Unit 3, CH 9, Dornbusch, Macro
Unit 3, CH 9, Dornbusch, Macro
Unit 3
(Rudiger Dornbusch, Stanley Fischer, Richard Startz )
• Central questions in macroeconomics are why output fluctuates around its potential
level.
• Growth is highly uneven. In business cycle booms and recessions, output rises and
falls relative to the trend of potential output.
• This chapter offers a first theory of these fluctuations in real output relative to trend.
• The Keynesian model of income determination that we develop in this chapter,
assume for the time being that prices do not change at all and that firms are willing to
sell any amount of output at the given level of prices.
• Thus, the aggregate supply curve, is assumed to be entirely flat.
• Key finding in this chapter is that because of the feedback between spending and
output, increases in autonomous spending—increased government purchases, for
example—generate further increases in aggregate demand.
• Output is at its equilibrium level when the quantity of output produced is equal to the
quantity demanded.
• Thus, an economy is at equilibrium output when
• When aggregate demand—the amount people want to buy—is not equal to output,
there is unplanned inventory investment or disinvestment.
• In practice, the demand for consumption goods is not constant but, rather, increases
with income: Families with higher incomes consume more than families with lower
incomes, and countries where income is higher have higher levels of total
consumption.
• The relationship between consumption and income is described by the
consumption function.
• Variable ̅𝐶 , the intercept, represents the level of consumption when income is zero.
• For every dollar increase in income, the level of consumption increases by $ c.
• The slope of the consumption function is c, have a special name, the marginal
propensity to consume (MPC).
• The marginal propensity to consume is the increase in consumption per unit increase
in income.
• It lies between 0 and 1.
• What happens to the rest of the dollar of income, the fraction (1- c), that is not spent
on consumption?
• If it is not spent, it must be saved. Income is either spent or saved
• Income not spent on consumption is saved.
• Now we add investment, government spending and taxes, and foreign trade to our
model, but we assume for the moment that each is autonomous, that is, determined
outside the model and specifically assumed to be independent of income.
• The aggregate demand schedule is obtained by adding (vertically) the demands for
consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports at each level of
income.
• The equilibrium level of income is such that aggregate demand equals output (which
in turn equals income).
• The 45°-line, AD = Y, shows points at which output and aggregate demand are equal.
• Only at point E, and at the corresponding equilibrium levels of income and output,
does aggregate demand exactly equal output. At that level of output and income,
planned spending precisely matches production.
• At any income level below Y, firms find that demand exceeds output and inventories
are declining, and they therefore increase production. Conversely, for output levels
above, firms find inventories piling up and therefore cut production.
• This process leads to the equilibrium output level, at which current production exactly
matches planned aggregate spending and unintended inventory changes ( IU ) are
therefore equal to zero.
• FORMULA FOR EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT: Y = AD
• This implies,
• The position of the aggregate demand schedule is characterized by its slope, c (the
marginal propensity to consume), and intercept - (autonomous spending).
• A steeper aggregate demand function—as would be implied by a higher marginal
propensity to consume—implies a higher level of equilibrium income.
• Similarly, for a given marginal propensity to consume, a higher level of autonomous
spending, a larger intercept—implies a higher equilibrium level of income.
• Thus, the equilibrium level of output is higher the larger the marginal propensity to
consume, c, and the higher the level of autonomous spending.
• We are interested in knowing how a change in some component of autonomous
spending would change output.
• For example, if the marginal propensity to consume is .9, then 1/(1 − c ) = 10.
• So, a $1 billion increase in government spending increases output by $10 billion,
since the recipients of the increased government spending increase their own
spending, the recipients of that spending increase theirs, and so on.
• Note that we can compute the change in output without specifying the level of output
either before or after the change.
• Alternative formulation of the equilibrium condition that aggregate demand is equal
to output.
• In equilibrium, planned investment equals saving, applies only to an economy in
which there is no government and no foreign trade.
• Without government and foreign trade, the vertical distance between the aggregate
demand and consumption schedules in the figure is equal to planned investment
spending.
• Accordingly, at the equilibrium level of income, and only at that level, the two
vertical distances are equal.
• Thus, at the equilibrium level of income, saving equals (planned) investment.
• By contrast, above the equilibrium level of income, saving (the distance between the
45° line and the consumption schedule) exceeds planned investment, while below the
equilibrium level of income, planned investment exceeds saving.
• Since income is either spent or saved, Y = C + S.
• Without government and foreign trade, aggregate demand equals consumption plus
investment, Y = C + I.
• This implies, S = I.
• If we include government and foreign trade then Y = C + S + TA + TR and Y = C + I
+ G + NX. Therefore, I = S + TA + TR – G – NX.
• Thus, investment equals private savings (S) plus the government budget surplus
• (TA − TR − G) minus net exports (NX).
• Investment is the leftover corn that will be planted for next year’s crop. The sources
of corn investment are corn saved by individuals, any corn left over from government
tax collections net of government spending, and any net corn imported from abroad.
• By how much does a $1increase in autonomous spending raise the equilibrium level
of income?
• Suppose first that output increased by $1 to match the increased level of autonomous
spending. This increase in output and income would in turn give rise to further
induced spending as consumption rises because the level of income has risen.
• Out of an additional dollar of income, a fraction c is consumed. Assume, then, that
production increases further to meet this induced expenditure, that is, that output and
thus income increase by 1 - c. That will still leave us with an excess demand, because
the expansion in production and income by 1 c will
give rise to further induced spending. This story could clearly take a long time to tell.
Does the process have an end?
• For a value of c < 1, the successive terms in the series become progressively smaller.
In fact, we are dealing with a geometric series, so the equation simplifies to
• The cumulative change in aggregate spending is equal to a multiple of the increase in
autonomous spending.
• The multiple 1/(1 - c ) is called the multiplier.
• The multiplier is the amount by which equilibrium output changes when autonomous
aggregate demand increases by 1 unit.
𝛥𝑦
• The general definition of the multiplier is 𝛥𝐴̅ , the change in equilibrium output when
autonomous demand increases by 1 unit.
• Larger the marginal propensity to consume, the larger the multiplier.
• This is because a high marginal propensity to consume implies that a larger fraction of
an additional dollar of income will be consumed, and thus added to aggregate
demand, thereby causing a larger induced increase in demand.
• If the economy for some reason—for example, a loss in confidence that reduces
investment spending—experiences a shock that reduces income, people whose
incomes have gone down will spend less, thereby driving equilibrium income down
even further. The multiplier is therefore potentially part of the explanation of why
output fluctuates.
• The larger the increase in autonomous spending, represented in Figure 9-3 by the
parallel shift in the aggregate demand schedule, the larger the income change.
• Furthermore, the larger the marginal propensity to consume—that is, the steeper the
aggregate demand schedule—the larger the income change.
• There are three points to remember from this discussion of the multiplier:
• An increase in autonomous spending raises the equilibrium level of income.
• The increase in income is a multiple of the increase in autonomous spending.
• The larger the marginal propensity to consume, the larger the multiplier arising
from the relation between consumption and income.
• Disposable income (YD) is the net income available for spending by households after
they receive transfers from and pay taxes to the government. It thus consists of income
plus transfers minus taxes, Y + TR − TA.
• we can rewrite the consumption function,
• The slope of the AD schedule is flatter because households now have to pay part of
every dollar of income in taxes and are left with only 1 - t of that dollar. Thus, as
equation (20) shows, the marginal propensity to consume out of income is now c(1 – t)
instead of c .
• We see that the government sector makes a substantial difference. It raises autonomous
spending by the amount of government purchases, and by the amount of induced
spending out of net transfers; in addition, the presence of the income tax lowers the
multiplier.
• Suppose that instead of raising government spending on goods and services, the
government increases transfer payments. Autonomous spending, will increase by only 𝑐𝛥𝑇𝑅̅̅̅̅ ,
̅̅̅̅ .
so output will rise by 𝛼𝐺 ∗ 𝑐𝛥𝑇𝑅
• The multiplier for transfer payments is smaller than that for government spending—
by a factor c —because part of any increase in TR is saved.
• If the government raises marginal tax rates, two things happen.
• The direct effect is that aggregate demand will be reduced since the increased taxes
reduce disposable income and therefore consumption. In addition, the multiplier will
be smaller, so shocks will have a smaller effect on aggregate demand.
• Since the theory we are developing implies that changes in government spending and
taxes affect the level of income; it seems that fiscal policy can be used to stabilize the
economy.
• When the economy is in a recession, or growing slowly, perhaps taxes should
be cut or spending increased to get output to rise. And when the economy is booming,
perhaps taxes should be increased or government spending cut to get back down to
full employment. Indeed, fiscal policy is used actively to try to stabilize the economy.
• The budget deficit on which the media and politicians focus is the federal budget.
• “Government” in the national income accounts consists of all levels of government—
federal, state, and local. State and local governments tend to run small (less than 1
percent of GDP) surpluses in boom years and small deficits in recession years.
• Is there a reason for concern over a budget deficit? The fear is that the government’s
borrowing makes it difficult for private firms to borrow and invest and thus
slows the economy’s growth.
• The budget surplus is the excess of the government’s revenues, taxes, over its total
expenditures, consisting of purchases of goods and services and transfer payments.
• A negative budget surplus, an excess of expenditure over revenues, is a budget deficit.
• At low levels of income, the budget is in deficit (the surplus is negative) because
government spending, exceeds income tax collection.
• At high levels of income, by contrast, the budget shows a surplus, since income tax
collection exceeds expenditures in the form of government purchases and transfers.
• For instance, suppose there is an increase
in investment demand that increases the level of output. Then the budget deficit will
fall or the surplus will increase because tax revenues have risen. But the government
has done nothing that changed the deficit.
• Budget deficits in recessions, periods when the government’s tax receipts are low.
And in practice, transfer payments, through unemployment benefits, also increase
during recessions
• Recall that increases in taxes add to the surplus and that increases in government
expenditures reduce the surplus.
• It seems that the budget surplus is a convenient, simple measure of the overall
effects of fiscal policy on the economy. For instance, when the budget is in deficit,
we would say that fiscal policy is expansionary, tending to increase GDP.
• However, the budget surplus by itself suffers from a serious defect as a measure of
the direction of fiscal policy.
• The defect is that the surplus can change because of changes in autonomous private
spending
• Thus, an increase in the budget deficit does not necessarily mean that the government
has changed its policy in an attempt to increase the level of income.
• Since we frequently want to measure the way in which fiscal policy is being used
to affect the level of income, we require some measure of policy that is independent
of the particular position of the business cycle—boom or recession—in which we may
find ourselves.
• Such a measure is provided by the full-employment budget surplus, which we denote
by BS *.
• The full-employment budget surplus measures the budget surplus at the full-
employment level of income or at potential output.
• Other names- cyclically adjusted surplus (or deficit), the high-employment surplus,
the standardized budget surplus, and the structural surplus.
• The difference between the actual and the full-employment budgets, we subtract the
actual budget surplus from the full-employment budget surplus to obtain
QUESTIONS
10. How is equilibrium of GDP determined in four sector economy? Explain with the
help of diagram using aggregate output-expenditure approach.
11. If C = 50 crores + 0.75 YD and I = 50, G = 130 and T = 100 crores. Calculate
a) Equilibrium Y and C
b) Proportion of national income collected by government as taxes.
c) The value of multiplier
12. What is meant by multiplier? Explain the working of multiplier using suitable
diagram and example.
13. Derive corresponding saving function for C = 10 + 0.85 Y. Also, find the level of
income where saving is 0. Find the MPC and MPS as well.
14. Explain the determination of equilibrium level of national income in a 2-sector
economy. Is the equilibrium level of income found only at full employment level?
15. What is investment multiplier? Discuss the working of the multiplier process.
16. If C = 50 + 0.6Y and I = 20 crores.
a) Find the value of multiplier
b) By how much consumption and income will increase as a result of increase in
investment by 30 crores?