Fundamentals of Corporate Finance, 11ce - Compressed-662-731
Fundamentals of Corporate Finance, 11ce - Compressed-662-731
CHAPTER 13
Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line
Iftekkhar/Shutterstock
As of December 2020, Discovery, Inc. (DISCA) posted a return of 26.6%, outperforming the
S&P 500, which finished 2020 with a gain of 16.26% for the year. In hindsight, investing in
DISCA looks better than S&P 500. But can we judge an investment only on the basis of return?
Indeed, one cannot talk about returns in isolation because investment decisions always involve
a trade-off between risk and return. This chapter explores the relationship between risk and
return, and also introduces the important concepts of diversification and asset pricing.
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
LO The calculation for expected returns and standard deviations for individual
In our last chapter, we learned some important lessons from capital market history. Most importantly, there is
a reward, on average, for bearing risk. We called this reward a risk premium. The second lesson is that this risk
premium is larger for riskier investments. The principle that higher returns can be earned only by taking greater
risks appeals to our moral sense that we cannot have something for nothing. This chapter explores the
economic and managerial implications of this basic idea.
Thus far, we have concentrated mainly on the return behaviour of a few large portfolios. We need to expand our
consideration to include individual assets and mutual funds. Accordingly, the purpose of this chapter is to
provide the background necessary for learning how the risk premium is determined for such assets.
Page 468
When we examine the risks associated with individual assets, we find two types of risk: systematic and
unsystematic. This distinction is crucial because systematic risks affect almost all assets in the economy, at
least to some degree, while a particular unsystematic risk affects at most a small number of assets. We then
develop the principle of diversification, which shows that highly diversified portfolios tend to have almost no
unsystematic risk.
The principle of diversification has an important implication. To a diversified investor, only systematic risk
matters. It follows that in deciding whether to buy a particular individual asset, a diversified investor is
concerned only with that asset’s systematic risk. This is a key observation, and it allows us to say a great deal
about the risks and returns on individual assets. In particular, it is the basis for a famous relationship between
risk and return called the security market line, or SML. To develop the SML, we introduce the equally famous
beta coefficient, one of the centrepieces of modern finance. Beta and the SML are key concepts because they
supply us with at least part of the answer to the question of how to determine the required return on an
investment.
LO1 13.1 | Expected Returns and Variances
In the previous chapter, we discussed how to calculate average returns and variances using historical data.
We now begin to discuss how to analyze returns and variances when the information we have concerns future
possible returns and their possibilities.
Expected Return
We start with a straightforward case. Consider a single period of time; say, one year. We have two stocks, L
and U, with the following characteristics. Stock L is expected to have a return of 25% in the coming year,
while Stock U is expected to have a return of 20% for the same period. 1
In a situation like this, if all investors agreed on the expected returns, why would anyone want to hold Stock
U? After all, why invest in one stock when the expectation is that another will do better? Clearly, the answer
must depend on the risk of the two investments. The return on Stock L, although it is expected to be 25%,
could actually be higher or lower.
For example, suppose the economy booms. In this case, we think Stock L would have a 70% return. If the
economy enters a recession, we think the return would be −20%. Thus, we say there are two states of the
economy, meaning that these are the only two possible situations. This setup is oversimplified, of course,
but it allows us to illustrate some key concepts without a lot of computation.
Suppose we think a boom and a recession are equally likely to happen, a 50–50 chance of either.
Table 13.1 illustrates the basic information we have described and some additional information about
Stock U. Notice that Stock U earns 30% if there is a recession and 10% if there is a boom.
Page 469
TABLE 13.1
Obviously, if you buy one of these stocks, say Stock U, what you earn in any particular year depends on
what the economy does during that year. However, suppose the probabilities stay the same through time. If
you hold U for a number of years, you’ll earn 30% about half the time and 10% the other half. In this case,
we say that your expected return on Stock U, E(RU), is 20%:
E(R U ) = (.50 × 30%) + (.50 × 10%) = 20%
In other words, you should expect to earn 20% from this stock, on average.
For Stock L, the probabilities are the same, but the possible returns are different. Here we lose 20% half the
time, and we gain 70% the other half. The expected return on L, E(RL), is thus 25%:
E(R L ) = (.50 × −20%) + (.50 × 70%) = 25%
TABLE 13.2
Stock L Stock U
(2) P robability (3) Rate of (5) Rate of
(1) State of of State of Return if State (4) P roduct Return if State (6) P roduct
Economy Economy Occurs (2) × (3) Occurs (2) × (5)
Recession 0.5 −.20 −.10 .30 .15
Boom 0.5 .70 .35 .10 .05
1.0 E(RL) = 25% E(RU) = 20%
In our previous chapter, we defined the risk premium as the difference between the return on a risky
investment and a risk-free investment, and we calculated the historical risk premiums on some different
investments. Using our projected returns, we can calculate the projected or expected risk premium as the
difference between the expected return on a risky investment and the certain return on a risk-free investment.
For example, suppose risk-free investments are currently offering 8%. We say the risk-free rate (which we
label as Rf) is 8%. Given this, what is the projected risk premium on Stock U? On Stock L? Since the
expected return on Stock U, E(RU), is 20%, the projected risk premium is:
= 20% − 8% = 12%
Page 470
E(R) = ∑ R j × P j
[13.2]
j
where:
R j = value of the jth outcome
Table 13.3 summarizes the calculations for both stocks. Notice that the expected return
on L is −2%.
TABLE 13.3
Stock L Stock U
(2) P robability (3) Rate of (5) Rate of
(1) State of of State of Return if State (4) P roduct Return if State (6) P roduct
Economy Economy Occurs (2) × (3) Occurs (2) × (5)
Recession .80 −.20 −.16 .30 .24
Boom .20 .70 .14 .10 .02
1.0 E(RL) = −2% E(RU) = 26%
The risk premium for Stock U is 26% − 10% = 16% in this case. The risk premium for
Stock L is negative: −2% − 10% = − 12%. This is a little odd, but, for reasons we discuss
later, it is not impossible.
Page 471
2
2
[13.3]
2
σ = ∑ [R j − E(R)] × Pj
j
2
σ = √σ
To illustrate, Stock U has an expected return of E (R ) = 20% . In a given year, it could actually return
U
either 30% or 10%. The possible deviations are thus 30% − 20% = 10% or 10% − 20% = −10% . In
this case, the variance is:
2 2 2
Variance = σ = (.50 × (10%) ) + (.50 × (−10%) ) = .01
Table 13.4 summarizes these calculations for both stocks. Notice that Stock L has a much larger
variance.
TABLE 13.4
Calculation of variance
When we put the expected return and variability information for our two stocks together, we have:
Stock L Stock U
Expected return, E(R) 25% 20%
Variance, σ 2 .2025 .0100
Standard deviation, σ 45% 10%
Stock L has a higher expected return, but U has less risk. You could get a 70% return on your investment
in L, but you could also lose 20%. Notice that an investment in U always pays at least 10%.
Which of these two stocks should you buy? We can’t really say; it depends on your personal preferences. We
can be reasonably sure that some investors would prefer L to U and some would prefer U to L.
Page 472
You’ve probably noticed that the way we calculated expected returns and variances here is somewhat
different from the way we did it in the last chapter. The reason is that, in Chapter 12, we were examining
actual historical returns, so we estimated the average return and the variance based on some actual events.
Here, we have projected future returns and their associated probabilities, so this is the information with
which we must work.
XAMPLE 13.2
More Unequal Probabilities
Going back to Example 13.1, what are the variances on the two stocks once we have
unequal probabilities? The standard deviations? We can summarize the needed
calculations as follows:
(1) State of (2) P robability of State of (3) Return Dev iation from (4) Squared Return Dev iation (5) P roduc
Economy Economy Expected Return from Expected Return (2) × (4)
Stock L
Recession .80 −.20 − (−.02) = −.18 .0324 .02592
Boom .20 .70 − (−.02) = .72 .5184 .10368
σ2 L= .1296
Stock U
Recession .80 .30 − .26 = .04 .0016 .00128
Boom .20 .10 − .26 = −.16 .0256 .00512
σ 2 U = .0064
These calculations give a standard deviation for L of σ L = √ .1296 = 36% . The standard
deviation for U is much smaller; σ = √.0064 = 8%.
U
Concept Questions
. How do we calculate the expected return on a security?
. In words, how do we calculate the variance of the expected return?
LO2 13.2 | Portfolios
Thus far in this chapter, we have concentrated on individual assets considered separately. However, most
investors actually hold a portfolio of assets. All we mean by this is that investors tend to own more than just
a single stock, bond, or other asset. Given that this is so, portfolio return and portfolio risk are of obvious
relevance. Accordingly, we now discuss portfolio expected returns and variances.
Portfolio Weights
There are many equivalent ways of describing a portfolio. The most convenient approach is to list the
percentages of the total portfolio’s value that are invested in each portfolio asset. We call these percentages
the portfolio weights.
Page 473
For example, if we have $50 in one asset and $150 in another, our total portfolio is worth $200. The
percentage of our portfolio in the first asset is $50/$200 = 25% . The percentage of our portfolio in the
second asset is $150/$200 = 75% . Thus, our portfolio weights are .25 and .75 respectively. Notice that
the weights have to add up to 1.00 since all of our money is invested somewhere. 2
Table 13.5 summarizes the remaining calculations. Notice that when a boom occurs, your portfolio
would return 40%:
R P = (.50 × 70%) + (.50 × 10%) = 40%
TABLE 13.5
Page 474
This says that the expected return on a portfolio is a weighted combination of the expected returns on the
assets in that portfolio. This seems somewhat obvious, but, as we examine next, the obvious approach is
not always the right one.
XAMPLE 13.3
Portfolio Expected Returns
Suppose we have the following projections on three stocks:
Returns
State of Economy P robability of State Stock A Stock B Stock C
Boom .40 10% 15% 20%
Bust .60 8% 4% 0%
What would be the expected return on a portfolio with equal amounts invested in each of
the three stocks? What would the expected return be if half the portfolio were in A, with the
remainder equally divided between B and C?
From our earlier discussions, the expected returns on the individual stocks are (check these
for practice):
E (R A ) = 8.8%
E (R B ) = 8.4%
E (R C ) = 8.0%
If a portfolio has equal investments in each asset, the portfolio weights are all the same.
Such a portfolio is said to be equally weighted. Since there are three stocks, the weights
are all equal to 1/3. Therefore portfolio expected return is:
1 1 1
E (R P ) = ( × 8.8%) + ( × 8.4%) + ( × 8.0%)
3 3 3
= 8.4%
In the second case, check that the portfolio expected return is 8.5%.
Portfolio Variance
From our previous discussion, the expected return on a portfolio that contains equal investment in Stocks
U and L is 22.5%. What is the standard deviation of return on this portfolio? Simple intuition might suggest
that half the money has a standard deviation of 45% and the other half has a standard deviation of 10%, so the
portfolio’s standard deviation might be calculated as:
σ P = (. 50 × 45%) + (.50 × 10%) = 27.5%
Let’s see what the standard deviation really is. Table 13.6 summarizes the relevant calculations. As we
see, the portfolio’s variance is about .031, and its standard deviation is less than we thought—it’s only
17.5%. What is illustrated here is that the variance on a portfolio is not generally a simple weighted
combination of the variances of the assets in the portfolio.
TABLE 13.6
(1) State of (2) P robability of (3) P ortfolio Return (4) Squared Dev iation from Expected (5) P roduct
Economy State of Economy if State Occurs Return (2) × (4)
Recession .50 5% (.05 − .225) 2 = .030625 .0153125
Boom .50 40% (.40 − .225) 2 = .030625 .0153125
2
σ P = .030625
σ P = √ .030625 = 17.5%
We can illustrate this point a little more dramatically by considering a slightly different set of portfolio
weights. Suppose we put 2/11 (about 18%) in L and the remaining 9/11 (about 82%) in U. If a recession
occurs, this portfolio would have a return of:
2 9
RP = ( × −20%) + ( × 30%) = 20.91%
11 11
Notice that the return is the same no matter what happens. No further calculations are needed. This
portfolio has a zero variance. Apparently, combining assets into portfolios can substantially alter the risks
faced by the investor. This is a crucial observation, and we explore its implications in the next section.
XAMPLE 13.4
Portfolio Variance and Standard Deviation
In Example 13.3, what are the standard deviations on the two portfolios? To answer, we
first have to calculate the portfolio returns in the two states. We will work with the second
portfolio, which has 50% in Stock A and 25% in each of Stocks B and C. The relevant
calculations can be summarized as follows:
Returns
State of Economy P robability of State Stock A Stock B Stock C Portfolio
Boom .40 10% 15% 20% 13.75%
Bust .60 8% 4% 0% 5.00%
The return when the economy goes bust is calculated the same way. The expected return
on the portfolio is (.40 × 13.75%) + (.60 × 5.00%) = 8.5% with a variance of:
σ 2 2 2
= [.40 × (.1375 − .085) ] + [.60 × (.05 − .085) ]
= .0018375
The standard deviation is about 4.3%. For our equally weighted portfolio, check to see that
the standard deviation is about 5.5%.
Figure 13.1 shows these three benchmark cases for two assets, A and B. The graphs on the left side plot
the separate returns on the two securities through time. Each point on the graphs on the right side
represents the returns for both A and B over a particular time interval. The figure shows examples of
different values for the correlation coefficient, CORR (RA, RB), that range from −1.0 to 1.0.
FIGURE 13.1
Examples of different correlation coeffi cients
The graphs on the left-hand side of the figure plot the separate returns on the two securities through time. Each point on the graphs on the right-hand side
represents the returns for both A and B over a particular time period.
To show how the graphs are constructed, we need to look at points 1 and 2 (on the upper left graph) and
relate them to point 3 (on the upper right graph). Point 1 is a return on Company B and point 2 is a return
on Company A. They both occur over the same time period; say, for example, the month of June. Both
returns are above average. Point 3 represents the returns on both stocks in June, with the x-axis
representing the return on A and the y-axis representing the return on B. Other dots in the upper right graph
represent the returns on both stocks in other months.
Page 477
Because the returns on Security B have bigger swings than the returns on Security A, the slope of the line in
the upper right graph is greater than one. Perfect positive correlation does not imply that the slope is
necessarily one. Rather, it implies that all points lie exactly on the line. Less than perfect positive
correlation implies a positive slope, but the points do not lie exactly on the line. An example of less than
perfect positive correlation is provided on the left side of Figure 13.2. As before, each point in the
graph represents the returns on both securities in the same month. In a graph like this, the closer the points
lie to the line, the closer the correlation is to one. In other words, a high correlation between the two
returns implies that the graph has a tight fit. 4
FIGURE 13.2
Graphs of possible relationships between two stocks
Less than perfect negative correlation implies a negative slope, but the points do not lie exactly on the line,
as shown on the right side of Figure 13.2.
XAMPLE 13.5
Correlation between Stocks U and L
What is the correlation between Stocks U and L from our earlier example if we assume the
two states of the economy are equally probable? Table 13.2 shows the returns on each
stock in recession and boom states.
Stock L Stock U
Stock L Stock U
Recession −.20 .30
Boom .70 .10
Page 478
Figure 13.3 plots the line exactly the same way as we plotted the graphs on the right
sides of Figures 13.1 and 13.2. You can see from the figure that the line has a
negative slope and all the points lie exactly on the line. (Since we only have two outcomes
for each stock, the points must plot exactly on a straight line.) You can conclude that the
correlation between Stocks U and L is equal to −1.0.
FIGURE 13.3
Correlation between Stocks U and L
Our discussion of correlation provides us with a key building block of a formula for
portfolio standard variance and its square root, portfolio standard deviation.
σ
2
p
= x
2
L
σ
2
L
+ x
2
U
σ
2
U
+ 2x L x U CORR L,U σ L σ U
[13.5]
σp = √σ 2
p
Recall that xL and xU are the portfolio weights for Stocks U and L, respectively. CORRL,U is
the correlation of the two stocks. We can use the formula to check our previous calculation
of portfolio standard deviation for a portfolio invested equally in each stock.
2 2 2 2
= (.50 × .45 ) + (.50 × .10 ) + (2 ×.50 × .50 × − 1.0 × .45 × .10)
= .030625
= √ .030625 = 17.5%
FIGURE 13.4
Opportunity sets composed of holdings in Stock L and Stock U
FIGURE 13.5
Effi cient frontier
Page 480
XAMPLE 13.6
The Zero-Variance Portfolio
Can you find a portfolio of Stocks U and L with zero variance? Earlier, we showed that
investing 2/11 (about 18%) of the portfolio in L and the other 9/11 (about 82%) in U gives the
same expected portfolio return in either recession or boom. As a result, the portfolio
variance and standard deviation should both be zero. We can check this with our formula
for portfolio variance.
2 2
2 9 2 9
2 2 2
σ p
= ( ) × (.45) + ( ) × (.10) + 2 × ( ) × ( ) × (−1.0) × (.45) × (.10)
11 11 11 11
To explore how the portfolio standard deviation depends on correlation, Table 13.7
recalculates the portfolio standard deviation, changing the correlation between U and L, yet
keeping the portfolio weights and all the other input data unchanged. When the correlation
is perfectly negative (CORR = −1.0), the portfolio standard deviation is 0 as we just
U,
L
calculated. If the two stocks were uncorrelated (CORR = 0), the portfolio standard
L,
U
16.3636%.
TABLE 13.7
When the returns on the two assets are perfectly correlated, the portfolio standard
deviation is simply the weighted average of the individual standard deviations. In this
special case:
2 9
( × 45%) + ( × 10%) = 16. 3636%
11 11
Page 481
With perfect correlation, all possible portfolios lie on a straight line between U and L in
expected return/standard deviation space as shown in Figure 13.4. In this polar case,
there is no benefit from diversification. But, as soon as correlation is less than perfectly
positive (CORRL,U < +1.0), diversification reduces risk.
As long as CORR is less than +1.0, the standard deviation of a portfolio of two securities is
less than the weighted average of the standard deviations of the individual securities.
Figure 13.4 shows this important result by graphing all possible portfolios of U and L
for the four cases for CORRL,U given in Table 13.7. The portfolios marked 1, 2, 3, and 4
in Figure 13.4 all have an expected return of 20.91%, as calculated in Table 13.7.
Their standard deviations also come from Table 13.7. The other points on the respective
lines or curves are derived by varying the portfolio weights for each value of CORRL,U.
Each line or curve represents all the possible portfolios of U and L for a given correlation.
Each is called an opportunity set or feasible set. The lowest opportunity set representing
CORRL,U = 1.0 always has the largest standard deviation for any return level. Once again,
this shows how diversification reduces risk as long as correlation is less than perfectly
positive.
Concept Questions
. What is a portfolio weight?
. How do we calculate the expected return on a portfolio?
. Is there a simple relationship between the standard deviation on a portfolio and the
standard deviation of the assets in the portfolio?
. For diversification purposes, why must correlation between individual assets in a portfolio
be below 1.0?
LO3 13.3 | Announcements, Surprises, and
Expected Returns
Now that we know how to construct portfolios and evaluate their returns, we begin to describe more
carefully the risks and returns associated with individual securities. So far, we have measured volatility by
looking at the differences between the actual returns on an asset or portfolio, R, and the expected return,
E(R). We now look at why those deviations exist.
Page 482
Based on this discussion, one way to write the return on TransCanada’s stock in the coming year would be:
where R stands for the actual total return in the year, E(R) stands for the expected part of the return, and U
stands for the unexpected part of the return. What this says is that the actual return, R, differs from the
expected return, E(R), because of surprises that occur during the day.
To give a more concrete example, on April 30, 2015, Tesla Motors Inc. announced its expansion into the
home battery business. This announcement seems to be great news for Tesla, but the share price dropped
by 0.99% the day after the announcement. Why? Because the company’s entry into the home battery market
was anticipated and this gave market participants time to re-price Tesla shares. Tesla’s share price had risen
by more than 20% in the month prior to the announcement.
A common way of saying that an announcement isn’t news is to say that the market has already “discounted”
the announcement. The use of the word discount here is different from the use of the term in computing
present values, but the spirit is the same. When we discount a dollar in the future, we say it is worth less to
us because of the time value of money. When we discount an announcement or a news item, we mean it has
less of an impact on the market because the market already knew much of it.
For example, going back to TransCanada Industries, suppose that the government announced that the
actual GNP increase during the year was 1.5%. Now shareholders have learned something; namely, that the
increase is one percentage point higher than had been forecast. This difference between the actual result and
the forecast, 1 percentage point in this example, is sometimes called the innovation or the surprise.
An announcement, then, can be broken into two parts—the anticipated, or expected, part and the surprise,
or innovation:
The expected part of any announcement is the part of the information that the market uses to form the
expectation, E(R), of the return on the stock. The surprise is the news that influences the unanticipated
return on the stock, U.
Our discussion of market efficiency in the previous chapter bears on this discussion. We are assuming that
relevant information that is known today is already reflected in the expected return. This is identical to
saying that the current price reflects relevant publicly available information. We are implicitly assuming that
markets are at least reasonably efficient in the semistrong form sense.
Going forward, when we speak of news, we mean the surprise part of an announcement and not the portion
that the market has expected and already discounted.
Concept Questions
. What are the two basic parts of a return?
. Under what conditions does an announcement have no effect on common stock prices?
LO3 13.4 | Risk: Systematic and Unsystematic
The unanticipated part of the return, that portion resulting from surprises, is the true risk of any investment.
After all, if we always receive exactly what we expect, the investment is perfectly predictable and, by
definition, risk-free. In other words, the risk of owning an asset comes from surprises—unanticipated events.
Page 484
There are important differences, though, among various sources of risk. Look back at our previous list of
news stories. Some of these stories are directed specifically at TransCanada Industries, and some are more
general. Which of the news items are of specific importance to TransCanada Industries?
Announcements about interest rates or GNP are clearly important for nearly all companies, whereas the
news about TransCanada Industries’ president, its research, or its sales are of specific interest to
TransCanada Industries. We distinguish between these two types of events, however, because, as we shall
see, they have very different implications.
We now recognize that the total surprise for TransCanada Industries, U, has a systematic and an
unsystematic component, so:
R = E (R) + Syst emat ic port ion + Unsyst emat ic port ion [13.8]
Page 485
Because it is traditional, we use the Greek letter epsilon, ε, to stand for the unsystematic portion. Since
systematic risks are often called market risks, we use the letter m to stand for the systematic part of the
surprise. With these symbols, we can rewrite the total return:
R = E (R) + U
= E (R) + m + ε
The important thing about the way we have broken down the total surprise, U, is that the unsystematic
portion, ε, is more or less unique to TransCanada Industries. For this reason, it is unrelated to the
unsystematic portion of return on most other assets. To see why this is important, we need to return to the
subject of portfolio risk.
Concept Questions
. What are the two basic types of risk?
. What is the distinction between the two types of risk?
LO2 13.5 | Diversification and Portfolio Risk
We’ve seen earlier that portfolio risks can, in principle, be quite different from the risks of the assets that
make up the portfolio. We now look more closely at the riskiness of an individual asset versus the risk of a
portfolio of many different assets. We once again examine some market history to get an idea of what
happens with actual investments in capital markets.
To examine the relationship between portfolio size and portfolio risk, Table 13.8 illustrates typical
average annual standard deviations for equally weighted portfolios that contain different numbers of
randomly selected NYSE securities. 5
TABLE 13.8
(1) Number of Stocks (2) Av erage Standard Dev iation of (3) Ratio of P ortfolio Standard Dev iation to Standard
in P ortfolio Annual P ortfolio Returns Dev iation of a Single Stock
1 49.24% 1.00
2 37.36 0.76
4 29.69 0.60
6 26.64 0.54
8 24.98 0.51
10 23.93 0.49
20 21.68 0.44
30 20.87 0.42
40 20.46 0.42
50 20.20 0.41
100 19.69 0.40
200 19.42 0.39
300 19.34 0.39
400 19.29 0.39
500 19.27 0.39
(1) Number of Stocks (2) Av erage Standard Dev iation of (3) Ratio of P ortfolio Standard Dev iation to Standard
in P ortfolio Annual P ortfolio Returns Dev iation of a Single Stock
1,000 19.21 0.39
Page 486
In Column 2 of Table 13.8, we see that the standard deviation for a “portfolio” of one security is about
49%. What this means is that, if you randomly selected a single NYSE stock and put all your money into it,
your standard deviation of return would typically have been a substantial 49% per year. If you were to
randomly select two stocks and invest half your money in each, your standard deviation would have been
about 37% on average, and so on.
The important thing to notice in Table 13.8 is that the standard deviation declines as the number of
securities increases. By the time we have 30 randomly chosen stocks, the portfolio’s standard deviation has
declined by about 60%, from 49 to about 20%. With 500 securities, the standard deviation is 19.27%,
similar to the 21% we saw in our previous chapter for the large common stock portfolio. The small
difference exists because the portfolio securities and time periods examined are not identical.
FIGURE 13.6
P ortfolio div ersifi cation
Figure 13.6 illustrates two key points. First, the principle of diversification (discussed earlier) tells us
that spreading an investment across many assets eliminates some of the risk. The shaded area in
Figure 13.6, labelled diversifiable risk, is the part that can be eliminated by diversification.
The second point is equally important. A minimum level of risk cannot be eliminated simply by
diversifying. This minimum level is labelled nondiversifiable risk in Figure 13.6. Taken together, these
two points are another important lesson from capital market history—diversification reduces risk, but only
up to a point. Put another way, some risk is diversifiable and some not.
To give a recent example of the impact of diversification, the S&P TSX Composite Index, an index of large
Canadian stocks, plunged 37% from peak to trough due to COVID-19 pandemic impacts, then bounced
back to post a modest 2% gain in 2020. The Information Technology sector within that index was up by
80% (led by Shopify) while the Energy sector returned –31%. Again, the lesson is clear—diversification
reduces exposure to extreme outcomes, both good and bad.
Diversification and Unsystematic Risk
From our discussion of portfolio risk, we know that some of the risk associated with individual assets can
be diversified away and some cannot. We are left with an obvious question: why is this so? It turns out that
the answer hinges on the distinction we made earlier between systematic and unsystematic risk.
Page 488
By definition, an unsystematic risk is one that is particular to a single asset or, at most, a small group. For
example, if the asset under consideration is stock in a single company, the discovery of positive NPV
projects such as successful new products and innovative cost savings tend to increase the value of the
stock. Unanticipated lawsuits, industrial accidents, strikes, and similar events tend to decrease future cash
flows, thereby reducing share values.
Here is the important observation. If we held only single stock, the value of our investment would fluctuate
because of company-specific events. If we held a large portfolio, on the other hand, some of the stocks in
the portfolio would go up in value because of positive company-specific events and some would go down
in value because of negative events. The net effect on the overall value of the portfolio is relatively small,
however, as these effects tend to cancel each other out.
Now we see why some of the variability associated with individual assets is eliminated by diversification. By
combining assets into portfolios, the unique or unsystematic events—both positive and negative—tend to
wash out once we have more than just a few assets.
This important point bears repeating: Unsystematic risk is essentially eliminated by diversification, so a
relatively large portfolio has almost no unsystematic risk. In fact, the terms diversifiable risk and unsystematic
risk are often used interchangeably.
Systematic risk is also called nondiversifiable risk or market risk. Unsystematic risk is also called
diversifiable risk, unique risk, or asset-specific risk. For a well-diversified portfolio, the unsystematic risk is
negligible. For such a portfolio, essentially all of the risk is systematic.
Would you take such a bet? Perhaps you would, but most people would not. Leaving aside any moral
question that might surround gambling and recognizing that some people would take such a bet, it’s our
view that the average investor would not.
To induce the typical risk-averse investor to take a fair gamble, you must sweeten the pot. For example, you
might need to raise the odds of winning from 50–50 to 70–30 or higher. The risk-averse investor can be
induced to take fair gambles only if they are sweetened so that they become unfair to the investor’s
advantage.
XAMPLE 13.7
Risk of Canadian Mutual Funds
Table 13.9 shows the returns and standard deviations for two Canadian mutual funds
over the three-year period ending December 31, 2017. The table also shows comparable
statistics for the S&P/TSX Composite. As you would expect, the TSX portfolio is the most
widely diversified of the three portfolios and has the lowest unsystematic risk. For this
reason, it has the lowest portfolio standard deviation. The next lowest standard deviation is
the CIBC Canadian Equity fund, which invests in equities across different Canadian
industries.
TABLE 13.9
Average returns and standard deviations for two Canadian mutual funds and S&P/TSX Composite, 2015–2017
The CIBC Precious Metals fund focuses on one sector of the economy. For example, its top
three holdings at the end of December 2017 were Newmont Mining, Franco-Nevada Corp.,
and Agnico Eagle Mines. The narrower focus of this fund makes it less diversified, with
higher standard deviations.
What does this example tell us about how good these funds were as investments? To
answer this question, we have to investigate asset pricing, our next topic.
Concept Questions
. What happens to the standard deviation of return for a portfolio if we increase the number
of securities in the portfolio?
. What is the principle of diversification?
. Why is some risk diversifiable? Why is some risk not diversifiable?
. Why can’t systematic risk be diversified away?
. Explain the concept of risk aversion.
Page 490
Table 13.10 contains the estimated beta coefficients for the stocks of some well-known companies
ranging from 0.36 to 2.77.
TABLE 13.10
XAMPLE 13.8
Total Risk versus Beta
Consider the following information on two securities. Which has greater total risk? Which
has greater systematic risk? Greater unsystematic risk? Which asset has a higher risk
premium?
From our discussion in this section, Security A has greater total risk, but it has substantially
less systematic risk. Since total risk is the sum of systematic and unsystematic risk, Security
A must have greater unsystematic risk. Finally, from the systematic risk principle, Security B
has a higher risk premium and a greater expected return, despite the fact that it has less
total risk.
Remember that the expected return, and thus the risk premium, on an asset depends only on its systematic
risk. Because assets with larger betas have greater systematic risks, they have greater expected returns. Thus,
in Table 13.10, an investor who buys stock in Bank of Nova Scotia, with a beta of 0.88, should expect
to earn less, on average, than an investor who buys stock in IGM Financial, with a beta of 1.70.
Portfolio Betas
Earlier, we saw that the riskiness of a portfolio does not have any simple relationship to the risks of the
assets in the portfolio. A portfolio beta, however, can be calculated just like a portfolio expected return.
For example, looking at Table 13.10, suppose you put half of your money in Bank of Nova Scotia and
half in IGM Financial. What would the beta of this combination be? Since Bank of Nova Scotia (BNS) has
a beta of 0.88 and Teck Resources Ltd. (TRL) has a beta of 1.70, the portfolio’s beta, βP, would be:
βP = (.50 ×β BN S ) + (.50 × β T RL )
= 1. 29
Page 492
In general, if we had a large number of assets in a portfolio, we would multiply each asset’s beta by its
portfolio weight and then add the results to get the portfolio’s beta.
XAMPLE 13.9
Portfolio Betas
Suppose we had the following investments:
What is the expected return on this portfolio? What is the beta of this portfolio? Does this
portfolio have more or less systematic risk than an average asset?
To answer, we first have to calculate the portfolio weights. Notice that the total amount
invested is $10,000. Of this, $1,000/$10,000 = 10% is invested in Stock A. Similarly, 20% is
invested in Stock B, 30% is invested in Stock C, and 40% is invested in Stock D. The
expected return, E(RP), is:
E(R P ) = .10 × E(R A ) + .20 × E(R B ) + .30 × E(R C ) + .40 × E(R D )
This portfolio thus has an expected return of 14.9% and a beta of 1.16. Since the beta is
larger than 1.0, this portfolio has greater systematic risk than an average asset.
Concept Questions
. What is the systematic risk principle?
. What does a beta coefficient measure?
. How do you calculate a portfolio beta?
. Does the expected return on a risky asset depend on that asset’s total risk? Explain.
Page 493
the return on three-month Treasury bills. We choose this measure because it matches the investor’s horizon
for measuring performance. Notice that a risk-free asset, by definition, has no systematic risk (or
unsystematic risk), so a risk-free asset has a beta of 0.
= 11.0%
= .25 × 1.6
= .40
Notice that, since the weights have to add up to 1, the percentage invested in the risk-free asset is equal to 1
minus the percentage invested in Asset A.
One thing that you might wonder about is whether it is possible for the percentage invested in Asset A to
exceed 100%. The answer is yes. This can happen if the investor borrows at the risk-free rate. For example,
suppose an investor has $100 and borrows an additional $50 at 8%, the risk-free rate. The total investment
in Asset A would be $150, or 150% of the investor’s wealth. The expected return in this case would be:
E(R P ) = 1.50 × E(R A ) + (1 − 1.50) × R f
= 26%
= 1.50 × 1.6
= 2.4
Page 494
In Figure 13.8A, the portfolio expected returns are plotted against the portfolio betas. Notice that all
the combinations fall on a straight line.
FIGURE 13.8A
P ortfolio expected returns and betas for Asset A
20% − 8%
= = 7.50%
1.6
What this tells us is that Asset A offers a reward-to-risk ratio of 7.50%. 7 In other words, Asset A has a risk
premium of 7.50% per unit of systematic risk.
= 10%
Page 495
= .25 × 1.2
= .30
When we plot these combinations of portfolio expected returns and portfolios betas in Figure 13.8B, we
get a straight line just as we did for Asset A.
FIGURE 13.8B
P ortfolio expected returns and betas for Asset B
The key thing to notice is that when we compare the results for Assets A and B, as in Figure 13.8C, the
line describing the combinations of expected returns and betas for Asset A is higher than the one for Asset
B. This tells us that for any given level of systematic risk (as measured by β), some combination of Asset A
and the risk-free asset always offers a larger return. This is why we were able to state that Asset A is a better
investment than Asset B.
Page 496
FIGURE 13.8C
P ortfolio expected returns and betas for both assets
Another way of seeing that A offers a superior return for its level of risk is to note that the slope of our line
for Asset B is:
E(R B ) − R f
Slope =
βB
16% − 8%
= = 6.67%
1.2
Thus, Asset B has a reward-to-risk ratio of 6.67%, which is less than the 7.5% offered by Asset A.
all plot on the same straight line. Assets A and B are examples of this behaviour. Asset C’s expected return is too high; Asset D’s is too low.
Page 497
The arguments we have presented apply to active, competitive, well-functioning markets. The financial
markets, such as the TSX, NYSE, and NASDAQ, best meet these criteria. Other markets, such as real asset
markets, may or may not. For this reason, these concepts are most useful in examining financial markets.
We thus focus on such markets here. However, as we discuss in a later section, the information about risk
and return gleaned from financial markets is crucial in evaluating the investments that a corporation makes
in real assets.
XAMPLE 13.10
Determining Portfolio Weights
Suppose you are a risk-averse investor and you want to construct an investment portfolio
with 5% standard deviation. There are two assets in the market you can choose from: a
riskless Government of Canada T-bill with expected return of 3%, and a risky S&P/TSX
index fund with expected return of 10% and standard deviation of 16%. What are the
portfolio weights? What is the expected return of the portfolio?
We can use Equation 13.5 to calculate the weights of two assets:
2 2 2 2 2
(5%) = x × (0%) + x × (16%) + 2 × x T × x S × 0 × (0%) × (20%)
T S
2
0.0025 = x × 0.0256
S
2
x = 0.09766
S
xS = 31.25%
xT = 1 − x S = 68.75%
You will allocate 68.75% of your investment in T-bills and 31.25% in the S&P/TSX index fund.
The portfolio has an expected return of 5.19% = 3% × 68.75% + 10% × 31.25%.
Page 498
XAMPLE 13.11
Beta and Stock Valuation
An asset is said to be overvalued if its expected return is too low given its risk. Suppose
you observe the following situation:
The risk-free rate is currently 6%. Is Insec overvalued or undervalued relative to the market
portfolio?
To answer, we compute the reward-to-risk ratio for both. For Insec, this ratio is
(10% − 6%)/0.8 = 5%. For the market, this ratio is 6%. What we conclude is that Insec
offers an insufficient expected return for its level of risk. Insec plots below the security
market line. As investors are attracted to the market portfolio and away from Insec, Insec’s
share price would drop. As a result, Insec’s expected return would rise until the security has
the same reward-to-risk ratio as the market portfolio. To see why this is true, recall that the
dividend valuation model presented in Chapter 8 treats price as the present value of
future dividends.
D1
P0 =
r − g
Projecting the dividend stream gives us D1 and g. If the required rate of return is too low,
the stock price will be too high. For example, suppose D = $2.00 and g = 7%. If the
1
expected rate of return on the stock is wrongly underestimated at 10%, the stock price
estimate is $66.67. This price is too high if the true expected rate of return is 10.8% (we will
show how the true expected rate of return is calculated in a later section). At this higher rate
of return, the stock price should fall to $52.63. In other words, Insec is overvalued, and we
would expect to see its price fall to $52.63.
Calculating Beta
The beta of a security measures the responsiveness of that security’s return to the return on the market as a
whole. To calculate beta, we draw a line relating the expected return on the security to different returns on
the market. This line, called the characteristic line of the security, has a slope equal to the stock’s beta.
XAMPLE 13.12
Mutual Fund Performance
TABLE 13.11
Average returns and betas for selected Canadian mutual funds, S&P/TSX Composite, and Canadian three-month
Treasury bills, 15 years ending March 31, 2015
Table 13.11 gives the inputs needed to compute the reward-to-risk ratios for the TSX
and two mutual funds. Starting with the TSX, the reward-to-risk ratio was:
Average return − Riskless rate
Beta
5.57 − 2.38
= 3.19%
1. 00
Page 499
You can verify that the reward-to-risk ratio for RBC Canadian Equity was 3.20% and the
ratio for BMO Dividend was 9.81%. BMO Dividend fund beat the market by earning a higher
reward-to-risk ratio than the TSX, while RBC Canadian Equity fund slightly outperformed
over this period. Keep in mind that it is unlikely for a mutual fund, such as RBC Canadian
Equity fund, to constantly outperform the index it tracked. This is because mutual funds
charge management fees. For example, RBC Canadian Equity charges a management fee
of 1.75%.
Unfortunately, in an efficient market, while past performance may guide expectations of
future returns, these expectations may not be realized in actual returns. So, we would not
expect that BMO Dividend fund would beat the market consistently over time.
Consider Figure 13.10, which displays returns for both a hypothetical company and the market as a
whole. 8 Each point represents a pair of returns over a particular month. The vertical dimension measures
the return on the stock over the month and the horizontal dimension measures that of the S&P/TSX
Composite. (The S&P/TSX Composite is considered a reasonable proxy for the general market.)
FIGURE 13.10
Graphic representation of beta
Figure 13.10 also shows the line of best fit superimposed on these points. In practical applications, this
line is calculated from regression analysis. As one can see from the graph, the slope is 1.28. Because the
average beta is 1, this indicates the stock’s beta of 1.28 is higher than that for the average stock.
Page 500
The goal of a financial analyst is to determine the beta that a stock will have in the future, because this is
when the proceeds of an investment are received. Of course, past data must be used in regression analysis.
Thus, it is incorrect to think of 1.28 as the beta of our example company. Rather, it is our estimate of the
firm’s beta from past data.
The bottom of Figure 13.10 indicates that the company’s R2 over the time period is 0.584. What does
this mean? R2 measures how close the points in the figure are to the characteristic line. The highest value
for R2 is 1, a situation that would occur if all points lay exactly on the characteristic line. This would be the
case where the security’s return is determined only by the market’s return without the security having any
independent variation. The R2 is likely to approach one for a large portfolio of securities. For example,
many widely diversified mutual funds have R2s of 0.80 or more. The lowest possible R2 is zero, a situation
occurring when two variables are entirely unrelated to each other. Those companies whose returns are pretty
much independent of returns on the stock market would have R2s near zero.
The risk of any security can be broken down into unsystematic and systematic risk. Whereas beta measures
the amount of systematic risk, R2 measures the proportion of total risk that is systematic. Thus, a low R2
9
indicates that most of the risk of a firm is unsystematic. 9
The mechanics for calculating betas are quite simple. People in business frequently estimate beta by using
commercially available computer programs. Certain handheld calculators are also able to perform the
calculation. In addition, a large number of services sell or even give away estimates of beta for different
firms. For example, Table 13.10 presents a set of betas calculated by Yahoo Finance in February 2021.
In calculating betas, analysts make a number of assumptions consistent with Canadian research on the
capital asset pricing model. 10 First, they generally choose monthly data, as do many financial economists.
On the one hand, statistical problems frequently arise when time intervals shorter than a month are used. On
the other hand, important information is lost when longer intervals are employed. Thus, the choice of
monthly data can be viewed as a compromise.
Second, analysts typically use just under five years of data, the result of another compromise. Due to
changes in production mix, production techniques, management style, and/or financial leverage, a firm’s
nature adjusts over time. A long time period for calculating beta implies many out-of-date observations.
Conversely, a short time period leads to statistical imprecision, because few monthly observations are used.
Concept Questions
. What is the statistical procedure employed for calculating beta?
. Why do financial analysts use monthly data when calculating beta?
. What is R2?
Page 501
MARKET PORTFOLIOS
It will be very useful to know the equation of the SML. There are many different ways that we could write it,
but one way is particularly common. Suppose we were to consider a portfolio made up of all of the assets
in the market. Such a portfolio is called a market portfolio, and we write the expected return on this market
portfolio as E(RM).
Since all the assets in the market must plot on the SML, so must a market portfolio made of those assets.
To determine where it plots on the SML, we need to know the beta of the market portfolio, βM. Because this
portfolio is representative of all the assets in the market, it must have average systematic risk. In other
words, it has a beta of one. We could therefore write the slope of the SML as:
[E(R M ) − R f ] [E(R M ) − R f ]
SML slope = = = E(R M ) − R f
βM 1
The term E(RM) − Rf is often called the market risk premium since it is the risk premium on a market
portfolio.
If we rearrange this, we can write the equation for the SML as:
E(R i ) = R f + [E(R M ) − R f ] × β i
[13.10]
This result is identical to the famous capital asset pricing model (CAPM). 11
The CAPM shows that the expected return for a particular asset depends on three things:
1. The pure time value of money. As measured by the risk-free rate, Rf, this is the reward for merely waiting
for your money, without taking any risk.
2. The reward for bearing systematic risk. As measured by the market risk premium [E(RM) − Rf], this
component is the reward the market offers for bearing an average amount of systematic risk in addition to
waiting.
3. The amount of systematic risk. As measured by β,i this is the amount of systematic risk present in a
particular asset, relative to an average asset.
Page 502
Recall that in Example 13.12, we used 10.8% as the true expected return of Insec. It is calculated using
the CAPM as follows:
E(R) = R f + [E(R M ) − R f ] × β = 6% + [6% × 0.8] = 10.8%
By the way, the CAPM works for portfolios of assets just as it does for individual assets. In an earlier
section, we saw how to calculate a portfolio’s β. To find the expected return on a portfolio, we simply use
this β in the CAPM equation.
Figure 13.11 summarizes our discussion of the SML and the CAPM. As before, we plot the expected
return against beta. Now we recognize that, based on the CAPM, the slope of the SML is equal to the
market risk premium [E(RM) − Rf]. This concludes our presentation of concepts related to the risk-return
trade-off. For future reference, Table 13.12 summarizes the various concepts in the order we discussed
them in.
Page 503
FIGURE 13.11
The security market line (SML)
The slope of the security market line is equal to the market risk premium; that is, the reward for bearing an average amount of systematic risk.
E (R ) = R + β × [E (R ) − R ]
i f i M f
TABLE 13.12
Total Risk
The total risk of an investment is measured by the variance or, more commonly, the standard deviation of its return.
Total Return
The total re turn on an investment has two components: the expected return and the unexpected return. The unexpected return comes
about because of unanticipated events. The risk from investing stems from the possibility of unanticipated events.
Systematic and Unsystematic Risks
Systematic risks (also called market risks) are unanticipated events that affect almost all assets to some degree because they are
economy wide. Unsystematic risks are unanticipated events that affect single assets or small groups of assets. Unsystematic risks are
also called unique or asse t-spe cific risks.
The Effect of Div ersifi cation
Some, but not all, of the risk associated with a risky investment can be eliminated by diversification. The reason is that unsystematic
risks, which are unique to individual assets, tend to wash out in a large portfolio; systematic risks, which affect all of the assets in a
portfolio to some extent, do not.
The Systematic Risk P rinciple and Beta
Because unsystematic risk can be freely eliminated by diversification, the syste matic risk principle states that the reward for bearing risk
depends only on the level of systematic risk. The level of systematic risk in a particular asset, relative to average, is given by the beta of
that asset.
The Reward-to-Risk Ratio and the Security Market Line
Total Risk
The reward-to-risk ratio for asset i is the ratio of its risk premium E(Ri) − Rf to its beta, β:i
E(R i ) − R f
βi
In a well-functioning market, this ratio is the same for every asset. As a result, when asset expected returns are plotted against asset
betas, all assets plot on the same straight line, called the se curity marke t line (SML).
The Capital Asset P ricing Model
From the SML, the expected return on asset i can be written:
E(R i ) = R f + [E(R M ) − R f ] × β i
This is the capital asse t pricing mode l (CAPM). The expected return on a risky asset thus has three components: The first is the pure
time value of money (Rf), the second is the market risk premium [E(RM) − Rf], and the third is the beta for that asset, β.i
The weakening outlook for Canada has many investors looking for opportunities
elsewhere, but investing internationally in individual foreign stocks can be challenging. Many
find buying and selling shares on markets outside of Canada difficult, confusing, and
expensive. ETFs, however, make it easy and cost-effective for investors, because they
provide a wide array of international exposures in a low-cost, transparent and convenient
way.
More and more investors are turning to ETFs to gain international exposures in the core of
their portfolios, where the strategy is to buy and hold for the long term. Cost-efficiency is
key. The good news is that with one trade, an investor can get access to a wide diversity of
stocks and geographies through an ETF. An example is the iShares Core MSCI All Country
World ex Canada Index ETF (XAW), which provides low-cost exposure to about 5,000
large-, mid- and small-cap companies in more than 40 countries, covering 99 percent of
global equity markets outside Canada. With XAW, investors can achieve near-total global
diversification, at one-tenth the cost of a traditional global equity mutual fund.
Beyond core holdings, however, ETFs are also increasingly finding favour among investors
who want to make more tactical plays on international markets to seek higher returns than
they can achieve through domestic allocations.
Whichever path investors choose, it’s clear that ETFs can provide new ways to realize the
benefits of portfolio diversification and growth potential beyond Canada’s borders.
Canadian investors really do have a world of opportunity to explore, and ETFs are helping
them get there.
Pat Chiefalo is the Managing Director, head of Canadian Product for iShares, BlackRock Asset Management Canada Limited. His comments are
excerpted with permission from “Going Global with ETFs,” Your Guide to ETF Investing (June 1, 2015). The information and opinions herein are provided for
informational purposes only, are subject to change and should not be relied upon as the basis for your investment decisions. © 2016 BlackRock. All rights
XAMPLE 13.13
Risk and Return
Suppose the risk-free rate is 4%, the market risk premium is 8.6%, and a particular stock
has a beta of 1.3. Based on the CAPM, what is the expected return on this stock? What
would the expected return be if the beta were to double?
With a beta of 1.3, the risk premium for the stock would be 1.3 × 8.6% = 11.18%. The risk-
free rate is 4%, so the expected return is 15.18%. If the beta doubles to 2.6, the risk premium
would double to 22.36%, so the expected return would be 22.36% + 4% = 26.36%.
Concept Questions
. What is the fundamental relationship between risk and return in well-functioning markets?
. What is the security market line? Why must all assets plot directly on it in a well-functioning
market?
. What is the capital asset pricing model (CAPM)? What does it tell us about the required
return on a risky investment?
LO4 13.8 | Arbitrage Pricing Theory and
Empirical Models
The CAPM and the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) are alternative models of risk and return. One advantage
of the APT is that it can handle multiple factors that the CAPM ignores. Although the bulk of our
presentation in this chapter focused on the one-factor model, a multifactor model is probably more
reflective of reality.
Page 505
The APT assumes that stock returns are generated according to factor models. For example, we have
described a stock’s return as:
Total return = Expected return + Unexpected return
R = E(R) + U
In APT, the unexpected return is related to several market factors. Suppose there are three such factors:
unanticipated changes in inflation, GNP, and interest rates. The total return can be expanded as:
The three factors FI , FGNP, and Fr represent systematic risk because these factors affect many securities.
The term ε is considered unsystematic risk because it is unique to each individual security.
Under this multifactor APT, we can generalize from three to K factors to express the relationship between
risk and return as:
E(R) = RF + E[(R1) − RF ]β1 + E[(R2) − RF ]β2 + E[(R3) − RF ]β3 + … + E[(RK ) − RF ]βK [13.12]
In this equation, β1 stands for the security’s beta with respect to the first factor, β2 stands for the security’s
beta with respect to the second factor, and so on. For example, if the first factor is inflation, β1 is the
security’s inflation beta. The term E(R1 ) is the expected return on a security (or portfolio) whose beta with
respect to the first factor is one and whose beta with respect to all other factors is zero. Because the market
compensates for risk, E[(R1 ) − Rf)] is positive in the normal case. 12 (An analogous interpretation can be
given to E(R2), E(R3 ), and so on.)
The equation states that the security’s expected return is related to its factor betas. The argument is that each
factor represents risk that cannot be diversified away. The higher a security’s beta is with regard to a
particular factor, the higher the risk that security bears. In a rational world, the expected return on the
security should compensate for this risk. The preceding equation states that the expected return is a
summation of the risk-free rate plus the compensation for each type of risk the security bears.
As an example, consider a Canadian study where the factors were:
1. The rate of growth in industrial production (INDUS).
2. The changes in the slope of the term structure of interest rates (the difference between the yield on long-
term and short-term Canada bonds) (TERMS).
3. The default risk premium for bonds (measured as the difference between the yield on long-term Canada
bonds and the yield on the ScotiaMcLeod corporate bond index) (RISKPREM).
4. The inflation (measured as the growth of the consumer price index) (INFL).
5. The value-weighted return on the market portfolio (S&P/TSX Composite) (MKRET). 13
Page 506
Using the period 1970–84, the empirical results of the study indicated that expected monthly returns on a
sample of 100 TSX stocks could be described as a function of the risk premiums associated with these five
factors.
Because many factors appear on the right side of the APT equation, the APT formulation explained
expected returns in this Canadian sample more accurately than did the CAPM. However, as we mentioned
earlier, one cannot easily determine which are the appropriate factors. The factors in this study were
included for reasons of both common sense and convenience. They were not derived from theory, and the
choice of factors varies from study to study. A more recent Canadian study, for example, includes changes
in a U.S. stock index and in exchange rates as factors. 14
The CAPM and the APT by no means exhaust the models and techniques used in practice to measure the
expected return on risky assets. Both the CAPM and the APT are risk based. They each measure the risk of a
security by its beta(s) on some systematic factor(s), and they each argue that the expected excess return
must be proportional to the beta(s). As we have seen, this is intuitively appealing and has a strong basis in
theory, but there are alternative approaches.
One popular alternative is a multifactor empirical model developed by Fama and French and based less on a
theory of how financial markets work and more on simply looking for regularities and relations in the past
history of market data. In such an approach, the researcher specifies some parameters or attributes
associated with the securities in question and then examines the data directly for a relation between these
attributes and expected returns. Fama and French examine whether the expected return on a firm is related to
its size and market to book ratio in addition to its beta. Is it true that small firms have higher average
returns than large firms? Do growth companies with high market to book ratios have higher average returns
than value companies with low market to book ratios?15 A well-known extension of the Fama-French
model includes a fourth, momentum, factor measured by last year’s stock return. 16
Although multifactor models are commonly used in investment performance analysis, they have not become
standard practice in estimating the cost of capital. Surveys of corporate executives show that only one in
three employ multifactor models for this purpose while over 70% rely on the CAPM. 17
Concept Questions
. What is the main advantage of the APT over the CAPM?
Page 507
This chapter covered the essentials of risk. Along the way, we introduced a number of definitions
and concepts. The most important of these is the security market line, or SML. The SML is
important because it tells us the reward offered in financial markets for bearing risk. Once we know
this, we have a benchmark against which to compare the returns expected from real asset
investments and to determine if they are desirable.
Because we covered quite a bit of ground, it’s useful to summarize the basic economic logic
underlying the SML as follows:
1. Based on capital market history, there is a reward for bearing risk. This reward is the risk
premium on an asset.
2. The total risk associated with an asset has two parts: systematic risk and unsystematic risk.
Unsystematic risk can be freely eliminated by diversification (this is the principle of
diversification), so only systematic risk is rewarded. As a result, the risk premium on an asset is
determined by its systematic risk. This is the systematic risk principle.
3. An asset’s systematic risk, relative to average, can be measured by its beta coefficient, β.i The
risk premium on an asset is then given by its beta coefficient multiplied by the market risk
premium [E (R ) − R ] × β .
M f i
4. The expected return on an asset, E(Ri), is equal to the risk-free rate, Rf, plus the risk premium:
E(Ri) = Rf + [E(RM ) − Rf ] × βi
This is the equation of the SML, and it is often called the capital asset pricing model (CAPM).
This chapter completes our discussion of risk and return and concludes Part 5 of our book.
Now that we have a better understanding of what determines a firm’s cost of capital for an
investment, the next several chapters examine more closely how firms raise the long-term capital
needed for investment.
Key Terms
arbitrage pricing theory (APT)
beta coefficient
capital asset pricing model (CAPM)
expected return
market risk premium
portfolio
portfolio weights
principle of diversification
security market line (SML)
systematic risk
systematic risk principle
unsystematic risk
Page 508
Chapter Review Problems
and Self-Test
1. Expected Return and Standard Deviation This problem gives you some practice
calculating measures of prospective portfolio performance. There are two assets and three states
of the economy:
What are the expected returns and standard deviations for these two stocks?
2. Portfolio Risk and Return Using the information in the previous problem, suppose you have
$20,000 total. If you put $15,000 in Stock A and the remainder in Stock B, what will be the
expected return and standard deviation on your portfolio?
3. Risk and Return Suppose you observe the following situation:
If the risk-free rate is 7%, are these securities correctly priced? What would the risk-free rate have
to be if they are correctly priced?
4. CAPM Suppose the risk-free rate is 8%. The expected return on the market is 16%. If a
particular stock has a beta of .7, what is its expected return based on the CAPM? If another
stock has an expected return of 24%, what must its beta be?
Answers to Self-Test Problems
1. The expected returns are just the possible returns multiplied by the associated probabilities:
Page 509
The variances are given by the sums of the squared deviations from the expected returns
multiplied by their probabilities:
2 2 2 2
σ A
= .20 × (−.15 − .25) + .50 × (.20 − .25) + .30 × (.60 − .25)
2 2 2
= (.20 × −.40 ) + (.50 × −.05 ) + (.30 × .35 )
= .0700
2 2 2 2
σ B
= .20 × (.20 − .31) + .50 × (.30 − .31) + .30 × (.40 − .31)
2 2 2
= (.20 × −.11 ) + (.50 × −.01 ) + (.30 × .09 )
= .0049
σB = √ .0049 = 7%
2. The portfolio weights are $15,000/20,000 = .75 and $5,000/20,000 = .25. The expected
return is thus:
E(RP ) = .75 × E(RA) + .25 × E(RB)
= 26.5%
= .0466
If they are correctly priced, they must offer the same reward-to-risk ratio. The risk-free rate
would have to be such that:
(22% − Rf )/1.8 = (20.44% − Rf )/1.6
With a little algebra, we find that the risk-free rate must be 8%:
Rf = 8%
4. Because the expected return on the market is 16%, the market risk premium is
16% − 8% = 8% . (the risk-free rate is 8%). The first stock has a beta of .7, so its expected
return is 8% + .7 × 8% = 13.6% .
For the second stock, notice that the risk premium is 24% − 8% = 16% . Because this is
twice as large as the market risk premium, the beta must be exactly equal to 2. We can verify this
using the CAPM:
E(Ri) = Rf + [E(RM ) − Rf ] × βi
βi = 16%/8%
= 2.0
Concepts Review
and Critical Thinking Questions
1. (LO3) In broad terms, why is some risk diversifiable? Why are some risks nondiversifiable?
Does it follow that an investor can control the level of unsystematic risk in a portfolio, but not
the level of systematic risk?
2. (LO3) Suppose the government announces that, based on a just-completed survey, the growth
rate in the economy is likely to be 2% in the coming year, as compared to 5% for the year just
completed. Will security prices increase, decrease, or stay the same following this
announcement? Does it make any difference whether or not the 2% figure was anticipated by the
market? Explain.
3. (LO3) Classify the following events as mostly systematic or mostly unsystematic. Is the
distinction clear in every case?
a. Short-term interest rates increase unexpectedly.
b. The interest rate a company pays on its short-term debt borrowing is increased by its bank.
c. Oil prices unexpectedly decline.
d. An oil tanker ruptures, creating a large oil spill.
e. A manufacturer loses a multimillion-dollar product liability suit.
f. A Supreme Court of Canada decision substantially broadens producer liability for injuries
suffered by product users.
Page 511
4. (LO3) Indicate whether the following events might cause stocks in general to change price, and
whether they might cause Big Widget Corp.’s stock to change price.
a. The government announces that inflation unexpectedly jumped by 2% last month.
b. Big Widget’s quarterly earnings report, just issued, generally fell in line with analysts’
expectations.
c. The government reports that economic growth last year was at 3%, which generally agreed
with most economists’ forecasts.
d. The directors of Big Widget die in a plane crash.
e. The Government of Canada approves changes to the tax code that will increase the top
marginal corporate tax rate. The legislation had been debated for the previous six months.
5. (LO1) If a portfolio has a positive investment in every asset, can the expected return on the
portfolio be greater than that on every asset in the portfolio? Can it be less than that on every
asset in the portfolio? If you answer yes to one or both of these questions, give an example to
support your answer.
6. (LO2) True or false: The most important characteristic in determining the variance of return of a
well-diversified portfolio is the variances of the individual assets in the portfolio. Explain.
7. (LO2) If a portfolio has a positive investment in every asset, can the standard deviation on the
portfolio be less than that on every asset in the portfolio? What about the portfolio beta?
8. (LO4) Is it possible that a risky asset could have a beta of zero? Explain. Based on the CAPM,
what is the expected return on such an asset? Is it possible that a risky asset could have a
negative beta? What does the CAPM predict about the expected return on such an asset? Can
you give an explanation for your answer?
9. (LO4) In our discussion of the SML, we defined alpha. What does alpha measure? What alpha
would you like to see on your investments?
10. (LO4) Common advice on Wall Street is “Keep your alpha high and your beta low.” Why?
11. (LO1) In recent years, it has been common for companies to experience significant stock price
changes in reaction to announcements of massive layoffs. Critics charge that such events
encourage companies to fire long-time employees and that Bay Street is cheering them on. Do
you agree or disagree?
12. (LO1) As indicated by a number of examples in this chapter, earnings announcements by
companies are closely followed by, and frequently result in, share price revisions. Two issues
should come to mind. First, earnings announcements concern past periods. If the market values
stocks based on expectations of the future, why are numbers summarizing past performance
relevant? Second, these announcements concern accounting earnings. Going back to
Chapter 2, such earnings may have little to do with cash flow, so, again, why are they
relevant?
Page 512
6. Calculating Expected Return (LO1) Based on the following information, calculate the
expected return:
7. Calculating Returns and Standard Deviations (LO1) Based on the following information,
calculate the expected return and standard deviation for the two stocks:
a. What is the expected return on an equally weighted portfolio of these three stocks?
b. What is the variance of a portfolio invested 20% each in A and B and 60% in C?
10. Returns and Standard Deviations (LO1, 2) Consider the following information:
a. Your portfolio is invested 30% each in A and C, and 40% in B. What is the expected
return of the portfolio?
11. Calculating Portfolio Betas (LO4) You own a stock portfolio invested 20% in Stock Q,
30% in Stock R, 35% in Stock S, and 15% in Stock T. The betas for these four stocks are
.84, 1.17, 1.08, and 1.36, respectively. What is the portfolio beta?
12. Calculating Portfolio Betas (LO4) You own a portfolio equally invested in a risk-free asset
and two stocks. If one of the stocks has a beta of 1.32 and the total portfolio is equally as
risky as the market, what must the beta be for the other stock in your portfolio?
13. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) A stock has a beta of 1.15, the expected return on the market is
10.3%, and the risk-free rate is 3.8%. What must the expected return on this stock be?
14. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) A stock has an expected return of 10.2%, the risk-free rate is 4.1%,
and the market risk premium is 7.2%. What must the beta of this stock be?
15. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) A stock has an expected return of 11.05%, its beta is 1.13, and the
risk-free rate is 3.6%. What must the expected return on the market be?
16. Using CAPM (LO4) A stock has an expected return of 12.15%, its beta is 1.31, and the
expected return on the market is 10.2%. What must the risk-free rate be?
Page 514
17. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) A stock has a beta of 1.14 and an expected return of 10.5%. A risk-
free asset currently earns 2.4%.
a. What is the expected return on a portfolio that is equally invested in the two assets?
b. If a portfolio of the two assets has a beta of .92, what are the portfolio weights?
c. If a portfolio of the two assets has an expected return of 9%, what is its beta?
d. If a portfolio of the two assets has a beta of 2.28, what are the portfolio weights? How
do you interpret the weights for the two assets in this case? Explain.
18. Using the SML (LO1, 4) Asset W has an expected return of 11.8% and a beta of 1.15. If the
risk-free rate is 3.7%, complete the following table for portfolios of Asset W and a risk-free
asset. Illustrate the relationship between portfolio expected return and portfolio beta by
plotting the expected returns against the betas. What is the slope of the line that results?
19. Reward-to-Risk Ratios (LO4) Stock Y has a beta of 1.2 and an expected return of 11.4%.
Stock Z has a beta of .80 and an expected return of 8.06%. If the risk-free rate is 2.5% and
the market risk premium is 7.2%, are these stocks correctly priced?
20. Reward-to-Risk Ratios (LO4) In the previous problem, what would the risk-free rate have to
be for the two stocks to be correctly priced?
a. If your portfolio is invested 40% each in A and B and 20% in C, what is the portfolio
expected return? The variance? The standard deviation?
b. If the expected T-bill rate is 3.80%, what is the expected risk premium on the portfolio?
c. If the expected inflation rate is 3.50%, what are the approximate and exact expected real
returns on the portfolio? What are the approximate and exact expected real risk
premiums on the portfolio?
Page 515
24. Analyzing a Portfolio (LO2) You want to create a portfolio equally as risky as the market,
and you have $1,000,000 to invest. Given this information, fill in the rest of the following
table:
The market risk premium is 7%, and the risk-free rate is 4%. Which stock has the most
systematic risk? Which one has the most unsystematic risk? Which stock is “riskier”?
Explain.
27. SML (LO4) Suppose you observe the following situation:
Security Beta Expected Return
Pete Corp. 1.15 .129
Repete Co. .84 .102
Page 516
Assume these securities are correctly priced. Based on the CAPM, what is the expected
return on the market? What is the risk-free rate?
28. SML (LO1, 4) Suppose you observe the following situation:
b. Assuming the capital asset pricing model holds and stock A’s beta is greater than stock
B’s beta by .25, what is the expected market risk premium?
29. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) A portfolio invests in a risk-free asset and the market portfolio has
an expected return of 7% and a standard deviation of 10%. Suppose the risk-free rate is 4%,
and the standard deviation on the market portfolio is 22%. According to the CAPM, what
expected rate of return would a security earn if it had a 0.55 beta?
30. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) A security’s beta can be calculated using covariance of the
security’s return with the market, divided by variance of return of the market portfolio. We
will show why this is true in Appendix 13A. Suppose the risk-free rate is 4.8% and the
market portfolio has an expected return of 11.4%. The market portfolio has a variance of
0.0429. Portfolio Z has a covariance of 0.39 with the market portfolio. According to the
CAPM, what is the expected return on portfolio Z?
31. Using CAPM (LO1, 4) There are two stocks in the market, stock A and stock B. The price
of stock A today is $65. The price of stock A next year will be $53 if the economy is in a
recession, $73 if the economy is normal, and $85 if the economy is expanding. The
probabilities of recession, normal times, and expansion are 0.2, 0.6, and 0.2, respectively.
Stock A pays no dividends and has a beta of 0.68. Stock B has an expected return of 13%, a
standard deviation of 34%, a beta of 0.45, and a correlation with stock A of 0.48. The
market portfolio has a standard deviation of 14%. Assume the CAPM holds.
a. What are the expected return and standard deviation of stock A?
b. If you are a typical, risk-averse investor with a well-diversified portfolio, which stock
would you prefer? Why?
c. What are the expected return and standard deviation of a portfolio consisting of 60% of
stock A and 40% of stock B?
APPENDIX 13A
2 2 2 2 2
[13A.1]
σ P = x Lσ L + x U σ U + 2x L x U CORR L,U σ L σ U
However, by definition, the risk-free asset (say, L in this example) has no variability so the equation for
portfolio standard deviation reduces to:
2 2 2
σ p = x U σ U
2
σ p = √σ p = x U σ U
The relationship between risk and return for one risky and one riskless asset is represented on a straight
line between the risk-free rate and a pure investment in the risky asset as shown in Figure 13A.1. The
line extends to the right of the point representing the risky asset when we assume the investor can borrow
at the risk-free rate to take a leveraged position of more than 100% in the risky asset.
FIGURE 13A.1
Relationship between expected return and standard dev iation for an inv estment in a combination of risky securities and the
riskless asset
To form an optimal portfolio, an investor is likely to combine an investment in the riskless asset with a
portfolio of risky assets. Figure 13A.1 illustrates our discussion by showing a risk-free asset and four
risky assets: A, X, Q, and Y. If there is no riskless asset, the efficient set is the curve from X to Y. With a
risk-free asset, it is possible to form portfolios like 1, 2, and 3 combining Q with the risk-free asset.
Portfolios 4 and 5 combine the riskless asset with A.
Page 519
The graph illustrates an important point. With riskless borrowing and lending, the portfolio of risky
assets held by any investor would always be point A. Regardless of the investor’s tolerance for risk, they
would never choose any other point on the efficient set of risky assets. Rather, an investor with a high
aversion to risk would combine the securities of A with riskless assets. The investor would borrow at the
risk-free rate to invest more funds in A had they low aversion to risk. In other words, all investors would
choose portfolios along Line II, called the capital market line.
To move from our description of a single investor to market equilibrium, financial economists imagine a
world where all investors possess the same estimates of expected returns, variance, and correlations.
This assumption is called homogeneous expectations.
If all investors have homogeneous expectations, Figure 13A.1 becomes the same for all individuals.
All investors sketch out the same efficient set of risky assets because they are working with the same
inputs. This efficient set of risky assets is represented by the curve XAY. Because the same risk-free rate
applies to everyone, all investors view point A as the portfolio of risky assets to be held. In a world with
homogeneous expectations, all investors would hold the portfolio of risky assets represented by point A.
19
If all investors choose the same portfolio of risky assets, A, then A must be the market portfolio. 19 This
is because, in our simplified world of homogeneous expectations, no asset would be demanded (and
priced) if it were not in portfolio A. Since all assets have some demand and non-zero price, A has to be
the market portfolio including all assets.
The variance of the market portfolio can be represented as:
x i x j σ ij
[13A.2]
where we define σij as the covariance of i with j if i ≠ j and σij is the variance or σ2i if i = j.
σ ij = CORR i,j σ i σ j
Using a little elementary calculus, we can represent a security’s systematic risk (the contribution of
security i to the risk of the market portfolio) by taking the partial derivative of the portfolio risk with
respect to a change in the weight of the security. This measures the change in the portfolio variance when
the weight of the security is increased slightly. For security 2,
N
[13A.3]
2
δσ p
2
= 2 ∑ x j σ i2 = 2 [x 1 COV (R 1 , R 2 ) + x 2 σ 2 + x 3 COV (R 3 , R 2 ) + … + x N COV (R N , R 2 )]
δx 2
j=1
The term within brackets (in Equation 13A.3) is COV(R2, RM). This shows that systematic risk is
proportional to a security’s covariance with the market portfolio.
The final step is to standardize systematic risk by dividing by the variance of the market portfolio. The
result is β2 as presented in the text.
[13A.4]
COV(R 2 , R M )
β2 =
2
σ (R M )
If you consult any basic statistics text, you will see that this formula is identical to the β2 obtained from
a regression of R2 on RM.
We can now redraw Figure 13A.1 in expected return-β space, as shown in Figure 13A.2. The
vertical axis remains the same, but on the horizontal axis we replace total risk (σ) with systematic risk as
measured by β. We plot the two points on the capital market line from Figure 13A.1: RF with β = 0
and M (the market portfolio represented by A) with a β = 1. To see that β = 1, substitute portfolio M
CORR M ,M σ M σ M
=
2
σ (R M )
2
1.0 × σ
M
=
2
σ (R M )
βM = 1.0
Page 520
The result is the security market line shown in Figure 13A.2. We can use the slope-intercept method
to find that the intercept of the SML is RF and the slope is (RM−RF). The equation for the SML is:
E(R) = R F + β(R M − R F )
And this completes the derivation of the capital asset pricing model.
FIGURE 13A.2
Relationship between expected return on an indiv idual security and beta of the security