The document discusses the regulation of multinational enterprises by their home countries, highlighting key areas such as competition law, product safety, and employment regulations. It emphasizes the extraterritorial application of laws, particularly by the United States and the EU, and outlines the principles of antitrust law, including the Sherman Antitrust Act and the Clayton Act. Additionally, it details specific provisions of competition law in Egypt, including prohibitions on monopolistic practices and agreements that restrict competition.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0 ratings0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views16 pages
Chapter 4 - Home State Regulation of MNEs
The document discusses the regulation of multinational enterprises by their home countries, highlighting key areas such as competition law, product safety, and employment regulations. It emphasizes the extraterritorial application of laws, particularly by the United States and the EU, and outlines the principles of antitrust law, including the Sherman Antitrust Act and the Clayton Act. Additionally, it details specific provisions of competition law in Egypt, including prohibitions on monopolistic practices and agreements that restrict competition.
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 16
Dr.
AbdelRahman Mohamed Sayed
To the extent that a multinational enterprise operates within the domestic marketplace of its home country, the home country regulates it in the same way that national enterprises are regulated. The most important forms of national regulation include; (1) the regulation of competition, (2) the regulation of injuries caused by defective products, (3) the prohibition of sharp sales practices, (4) the regulation of securities, (5) the regulation of labor and employment, (6) the establishment of accounting standards, and (7) taxation. With the growth of international trade, many of these rules have been applied to activities that take place outside the territorial boundaries of a particular state, most notably the first three: regulation of competition, regulation of injuries caused by defective products, and prohibition of fraudulent sales practices. The country most willing to apply its laws extraterritorially has been the United States, an inclination the international community has not received kindly. Indeed, most countries regard such action as an intrusion into their domestic affairs. The United States has, nevertheless, persisted; and another major player in the international commercial community, the EU, has begun to apply its internal regulations extraterritorially as well. Competition law (a.k.a. Antitrust law) is the night-watchman of market economy. The goal of Antitrust Law is to ensure that the market functions optimally, because according to economists an optimal operation of the market leads to greater welfare. A well functioning market leads to productive efficiency A) the products are produced at lowest possible cost B) no more materials are used in production than is absolutely necessary C) Producers are forced to look at better production methods Competition law is a part of competition policy, that describes the way in which governments (or super national organizations like E.U.) take measures to promote competitive market competition policy : it must enforce competition law whenever there are harmful effects on citizens or business. It must ensure that the regulatory environment fosters competition markets also with screening proposed and existing legislations. It must develop a competition culture in the society in which it operates. An early example was enacted during the Roman Republic around 50 BC. To protect the grain trade, heavy fines were imposed on anyone directly, deliberately, and insidiously stopping supply ships. While the development of competition law stalled in Europe during the late 19th century, in 1889 Canada enacted what is considered the first competition statute of modern times. The Act for the Prevention and Suppression of Combinations formed in restraint of Trade was passed one year before the United States enacted the most famous legal statute on competition law, the Sherman Act of 1890. In the 1800s, in US there were several cartels in the form of “trusts”. They controlled important sectors of the economy, like railroads, oil, steel, sugar. The trusts threatened from all sides to bring the American economy under their control. Prices were high, and quality low. In the United States, the principal law regulating anticompetitive activity is the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890. Section 1 of the act prohibits contracts, agreements, and conspiracies that restrain interstate or international trade. The American courts have interpreted this as applying only to conduct between two or more parties and only to contracts that unreasonably restrain trade. In determining whether a particular activity violates §1, the courts ordinarily do so on a case-by-case basis using a so-called rule of reason. That is, “the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.” Over the years, however, certain agreements or joint actions involving interstate (but not international) trade have come to be classified as automatically illegal, or per se violations. These include (1) horizontal price fixing (where competitors at the same level expressly or impliedly agree to charge the same price for competing products), (2) vertical price fixing (where a seller at one level sells goods to a buyer at a different level on the condition that the latter will not resell below an agreed-upon price), (3) horizontal market division (where competitors agree not to sell in each other’s territories), and (4) joint refusals to deal (i.e., group boycotts). Once a particular kind of activity is classified as a per se violation, the courts do not apply the case-by-case rule of reason analysis but proceed directly to a consideration of the appropriate remedy in the particular case. Section 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act forbids monopolies and attempts to monopolize commerce or trade either between the states of the United States or in international commerce affecting the United States. Unlike Section 1, it applies to the conduct of a single enterprise if the enterprise is a “dominant firm,” that is, a firm that “has the power to control the price” of the commodity it produces and has the ability to “exclude competitors from the market.” To prove a violation, a plaintiff has to show that the defendant intended to monopolize the marketplace. This is normally done circumstantially, by showing a practice of discriminatory pricing, of dumping (i.e., selling goods below their cost of production), of using tying clauses (i.e., requiring purchasers of one product to buy other unrelated products), or similar conduct. The Clayton Act of 1914 was enacted to give more teeth to the Sherman Antitrust Act, both by expanding its enforcement provisions and by defining certain specific acts that constitute unfair business competition. These include exclusive dealing and tying clauses, mergers that result in a monopoly, and interlocking directorates. The Robinson-Patman Act of 1936 was added to the panoply of American anti-trust law to make price discrimination illegal. The Law No. 3 of 2005 on the Protection of Competition and the Prohibition of Monopolistic Practices. In the application of the provisions of this Law, dominance in a relevant market is the ability of a Person, holding a market share exceeding 25% of the aforementioned market, to have an effective impact on prices or on the volume of supply on it, without his competitors having the ability to limit it. The provisions of this Law shall apply to acts committed abroad should these acts result into the prevention, restriction or harm of the freedom of competition in Egypt and which constitute crimes under this Law. Agreements or contracts between competing Persons in any relevant market are prohibited if they are intended to cause any of the following: a) Increasing, decreasing or fixing prices of sale or purchase of products subject matter of dealings. b) Dividing product markets or allocating them on grounds of geographic areas, distribution centers, type of customers, goods, seasons or time periods. c) Coordinating with regard to proceeding or refraining from participating in tenders, auctions, negotiations and other calls for procurement. d) Restricting the production, distribution or marketing operations, or limiting the distribution of services in terms of its kind or volume or applying restrictions or conditions for their availability. Agreements or contracts between a Person and any of its supplier or clients are prohibited if they are intended to restrict competition. A Person holding a dominant position in a relevant market is prohibited from carrying out any of the following: a) Undertaking an act that leads to the non-manufacturing, or non- production or the non-distribution of a product for a certain period or certain periods of time. b) Refraining to enter into sale or purchase transactions regarding a product with any Person or totally ceasing to deal with him in a manner that results in restricting that Person’s freedom to access or exit the market at any time. c) Undertaking an act that limits distribution of a specific product, on the basis of geographic areas, distribution centers, clients, seasons or periods of time among Persons with vertical relationships. d) To impose as a condition, for the conclusion of a sale or purchase contract or agreement of a product, the acceptance of obligations or products unrelated by their very nature or by commercial custom to the original transaction or agreement. e) Discriminating between sellers or buyers having similar commercial positions in respect of sale or purchase prices or in the terms of the transaction. f) Refusing to produce or provide a product that is circumstantially scarce when its production or provision is economically possible. g) Dictating on Persons dealing with him not to permit a competing person to have access to their utilities or services, despite this being economically viable. h) Selling products below their marginal cost or average variable cost. i) Obliging a supplier not to deal with a competitor. The provisions of this Law shall not apply to public utilities managed by the State. The Authority may, upon the request of the concerned parties, exempt some or all the acts provided for in articles 6, 7 and 8 regarding public utilities that are managed by companies subject to the Private Law where this is in the public interest or for attaining benefits to the consumers that exceed the effects of restricting the freedom of competition. This shall be done in accordance with the regulations and procedures set out by the Executive Regulation of this Law.