ECON210 Lecture 3
ECON210 Lecture 3
Elasticity
Rengin Meryem Ayhan
• Situation: Severe drought leads farmers to leave 500,000 acres of land fallow.
• Effect:
• Effect:
1
3. Edible Oils (China and India)
• Situation: A growing middle class in China and India demands more edible oils; U.S.
farmers shift land from soy to corn (for ethanol).
• Effect:
• A movement along the curve occurs when the good’s own price changes, holding
other factors constant.
• A shift of the curve occurs when external factors (e.g., weather, technology, incomes,
tastes) change.
2
Figure 2: Demand and Supply Applications
Matching Exercise
Match each scenario to the correct shifts:
The exercise reinforces:
• If demand shifts right more than supply, price tends to rise significantly.
• If supply shifts left more than demand, quantity tends to fall sharply.
• Combinations of shifts can lead to ambiguous outcomes if both curves move in the
same direction with differing magnitudes.
1. Price Ceilings
A price ceiling is a government-imposed limit on how high a price can be charged for a
good or service. When the ceiling is set below the market equilibrium, it creates a shortage
because the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied at that artificially low price.
Rent Control Example: Rent control has been implemented in various cities, such
as Paris (especially during and after World War II) and New York. While it aims to keep
housing affordable, several unintended consequences often arise.
3
Figure 3: Demand and Supply Applications
• Outcome: Chronic shortages, lower-quality apartments, and black markets for rental
units.
• Historical Cases: Rent controls in Paris and New York City often led to mismatches
between supply and demand.
2. Price Floors
A price floor is a government-imposed minimum price, set above the market equilibrium.
Minimum Wage Example
• Goal: Ensure workers receive a wage deemed sufficient for basic living expenses.
• Debate: Some argue moderate minimum wages have minimal negative effects; others
highlight reduced job opportunities for lower-skilled workers.
3. Excise Taxes
An excise tax is placed on a specific good, such as boats or cigarettes.
Boat Tax Example
4
Figure 4: Demand and Supply Applications
• Goal: The United States introduced a luxury tax on expensive boats. Generate
revenue from luxury goods.
• Outcome: Reduces quantity sold; tax burden shared by producers and consumers
depending on elasticity.
• Revenue vs. Quantity: If demand is elastic, total revenue from the tax may be lower
than anticipated.
4. Tariffs
A tariff is a tax on imported goods, aimed at protecting domestic producers by making
foreign products more expensive in the domestic market.
*Steel Tariff Example
• Goal: A 30% tariff was imposed on imported steel in the early 2000s to shield U.S.
steelmakers from cheaper foreign competition.
• Outcome: Higher domestic steel prices benefit local steel producers but raise costs for
industries relying on steel (e.g., car manufacturers). This can lead to higher consumer
prices and potentially reduced trade volume.
5
Figure 5: Demand and Supply Applications
5. Quantity Restrictions
A quantity restriction is a government-imposed limit on how many units of a good or
service can be produced or sold.
• Historical Context: In 1937, New York City began issuing a fixed number of taxi
licenses (medallions), effectively restricting the supply of taxis.
• Market Effect: With a capped number of medallions, demand for taxi services grew
over time, driving up the value of each medallion. Medallions were bought and sold on
a secondary market at high prices.
• Implications:
6
– Drivers without medallions had to purchase or lease them from existing holders,
often at steep costs.
– The limited number of taxis contributed to higher fares, benefiting medallion
owners but reducing competition.
Conclusion
All these interventions alter market equilibria by shifting supply or demand curves and
imposing legal constraints on prices. While they may achieve specific objectives, they also
produce unintended side effects such as shortages, surpluses, and inefficiencies. Economists
analyze these outcomes by looking at changes in equilibrium price, quantity, and overall
welfare, balancing efficiency against equity considerations.
Appendix
These simple linear equations illustrate the fundamental distinction between supply and
demand:
• Demand: Negatively sloped; higher prices reduce the quantity consumers purchase.
Equilibrium Condition
Market equilibrium occurs where the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded:
a + bP = c − dP.
7
Figure 7: Demand and Supply Applications
5
5 + 2P = 10 − P =⇒ 3P = 5 =⇒ P∗ = ≈ 1.67.
3
Then, Q∗ = 5 + 2(1.67) ≈ 8.33.
• Quantity Supplied Increases: Suppliers are more willing to provide larger quan-
tities at higher prices (reflecting the positive relationship between price and quantity
supplied).
8
Figure 8: Demand and Supply Applications
• Quantity Demanded Decreases: Consumers buy fewer units as the price goes up
(reflecting the negative relationship between price and quantity demanded).
A change in the price of the good causes a movement along the existing supply or demand
curve. For instance, if the price increases from $1 to $2, the change in quantity demanded
or supplied can be calculated by substituting the new price into the equation.
• A rightward shift in the supply curve, increasing the quantity supplied by a constant
amount at every price.
• A rightward shift in the demand curve, increasing the quantity demanded by a constant
amount at every price.
• Additional examples illustrating how to set up and solve linear supply and demand
equations step by step.
9
1. Shifting Supply: Example
Suppose the original supply equation is:
QS = −5 + 2P,
and we shift it outward by 3 units at every price, making the new supply:
Q′S = −2 + 2P.
QD = 10 − P.
10 − P = −2 + 2P.
3P = 12 =⇒ P ∗ = 4.
Q′S = −2 + 2(4) = 6 or QD = 10 − 4 = 6.
Thus, the equilibrium price rises to $4, and the equilibrium quantity becomes 6 units, con-
sistent with a rightward shift in supply raising both price and quantity.
QD = 10 − P,
10
If supply remains at QS = −5 + 2P , then:
13 − P = −5 + 2P =⇒ 3P = 18 =⇒ P ∗ = 6.
QS = −5 + 2(6) = 7 or Q′D = 13 − 6 = 7.
Hence, the new equilibrium is (P ∗ , Q∗ ) = (6, 7). This scenario shows how a rightward shift
in demand increases both equilibrium price and quantity.
and
Q∗ = −100 + 4(100) = 300.
QS = −5 + 2P, QD = 10 − P.
11
1. Equilibrium Calculation
−5 + 2P = 10 − P
3P = 15
P ∗ = 5, Q∗ = 5.
Thus, the equilibrium price is $5, and the equilibrium quantity is 5 units.
2. Price Ceiling at $4
A price ceiling is a government-imposed maximum price set below equilibrium:
P = 4.
• Quantity Demanded: QD = 10 − 4 = 6.
P = 6.
• Quantity Demanded: QD = 10 − 6 = 4.
Excise Taxes
An excise tax on a good introduces a wedge between the price consumers pay (PD ) and the
price producers receive (PS ). For a per-unit tax t levied on producers:
PS = PD − t.
This effectively shifts the supply curve upward. The new equilibrium is found by substituting
PS into the supply equation and solving for the adjusted equilibrium.
12
1. Tax on the Supplier
Original Supply and Demand
QS = −5 + 2P, QD = 10 − P.
−5 + 2P = 10 − P =⇒ 3P = 15 =⇒ P ∗ = 5, Q∗ = 5.
17
−7 + 2P = 10 − P =⇒ 3P = 17 =⇒ P = ≈ 5.67.
3
This is the price consumers pay. The supplier receives P − 1 ≈ 4.67. The new equilibrium
quantity is found by substituting P back:
17 −21 + 34 13
Q = −7 + 2 = = ≈ 4.33.
3 3 3
2. Tax on the Demander
If the $1 tax is placed on demanders, they effectively pay (P + 1) for each unit. The
demand equation becomes:
QD = 10 − (P + 1) = 9 − P.
14
−5 + 2P = 9 − P =⇒ 3P = 14 =⇒ P = ≈ 4.67.
3
Here, the supplier receives P ≈ 4.67, while consumers pay P + 1 ≈ 5.67. Substituting P into
either equation yields:
14 −15 + 28 13
Q = −5 + 2 = = ≈ 4.33.
3 3 3
13
• Supplier Tax: Consumer price is $5.67, producer net is $4.67.
Subsidies
Subsidies work like negative taxes by lowering production costs or increasing effective de-
mand. A subsidy shifts the supply curve downward (or the demand curve upward) and leads
to a higher equilibrium quantity, with a differential between the price paid by consumers
and the net price received by producers.
QD > QS .
Example: Rent control in some cities restricts rental prices, leading to housing shortages
and reduced property maintenance.
Price Floors A price floor is a legal minimum price set above the market equilibrium.
When binding, it creates a surplus because:
QS > QD .
Example: A minimum wage set above the market-clearing wage can lead to unemployment
as the number of workers willing to work exceeds the number of jobs available at that wage.
5. Quotas
A quota is a government-imposed limit on the quantity of a good that can be produced or
sold. Instead of controlling price directly, quotas restrict the maximum quantity available,
which can lead to higher prices if demand remains strong. Quotas may create an implicit
price called quota rent, similar in effect to the wedge created by a tax. Example: Quota
of 34 Units Consider a simple demand equation:
QD = 10 − P,
14
and a quota limiting supply to:
4
QS = .
3
Since the quantity supplied is fixed at 43 , the market price must adjust until consumers are
willing to buy exactly 43 units.
Finding the Price Set QD = 43 :
4 4 26
= 10 − P =⇒ P = 10 − = ≈ 8.67.
3 3 3
This is the price consumers pay. Suppliers receive this entire amount since there is no explicit
tax, but they can only sell 43 units in total.
Comparison to a Tax
Much like a tax, a quota restricts the quantity below equilibrium. However, the difference
is:
• Tax: Creates a wedge between the price consumers pay and the price producers receive.
The government collects tax revenue.
• Quota: Imposes a hard cap on quantity, raising the market price until demand meets
that fixed supply. The “quota rent” (the difference between the lower free-market price
and the higher quota-driven price) goes to whoever holds the quota rights.
6. Overall Takeaways
• Algebraic methods allow us to calculate equilibrium price and quantity precisely.
• Movements along the curves are driven by changes in the good’s own price, while
shifts result from changes in external factors.
• Taxes and subsidies alter the effective prices, shifting curves and changing equilib-
rium outcomes.
• Price ceilings and floors are direct government interventions that can lead to short-
ages or surpluses.
• Quotas restrict the total quantity available and can raise market prices.
15
Conclusion
By transitioning from graphical representations to algebraic equations, we gain a clearer,
quantitative understanding of how market forces interact and how policies impact these
forces. Whether dealing with taxes, subsidies, price controls, or quantity restrictions, the
algebraic approach helps us predict changes in equilibrium and assess the trade-offs involved.
This framework is essential for analyzing both theoretical models and real-world economic
policies.
Because supply generally has a direct relationship with price, Es is typically reported as
a positive value. In contrast, demand has an inverse relationship with price, leading to a
negative elasticity, though economists often discuss the magnitude as a positive number for
convenience.
Illustrative Examples
• Price Elasticity of Demand Example: If the price of a good rises by 10% and
quantity demanded falls by 20%, the price elasticity of demand is:
20%
Ed = = 2.
10%
Even though the mathematical result is −2 due to the inverse relationship, economists
typically use the absolute value and say “2” to emphasize the responsiveness.
16
• Price Elasticity of Supply Example: Suppose the price rises by 10%, and quantity
supplied increases by 2%. The price elasticity of supply is:
2%
Es = = 0.2.
10%
This relatively small value indicates that suppliers are not highly responsive to price
changes in this scenario.
• Another Demand Example: If a 10% price hike causes a 15% drop in quantity
demanded, the price elasticity of demand is:
15%
Ed = = 1.5.
10%
Interpretation
• A larger elasticity (greater than 1 in absolute value) means quantity is highly re-
sponsive to price changes.
• A smaller elasticity (less than 1 in absolute value) indicates quantity changes rela-
tively little in response to price shifts.
Price elasticity of demand and supply quantitatively measures how much the quan-
tity demanded or supplied responds to a change in price. A higher elasticity value indicates a
more pronounced response to price shifts, while a lower elasticity value suggests a relatively
minor response.
• Elasticity of Demand = 5: The same 10% increase in price causes a 50% drop in
quantity demanded, reflecting a highly responsive (elastic) demand.
2. Types of Elasticity
• Elastic Demand: Elasticity > 1. A 1% price increase leads to more than a 1% decrease
in quantity demanded.
• Inelastic Demand: Elasticity < 1. A 1% price increase leads to less than a 1% decrease
in quantity demanded.
17
• Perfectly Inelastic: Elasticity = 0. Quantity demanded does not change at all with
price (rare in real markets).
• Case 2 (Gasoline in Washington, D.C.): When gas prices rose by 1%, quantity
demanded fell by 4%. This corresponds to an elasticity of 4, showing an elastic response
to price changes.
P2 − P1
%∆P = (P2 +P1 )
× 100%.
2
Q2 − Q1
%∆Q = (Q2 +Q1 )
× 100%.
2
Once these percentage changes are found, price elasticity of demand is:
%∆Q
Ed = .
%∆P
Illustrative Example
If the price increases from $20 to $26:
(26 − 20) 6
%∆P = 26+20 × 100% = × 100% ≈ 26.1%.
2
23
18
Figure 9: Demand and Supply Applications
(10 − 14) −4
%∆Q = 10+14 × 100% = × 100% = −33.3%.
2
12
• Low-price, high-quantity region: Demand (or supply) becomes less elastic because
a change in quantity is a smaller percentage relative to the larger base quantity.
19
6. Five Terms to Describe Elasticity
1. Perfectly Elastic (E = ∞): Even a tiny price change causes an infinite change in
quantity.
2. Elastic (E > 1): The percentage change in quantity exceeds the percentage change in
price.
3. Unit Elastic (E = 1): The percentage change in quantity equals the percentage
change in price.
4. Inelastic (E < 1): The percentage change in quantity is smaller than the percentage
change in price.
5. Perfectly Inelastic (E = 0): Quantity does not respond at all to price changes.
• The point at which E = 1 (unit elastic) divides the curve into an elastic region above
and an inelastic region below (for a typical downward-sloping demand curve).
• Supply curves can also move from perfectly inelastic (where the curve intercepts the
quantity axis) to perfectly elastic (where it intercepts the price axis), changing elasticity
along the way.
• Time Horizon: Demand (or supply) often becomes more elastic over time as con-
sumers (or producers) find alternatives or adjust behaviors.
• Necessities vs. Luxuries: Necessities (e.g., salt) tend to be inelastic; luxuries (e.g.,
cheesecake) are more elastic.
20
Figure 10: Demand and Supply Applications
• Share of Budget: Goods that consume a large portion of one’s budget are more
elastic in demand because price changes have a greater impact on overall spending.
Illustrative Examples
• Gas Taxes: A 10% price increase may have only a small immediate effect on quantity
demanded if consumers lack quick alternatives, but over time, they may buy more
fuel-efficient cars, making long-run demand more elastic.
• Regional Price Differences: In border areas (e.g., Vermont vs. New Hampshire,
21
Washington vs. Oregon), consumers may cross state lines to take advantage of cheaper
prices, showing higher elasticity for certain goods.
22
10. Other Types of Elasticity
Income Elasticity of Demand
- If a good is normal, the income elasticity is positive (EI > 0). - If a good is inferior, the
income elasticity is negative (EI < 0). - For a necessity, 0 < EI < 1; for a luxury, EI > 1.
Examples - Luxury vs. Necessity: A 20% income increase might raise music stream-
ing consumption by more than 20% if it’s considered a luxury (elastic). By contrast, a basic
staple like shoes might have an income elasticity between 0 and 1, showing a smaller propor-
tional increase in quantity demanded. - Inferior Goods: Some goods (e.g., certain cheaper
staple foods) may experience a decline in consumption as income rises.
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
- If the cross-price elasticity is positive, the goods are substitutes (e.g., iPhones and
Android phones). - If it is negative, the goods are complements (e.g., hot dogs and
buns). - If it is zero, the goods are unrelated.
Examples - Beef and Lamb: If the price of beef rises, and consumers switch to lamb,
we see a positive cross-price elasticity for lamb. - Gasoline and Cars: Typically, gasoline
and large cars could be seen as complements, implying a negative cross-price elasticity if a
price change in one affects demand for the other in the opposite direction.
• Elastic Demand: If demand is elastic, raising prices can lead to a significant drop in
quantity demanded, causing total revenue to fall. In such markets, lowering the price
could increase total revenue by attracting more buyers.
23
12. The Power of Supply/Demand Analysis
• Long-Run vs. Short-Run Effects: Elasticities often grow larger over time as buy-
ers adjust. A short-run price hike could yield higher revenue, but in the long run,
consumers may reduce usage or switch to substitutes, eroding those gains.
• Firm Strategy: Firms use elasticity insights to forecast how a price change will affect
revenue and profit, considering both immediate reactions and longer-term adjustments
in the market.
• Policy Insight: Policymakers also rely on elasticity analysis to anticipate how taxes,
subsidies, or regulations will shift consumption, production, and overall market behav-
ior.
Key Insight
• Elastic Demand (or Supply): A shift in the opposite curve (supply or demand)
primarily affects quantity rather than price. For example, if demand is highly elastic
and supply shifts, the new equilibrium will see a large change in quantity but only a
small change in price.
• Inelastic Demand (or Supply): A shift in the opposite curve largely affects price
rather than quantity. For example, if demand is highly inelastic and supply shifts,
the new equilibrium will show a significant price change but only a minor change in
quantity.
24
Conclusion
Understanding whether supply or demand is elastic or inelastic is crucial for predicting
how shifts in one curve will affect equilibrium. If either side is inelastic, expect substantial
price movements and minimal quantity changes. If either side is elastic, anticipate more
substantial quantity changes and smaller price adjustments. This interplay helps economists
and policymakers forecast market outcomes when external factors (technology, preferences,
resource costs, etc.) shift supply or demand.
25