Drik Lehmkuhl. “Introduction: The Shadow of Hierarchy
and New Modes of Governance.” Journal of Public Policy 28, no. 1 (2008): 1–17.
Jacobzone, Stephane. “Independent Regulatory Authorities in OECD Coun-
tries: An Overview.” In Designing Independent and Accountable Regulatory
Authorities for High Quality Regulation – Proceedings of an Expert Meeting in
L ondon, United Kingdom 10–11 January 2005, edited by OECD Working Party
on Regulatory Management and Reform, 72–100. Paris: OECD, 2005.
Jordana, Jacint, and David Levi-Faur, eds. The Politics of Regulation: Institutions
and Regulatory Reforms for the Age of Governance. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
Jordana, J, 2004.
Kerwin, Cornelius M. Rulemaking: How Government Agencies Write Law and
Make Policy. Washington, DC: CQ Press, 1999.
Keyes, John Mark. “Power Tools: The Form and Function of Legal Instru-
ments for Government Action.” Canadian Journal of Administrative Law and
Practice 10 (1996): 133–74.
Kiviniemi, Markku. “Public Policies and Their Targets: A Typology of the
Concept of Implementation.” International Social Science Journal 38, no. 108
(1986): 251–66.
Kuhlmann, Ellen, and Judith Allsop. “Professional Self-Regulation in a
Changing Architecture of Governance: Comparing Health Policy in the
UK and Germany.” Policy & Politics 36, no. 2 (2008): 173–89.
Leroux, Thérèse, Marie Hirtle, and Louis-Nicolas Fortin. “An Overview of
Public Consultation Mechanisms Developed to Address the Ethical and
Social Issues Raised by Biotechnology.” Journal of Consumer Policy 21, no. 4
(December 1, 1998): 445–81.
May, Peter J. “Social Regulation.” In The Tools of Government: A Guide to the
New Governance, edited by Lester M. Salamon, 156–85. New York: Oxford
University Press, 2002.
McCubbins, Mathew D., and Thomas Schwartz. “Congressional Oversight
Overlooked: Police Patrols Versus Fire Alarms.” American Journal of Political
Science 28, no. 1 (1984): 165–79.
78 Policy tools
Mitnick, Barry M. “The Concept of Regulation.” Bulletin of Business Research
53, no. 5 (1978): 1–20.
Moffet, John, and François Bregha. 1999. “Non-Regulatory Environmental
Measures.” In Voluntary Initiatives: The New Politics of Corporate Greening, ed-
ited by R. B. Gibson, 15–31. Peterborough: Broadview Press.
Phillips, Susan D., and Michael Orsini. 2002. Mapping the Links: Citizen Involve-
ment in Policy Processes. Ottawa, ON: Canadian Policy Research Networks.
Pierre, Jon. “Public Consultation and Citizen Participation: Dilemmas of
Policy Advice.” In Taking Stock: Assessing Public Sector Reforms, edited by
B. Guy Peters and Donald J. Savoie, 137–63. Montreal, QC: McGill-Queen’s
Press, 1998.
Porter, Tony, and Karsten Ronit. “Self-Regulation as Policy Process: The
Multiple and Crisscrossing Stages of Private Rule-Making.” Policy Sciences
39 (2006): 41–72.
Ramesh, M., and Michael Howlett. Deregulation and Its Discontents: Rewriting
the Rules in Asia. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 2006.
Reagan, Michael D. Regulation: The Politics of Policy. Boston, MA: Little Brown,
1987.
Rosenbloom, David H. “Administrative Law and Regulation.” In Handbook of
Public Administration, edited by Jack Rabin, W. Bartley Hildreth, and Gerald
J. Miller, 635–96. London: CRC Press, 2007.
Royer, Annie. “The Emergence of Agricultural Marketing Boards Revisited:
A Case Study in Canada.” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56
(2008): 509–22.
Sappington, David E. M. “Designing Incentive Regulation.” Review of Indus-
trial Organization 9, no. 3 ( June 1, 1994): 245–72.
Scherer, Frederic M. The Historical Foundations of Communications Regulation.
Boston, MA: Harvard University, 2008.
Scott, Colin. “Analysing Regulatory Space: Fragmented Resources and
Institutional Design.” Public Law (Summer 2001): 329–53.
Smith, Thomas B. “Advisory Committees in the Public Policy Process.” Inter-
national Review of Administrative Sciences 43, no. 2 (1977): 153–66.
Stavins, Robert N. “What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment?
Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12,
no. 3 (1998): 69–88.
Stigler, George Joseph. The Citizen and the State: Essays on Regulation. Chicago,
IL: University of Chicago Press, 1975.
Tallontire, Anna. “CSR and Regulation: Towards a Framework for Under-
standing Private Standards Initiatives in the Agri-Food Chain.” Third World
Quarterly 28, no. 4 (2007): 775–91.
Townsend, Ralph E., James McColl, and Michael D. Young. “Design Prin-
ciples for Individual Transferable Quotas.” Marine Policy 30 (2006): 131–41.
Tuohy, Carolyn J., and Alan D. Wolfson. “Self-Regulation: Who Qualifies?”
In The Professions and Public Policy, edited by Phillip Slayton and Michael J.
Trebilcock, 111–22. Toronto, ON: University of Toronto Press, 1978.
Authoritative implementation tools 79
Weimer, David L. “Public and Private Regulation of Organ Transplantation:
Liver Allocation and the Final Rule.” Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law
32, no. 1 (February 2007): 9–49.
Wolf Jr, Charles. “Markets and Non-Market Failures: Comparison and Assess-
ment.” Journal of Public Policy 7, no. 1 (1987): 43–70.
Wonka, Arndt, and Berthold Rittberger. “Credibility, Complexity and Un-
certainty: Explaining the Institutional Independence of 29 EU – Agencies.”
West European Politics 33, no. 4 (2010): 730.
Wu, Irene. “Who Regulates Phones, Television, and the Internet? What
Makes a Communications Regulator Independent and Why It Matters.”
Perspectives on Politics 6, no. 4 (2008): 769–83.
Ziller, Jacques. “Public Law: A Tool for Modern Management, Not an Im-
pediment to Reform.” International Review of Administrative Sciences 71, no. 2
(2005): 267–77.
5 Financial implementation
tools
Excise taxes
Excise taxes are another treasure-based tool, one that acts as a disincen-
tive to individuals, organizations and groups to undertake specific ac-
tions and activities. Cnossen (2005: 2) defines these as ‘all selective taxes
and related levies and charges on goods and services’. They have several
general purposes: (1) to raise revenue for general purposes, (2) to offset
‘external costs’ associated with the activity, like the costs of dealing
with negative health outcomes from smoking, (3) to discourage con-
sumption and (4) to pay for public goods like roads and infrastructure
from freight and shipping taxes and charges.
Raising revenue through taxes is, of course, the oldest technique of
government practised, from taxes placed on road use by the Romans
to the tea tax US colonists rebelled against at the Boston Tea Party
and is exercised by every level of government, from the local to the
national (Nowlan 1994). Using taxes to offset costs of production – to
pay for pollution clean-up or health consequences of tobacco use in or-
der to correct production or consumption ‘externalities’ like pollution
or carbon emissions which otherwise would be passed onto the general
public – is a much newer form (Pope and Owen 2009). A similar effort
involves the so-called ‘vice taxes’ collected in recent years for activities
such as gambling, alcohol consumption, lotteries or, more frequently in
the present era, various forms of ‘virtuous’ ‘green’ taxes such as those
designed to cover the cost of recycling car batteries or used oil or paint,
returnable bottle deposits or even carbon emissions, all designed to
84 Policy tools
offset the costs of the activities to external actors and society (Cnossen
2005). The use of motor fuel taxes to cover the cost of road construc-
tion or mass transit is an example of using specialized taxes to pay for
public goods.
Such taxes generally discourage the taxed activity by raising its price.
This, of course, can be a mixed blessing for activities such as public tran-
sit, and can often result in unintended consequences for items taxed in
order to raise revenues, both in terms of taxpayer resistance and upset,
and in the unintended encouragement of the increased use of non-taxed
items or substitute goods and services. They are generally inexpensive
to establish, although they require an extensive revenue collection and
enforcement presence to avoid evasion, and can be either highly visible,
if added onto prices, or almost invisible, if included with posted prices.
They can be targeted to specific kinds of goods and services and set up
to be highly automated. They are generally considered to be quite in-
trusive by those paying them, however, which is the main reason they
are often excluded from policy designs (Hofmann et al. 2014).
Preferential procurement
Preferential procurement involves the use of government purchases
to subsidize companies or investors which agree to abide by specific
provisions of government contracts. These can extend to preferential
treatment for firms which, for example, employ the disabled or women,
or ethnic or linguistic minorities, but also often extend to special
favourable treatment for small business, national defence contractors
and regional development schemes in which investors receive govern-
ment contracts if they agree to locate factories or distribution or other
services in specially designated regions (Rolfstam 2009).
Financial implementation tools 85
Procurement schemes play a major part in efforts by governments
to promote the ‘third sector’ or volunteer community- or group-based
delivery of public services discussed in Chapters 3 and 4 and are often a
part of corporatist governance arrangements (Dollery and Wallis 2003).
In many cases, it may be illegal or unconstitutional for a government
to directly deliver funding to such groups, especially if NGOs have
a religious or ‘faith base’ which can violate constitutional and other
legal limits separating church and state activities (Black et al. 2004).
However, these groups may still be able to receive favourable treatment
such as in bidding for government contracts, often making procure-
ment an important part of their funding base and a de facto subsidy to
their other religious activities (Carmel and Harlock 2008).
Like direct cash subsidies, many trade agreements attempt to ban
procurement plans which favour national over international suppliers,
but these provisions do not extend to favourable treatment for margin-
alized groups or individuals or companies linked to national defence
and security. Such procurement schemes, of course, by extending fa-
vourable treatment to some contractors, also act as a disincentive to
non-favoured groups and firms which are discouraged from bidding
for contracts and other services to the extent of the subsidy provided
(McCrudden 2004). The main advantage of such forms of subsidy over
other forms of payments is their low visibility profile, which encour-
ages their use. They can be organized in many different ways, from
open-bidding to closed, and involve a variety of clauses and requisites
concerning qualification for them (Bajari and Tadelis 2001).
Table 5.1 A
verage percentage of ‘seed money’ obtained by groups from each
source by group type
Foundations 38 38 0 23 19
The government 0 0 0 0 0
Corporations 0 1 17 3 2
Other
Associations 32 11 3 0 2
Individuals 19 18 3 28 29
Personal funds 0 31 60 43 43
Othera 11 1 17 3 5
Total 100 100 100 100 100
n 10 12 6 16 16
Government 33 40 38 52
Dues 8 20 9 0
Fund-raising 17 7 2 11
Other n/a 42 33 51 37
100 100 100 100
References
Anheier, Helmut K., Stefan Toepler, and S. Wojciech Sokolowski. “The Im-
plications of Government Funding for Non-Profit Organizations: Three
Propositions.” International Journal of Public Sector Management 10, no. 3
(1997): 190–213.
Atkinson, Michael M., and William D. Coleman. “Policy Networks, Policy Com-
munities and the Problems of Governance.” Governance 5, no. 2 (1992): 154–80.
Bajari, Patrick, and Steven Tadelis. “Incentives versus Transaction Costs: A
Theory of Procurement Contracts.” RAND Journal of Economics 32, no. 3
(2001): 387–407.
Balch, George I. “The Stick, the Carrot, and Other Strategies: A Theoretical
Analysis of Governmental Intervention.” Law and Policy Quarterly 2, no. 1
(1980): 35–60.
Binderkrantz, Anne. “Interest Group Strategies: Navigating Between Privi-
leged Access and Strategies of Pressure.” Political Studies 53 (2005): 694–715.
Black, Amy E., Douglas L. Koopman, and David K. Ryden. Of Little Faith:
The Politics of George W. PBush’s Faith-Based Initiative. Washington, DC:
Georgetyown University Press, 2004.
Burt, Sandra. “Canadian Women’s Groups in the 1980s: Organizational Devel-
opment and Policy Influence.” Canadian Public Policy 16, no. 1 (1990): 17–28.
Carmel, Emma, and Jenny Harlock. “Instituting the ‘Third Sector’ as a
Governable Terrain: Partnership, Procurement and Performance in the
UK.” Policy & Politics 36, no. 2 (2007): 155–71.
Cnossen, Sijbren. Theory and Practice of Excise Taxation: Smoking, Drinking,
Gambling, Polluting and Driving. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005.
Deber, Raisa, Marcus J. Hollander, and Philip Jacobs. “Models of Funding and
Reimbursment in Health Care: A Conceptual Framework.” Canadian Public
Administration 51, no. 3 (2008): 381–405.
Dollery, Brain E., and Joe L. Wallis. The Political Economy of the Voluntary Sector:
A Reappraisal of the Comparative Institutional Advantage of Voluntary Organiza-
tions. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2003.
94 Policy tools
Furlong, Scott R., and Cornelius M. Kerwin. “Interest Group Participation in
Rule Making: A Decade of Change.” Journal of Public Administration Research
and Theory 15, no. 3 (2004): 353–70.
Haider, Donald. “Grants as a Tool of Public Policy.” In Beyond Privatiza-
tion: The Tools of Government Action, edited by Lester M. Salamon, 93–124.
Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 1989.
Hofmann, Eva, Katharina Gangl, Erich Kirchler, and Jennifer Stark.
“Enhancing Tax Compliance through Coercive and Legitimate Power of
Tax Authorities by Concurrently Diminishing or Facilitating Trust in Tax
Authorities.” Law & Policy 36, no. 3 ( July 2014): 290–313.
Hood, Christopher. The Tools of Government. Chatham: Chatham House Pub-
lishers, 1986.
Howard, Christopher. The Hidden Welfare State: Tax Expenditures and Social
Policy in the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997.
Howlett, Michael, and Andrea Migone. “The Permanence of Temporary
Services: The Reliance of Canadian Federal Departments on Policy and Man-
agement Consultants.” Canadian Public Administration 56, no. 3 (2013): 369–90.
Hudson, John, Stuart Lowe, Natalie Oscroft, and Carolyn Snell. “Activating
Policy Networks: A Case Study of Local Environmental Policy-Making in
the United Kingdom.” Policy Studies 28, no. 1 (2007): 55–70.
Kash, Jeffrey P. “Enemies to Allies: The Role of Policy-Design Aadaptation in
Facilitating a Farmer-Environmentalist Alliance.” Policy Studies Journal 36,
no. 1 (2008): 39–60.
King, David C. “The Origins and Maintenance of Groups.” In Mobilizing
Interest Groups in America: Patrons, Professions and Social Movements, edited by
Jack L. Walker, 75–102. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991.
Klitgaard, Michael Baggesen. “School Vouchers and the New Politics of the
Welfare State.” Governance 21, no. 4 (2008): 479–98.
Leeuw, Frans L. “The Carrot: Subsidies as a Tool of Government.” In
Carrots, Sticks and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation, edited by
Bemelmans-Videc, Mary-Louise, Ray C. Rist, and Evert Vedung, Evert,
77–102. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 1998.
Lowry, Robert C. “Foundation Patronage toward Citizen Groups and Think
Tank: Who Gets Grants?” The Journal of Politics 81, no. 3 (1999): 758–76.
Lybecker, Kristina M., and Robert A. Freeman. “Funding Pharmaceutical In-
novation through Direct Tax Credits.” Health Economics, Politics and Law 2,
no. 3 (2007): 267–84.
Mahoney, Christine, and Michael Joseph Beckstrand. “Following the Money:
EU Funding of Civil Society Organizations.” Potsdam, 2009.
Maslove, Allan M. “Loans and Loan Guarantees: Business as Usual Versus the
Politics of Risk.” In How Ottawa Spends: The Liberals, The Opposition and
Federal Priorities, edited by G. Bruce Doern, 121–32. Toronto, ON: James
Lorimer, 1983.
Maslove, Allan M. “The Other Side of Public Spending: Tax Expenditures in
Canada.” In The Public Evaluation of Government Spending, edited by G. Bruce
Doern and Allan M. Maslove, 149–68. Toronto, ON: Buttersworth, 1979.
Financial implementation tools 95
McCrudden, Christopher. “Using Public Procurement to Achieve Social
Outcomes.” Natural Resources Journal 28 (2004): 257–67.
Nowlan, David M. “Local Taxation as an Instrument of Policy.” In The Chang-
ing Canadian Metropolis: A Public Policy Perspective, edited by Frances Frisken,
799–841. Berkeley, CA: Institute of Governmental Studies, 1994.
Nownes, Anthony J. “The Population Ecology of Interest Group Formation:
Mobilizing for Gay and Lesbian Rights in the United States, 1950–98.”
British Journal of Political Science 34, no. 1 (2004): 49–67.
Nownes, Anthony, and Grant Neeley. “Toward an Explanation for Public
Interest Group Formation and Proliferation: ‘Seed Money’, Disturbances, En-
trepreneurship, and Patronage.” Policy Studies Journal 24, no. 1 (1996): 74–92.
Olson, Mancur. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of
Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.
Pal, Leslie A. Interests of State: The Politics of Language, Multiculturalism, and
Feminism in Canada. Montreal, QC: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1993.
Phillips, Susan. “Meaning and Structure in Social Movements: Mapping the
Network of National Canadian Women’s Organizations.” Canadian Journal
of Political Science 24, no. 4 (1991): 755–82.
Phillips, Susan, and Tessa Hebb. “Financing the Third Sector: Introduction.”
Policy and Society 29, no. 3 (August 2010): 181–87.
Pope, Jeff, and Anthony D. Owen. “Emission Trading Schemes: Potential
Revenue Effects, Compliance Costs and Overall Tax Policy Issues.” Energy
Policy 37 (2009): 4595–603.
Rich, Andrew. Think Tanks, Public Policy, and the Politics of Expertise. New
York: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
Rolfstam, Max. “Public Procurement as an Innovation Policy Tool: The Role
of Institutions.” Science and Public Policy 36, no. 5 (2009): 349–60.
Schmitter, Philippe C. “Modes of Interest Intermediation and Models of
Societal Change in Western Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 10, no. 1
(1977): 7–38.
Stanbury, William T. “A Skeptic’s Guide to the Claims of So-Called Public
Interest Groups.” Canadian Public Administration 36, no. 4 (1993): 580–605.
Stasiulis, Daiva K. “The Symbolic Mosaic Reaffirmed: Multiculturalilsm
Policy.” In How Ottawa Spends 1988/89: The Conservatives Heading into the
Stretch, edited by Katherine A. Graham, 81–111. Ottawa, ON: Carleton
University Press, 1988.
Strolovitch, Dara Z. “Do Interest Groups Represent the Disadvantaged?
Advocacy at the Intersections of Race, Class and Gender.” The Journal of
Politics 68, no. 4 (2006): 894–910.
Sunnevag, Kjell J. “Designing Auctions for Offshore Petroleum Lease Alloca-
tion.” Resources Policy 26 (2000): 3–16.
Surrey, Stanley S. “Tax Incentives as a Device for Implementing Government
Policy: A Comparison with Direct Government Expenditures.” Harvard
Law Review 83, no. 4 (February 1, 1970): 705–38.
Toke, David. “Policy Network Creation: The Case of Energy Efficiency.”
Public Administration 78, no. 4 (2000): 835–54.
96 Policy tools
Valkama, Pekka, and Stephen J. Bailey. “Vouchers as an Alternative Public
Sector Funding System.” Public Policy and Administration 16, no. 1 (2001):
32–58.
Walker, Jack L. Mobilizing Interest Groups in America: Patrons, Professions and So-
cial Movements. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991.
Woodside, Ken. “Tax Incentives vs. Subsidies: Political Considerations in
Governmental Choice.” Canadian Public Policy 5, no. 2 (1979): 248–56.
6 Information-based
implementation tools
Information-based tools are those based on the last of the four categories
of resources set out by Hood (1986): ‘nodality’ or ‘centrality’ or, as defined
in Chapter 1, involved in communicating ‘knowledge’ or ‘information’
to target groups or collecting it from them in the expectation that this
will alter their behaviour or better inform government policy-making.
These are the ‘sermon’ in the ‘carrots, sticks and sermons’ formulation
of policy instruments, alongside the ‘carrot’ of financial tools and the
‘stick’ or authority-based ones.
As Evert Vedung defines them, information-based policy tools are
‘efforts to use the knowledge and data available to governments to
influence consumer and producer behaviour in a direction consistent
with government aims and wishes and/or gather information in order
to further their aims and ambitions’ (Vedung and van der Doelen 1998).
Exactly what is meant by the term ‘information’ or ‘communica-
tion’ varies from author to author, ranging from its association with
all forms of political activity to a very specific focus on one type of
action, like public service or political advertising (Firestone 1970). It is
also important to note that many new communication practices have
emerged in recent years, at least in part due to the development of new
information technologies, notably computerization, the internet and
the rise of social media, which have broadened the range and menu
of government nodality tools (Feldman and Khademian 2007). These
include the development and use of instruments which promote citizen
empowerment such as freedom of information (FOI) legislation, the use
of public performance measures, various forms of e- or ‘digital’ gov-
ernment and the increased use of government surveys and advertising
including in the use of platforms such as Twitter or Facebook, amongst
others (Margetts and Sutcliffe 2013).
And this definition, while useful, is limited in that it conceals or
elides the two different general purposes to which these resources can
98 Policy tools
be put. These are the familiar procedural versus substantive distinction
used throughout this book – whether these activities are intended to
serve as devices primarily oriented towards the manipulation of the
behaviour of policy actors in policy processes or as social and economic
ones involved in and affecting the production, distribution and con-
sumption of different types of goods and services ( Jahn et al. 2005).
Disentangling the two is necessary in order to provide a clearer analysis
of the role each plays in policy designs.
Information campaigns
Mass media and targeted information campaigns, on the other hand, are
much more visible, by definition, and tend to be aimed less at producers
than at consumers (Hornik 1989). Adler and Pittle (1984) describe these
tools as ‘notification instruments’ which ‘convey factual information to
the intelligent target. Implicit in the notification approach is the belief that
the target, once apprised of the facts, will make the appropriate decision’.
Some notification tools do attempt to be purely factual, ongoing and
passive in nature, such as nutritional labelling on foodstuffs or health
warnings on cigarettes (Padberg 1992; Baksi and Bose 2007). They
are usually enacted in regulations (i.e. disclosure is mandatory) and are
aimed at providing information to consumers allowing them to make
better decisions, or overcome information asymmetries between pro-
ducers and consumers, with the expectation that consumers will change
their behaviour in some way consistent with government goals – for
example, reducing smoking, exercising more or eating nutritional foods
100 Policy tools
rather than snacks ( Jahn et al. 2005). Although the evidence of the ef-
fectiveness of such campaigns is mixed (Mann and Wustemann 2010;
Barreiro-Hurlé et al. 2010), this has not dampened their growth.
Other information campaigns are more active and less factual, but
have the same intent, that is, providing social actors with more infor-
mation about aspects of their behaviour and its advantageous or dele-
terious quality, urging enhancement of the former and diminishment
of the latter. The information transmitted through such information
instruments is not always so factual, however, but can be used to ‘sell’ a
government’s policies in the same way that other products are marketed
(Rothschild 1979). Such campaigns are often conducted at the mass
level and use a variety of mass-media delivery mechanisms (commer-
cials, broadcasts, newspaper and social media advertisements and the
like). High-profile campaigns in many countries to prevent drinking
and driving or those that encourage the purchase of war bonds during
wartime are good examples of the use of this kind of instrument.
This kind of mass campaign began with the emergence of mass me-
dia and is now common in most countries, including in most cases
an extensive social media component. Many national governments are
now the largest purchasers of advertising in their countries and far out-
strip national brands well known for their advertising overkill, such
as alcoholic beverage, soft drink companies as well as fast food chains.
The federal government of Canada, for example, has been the larg-
est advertiser in the country since 1976 (Stanbury et al. 1983), with
the larger provincial governments in the top ten as well. Ryan (1995)
noted that federal advertising expanded from $3.4 million in 1968, to
$106.5 m illion in 1992, a 3,000 per cent increase. Even inflation ad-
justed this amounted to a 665 per cent increase in 25 years.
Although they can be costly, such campaigns are generally less expen-
sive than many other alternatives, although the costs of non-compliance
must also be taken into account (Pellikaan and van der Veen 2002).
Generally, governments will tend to include information tools and
government communications in policy designs only when:
i Changing default rules such as making people opt out rather than
in to some scheme,
ii Simplification of the options presented to individuals, such as a
shortened contract,
iii Use of social norms to encourage people to conform to certain
practices, such as not littering or jaywalking,
iv Increases in ease and convenience such as making bike paths and
exercise areas common and easily accessible,
v Disclosure, that is, mandating the provision of certain kinds of in-
formation, like the real interest rate charged to credit card debt,
vi Warnings, graphic or otherwise, to discourage behaviour, such as
mandatory pictures of cancer victims on cigarette packages,
vii Pre-commitment strategies such as the provision of peer-supported
anti-obesity or alcoholism support groups such as Weight Watchers
or Alcoholics Anonymous,
viii Reminders of important activities such as children’s dental ap-
pointment or vaccination schedules,
ix Eliciting implementation intentions through various campaigns
such as voter registration drives or pension planning and
102 Policy tools
x Informing people of the nature and consequences of their own past
choices such as informing them of the amount they have spent on
electricity in past months or years on their current bill.
Many of these items deal with the design of bills, forms or mailings
of various kinds and are intended to provide use and cost information
about their behaviour to consumers, which might otherwise be difficult
or impossible for them to collect and which might alter their behaviour,
such as revealing what is their water or electricity use compared to their
neighbours.
Although the idea of ‘nudging’ received a surge of attention in recent
years, the effectiveness of such measures remains unclear as does their
application. Evidence suggests, for example, that they may have a role to
play in solving large-scale policy issues such as energy conservation but
only when they are exercised in tandem with other policy tools such
as financial incentives or penalties (Schubert 2017). And their impact
appears to vary by country and target population.
Moreover, there may be an unintended ‘behavioural spillover’ of
nudges (Galizzi 2014). That is, there is a risk of infantilizing and dimin-
ishing people’s autonomous decision-making capacities by constantly
manipulating them, as happened often in the business world around,
for example, multiple subtle changes to mobile phone plans. They are
also subject to diminishing returns and also to a concern regarding the
potential for abuse in the use of nudging to shape people’s choices in
pro-government ways (Hausman and Welch 2010). Governments may
also be unable to counter ‘nudge’-style tactics employed by private mar-
ket institutions which, for example, encourage people to spend rather
than save, or smoke or gamble rather than abstain, to name only a few.
Hagman et al. (2015) also find significant differences in the receptive-
ness of different populations to nudging activity. They find a high de-
gree of acceptance towards ‘nudge’ policies among a sample population
drawn from Sweden and the United States, but also a majority of the
respondents perceiving such policies to be intrusive to their freedom of
choice. Policies that the researchers classified as pro-social (i.e. focusing
on social welfare) had a significantly lower acceptance rate compared
to pro-self nudge policies (i.e. focusing on private w elfare). In addition,
‘overt’ nudges, that is, those that target conscious, higher-order cogni-
tive processes of decision-making were preferred by people over ‘cov-
ert’ nudges (i.e. those that target subconscious, lower-order processes of
decision-making). (Felsen et al. 2013).
Regardless of the information-based behavioural tool being em-
ployed, whether a nudge, shove or budge, in cases where incentives for
Information-based implementation tools 103
non-compliance are high, such information-based tools may be u nlikely
to secure compliance by themselves. In such cases, policy-makers need
to think about both the barriers that may be preventing compliance and
how to match a variety of policy tools to the most important barriers,
taking into account the heterogeneity within the given population in
terms of their receptiveness to different tool uses.
Censorship
This has occurred in many countries during wartime but also in
peacetime, for example, as media, film or theatre censorship. This latter
use has been slowly whittled away in most advanced countries, as indi-
vidual rights in democratic states have been ruled to trump government
or collective ones, but wartime prohibitions of this kind remain very
common (Qualter 1985).
References
Anderson, Derrick M., and Andrew Whitford. “Designing Systems for the
Co-Production of Public Knowledge: Considerations for National Statis-
tical Systems.” Policy Design and Practice 1, no. 1 ( January 2, 2018): 79–89.
Baksi, Soham, and Pinaki Bose. “Credence Goods, Efficient Labeling P olicies,
and Regulatory Enforcement.” Environmental and Resource Economics 37
(2007): 411–30.
Bardach, E., and L. M. Salamon. “Social Regulation as a Generic Policy
Instrument.” In Beyond Privatization: The Tools of Government Action, edited
by L. M. Salamon, 197–229. Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 1989.
Barreiro-Hurlé, Jesús, Azucena Gracia, and Tiziana de-Magistris. “Does
Nutrition Information on Food Products Lead to Healthier Food Choices?”
Food Policy 35, no. 3 ( June 2010): 221–29.
Bennett, C. J., and C. D. Raab. The Governance of Privacy: Policy Instruments in
Global Perspective. Aldershot: Ashgate, 2003.
Burris, Scott, Peter Drahos, and Clifford Shearing. “Nodal Governance.”
Australian Journal of Legal Philosophy 30 (2005): 30.
Clarke, Amanda, Evert A. Lindquist, and Jeffrey Roy. “Understanding Govern-
ance in the Digital Era: An Agenda for Public Administration Research in
Canada.” Canadian Public Administration 60, no. 4 (December 1, 2017): 457–75.
Information-based implementation tools 109
Feldman, Martha S., and Anne M. Khademian. “The Role of the Public
Manager in Inclusion: Creating Communities of Participation.” Governance
20, no. 2 (2007): 305–24.
Felsen, Gidon, Noah Castelo, and Peter B. Reiner. “Decisional Enhance-
ment and Autonomy: Public Attitudes towards Overt and Covert Nudges.”
Judgment and Decision Making 8, no. 3 (2013): 202–13.
Firestone, O. J. The Public Persuader: Government Advertising. Toronto, ON:
Methuen, 1970.
Galizzi, Matteo M. “What Is Really Behavioral in Behavioral Health Policy?
And Does It Work?” Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 36, no. 1 (March
1, 2014): 25–60.
Gelders, Dave, and Øyvind Ihlen. “Government Communication about Po-
tential Policies: Public Relations, Propaganda or Both?” Public Relations
Review 36, no. 1 (March 2010): 59–62.
Hagman, William, David Andersson, Daniel Västfjäll, and Gustav Tinghög.
“Public Views on Policies Involving Nudges.” Review of Philosophy and Psy-
chology 6, no. 3 (May 28, 2015): 439–53.
Hastak, M., M. B. Mazis, and L. A. Morris. “The Role of Consumer Surveys
in Public Policy Decision Making.” Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 20,
no. 2 (2001): 170–85.
Hausman, Daniel M., and Brynn Welch. “Debate: To Nudge or Not to
Nudge*.” Journal of Political Philosophy 18, no. 1 (March 1, 2010): 123–36.
Hood, Christopher. The Tools of Government. Chatham: Chatham House
Publishers, 1986.
Hood, Christopher. “What Happens When Transparency Meets Blame-
Avoidance?” Public Management Review 9, no. 2 (2007): 191–210.
Hood, Christopher, and Helen Z. Margetts. The Tools of Government in the
Digital Age. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007.
Hornik, R. “The Knowledge-Behavior Gap in Public Information
Campaigns.” In Information Campaigns: Managing the Process of Social Change,
edited by C. Salmon. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1989: 219–37.
Jahn, G., M. Schramm, and A. Spiller. “The Reliability of Certification:
Quality Labels as a Consumer Policy Tool.” Journal of Consumer Policy 28
(2005): 53–73.
Johansson, R., and K. Borell. “Central Steering and Local Networks: Old-Age
Care in Sweden.” Public Administration 77, no. 3 (1999): 585–98.
Kahneman, Daniel. Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and
Giroux, 2013.
Mann, Stefan, and Henry Wustemann. “Public Governance of Information
Asymmetries: The Gap between Reality and Economic Theory.” The Jour-
nal of Socio-Economics 39, no. 2 (2010): 278–85.
Margetts, Helen, and David Sutcliffe. “Addressing the Policy Challenges
and Opportunities of ‘Big Data.’” Policy & Internet 5, no. 2 ( June 1, 2013):
139–46.
Nutley, Sandra M., Isabel Walter, and Huw T. O. Davies. Using Evidence: How
Research Can Inform Public Services. Bristol: Policy Press, 2007.
110 Policy tools
Padberg, D. I. “Nutritional Labeling as a Policy Instrument.” American Journal
of Agricultural Economics 74, no. 5 (1992): 1208–13.
Page, Christopher. The Roles of Public Opinion Research in Canadian Government.
Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2006.
Pasquier, Martial, and Jean-Patrick Villeneuve. “Organizational Barriers
to Transparency: A Typology and Analysis of Organizational Behaviour
Tending to Prevent of Restrict Access to Information.” International Review
of Administrative Sciences 73, no. 1 (2007): 147–62.
Pellikaan, Huib, and Robert J. van der Veen. Environmental Dilemmas and Policy
Design. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.
Qualter, T. H. Opinion Control in the Democracies. London: Macmillan, 1985.
Robert S. Adler and R. David Pittle. “Cajolry or Command: Are Education
Campaigns an Adequate Substitute for Regulation?” Yale Journal on Regula-
tion 1, no. 2 (1984): 159–93.
Rose, J. “Government Advertising in a Crisis: The Quebec Referendum Prec-
edent.” Canadian Journal of Communication 18 (1993): 173–96.
Rothmayr, C., and S. Hardmeier. “Government and Polling: Use and Impact
of Polls in the Policy-Making Process in Switzerland.” International Journal of
Public Opinion Research 14, no. 2 (2002): 123–40.
Rothschild, M. L. “Marketing Communications in Nonbusiness Situations or
Why It’s So Hard to Sell Brotherhood Like Soap.” Journal of Marketing 43,
no. Spring (1979): 11–20.
Rowe, Mike, and Laura McAllister. “The Roles of Commissions of Inquiry
in the Policy Process.” Public Policy and Administration 21, no. 4 (December
1, 2006): 99–115.
Ryan, P. “Miniature Mila and Flying Geese: Government Advertising and
C anadian Democracy.” In How Ottawa Spends 1995–96: Mid-Life Cri-
ses, e dited by S. D. Phillips, 263–86. Ottawa, ON: Carleton University
Press, 1995.
Salmon, C. “Campaigns for Social Improvement: An Overview of Values,
Rationales, and Impacts.” In Information Campaigns: Managing the Process of
Social Change, edited by C. Salmon, 1–32. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1989a.
Salmon, C. Information Campaigns: Managing the Process of Social Change.
Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1989b.
Schubert, Christian. “Green Nudges: Do They Work? Are They Ethical?”
Ecological Economics 132, no. Supplement C (February 1, 2017): 329–42.
Sheriff, P. E. “State Theory, Social Science, and Governmental Commissions.”
American Behavioural Scientist 26, no. 5 (1983): 669–80.
Stanbury, W. T., and J. Fulton. “Suasion as a Governing Instrument.” In How
Ottawa Spends 1984: The New Agenda, edited by A. Maslove, 282–324.
Toronto, ON: Lorimer, 1984.
Stanbury, W. T., G. J. Gorn, and C. B. Weinberg. “Federal Advertising
Expenditures.” In How Ottawa Spends: The Liberals, the Opposition and Federal
Priorities, edited by G. B. Doern, 133–72. Toronto, ON: James Lorimer and
Company, 1983.
Information-based implementation tools 111
Sunstein, Cass R. Why Nudge? The Politics of Libertarian Paternalism. Reprint
edition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2015.
Thaler, Richard H., and Cass R. Sunstein. Nudge: Improving Decisions about
Health, Wealth, and Happiness. Revised & Expanded edition. New York:
Penguin Books, 2009.
Vedung, E., and Frans C. J. van der Doelen. “The Sermon: Information
Programs in the Public Policy Process – Choice, Effects and Evaluation.”
In Carrots, Sticks and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation, edited
by M. L. Bemelmans-Videc and R. C. Rist, 103–28. New Brunswick, NJ:
Transaction Publishers, 1998.
Weiss, J. A., and M. Tschirhart. “Public Information Campaigns as Policy
Instruments.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 13, no. 1 (1994): 82–119.
Part III
Such interactions can range from ‘no effect’ to ‘direct interaction’, with
effects ranging from ‘duplication’ (positive or negative redundancy) to
‘extended coverage’ (positive redundancy) (del Rio 2014). E ffective
design involves avoiding strong conflicts, minimizing weak ones and
promoting complementarity and synergies. While this becomes more
difficult to do as the level of complexity of the design space increases, it
remains a central goal of policy portfolio design.
120 Designing policies and programmes
Sequencing: moving up the scale of coercion
in instrument choices
If policies are to entail a mix of tools, however, this raises the question
of whether they should all be adopted at one time or sequenced in some
fashion. A third principle of policy design which can be derived from
the older literature on the subject addresses these issues. This is the
idea that governments should be parsimonious in not only the num-
ber of instruments chosen at a specific point in time to attain a goal,
but also dynamically or sequentially. In the mid-1970s and the early
1980s, for example, G. Bruce Doern and his colleagues argued not only
that different policy instruments varied primarily in terms of the ‘de-
gree of government coercion’ each instrument choice entailed (Doern
and Wilson 1974) but also that tool choices should only ‘move up the
spectrum’ of coercion from minimum towards maximum, if and when
necessary.
This rationale is again based on a cost-effort calculation and is also
linked to an appreciation of the ideological preferences of liberal-
democratic governments for limited state activity and upon recogni-
tion of the difficulties posed to the exercise of state power and policy
compliance by the relative political ‘strength’ of the societal actors and
their ability to resist government efforts to shape their behaviour. As-
suming that all instruments are more or less technically ‘substitutable’
or could perform any task – although not necessarily as easily or at the
same cost – Doern and his colleagues argued that in a liberal dem-
ocratic society, governments, for both cost and ideological reasons,
prefer to use the least coercive instruments available and only ‘move
up the scale’ of coercion as far as is necessary in order to overcome
societal resistance to attaining their goals (Howlett 1991). Preferring
‘self-regulation’ as a basic default, for example, they argued govern-
ments should first attempt to influence overall target group perfor-
mance through exhortation and then only add instruments as required
in order to compel recalcitrant societal actors to abide by their wishes,
eventually culminating, if necessary, in the fully public provision of
goods and services.
References
Bode, I. “Disorganized Welfare Mixes: Voluntary Agencies and New Govern-
ance Regimes in Western Europe.” Journal of European Social Policy 16, no. 4
(2006): 346–59.
Creating an effective design policy 129
Boonekamp, Piet G.M. “Actual Interaction Effects Between Policy Measures
for Energy Efficiency—A Qualitative Matrix Method and Quantitative
Simulation Results for Households.” Energy 31, no. 14 (November 2006):
2848–73.
Braathen, Nils Axel. “Instrument Mixes for Environmental Policy: How
Many Stones Should Be Used to Kill a Bird?” International Review of Environ-
mental and Resource Economics 1, no. 2 (May 16, 2007): 185–235.
Brandl, James. “On Politics and Policy Analysis as the Design and Assessment of
Institutions.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 7, no. 3 (1988): 419–24.
Briassoulis, H. “Complex Environment Problems and the Quest of Policy
Integration.” In Policy Integration for Complex Environmental Problems: The Ex-
ample of Mediterranean Desertification, edited by Briassoulis, H, 1–49. Alder-
shot: Ashgate, 2005.
Capano, Giliberto. “Reconceptualizing Layering. From Mode of Institutional
Change to Mode of Institutional Design: Types and Outputs.” Public Admin-
istration, forthcoming 2019. doi:10.1111/padm.12583.
Capano, Giliberto, and Jun Jie Woo. “Resilience and Robustness in Policy
Design: A Critical Appraisal.” Policy Sciences 37, no. 4 (2018): 422–40.
Christensen, T., P. Laegreid, and L. R. Wise. “Transforming Administrative
Policy.” Public Administration 80, no. 1 (2002): 153–79.
Considine, Mark. “Thinking Outside the Box? Applying Design Theory to
Public Policy.” Politics & Policy 40, no. 4 (2012): 704–24.
deLeon, Peter. “The Contextual Burdens of Policy Design.” Policy Studies Jour-
nal 17, no. 2 (1988): 297–309.
Doern, G. B., and V. S. Wilson. “Conclusions and Observations.” In Issues in
Canadian Public Policy, edited by Doern, G. B., and V. S. Wilson, 337–45.
Toronto, ON: Macmillan, 1974.
Duesberg, Stefanie, Áine Ní Dhubháin, and Deirdre O’Connor. “Assessing
Policy Tools for Encouraging Farm Afforestation in Ireland.” Land Use Pol-
icy 38 (May 2014): 194–203.
Gleeson, Deborah, David Legge, Deirdre O’Neill, and Monica Pfeffer.
“Negotiating Tensions in Developing Organizational Policy Capacity:
Comparative Lessons to Be Drawn.” Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis:
Research and Practice 13, no. 3 ( June 2011): 237–63.
Grabosky, P. “Counterproductive Regulation.” International Journal of the Soci-
ology of Law 23 (1995): 347–69.
Gunningham, N., P. Grabosky, and D. Sinclair. Smart Regulation: Designing
Environmental Policy. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1998.
Head, Brian W. “Toward More ‘Evidence-Informed’ Policy Making?” Public
Administration Review 76, no. 3 (May 1, 2016): 472–84.
Hou, Yilin, and Gene Brewer. “Substitution and Supplementation Between
Co- Functional Policy Instruments: Evidence from State Budget Stabiliza-
tion Practices.” Public Administration Review 70, no. 6 (2010): 914–24.
Howlett, M. “Policy Instruments, Policy Styles, and Policy Implementation:
National Approaches to Theories of Instrument Choice.” Policy Studies Jour-
nal 19, no. 2 (1991): 1–21.
130 Designing policies and programmes
Howlett, M. Designing Public Policies: Principles and Instruments. New York:
Routledge, 2011.
Howlett, M. “From the ‘Old’ to the ‘New’ Policy Design: Design Thinking
Beyond Markets and Collaborative Governance.” Policy Sciences 47, no. 33
(May 28, 2014): 187–207.
Howlett, Michael P., and Jeremy Rayner. “Patching vs Packaging: Comple-
mentary Effects, Goodness of Fit, Degrees of Freedom and Intentionality
in Policy Portfolio Design.” SSRN Scholarly Paper. Rochester, NY: Social
Science Research Network, 2013.
Howlett, Michael, and Pablo del Rio. “The Parameters of Policy Portfolios: Ver-
ticality and Horizontality in Design Spaces and Their Consequences for Pol-
icy Mix Formulation.” Environment and Planning C 33, no. 5 (2015): 1233–45.
Howlett, Michael, and Ishani Mukherjee. Handbook of Policy Design. New
York: Routledge, 2019.
Howlett, Michael, and Jale Tosun, eds. Policy Styles and Policy-Making: Explor-
ing the Linkages. London: Routledge, 2019.
Jordan, Andrew, and Elah Matt. “Designing Policies That Intentionally Stick:
Policy Feedback in a Changing Climate.” Policy Sciences 47, no. 3 (2014):
227–47
Kern, Florian, and Michael Howlett. “Implementing Transition Management
as Policy Reforms: A Case Study of the Dutch Energy Sector.” Policy Sciences
42, no. 4 (November 1, 2009): 391–408.
Kirschen, E. S., J. Benard, H. Besters, F. Blackaby, O. Eckstein, J. Faaland, F.
Hartog, L. Morissens, and E. Tosco. Economic Policy in Our Time. Chicago,
IL: Rand McNally, 1964.
Knudson, William A. “The Environment, Energy, and the Tinbergen Rule.”
Bulletin of Science, Technology & Society 29, no. 4 (August 1, 2009): 308–12.
Lang, Achim. “Collaborative Governance in Health and Technology Policy:
The Use and Effects of Procedural Policy Instruments.” Administration &
Society, forthcoming (August 10, 2016).
Lanzalaco, Luca. “Bringing the Olympic Rationality Back In? Coherence, In-
tegration and Effectiveness of Public Policies.” World Political Science Review
7, no. 1 (May 25, 2011): 1098.
Larsen, T. P., P. Taylor-Gooby, and J. Kananen. “New Labour’s Policy Style:
A Mix of Policy Approaches.” International Social Policy 35, no. 4 (2006):
629–49.
Lasswell, H. “Key Symbols, Signs and Icons.” In Symbols and Values: An Initial
Study, edited by L. Bryson, L. Finkelstein, R. M. MacIver, and Richard
McKean, 77–94. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1954.
Maor, Moshe. “The Implications of the Emerging Disproportionate Policy
Perspective for the New Policy Design Studies.” Policy Sciences 50, no. 3
(September 1, 2017): 383–98.
Miller, S. M. “The Evolving Welfare State Mixes.” In Shifts in the Welfare Mix:
Their Impact on Work, Social Services and Welfare Policies, edited by A. Evers
and H. Winterberger, 371–88. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, 1990.
Creating an effective design policy 131
Moynihan, Donald P. “Combining Structural Forms in the Search for Policy
Tools: Incident Command Systems in U.S. Crisis Management.” Governance
21, no. 2 (2008): 205–29.
Nair, Sreeja, and Michael Howlett. “Policy Myopia as a Source of Policy Fail-
ure: Adaptation and Policy Learning under Deep Uncertainty.” Policy &
Politics 45, no. 1 (2017): 103–18.
Nair, Sreeja, and Michael Howlett. “Meaning and Power in the Design and
Development of Policy Experiments.” Futures, Policy-making for the long
term: puzzling and powering to navigate wicked futures issues, 76 (February
2016): 67–74.
Nielsen, Vibeke Lehmann, and Christine Parker. “Mixed Motives: Economic,
Social, and Normative Motivations in Business Compliance.” Law & Policy
34, no. 4 (2012): 428–62.
Oikonomou, V., A. Flamos, D. Zeugolis, and S. Grafakos. “A Qualitative As-
sessment of EU Energy Policy Interactions.” Energy Sources, Part B: Econom-
ics, Planning, and Policy 7, no. 2 (2011): 177–87.
Oikonomou, V., and C. J. Jepma. “A Framework on Interactions of Climate
and Energy Policy Instruments.” Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global
Change 13, no. 2 (February 15, 2008): 131–56.
Riddell, Norman. Policy Research Capacity in the Federal Government. Ottawa,
ON: Policy Research Initiative, 1998.
Rio, Pablo del. “Interactions between Climate and Energy Policies: The Case
of Spain.” Climate Policy 9, no. 2 (2009): 119–38.
Rio, Pablo del. “On Evaluating Success in Complex Policy Mixes: The Case
of Renewable Energy Support Schemes.” Policy Sciences 47, no. 3 (2014):
267–87.
Room, Graham. “Evidence for Agile Policy Makers: The Contribution of
Transformative Realism.” Evidence & Policy: A Journal of Research, Debate and
Practice 9, no. 2 (May 24, 2013): 225–44.
Sanderson, I. “Evaluation, Policy Learning and Evidence-Based Policy Mak-
ing.” Public Administration 80, no. 1 (2002): 1–22.
Schon, Donald A. The Reflective Practitioner: How Professionals Think In Action.
New York: Basic Books, 1984.
Swanson, Darren, Stephan Barg, Stephen Tyler, Henry Venema, Sanjay
Tomar, Suruchi Bhadwal, Sreeja Nair, Dimple Roy, and John Drexhage.
“Seven Tools for Creating Adaptive Policies.” Technological Forecasting and
Social Change 77, no. 6 (2010): 924–39.
Taeihagh, Araz, Moshe Givoni, and René Bañares-Alcántara. “Which Policy
First? A Network-Centric Approach for the Analysis and Ranking of Policy
Measures.” Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design 40, no. 4 (2013):
595–616.
Thelen, K. “How Institutions Evolve: Insights from Comparative Historical
Analysis.” In Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences, edited by J.
Mahoney and D. Rueschemeyer, 208–40. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press, 2003.
132 Designing policies and programmes
Tinbergen, Jan. On the Theory of Economic Policy. Dordrecht: North-Holland
Pub. Co., 1952.
Vreugdenhil, Heleen, Susan Taljaard, and Jill H. Slinger. “Pilot Projects
and Their Diffusion: A Case Study of Integrated Coastal Management in
South Africa.” International Journal of Sustainable Development 15, no. 1/2
(2012): 148.
Weaver, R. Kent. “Compliance Regimes and Barriers to Behavioral Change.”
Governance 27, no. 2 (April 1, 2014): 243–65.
Index
Note: Bold page numbers refers to tables and italics page numbers refer to
figures.