Caves Frankel and Jones
Caves Frankel and Jones
WORLD TRADE
AND PAYMENTS
AN INTRODUCTION
TENTH EDITION
RICHARD E. CAVES
HARVARD UNIVERSITY
JEFFREY A. FRANKEL
HARVARD UNIVERSITY
RONALD W. JONES
UNIVERSITY OF ROCHESTER
CAVE.6607.fm.pi-xviii 6/9/06 3:44 PM Page ix
Contents ix
x Contents
Contents xi
PART IV
CHAPTER 15
The Balance of
Payments Accounts
P
arts I through III of this book concentrated on the behavior of “real” variables in
the international economy—on the quantities of goods produced, consumed, and
traded. Prices were crucial in securing equilibrium, but only as the relative prices
of goods (the terms of trade) or of factors of production. The focus now turns to the
macroeconomic side of international economics.1 This requires an examination of the
behavior of monetary magnitudes—the quantity of money itself and various prices that
are measured in currency units. These include overall price levels, wage rates, and the
foreign exchange rate, which is the price at which currencies exchange for one another.
The subject of international monetary economics has grown rapidly in interest and
importance over the last 40 years. Much has happened over this period in the world
economy. In 1973 the major industrialized countries moved from a system under which
exchange rates were fixed by governments—a system that had held sway since World
War II—to a new system in which exchange rates are determined in the marketplace.
Meanwhile, both goods markets and financial markets have become highly inte-
grated, forcing even previously insular American macroeconomists to recognize the
importance of the foreign sector; oil price changes have induced economists to build
back into their view of the macroeconomy some of the real factors that had been left
behind; developing countries have become integrated into the global economy;
European countries have achieved monetary integration with each other; and large
new macroeconomic policy disturbances, unprecedented trade imbalances, and cur-
rency crises in some countries have tested the limits of the modern financial system.
Exchange rate flexibility has continued to spread, including to major developing coun-
tries. At the same time, thinking on the subject has been stimulated by new develop-
ments in the macroeconomic theory of closed economies: Intellectual revolutions that
introduced such concepts as rational expectations in financial markets, credible com-
mitment in monetary policy, and intertemporal optimization in saving behavior.
This half of the book will introduce eight or ten factors, or variables, that received
little or no attention in the first half of the book.The variables include the exchange rate,
output and employment (emphasizing the cyclical components of each), the interest
1
The term international finance applies as well, particularly to the material covered in Parts V and VI.
273
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 274
rate, stocks of money and reserves, the aggregate price level, the relative price of non-
traded goods, international flows of portfolio capital, and expectations. Understanding
how the macroeconomic system works can be quite difficult if one tries to consider all
ten variables simultaneously. These variables will be introduced one at a time, so that
each can be assimilated—understood in terms of its interaction with the other vari-
ables—before the next is introduced. Thus we need not discard what we have used at
each stage as we move on to the next stage and the next variable. Rather, we can con-
sider what came before to be the right answer when the variable in question is held con-
stant; we will then examine the corresponding change in the results when the new
variable is allowed to change.
Before proceeding, however, we briefly explain the sequence of the different vari-
ables. Chapter 16 will introduce the exchange rate and show how it helps determine a
country’s balance of trade. The effect of the exchange rate on the trade balance will be
examined first in the most controlled environment, in which price levels, income levels,
and all other variables are held constant. Then Chapter 17 will allow for cyclical fluctu-
ations in income. Unlike changes in output considered previously, these fluctuations
will represent changes relative to potential output, changes associated with unemploy-
ment of labor and unutilized capacity. They are the consequence of wages and prices
that are rigid, or at least “sticky”—that resist moving to equilibrate the labor and goods
markets. This represents a sharp departure from the first half of the book, in which all
prices were assumed to be flexible enough that they adjusted to ensure that supply
always equaled demand. Some of the results, such as the existence of unemployment
and excess capacity, are familiar from standard macroeconomics textbooks. However,
much will be new and different in the open economy. For example, when prices are not
free to adjust, the exchange rate can sometimes be used to restore equilibrium.
In the last part of Chapter 18 the money supply and the interest rate will make
their appearance. At this point we will address how five variables—trade balance,
exchange rate, level of income, money supply, and interest rate—all interrelate. Here,
and throughout the last half of the book, a key question concerns the effects of mone-
tary and fiscal policy on the open economy. In Chapter 19 two more factors are added.
The first half of the chapter introduces the stock of international reserves (e.g., gold)
that is held by the central bank. The second half of the chapter examines, for the first
time, the overall price level. Chapter 20 distinguishes between traded and nontraded
goods, providing a particularly useful model for developing countries and other coun-
tries that are small in world trade.
The core of Part V concerns the international flow of capital, the most powerful
new factor in the modern world macroeconomy. To simplify: Parts I through III con-
centrated on the international flow of goods, with the net trade balance generally con-
strained to zero; Part IV introduces the international flow of money, allowing nonzero
payments balances; and Part V introduces the international flow of portfolio capital—
assets such as stocks and bonds. Because an asset is a claim to future consumption,
international trade in assets is what allows countries to spend more than they earn in
some periods, then make up for it by spending less than they earn in other periods.
Finally, Part VI examines the determination of exchange rates in international asset
markets, where expectations also arise as a key variable.
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 275
We will see that two particular aspects of the structure of the world economy as it
evolved since the 1970s—the great ease of international capital movements and the
system of market-determined exchange rates—have completely altered how policy
changes and other macroeconomic disturbances operate. These aspects of the modern
economy have important implications for the resolution of international payments
imbalances and other policy problems that the world faces.
Before we begin exploring the operation of the international macroeconomy, it is
necessary to go through the mechanics of balance-of-payments accounting in the pres-
ent chapter. This tool would be necessary even if the subject were as tedious as mat-
ters of accounting sometimes appear. Balance-of-payments accounts, however, have
attained a new fascination. Some measures of the balance of payments are closely
watched by the press and policy makers.
Considerable insight into present international payments imbalances can be
gained simply from the accounting identities, even before the discussion turns to the
more interesting questions of economic causality. An accounting identity is an equation
that must hold precisely, as a matter of definition or arithmetic, as opposed to behav-
ioral equations, which represent theories of economic behavior that are not expected
to hold precisely.
TABLE 15.1
Schematic Representation of the Balance of Payments
Accounts and Subaccounts Cumulative Balances
CURRENT ACCOUNT (CA)
Merchandise . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Merchandise balance
Services
• Transportation
• Tourism
• Business and professional services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Balance of goods and services
Investment income. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Balance of goods, services,
and income
Unilateral transfers
• Government grants
• Private remittances . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Current account balance
PRIVATE CAPITAL ACCOUNT (KA)
Direct investment
Portfolio investments (securities and banking flows)
• Long term. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Basic balance
• Short term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Overall balance of payments
OFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS (ORT)
Changes in foreign central banks’ holding of domestic assets
Changes in the domestic central bank’s holding of foreign assets
• Gold
• IMF credits and SDRs
• Foreign exchange reserves
Note: Each balance at the right is the sum of the previous balance and the additional items listed before the dotted line.
families, from pensions to retired people living abroad, etc.). Transfers appear in the
current account rather than in the capital account because they do not create any
obligation for repayment in the future, as a loan does.
2
“Capital account” is generally used here to refer to the private capital account, as distinct from the transac-
tions of central banks. (It does include, however, any international transactions undertaken by government
agencies other than the central bank—for example, credits to U.S. armed forces stationed abroad.)
3
Special Drawing Rights, sometimes described as “paper gold,” are an asset created by the IMF. Their value is
defined in terms of four currencies: the dollar, yen, pound, and euro.
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 278
in the former case the debit appears on the capital account and in the latter case it
appears on the merchandise trade account. An American purchase of the bonds of a
Canadian provincial government is recorded as a portfolio capital outflow, a debit on
the long-term portfolio capital account. The American acquisition of a short-term asset
in another country—whether it is a Treasury bill, corporate IOU, certificate of deposit,
check, or currency—counts as a debit on the short-term portfolio capital account. This
point should be emphasized because it will be important for understanding the
accounting to follow. Remember that the reason this acquisition counts as a debit is
that an American has increased individual holdings of a foreign asset, even if the asset
is only foreign currency.
Ever since 1982, the U.S. capital account has shown many more credits than debits.
Foreign citizens have been acquiring assets of every sort in the United States: currency,
Treasury bills, bank loans, bonds, stocks, and direct investment. The term credit makes it
sound like a good thing for the receiving country. In one sense this is true: It can be
viewed as a vote of confidence when foreigners decide to invest in the United States.
The downside, of course, is that U.S. citizens will have to service the debt (i.e., pay inter-
est, and eventually repay the principal) in the future; or, in the cases of sales of stocks
and inward direct investment, dividends and profits will have to be repatriated abroad
in the future.
If American citizens resell to a foreign resident a bond originally issued by a for-
eign corporation, or any other foreign asset they acquired in the past, that too counts as
a credit. There is no economic difference between an increase in your obligations to a
foreigner or a decrease in a foreigner’s obligations to you. Both contribute to a
decrease in the net foreign investment position of the United States, which is simply
one more way of saying “capital inflow” or “credit on the capital account.” Similarly, if
an American buys back a U.S. Treasury bill from a foreign resident who acquired it in
the past, it counts as a debit in the U.S. capital account in the same way as when the
asset the American purchases from the foreign resident is one that was originally
issued by some foreign government or institution.4
The final place where credits and debits can appear is the Official Reserve
Transactions account. When the domestic central bank buys foreign currency or gold,
its purchase counts as a debit, just as it does when a private investor makes the pur-
chase, but here it appears on the ORT account rather than the private capital account.
As a device for remembering that it counts as a debit, the purchase can be thought of
as an import of gold or foreign currency by the central bank. In this sense it is like the
import of gold jewelry or shares in a foreign gold mine, except that in the jewelry case
the debit appears in the merchandise trade account and in the gold mine case in the
capital account. Only when the central bank makes the purchase does it appear on the
ORT account.
4
As a matter of fact, increases in U.S.-held assets issued abroad and decreases in foreign-held assets in the
United States are reported separately in the detailed balance-of-payments accounts published every quarter
by the Department of Commerce. Economic discussions of the balance of payments usually focus only on the
net capital flows, however. (Incidentally, since 1999, U.S. capital flows appear on what is now technically called
the “financial account.”)
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 280
Another example arises if the country in question is one whose currency is used by
other central banks as a reserve asset (as are the dollar, euro, and several other curren-
cies5). When a foreign central bank buys some of the domestic currency, its purchase
counts as a credit in the domestic balance-of-payments accounts, just as it does when a
private foreigner buys some.
5
Only convertible foreign currencies are held as foreign exchange reserves. Central banks do not hold
Tajikistani rubles as reserves because neither the government nor private banks will freely convert them into
gold, dollars, or other international reserve assets.
6
The unique case where one party does in fact give up something for nothing is the unilateral transfer. When
the United States donates grain to an African country, for example, a debit is assigned to the trade account of
the African country (or to its capital account if the donation consists of money) because something is entering
the country. A credit is assigned to the United States because something is leaving the country. As already
noted, the unilateral transfers account is where accountants, by convention, also assign a corresponding credit
to the recipient country and a debit to the donor country.
7
In a type of international transaction called countertrade, the exporter of goods to a country promises to
import a corresponding value of goods from that country. However, most countertrade transactions are still
paid for through the banking system. Relatively little of it is outright barter for goods, as this is awkward. Dalia
Martin, “Tying in International Trade: Evidence on Countertrade,” The World Economy, 13, no. 3 (1990):
445–462.
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 281
Other than paying for transactions by cash or check, the only other common
method is trade credit: The tractor manufacturer extends to the Argentine importer the
credit needed to buy the tractors (i.e., the importer does not have to pay until a later
date) or else a bank extends the credit to the importer. In this case the credit item
again appears in the short-term capital account: A foreign resident has acquired a
short-term claim against an Argentine resident. In this sense paying for an import on
short-term credit looks just like paying cash; both appear as credits in the same line of
the balance of payments.
current account debit is paid for by a short-term capital-account credit: A U.S. com-
pany has reduced its holdings of foreign assets, which represents a capital inflow just as
if it had sold off a security. (Recall that when the U.S. company decreases its credit
position vis-à-vis foreign companies, it is as if foreign companies had increased their
credit position vis-à-vis U.S. companies.) However, if the importer obtained the foreign
currency by drawing down some transactions balances that were kept on hand for the
purpose, subsequently it will probably want to replenish its stock of foreign currency
by buying some in the foreign exchange market. If the importer does not have a stock
of foreign currency to begin with, then again it has to go into the foreign exchange mar-
ket to obtain some. Either way, the importer needs foreign currency, and there will be a
second transaction in which it is obtained. If the importer obtains the foreign currency
from its central bank, the second transaction consists of a debit to the short-term capi-
tal account and a credit to the ORT account, exactly as in the first example.
Conversely, if the importer allows its stock of foreign currency to remain lower at
the end of the period than it was at the beginning (or goes into debt in foreign cur-
rency), then it must have decided deliberately to decrease its (net) holdings of foreign
assets. The net credit then remains on the capital account—as when foreign companies
increase their claims on domestic companies—rather than being transferred to the
ORT account.
import capital goods to invest in plants and equipment. Such countries are necessarily
borrowing from abroad to finance their current-account deficits. If they are spending
the funds well, they will in the future have the capital stock, particularly export capac-
ity, necessary to generate export earnings with which to repay that debt.
8
This may be the appropriate place to introduce the distinction between stocks and flows. Flows have a “per
unit of time” dimension, whereas stocks are absolute and dimensionless. Examples of stocks are the level of
reserves held by a central bank and the level of assets held by private investors, whether money, bonds, equi-
ties, or physical capital. Examples of flows are the balance of payments, the current account, income, spending,
and saving. A flow is the rate of change of a stock. The current account is the rate of change of the net interna-
tional investment position, with the proviso that the latter also changes discretely when there is a change in
the price of the assets (e.g., because of a change in the value of the currency). Such valuation effects have been
important in recent years for the United States.
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 284
negative number, then ORT is positive, which means the central bank is selling foreign
exchange reserves (or is buying the domestic currency that private agents in the mar-
ket want to sell).
9
The U.S. trade balance numbers differ from “net exports” in the national income and product accounts in a
number of minor technical ways, such as the treatment of gold.
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 285
Another place to draw the line is to include interest payments and other invest-
ment income. This total is referred to as the balance of goods, services, and income.10
Next comes the current-account balance, the measure of the balance of payments
that adds transfers in with goods, services, and investment income. We have already
explained that the current account is important because it represents the net acquisi-
tion of foreign assets, whether by private citizens of the home country or by the central
bank. Also discussed was the overall balance of payments (also called the official set-
tlements balance), which adds to the current account all private capital-account trans-
actions and is important because it represents the net acquisition of foreign reserve
assets by the central bank. Some economists have argued that the line should be drawn
between these two, that “exports” of claims to factories, along with other forms of for-
eign direct investment and sales of long-term assets, should count above the line—as
do exports of goods. Thus the basic balance adds these long-term capital inflows to the
current account. The accounting shows that this balance must be financed, or accom-
modated, either by short-term private capital flows or by official reserve transactions.
The basic balance is no longer reported for the United States. Indeed, it cannot even be
computed because the statistics collected no longer distinguish between long-term and
short-term portfolio investment. The balance is still reported for Japan and some other
countries.
10
The distinction among (1) the balance of goods and services; (2) the balance on goods, services, and income;
and (3) the current-account balance is roughly similar to the distinction between (1) gross domestic product,
which includes only income from domestic production; (2) gross national product, which also includes profits
from abroad (net factor income); and (3) total national income, which also includes income from transfers. The
U.S. government began to emphasize GDP over GNP in 1991.
11
The United States is one of the few countries that seldom intervenes in the foreign exchange market. Mexico,
Brazil, and Chile are three middle-income countries that joined the ranks of the floaters in the 1990s.
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 286
exchange rates, it made some sense to say that large U.S. balance-of-payments deficits
caused foreign central banks to buy up unwanted dollars. In the case of the deficits run
by the United States in recent years, however, it was as correct to say that the voluntary
decision by foreign central bankers to buy dollars allowed, or even “caused,” the U.S.
deficits.
This point is even more applicable when assets are sold to foreign private residents
rather than to foreign central banks. A surplus in the private capital account is what
allows, or even causes, a country to run a deficit on the current account, as much so as
the deficit in the current account giving rise to the surplus in the capital account. The
most prominent example is the large U.S. current-account deficit. To say that the
decision by private foreigners to increase their holdings of U.S. assets caused the U.S.
current-account deficits is as correct as saying that the decision by Americans to
import more goods and services caused the current-account deficits, which then had to
be financed by borrowing from abroad. The important point is that no clear presump-
tion exists as to the direction of causality. In reality, the various accounts are generally
determined simultaneously.
In fact, even the figures for the overall balance of payments are no longer explic-
itly reported for the United States, as can be seen from the actual balance of payments
statistics reproduced in Table 15.2. The net capital-account balance has to be com-
puted. In 1983 it turned sharply from deficit into surplus as foreigners began to acquire
U.S. assets in record amounts. We must add the capital-account number to the balance
on current account (a large deficit since 1983) to find the overall balance of payments.
At first, the private capital inflow was sufficient to finance the U.S. current-account
deficit. In 1986–2000, however, the private capital inflow has usually fallen short of the
current-account deficit. Foreign central banks make up the difference, as evidenced in
Table 15.2 under “foreign official assets.” The United States runs a deficit, not just on
its current account, but also on its overall balance of payments.
Making these calculations can be instructive even though we have abandoned the
presumption that the U.S. balance-of-payments deficit was necessarily causing central
banks to buy up unwanted dollars, rather than the other way around.
Foreign Statistical
Balance on Net foreign-owned U.S. Official Official Discrepancy
Balance on Goods and Unilateral Balance on Assets in U.S. Reserve Assets Reserve Assets (sum of the
Net Goods Net Goods and Investment Services and Transfers Current Excluding Official c Abroad d in the U.S. items with
Year Exports Imports Balance Services Services Income (Net) Income (Net)b Account (increase) (decrease) (increase) sign reversed)
1981 237.0 2265.1 228.0 11.9 216.2 32.9 16.7 211.7 5.0 227.7 24.1 5.0 21.8
1982 211.2 2247.6 236.5 12.3 224.2 35.2 11.0 216.5 25.5 229.9 25.0 3.6 36.6
1983 201.8 2268.9 267.1 9.3 257.8 36.4 221.4 217.3 238.7 17.7 21.2 5.8 16.2
1984 219.9 2332.4 2112.5 3.4 2109.1 35.1 274.0 220.3 294.3 77.4 23.1 3.1 16.7
1985 215.9 2338.1 2122.2 0.3 2121.9 25.7 296.2 222.0 2118.2 106.3 23.9 21.1 16.5
1986 223.3 2368.4 2145.1 6.5 2138.5 15.5 2123.0 224.1 2147.2 82.3 0.3 35.6 28.6
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 287
1987 250.2 2409.8 2159.6 7.9 2151.7 14.3 2137.4 223.3 2160.7 114.8 9.1 45.4 29.0
1988 320.2 2447.2 2127.0 12.4 2114.6 18.7 295.9 225.3 2121.2 104.1 23.9 39.8 219.3
1989 359.9 2477.7 2117.7 24.6 293.1 19.8 273.3 226.2 299.5 66.3 225.3 8.5 49.6
1990 387.4 2498.4 2111.0 30.2 280.9 28.6 252.3 226.7 279.0 28.6 22.2 33.9 25.2
1991 414.1 2491.0 276.9 45.8 231.1 24.1 27.0 9.9 2.9 23.3 5.8 17.4 244.8
1992 439.6 2536.5 296.9 57.7 239.2 24.2 215.0 235.1 250.1 51.9 3.9 40.5 245.6
1993 456.9 2589.4 2132.5 62.1 270.3 25.3 245.0 239.8 284.8 11.1 21.4 71.8 4.6
1994 502.9 2668.7 2165.8 67.3 298.5 17.1 281.3 240.3 2121.6 82.1 5.3 39.6 23.7
1995 575.2 2749.4 2174.2 77.8 296.4 20.9 275.5 238.2 2113.7 213.8 29.7 109.9 28.3
1996 612.1 2803.1 2191.0 86.9 2104.1 22.3 281.7 243.1 2124.9 4.3 6.7 126.7 212.2
1997 678.4 2876.5 2198.1 89.8 2108.3 12.6 295.7 245.2 2140.9 203.3 21.0 19.0 279.4
1998 670.4 2917.1 2246.7 81.7 2165.0 4.3 2160.7 253.3 2214.1 96.4 26.8 219.9 145.0
1999 684.0 21030.0 2346.0 82.6 2263.4 13.9 2249.5 250.6 2300.1 183.9 8.7 43.5 68.8
2000 772.0 21224.4 2452.4 74.1 2378.3 21.1 2357.2 258.8 2416.0 443.9 20.3 42.8 269.4
2001 718.7 21145.9 2427.2 64.5 2362.7 25.2 2337.5 251.9 2389.5 377.1 24.9 28.1 29.6
2002 682.4 21164.7 2482.3 61.1 2421.2 10.0 2411.2 264.0 2475.2 388.1 23.7 115.9 223.7
2003 713.4 21260.7 2547.3 52.5 2494.8 46.3 2448.5 271.2 2519.7 280.9 1.5 278.3 237.8
2004 807.5 21472.9 2665.4 47.8 2617.6 30.4 2587.1 280.9 2668.1 187.1 2.8 394.7 85.1
2005* 657.9 21224.2 2566.3 41.4 2524.8 20.5 2525.3 262.3 2587.6 416.4 9.3 146.3 20.6
287
CAVE.6607.cp15.p271-290 6/6/06 5:01 PM Page 288
impelled funds to seek a safe haven in the United States. The acquisition of such claims
by foreigners, called “capital flight,” often is clandestine and goes unrecorded. Sub-
sequently this net flow reversed, suggesting that this flight capital was returning home.
The absolute magnitude of the discrepancy is still large.
Another major discrepancy appears when the net current-account positions of all
countries are added together. Because every export is some country’s import, these
accounts would sum to zero if all countries got their measurements right. The discrep-
ancy has run as large as $100 billion in recent years. It appears as though the world
were running a deficit with other planets.
15.6 Summary
The study of international monetary economics begins with the balance-of-payments
accounts. The current account adds up all credits and debits arising from trade in goods
and services and from transfers, the private capital account covers the purchase and
sale of assets, and the official reserve transactions account consists of changes in inter-
national reserve holdings by central banks.
We will now turn from rules of accounting to models of economic behavior.
Throughout most of the book, the subaccounts will usually be ignored and the focus
will be on the CA/KA/ORT level of aggregation. For example, the discussion will often
abstract from transfers to speak interchangeably of the trade balance (TB) and current
account (CA).
CHAPTER PROBLEMS
Answer only the implications of the transaction specified for the U.S. balance of pay-
ments. Do not assume that the recipients of payments from abroad necessarily
exchange foreign currency with the central bank as would be the case if capital flows
were assumed to be zero.
1. U.S. imports BMWs from Germany; pays by check in euros.
2. U.S. exports grain to Japan; paid by check in dollars.
3. U.S. imports coffee from Brazil; agrees to pay in dollars 3 months later.
4. U.S. tourists spend Swiss francs in Geneva.
5. Mexico buys locomotives from U.S. firm, which agrees to let the Mexicans pay in
dollars 18 months later.
6. French firms and banks, because they are accumulating more dollars than they
want or than U.S. banks will accept, turn them in to the Federal Reserve, which
agrees to give them euros.
7. A U.S. investor buys a 2-year Canadian treasury note; pays by check.
8. U.S. firm builds a factory in Mexico; pays for land, local labor, and so on,
in pesos.
9. U.S. government sends foreign aid to Pakistan, which Pakistanis hold in the form
of dollars.
10. China buys nuclear reactors from the U.S. government; pays in gold. (No central
bank is involved.)
11. Portuguese immigrant sends money back to family in Lisbon in the form of
a 10-year U.S. savings bond.
12. U.S. firm receives profits in the form of pesos from the factory it previously built
in Mexico.
13. Dutch holding company buys a controlling interest in an American firm;
pays in dollars.
14. U.S. ship is leased to carry beef from Australia to Britain. Payment for freight
charges is in dollars.
15. Federal Reserve sells gold to support the value of the dollar.
2. We hear of financial transfers to “launder” illegally acquired funds. For example, a
South American smuggler might deposit income from illegal exports in a Miami bank,
and arrange for the bank to re-lend it to the smuggler to invest in a legitimate activity.
a. How would this transaction appear in the U.S. balance-of-payments accounts if
it were recorded correctly? How would it appear in the accounts of the South
American country?
b. What error will it create in the accounts if the exporter’s earnings and claim on
the Miami bank are not recorded in the exporter’s home country but the transac-
tions are recorded in the United States? (This could be the case if the commodity
exported is legal, but the exporter leaves the dollar proceeds in the Miami bank
to evade taxes.) What will this do to the worldwide current-account discrepancy?
c. What error will be created in the two countries’ accounts if the exporter’s claim
on the bank is not recorded in either country, but the export is reported in both?
(To minimize the chances of getting caught, the exporter simply fails to inform the
Miami bank that he or she is not a U.S. citizen.) What would this error do to the
worldwide current-account discrepancy?
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 291
CHAPTER 16
T
he foreign exchange market is where domestic money (for example, dollars) is
traded for foreign money (for example, pounds sterling). The exchange rate is
usually defined as the price of the foreign currency in terms of the domestic cur-
rency, although it could as easily have been the reverse.1 This convention will be fol-
lowed here. Note that a depreciation, a decrease in the value of the domestic currency,
is an increase in the exchange rate because it is an increase in the price of foreign cur-
rency. Some find it counterintuitive that a decrease in the value of the currency is
called an increase in the exchange rate. Yet just as economists often talk about an
increase in the prices of commodities rather than the equivalent depreciation of
money’s purchasing power over commodities, so it is often intuitive to talk about an
increase in the price of foreign currency rather than the equivalent decrease in the
value of the domestic currency.
We are simplifying when we speak of the exchange rate for a country. In reality,
each country has many exchange rates, one for every other currency in the world. The
United States, for example, has the dollar/yen rate, the dollar/pound rate, and so on.
Although these exchange rates tend to be correlated, the measure of the movements in
the home country’s currency depends on which exchange rate is used.To get a good idea
of the value of the currency overall, it is necessary to use an exchange rate index, known
as the effective exchange rate, which computes a weighted average of the exchange rates
against each of the individual countries. Typically the weights used are the countries’
shares in trade.
1
In the United Kingdom, for example, the practice is to speak in terms of the dollar/pound rate, an exception
to the general rule because the pound is the domestic currency.
291
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 292
FIGURE 16.1
Increase in Demand for Foreign Currency
When the demand for foreign currency shifts out from D to D9, the result depends on the
exchange rate regime. Panel (a) illustrates a floating exchange rate: An increase in the price
of foreign currency is necessary to equilibrate the private market. Panel (b) illustrates a fixed
exchange rate: The central bank intervenes by supplying the excess amount demanded, out of
its foreign exchange reserves.
Price of Price of
foreign foreign
exchange exchange
(E in $/£) D′ S (E in $/£) D′ S
D D
BP deficit
0 Quantity of foreign exchange (£) 0 Quantity of foreign exchange (£)
of foreign exchange—the exchange rate E—on the vertical axis. We can think of the
supply and demand for foreign exchange as functions of the currency’s price—the
exchange rate—just as the supply and demand for any commodity are functions of its
price. Unless otherwise specified, supply and demand refer to private sources (i.e.,
transactions on the current account and private capital account, not official reserve
transactions by the central bank). In Figure 16.1 the supply curve and demand curve
are (for the moment) simply assumed to slope the conventional ways: upward and
downward, respectively.
The behavior of the exchange rate varies considerably depending on which regime
is in effect: floating exchange rates or fixed exchange rates. Under pure floating, the
exchange rate is whatever it must be to equilibrate supply and demand in the private
market. Consider an increase in the demand for foreign exchange, an outward shift of
the curve in Figure 16.1(a) from D to D9. Such an outward shift in the demand for for-
eign currency could result, for example, from an increase in demand for imports or
from an increase in investors’ demand for foreign assets. Under floating, the increased
demand for foreign currency causes an increase in its price, the exchange rate, just as
an increase in demand for a commodity causes an increase in the price of the commod-
ity. E goes up.
With a completely fixed or “pegged” exchange rate, conversely, the central bank
stands ready to buy or sell foreign currency whenever private supply and demand are
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 293
16.1 ■ The Flow of Supply and Demand for Foreign Exchange 293
not equal at the fixed rate. The official exchange rate would only by coincidence be the
rate that precisely equates private supply and demand. Under this regime, an increase
in demand, illustrated in Figure 16.1(b), would result in an excess demand for for-
eign currency that must be met by sales of foreign currency by the central bank. From
our discussion of the balance-of-payments accounts, we know that the country runs a
balance-of-payments deficit. The central bank keeps the domestic currency from
depreciating by buying up the excess supply of the domestic currency. Obviously, the
central bank can continue this only as long as it has foreign exchange reserves. (The
other country’s central bank also could use its own currency to buy up the unwanted
domestic currency, if it were willing to do so.) There are policy changes, which will be
examined later, that the domestic government can make to reduce the deficit instead
of financing it, but such policies generally take time to have an effect. If the deficit con-
tinues, eventually the central bank will run out of foreign exchange reserves and will be
forced to withdraw support from the domestic currency. The central bank must then
either (1) set a new, higher exchange rate at which it will stand ready to sell foreign
exchange from then on, or (2) cease foreign exchange operations and allow the market
to determine the rate. The first option constitutes a devaluation of the currency, the
second the floating of the currency.2
2
The appendix to this chapter shows how stability in the foreign exchange market depends on the slopes of the
supply and demand curves in Figure 16.1(a). This analysis holds whether or not the curves are derived from
exports and imports, as in the next subsection. Chapter 21 will discuss the mechanics of how foreign exchange
is actually bought and sold, most of it by banks.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 294
on the price of the export expressed in domestic currency. Similarly, assume that foreign
residents look only at prices expressed in foreign currency when choosing the demand
for the home country’s exports (in the case of foreign consumers) or the supply of
imports to the home country (in the case of foreign firms). Changes in demand arising
from changes in income are ignored. This assumption, representing the defining charac-
teristic of the “elasticity approach” to devaluation, will be relaxed in Chapter 17.
Assumption 3. Finally, assume for now that firms set a price for their product and
then meet any forthcoming demand. In other words, assume that supply is infinitely
elastic. This assumption can be regarded as a special case that is only a realistic descrip-
tion of the short run. In light of Assumption 2, the price at which domestic firms supply
exportables with infinite elasticity must be set in domestic currency—call it P—and the
price at which foreign firms supply the home country with importables must be set in
foreign currency—call it P*. Assumption 3 will be relaxed later as well.
By Assumption 3, output levels are determined by demand. The demand for
imports, MD, is a decreasing function of the import’s price expressed in domestic cur-
rency, which is the fixed price in foreign currency times the exchange rate.
M 5 MD(EP *)
If a Range Rover costs £20,000 and the exchange rate is $2.00 / £, then the price to
an American is ($2.00 / £)(£20,000) 5 $40,000. Americans will buy fewer Range Rovers
when the dollar price goes up, without distinguishing whether it is the exchange rate or
the pound price that has changed. Figure 16.2 graphs prices in terms of foreign cur-
rency to facilitate calculation of export revenue and import spending. Thus the import
demand curve is drawn for a given exchange rate, E. A change in E would shift the
entire MD curve. The demand for exports, XD, is a decreasing function of their price
expressed in foreign currency, which is the fixed price in domestic currency divided by
the exchange rate.
X 5 XD(P/ E)
If a Ford costs $20,000 and the exchange rate is $2.00 / £, then the price in Britain
is $20,000 / ($2.00 / £) 5 £10,000. British buyers will buy fewer Fords when the pound
price goes up, regardless of whether it is the dollar price that rose or the exchange rate
that fell.
A devaluation, an increase in E, lowers the price of exports to foreigners. This is
a movement down the curve, increasing the quantity of exports demanded, XD, in
Figure 16.2(b). The devaluation also raises the price of imports to domestic residents,
reducing their demand, MD. This is represented in Figure 16.2(a) as a proportionate
downward shift of the entire import demand curve because the curve was drawn con-
tingent on the exchange rate.3
3
If the vertical axes had been expressed in domestic currency instead of foreign currency, the devaluation
would have been an upward movement along the import demand curve and an upward shift of the export
demand curve, instead of the other way around. (The effect on the quantities would have been the same as in
Figure 16.2.) The general rule is that a devaluation is a movement along the curve that describes the behavior
of the people (domestic or foreign residents) whose currency is on the vertical axis; it shifts the curve that
describes the behavior of the people whose currency is not on the axis.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 295
16.1 ■ The Flow of Supply and Demand for Foreign Exchange 295
FIGURE 16.2
Effect of a Devaluation on Trade
Panel (a) shows how a devaluation lowers the quantity of imports. Panel (b) shows how the
devaluation raises the quantity of exports. The effects on import spending and export revenue,
respectively, are shown by the areas of the shaded rectangles.
Price in Price in
foreign foreign
currency, currency,
P* P/E
MD (EP* ) XD (P/E )
MD (E ′P* )
P* P/E
P/E ′
0 M 0 X
Now consider the market for foreign exchange. Assumption 1 means that the
demand for foreign exchange is identical to import spending: In the absence of borrow-
ing, foreign exchange must be obtained on the market to pay for imports. Import
spending is quantity times the foreign currency price. The supply of foreign exchange is
identical to export revenue: All foreign exchange earned through exports is cashed in
on the foreign exchange market. Export revenue is export quantity times foreign cur-
rency price. So the demand for foreign currency prior to the devaluation is P*M, the
shaded rectangular area in Figure 16.2(a), and the supply is (P / E)X, the shaded area in
Figure 16.2(b). The net supply of foreign exchange is
(P/E )X 2 P *M
which is also the trade balance measured in foreign currency, TB*.
The appendix to this chapter considers the question of stability in the foreign
exchange market: Does an increase in the exchange rate increase the net supply of for-
eign exchange? This question is identical to this one: Does a devaluation improve the
trade balance? The two questions are the same because no capital flows have been
assumed. Domestic consumers cannot borrow abroad to get the foreign exchange
they need for imports, so the trade balance is the same as the net supply of foreign
exchange. We will now derive the condition under which the answer to the two ques-
tions is yes.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 296
4
The proof of the Marshall-Lerner condition in the present context (i.e., where the exchange rate takes the
role of the relative price) is given in the supplement to this chapter.
5
The proof of the Marshall-Lerner condition in terms of domestic currency is left to the student in Problem 5a
at the end of the chapter.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 297
Elasticity Pessimism
A view known as elasticity pessimism suggests that actual trade elasticities are too low
to satisfy the Marshall-Lerner condition. Several factors have contributed to this view
historically. First, floating exchange rates in the 1930s were unstable, in that they were
highly variable. The appendix to this chapter shows that the Marshall-Lerner condition
is also the necessary condition for a stable foreign exchange market under floating
rates. Thus highly variable exchange rates seemed to imply low trade elasticities.
Second, many countries on fixed exchange rates have found their trade balance wors-
ening after a devaluation, rather than improving.
6
You are asked to show this in Problem 5b at the end of the chapter.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 298
This is especially true of oil importers. Because the demand for oil is relatively
inelastic in the short run, many small countries discover that a devaluation against the
dollar raises their oil import bill proportionately when expressed in domestic currency,
thus worsening their trade balance. When a deficit country is advised to devalue its cur-
rency, it often argues that its elasticities are too low for a devaluation to help.
A third factor that originally contributed to the rise of elasticity pessimism was
that early econometric estimates of the demand elasticities were low, frequently less
than half. However, there were a number of problems with these estimates. They
ignored the possible simultaneous existence of an upward-sloping supply relationship,
problems of aggregation, errors in the measurement of the variables, and the crucial
role of time lags.7 Some studies measure only relatively short-run elasticities, but abun-
dant evidence indicates that the factor of time is important. Elasticities are higher in
the long run, which makes the Marshall-Lerner condition more likely to hold.
The J-Curve
Some studies that allow for lags of import demand in response to changes in relative
prices have found that only about 50 percent of the full quantity adjustment takes
place in the first three years; 90 percent occurs in the first five years. For example, the
dollar depreciated substantially between 1985 and 1987, but because of these lags, the
favorable effect on the quantities of exports and imports did not begin to show up until
the end of 1986, and the effect on the dollar trade balance did not begin to show up
until the end of 1987.
In this case, contrary to what we have assumed, dollar prices of imports did not
respond immediately or fully to the exchange rate. Many importers, rather than passing
exchange rate changes immediately through to import prices, at first absorbed in their
profit margins much of the difference between foreign currency prices and domestic
currency prices. The delayed pass-through to import prices added an extra lag at the
beginning, before the elasticities could even begin to come into play. The United States
is unusual in how small a portion of an exchange rate change tends to be immediately
passed through to import prices.
There are a number of reasons why demand elasticities rise over time, and why the
quantities demanded are slow to respond even after the change in the exchange rate is
passed through to import prices. First, there is a lag because of the imperfect dissemina-
tion of information, during which importers recognize that relative prices have changed.
Second, there is a lag in deciding to place a new import order. In the case of firms’
imports of inputs, it may take months or years before inventories are depleted or
machinery is worn out and replacements are needed. Also, a firm may be tied to a par-
ticular supplier, through implicit or explicit contracts. In the case of consumers’ imports,
7
Faulty measurement of prices is particularly common in foreign trade. For example, importers in some coun-
tries underinvoice, that is, they understate the price of their imports so as to minimize the import duty they
must pay. Also, where laws require exporters to turn over all their foreign exchange earnings to the govern-
ment, exporters might understate their prices to retain some of the scarce foreign exchange for themselves.
Such measurement errors in the price data make it more difficult to discern a statistical relationship.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 299
changing habits takes time. For example, when the price of energy jumps, continued
strong demand causes many observers to assert that energy demand is essentially
inelastic. With the passage of time, however, energy demand falls considerably. The
adjustment process requires not only overcoming the momentum of old patterns of
consumption but also changing where people live and what kind of cars they drive.
Third, after a new import order has been placed, there may be production and
delivery lags before it is filled. Much internationally traded merchandise is still trans-
ported by ship, requiring weeks or months in transit. Payment is typically not made
before delivery, even though the contract may have been signed months earlier.
The fourth reason why trade quantities respond more fully with the passage of
time, and the reason that can potentially draw out the process the longest, is that pro-
ducers sometimes relocate their factories to the country where costs are lower because
of an exchange rate advantage, regardless of whether it is the home country of the pro-
ducer or the country where the goods are sold. For example, when the yen appreciated
strongly from 1985 to 1995, some Japanese firms that had previously been exporting
with great success found that they were losing out to competition from countries with
lower cost. To compete more effectively, they moved some operations to other coun-
tries with lower-valued currencies. Sales in the world market that were previously
counted under Japan’s exports came to be counted under the host countries’ exports.
Thus the response of export and import quantities after an exchange rate change is
greater in the long run than in the short run because companies are able to relocate
their plant and equipment. The transition costs are large. For this reason, a company is
unlikely to relocate until the change in the exchange rate has lasted long enough to
convince the company that the fluctuation is not transitory. Such an endurance test
may take as long as five or ten years. Indeed, even after the exchange rate has returned
to old levels, a company that decided to move operations abroad when the dollar was
high might never move back, after having incurred the costs of moving. The word
hysteresis is used to describe such not-easily-reversed reactions.
The tendency of the elasticities to rise over time results in the commonly observed
phenomenon of the J-curve. The trade balance following a devaluation is observed first
to worsen and then to improve, in the J-like pattern of Figure 16.3. (The figure assumes
an initial trade balance of zero.) At the moment of the devaluation, quantities have had
no time to adjust and the Marshall-Lerner condition fails. In fact, if quantities do not
respond at all initially, then only the negative valuation effect remains: The trade bal-
ance worsens by the initial level of exports times the percentage decrease in their for-
eign currency value caused by the devaluation.8 However, as time passes, export
demand begins to pick up and import demand begins to fall. A point is reached where
the curve crosses the zero axis, which means that the elasticities are high enough to
sum to one and the trade balance is back at zero. After that point, the Marshall-Lerner
condition holds and the trade balance moves into surplus. The surplus must run for a
8
If it takes time before the exchange rate change is passed through to domestic prices of imports, the initial
worsening in the trade balance is spread over a longer period. The downward sweep of the J would then be
more round than as shown in the figure.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 300
FIGURE 16.3 TB
The J-Curve
In the aftermath of a devaluation,
the trade balance (1) worsens initially
because of the perverse valuation
effect, then (2) gradually improves over (3)
time as the elasticities rise, and finally +
(3) surpasses its starting point when the 0 Time
Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied. –
(1) (2)
while if the reserves accumulated are to outweigh the reserves lost during the initial
period of deficit.
All this assumes that exporters in the home country continue to supply whatever
quantity is demanded at the same fixed price. This may get increasingly harder, espe-
cially if they are operating close to full capacity. The exporters in the devaluing country
will be tempted to raise their prices in response to the increasing demand.Alternatively,
their workers may demand higher wages in response to the greater cost of imported
consumer goods, and the firms will be “forced” to pass through the higher labor costs in
the form of higher prices. However, we will stay with the fixed-price assumption until
Chapter 19.
16.3 Summary
The exchange rate is defined as the price of foreign exchange in terms of domestic cur-
rency. Under a floating exchange rate system, the central bank does not intervene in the
foreign exchange market, and the exchange rate is determined by supply and demand
in the market: An increase in the demand for foreign exchange causes an increase in the
price of foreign exchange (a depreciation of the domestic currency). Under a fixed
exchange rate system, an increase in demand for foreign exchange means that the cen-
tral bank has to supply the difference—the net demand for foreign exchange, which is
the balance-of-payments deficit—out of its foreign exchange reserves.
This chapter adopted the first and simplest model of what determines the balance
of payments. Part IV does not include capital flows; this chapter looked only at the
effect of the exchange rate on the trade balance, holding constant the level of income,
interest rate, price level, and other macroeconomic variables that we introduce in sub-
sequent chapters. A devaluation of the currency (or, under floating exchange rates, a
depreciation) increases the quantity of exports demanded by foreign residents and
decreases the quantity of imports, working to improve the trade balance. A third effect
that works to worsen the trade balance, however, is the higher cost in domestic currency
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 301
of any given quantity of imports that have prices set in foreign currency. Only if the sum
of the import and export elasticities is high enough, as in the Marshall-Lerner condition,
will the quantity effects dominate and the trade balance improve after the devaluation.
Empirically, the elasticities do appear to be high enough for a devaluation to
improve the trade balance, but only after enough time has passed. In the short run, the
trade balance often worsens, which gives rise to the J-curve pattern of response.
CHAPTER PROBLEMS
1. The newspaper reports that the dollar/euro exchange rate has risen.
a. Does this news mean that the value of the dollar has risen or fallen? The value of
the euro?
b. Does this mean that the dollar/yen rate is more likely to have gone up than down?
c. Does this mean that the euro/yen rate is more likely to have gone up than down?
(Hint: If neither the dollar/yen rate nor the euro/yen rate has changed, what does
that imply for the dollar/euro rate?)
2. Assume that the United States is currently exporting 10 million calculators at a price of
$10 apiece and importing .002 million BMWs at a price of 100,000 euros apiece, and
that the current exchange rate is 50 cents per euro. Calculate in a table the effect of a
10 percent devaluation of the dollar on each of 12 variables under each of four sets of
assumptions about the elasticities (assuming infinitely elastic supply and no income
effects). Round off.
Import
1
Elasticity: 0 0 ⁄2 1
(1) Export quantity 10m
(2) Import quantity .002m
(3) Export price $10
5
Expressed (4) Import price
in (5) Export earnings
$ (6) Import spending
(7) Trade balance
(8) Export price
5
Expressed (9) Import price 100,000 euros
in (10) Export earnings
euros (11) Import spending
(12) Trade balance
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 302
3. a. In the example from Problem 2, comment on the trade balances in (b) and (c) ver-
sus those in (d) and (e).
b. In which case is spending on imports in dollars very close to what it was before the
devaluation? Why?
c. In which case are earnings from exports in euros very close to what they were
before the devaluation? Why?
d. Starting from a position of importing .003 million BMWs, with everything else
remaining the same, what would be the initial trade balance in dollars? For given
elasticities, for example, (d), would the devaluation cause the trade balance to
improve (i.e., the trade deficit decrease) by more than, less than, or the same
amount as in Problem 2? (A numerical answer is not necessary but is fine if you
can’t do it intuitively.)
4. The trade balance expressed in domestic currency, with prices normalized to 1, is
TB 5 X(E) 2 EM(E).
a. Illustrate the effect of a devaluation graphically; that is, repeat Figure 16.2,
but with domestic-currency prices on the vertical axis.
b. If the import elasticity is greater than 1 and the export elasticity is greater than 0,
then the Marshall-Lerner condition holds. Is this condition sufficient to imply
that TB, the trade balance expressed in domestic currency, improves? (You may
assume the starting point is TB 5 0.) Explain why, in terms of export revenue and
import spending.
Extra Credit
5. a. If you know calculus, prove that the Marshall-Lerner condition is still the correct
condition necessary and sufficient for a devaluation to improve TB, the trade bal-
ance expressed in domestic currency, starting from TB 5 0.
b. Starting from TB , 0, is the Marshall-Lerner condition too strong or too weak for
a devaluation to improve the trade balance?
c. The trade balance expressed in domestic currency is equal to the exchange rate
times the trade balance expressed in foreign currency: TB 5 E TB*.
i. Does it follow that if the trade balance is in surplus when expressed in foreign
currency, then it is also in surplus when expressed in domestic currency?
ii. Does it follow that dTB / dE 5 E dTB* / dE? Why not?
iii. If initially TB , 0, which is greater: the left-hand side in the preceding ques-
tion or the right-hand side?
iv. Which side is greater if initially TB . 0?
v. Which is greater if initially TB 5 0?
d. Assume we start from a position of deficit, and the elasticities sum approximately
to one.
i. Notice from the supplement to Chapter 16 that if E M . X initially, the
Marshall-Lerner condition is more than sufficient to imply dTB* / dE . 0.
For example, if both elasticities are half, that is enough for a devaluation to
improve the trade balance in foreign currency. Conversely, from 5(b) we know
that dTB / dE , 0 under these conditions. Can the trade balance improve in
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 303
Appendix 303
where sM and sX are the supply elasticities of imports and exports, respectively.
a. Prove that in the limit, as sM and sX go to infinity, the formula reduces to the
Marshall-Lerner condition.
b. Does the presence of the supply elasticity terms make the condition more or less
stringent than the Marshall-Lerner condition?
APPENDIX
(a) E (b) E
S
S
ED ED
D D′ D D′
0 0
Quantity of foreign exchange Quantity of foreign exchange
(c) E
D D′
FIGURE 16.A.1 S
Think of foreign exchange traders as individuals who buy from and sell foreign
exchange to each other on the floor of centralized exchanges in New York and else-
where, or, in the case of the trading divisions of banks, on a network of telephones and
computer terminals. Assume that whenever foreign exchange traders find that demand
exceeds supply, they raise the exchange rate; whenever supply exceeds demand, they
lower it. Consider the following three cases.
1. Assume that the demand curve slopes down and the supply curve slopes up, as in
Figure 16.A.1(a). If the curves are derived from import spending and export earn-
ings, respectively, this first case is the one where the elasticity of demand for
exports is greater than one. In response to an increase in demand, from D to D9,
the traders raise the exchange rate. This raises export revenue, reduces the excess
demand for foreign exchange, and thus constitutes a move toward the new equilib-
rium. The market is stable.
2. Next, assume that the demand curve slopes down and the supply curve slopes down
also, but more steeply, as in Figure 16.A.1(b). Again, in response to an increase in
demand, the traders raise the exchange rate, causing a move toward equilibrium.
CAVE.6607.cp16.p291-306 6/6/06 12:00 PM Page 305
Appendix 305
Again the market is stable. This is the case where the elasticity of demand for
exports is less than one (so the increase in the exchange rate lowers export rev-
enue) but the sum of the two elasticities is nevertheless high enough to satisfy the
Marshall-Lerner condition.
3. Finally, assume that both curves slope down, but the supply curve is less steep, as in
Figure 16.A.1(c). This is the case where the Marshall-Lerner condition fails. This
time, when the traders respond to the increase in demand by raising the exchange
rate, they cause a move away from the new equilibrium. At the higher exchange
rate, excess demand is even greater, so the traders raise the exchange rate again,
and the situation is farther still from equilibrium. The market is unstable.
These examples show that the required condition for stability is that the supply
curve slopes up or, if sloping downward, is steeper than the demand curve.
As a practical matter, a floating exchange rate usually will not shoot off to infinity.
One possibility is that there are two stable equilibria surrounding an unstable one,
much as is shown in Figure 3.A.1. Even if the market is stable in the technical sense,
however, it may be unstable in the sense that the market-clearing price is highly vari-
able. Very small changes in demand may produce large jumps in the exchange rate.
High variability in the exchange rate may create uncertainty and imply high costs for
importers and exporters. These are cited as an argument against floating exchange
rates. This chapter showed that if the demands for exports and imports are relatively
inelastic, then the curves representing the supply and demand for foreign exchange will
be relatively steep. Resulting exchange rates may be highly variable if the exchange
rate is called on to clear the trade balance.
CAVE.6607.supp.pS1-S58 6/7/06 10:39 AM Page S-43
FIGURE 16.S.1
Effect of a Devaluation with Less Than Infinitely Elastic Supply
The devaluation can lower prices when expressed in foreign currency. Panel (a) shows the effect
on imports, and (b) shows the effects on exports.
Price in Price in
foreign foreign
currency, currency,
P* P/E
XS (P )
MS (P* )
XS (P )
MD (EP* )
MD (E P* ) XD (P/E )
0 M 0 X
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 307
CHAPTER 17
National Income
and the Trade Balance
T
his chapter examines the interaction of income and the trade balance. We use the
simple Keynesian multiplier model familiar from introductory macroeconomic
textbooks but open up the model to international trade. This will turn out to
make quite a difference.
Here Keynesian means simply that prices are assumed to be fixed (in terms of the
currency of the producing country, as in Chapter 16) and therefore that changes in
demand are reflected in output instead of price.This assumption is realistic for the short
run, especially in an economy with unemployed labor and excess capacity. Empirical
observation shows that prices are not perfectly flexible (to come in Chapter 19). In
addition to the short-run realism, a second reason for continuing to hold prices fixed
here concerns the structure of the remainder of the book. It helps to encounter new
variables one at a time. Chapter 16 focused on the effect of changes in the exchange
rate. This chapter adds the effect of changes in income. Only in Chapter 19 will we be
ready for changes in the price level, followed by international capital flows and other
factors. The introduction of all these variables at once would be quite confusing, so
they will be introduced one by one.
1
From this point on, imports are defined in domestic, not foreign, units. In other words, if the economy is the
United States, M (like Y and the other variables) is expressed in dollars. Because the price level is assumed to
be fixed, this is the same as expressing everything in units of U.S. output: number of automobiles, bushels of
wheat, and so on.
307
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 308
C 5 C 1 cY (17.3)
where c is the marginal propensity to consume. The essence of the Keynesian consump-
tion function is that households’ consumption increases, but less than proportionately,
in response to an increase in households’ disposable income.
Equation 17.2 does not show the exchange rate explicitly because the first step will
be to consider the case of a fixed exchange rate. Although many countries have highly
variable exchange rates, there are several reasons for beginning with the case of a fixed
exchange rate. First, it will provide a greater understanding of the 1950s and 1960s,
when almost all countries had fixed exchange rates. Second, it will aid in understanding
the many countries that, today, still have fixed exchange rates. Twelve European coun-
tries, for example, have adopted the ultimate mechanism for fixing their exchange rates
(vis-à-vis each other) by joining the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU)
and adopting the euro as their currency, created in 1999. Third, it will make it easier to
evaluate the frequently heard proposals to restore stability in exchange rates—from
ambitious schemes for a complete return to firmly fixed rates to more moderate pro-
posals for target zones.2 Finally, with the exchange rate held fixed, it is easier to under-
stand how the economy operates—before proceeding to what happens when the
exchange rate can change.
The demand for exports (foreigners’ imports) should be a function (analogous to
Equation 17.1) of relative prices and foreigners’ income, Y*.
Most countries are small enough that, although developments in the rest of the world
have important implications for the domestic economy, any impact of the domestic
economy on the rest of the world can be safely ignored. Thus this section begins with
the Keynesian small-country assumption that foreign income is exogenous. (This is in
contrast to the very different classical small-country assumption, which is that relative
prices are exogenous. That assumption is ruled out when export prices are set in
domestic currency.) Now we have the simplified export demand function,
X 5 Xd(E)
X 5 X. (17.5)
In other words, exports are given exogenously. Thus, from Equations 17.2 and 17.5, the
trade balance is given by
TB 5 X 2 M 5 X 2 (M 1 mY) (17.6)
2
Discussed in Section 27.6.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 309
where, for notational simplicity, we have defined the exogenous component of aggre-
gate demand as A ; C 1 I 1 G, and the marginal propensity to save as s ; 1 2 c.
(The part of each additional dollar of income that is not consumed must be saved.)
If government spending goes up by $1 billion (5 DG 5 DA ), by how much does
income go up? DY 5 $(1 / (s 1 m)) billion.The parameters s and m are fractions totaling
less than 1 because imports are a subset of total consumption. It follows that the multi-
plier is greater than 1: An autonomous increase in spending of a given amount raises
income by a greater amount. The explanation is that those who produce the goods and
services to which the spending goes see an increase in their income and so raise their
spending; this, in turn, raises the incomes of other producers, who raise their spending,
and so forth. The infinite series has a finite sum for the same reason as in a closed econ-
omy: At each round of spending, some “leaks out” of the system through saving, so each
round is smaller than the previous round. Notice that in the special case of a closed
economy, where m 5 0, the multiplier reduces to the familiar 1 / s, or 1 / (1 2 c). In gen-
eral, however, the open-economy multiplier is less than 1 / s because of a second leakage
from the spending stream: through imports.
3
Investment includes not only additions to plant, equipment, and inventories by firms but also residential
construction.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 310
17.3 Multipliers
Now consider Figure 17.1, where the horizontal axis represents income, Y. The saving
gap, NS 2 I, is an increasing function of Y, with slope s. Higher income means higher
4
If we wish to include government transfers such as unemployment compensation and social security in the
model, then T should be defined as taxes net of these transfers. If there are international transfers, they should
also be added in along with NFI.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 311
TABLE 17.1
U.S. National Saving, Investment, and Current Account
Net State and Net Net
Private Government Local Federal National Domestic Current
Saving Saving Saving Saving Saving Investment Account
(% of GDP) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) (% of GDP)
(1) (2) 5 (3) 1 (4) (3) (4) (5) 5 (1) 1 (2) (6) (7) < (5) 2 (6)
(average)
1961–1964 9.9 1.4 0.9 0.5 11.2 10.4 0.8
1965–1968 10.6 0.7 0.9 20.2 11.3 11.3 0.5
1969–1972 9.4 20.4 0.8 21.3 8.9 9.6 0.1
1973–1976 10.2 21.6 0.6 22.2 8.6 8.8 0.7
1977–1980 9.4 20.9 0.6 21.4 8.6 10.1 20.1
1981–1984 10.3 23.5 0.2 23.7 6.8 8.2 20.7
1985–1988 8.6 23.1 0.4 23.5 5.5 8.6 22.8
1989–1992 7.5 23.3 0.1 23.4 4.2 6.2 20.8
1993–1996 6.5 22.7 0.2 22.9 3.8 6.7 21.3
1997–2000 4.9 1.2 0.5 0.7 6.1 8.5 22.6
2001–2004 4.4 22.4 20.1 22.2 2.0 6.6 24.5
FIGURE 17.1 TB
Fiscal Expansion in the NS –I
Keynesian Model slope: s
The saving-investment line slopes XM
up because higher income, Y,
means higher national savings,
NS. An increase in government NS I
spending of DG shifts the
Y0 D1 C
line down. Point D is the new
intersection with the X 2 M line. 0 Y
G
D
D2
A
Y
XM
slope: m
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 312
saving.5 The other line in the figure represents the trade balance, X 2 M, a decreasing
function of Y, with slope 2m as given by Equation 17.6: Higher income means higher
imports. Equation 17.8 states that equilibrium occurs where the two lines cross. Fig-
ure 17.1 shows the initial intersection as occurring when saving equals investment and
exports equal imports. But the choice of this location is arbitrary; equilibrium could
occur as easily above or below the zero axis.
DY 1
5 (17.9)
DA s1m
Again, DY / DG, the multiplier effect on income, is smaller in the open economy than in
the closed economy because there is leakage through imports in addition to the leak-
age through saving. The multiplier formulas could also be derived geometrically. (See
Problem 3 at the end of the chapter.)
The convenient aspect of this graph is that it depicts not only income, Y, measured
on the horizontal axis, but also the trade balance, TB 5 X 2 M, measured on the verti-
cal axis. In Figure 17.1, the fiscal expansion pushes the trade balance into deficit
because the higher income draws in more imports. Algebraically,
DTB 5 2DM 5 2 mDY
Now use the multiplier, from Equation 17.9, to substitute for DY.
m
DTB 5 2 DG (17.10)
s1m
Equation 17.10 shows that the effect of a fiscal expansion on the trade balance is
clearly negative.
In short, the trade balance has been countercyclical in the United States, as in most
countries. Historical swings in the U.S. trade balance reflect the economy marching up
and down the X 2 M line in Figure 17.1. In the macroeconomic expansions of the
5
If it is recognized that tax revenues, T, depend positively on income, then the slope of NS is higher than s (by
the amount of the marginal tax rate). For simplicity in what follows, taxes will be treated as if they were exoge-
nous. The marginal tax rate is introduced, however, in problem 1 of Chapter 18. We also ignore the distinction
between the current account and trade balance in Figure 17.1; that is, we assume away investment income and
international transfers.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 313
1976–1978, 1983–1989, 1992–2000, and 2002–2005 periods, imports rose and the trade
deficit widened (as at point D). In the recessions of 1980, 1990–1991, and 2001, the
trade deficit shrank.
FIGURE 17.2 TB
Devaluation in the NS – I
Keynesian Model
The devaluation shifts up the s
s+m ∆X
X 2 M line (assuming the
Marshall-Lerner condition is
met). Income, Y, rises. The trade ∆X
balance also rises, but less than
+
it would if income were held
0 Y
constant.
–
(X ′ – M ) – mY
∆Y
(X – M ) – mY
6
For simplicity, the exogenous increase in net exports is represented by DX , even though it could be a fall in
imports as well as a rise in exports. One might want to think of the special case where the import elasticity is 1,
so total import spending is unaffected by changes in the exchange rate, and the entire improvement in the
dollar trade balance comes from export earnings X.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 314
The higher income means higher imports, according to the marginal propensity to
import, and so the improvement in the trade balance is less than if income were held
fixed.
DTB 5 D X 2 mDY
1
5 DX 2 m DX (17.11)
s1m
1
5 DX
s1m
The key point is that s 11 m , 1; the trade balance improves by less than the full exoge-
nous increase in net exports because of the higher imports that are drawn in by higher
income. Yet the effect is still positive: Imports do not go up as much as exports.
7
Here it is assumed for simplicity of notation that the money for the transfer is raised by taxation of the
public, T.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 315
FIGURE 17.3
Transfer Worsens the
Total Current Account
A transfer, T, to a foreign
country improves the domestic
trade balance, X 2 M, because TB
imports fall when domestic + S
disposable income falls. NS – I
Nevertheless, in the Keynesian E
0 Yd
model the overall current
CA T X–M
account, X 2 M 2 T, falls.
– T
R
X–M–T
8
The first to show this was not Keynes, but Lloyd Metzler, “The Transfer Problem Reconsidered,” Journal of
Political Economy (June 1942): 397–414.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 316
Repercussion Effects
If income, Y*, increases in the foreign country, foreigners import more from the home
country.
X 5 X 1 m*Y*
The foreign marginal propensity to import is represented by m*. In Equation 17.7, X is
replaced by the new expression for exports, resulting in the new formula for equilib-
rium income.
A 1 X 2 M 1 m*Y*
Y5 (17.12)
s1m
Obviously, domestic income depends positively on foreign income. Figure 17.4 graphs
this relationship. The slope DY / DY* is m* / (s 1 m), which is less than 1 unless the for-
eign country is much more open to imports than the home country.
The relationship explains how expansion in one country is transmitted to its trad-
ing partners through the trade balance. For example, in 1977–1978 the United States
pressured Germany and Japan to expand their economies. The plan, known as the loco-
motive theory, was to help pull the rest of the world out of recession. Often the United
FIGURE 17.4 Y m*
Slope: s+m
Transmission from Foreign Income
to Domestic Income
When foreign income, Y*, rises, imports
into the foreign country rise—that is,
exports from the domestic country rise;
as a result, domestic income, Y, also rises.
0
Y*
9
The Keynesian two-country model was developed by James Meade, The Theory of International Economic
Policy, Vol. I: The Balance of Payments (London, Oxford University Press, 1952), Chapters 4 and 5.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 317
States has been the locomotive pulling the world out of recession. In each episode, the
smaller, more open, and developing countries were anxious for the big industrialized
countries to expand because the economies of the smaller countries depend particu-
larly on foreign income. Of course, contraction is transmitted across countries, as well.
The prime example is the Great Depression of the 1930s, when declining income in one
country would result in declining imports, and thus declining income, among its trading
partners.
Now we are ready to drop the assumption that foreign income is exogenous. The
rationale has been that the domestic economy is too small to affect foreign income.
However, when a country as large as the United States (or the European Union or
Japan) expands, and consequently imports more from its trading partners, those
imports are a large enough component of world demand to raise income and expendi-
ture significantly among the trading partners. Then a large enough fraction of the for-
eign expenditure is spent on domestic goods, so that foreigners’ imports from the home
country in turn rise significantly. In other words, part of the spending that leaks out,
flows back. The result is that income increases in the home country, the place that
began the expansion, by more than one would expect based on its spending alone (the
model in Section 17.1). The feedback through the trading partner can be called a reper-
cussion effect. To model the repercussion effect, we now consider two countries that
are each large enough to affect the other’s income.
A* 1 M 1 mY 2 X
Y* 5 (17.13)
s* 1 m*
DY 1
5 (17.14)
DA m*m
s1m2
s* 1 m*
10
You are asked to do this in Problem 8a at the end of the chapter. Also see the appendix.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 318
FIGURE 17.5 TB
Repercussion Effect
Increases the Multiplier
NS – I
The effect of a fiscal expansion
is greater in the two-country
model (point D9), than in the
small-country model (point D)
because some of the spending
that leaks out of the country + NS ′ – I
through imports leaks back in 0 Y
through exports. B
–
D′
X–M
(two-country)
D
X – M (small-country)
results in a move to the new intersection at D9, whereas the intersection would be at
point D if foreign income, Y*, were kept constant.) Why? Some of the expenditure
stream that leaks out as imports now returns as exports. For every dollar increase in
domestic income, imports go up by m; because the other country’s exports go up by m,
its income goes up by s* 1m m*, and so it imports more from the home country. This effect
is represented by the term (m*m) / (s* 1 m*) in Equation 17.14. Because it reduces the
denominator, it increases the multiplier. The small-country multiplier is the special case
where a negligibly small proportion of foreign expenditure falls on domestic goods
(m* < 0), so this term can be ignored. Conversely, the multiplier is still necessarily less
than the closed-economy multiplier, 1 / s, as long as m and s* . 0. It is not possible for
all of the expenditure that leaks out through the trade balance to come back, as long as
any foreign income is saved.
We can continue to use a version of the X 2 M 5 NS 2 I graph of Figure 17.1.
Because
we can substitute
m
DY* 5 DY
s* 1 m*
from Equation 17.13 and so find the new slope of the X 2 M line:
m
DTB 5 m* 1 s* 1 m*
2 m DY2
ms*
DTB / DY 5 2 (17.16)
s* 1 m*
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 319
Notice that the slope is close to 2m, the slope of the TB line in the small-country case,
if m* is small. In general, however, the slope is less in absolute value than 2m, as evi-
denced in Figure 17.5. It is possible to see from the intersection with the NS9 2 I line
at point D9 the proposition already shown algebraically: An expansion (rightward shift
of NS 2 I) has a greater effect on domestic income in the two-country model than in
the small-country model because there is less leakage through the trade deficit.
FIGURE 17.6
U.S. Trade Balance and Current Account Balance, 1946–2005
1
Percentage of GDP
2
3
4
5
6
7
1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
Part of the answer is that in 1983–1984, and again in 1992–2000 and 2002–2005, the
United States was expanding more rapidly than were its trading partners. As is seen
from Equation 17.15, if the home country expands faster than the foreign country, the
home country suffers a worsening trade balance—assuming that the two countries
have the same marginal propensity to import.
What happens if both countries expand together, i.e., if income growth is equal?
If the two countries have the same elasticities of import demand with respect to
income, then there is no effect on the trade balance. The elasticity of demand with
respect to income is the marginal propensity to import (m 5 DM / DY) divided by the
ratio of imports to income: (DM / DY) / (M / Y). The usual way to think of it is the
percentage change in imports that results from a given percentage change in income,
(DM / M) / (DY / Y). There is evidence that imports are more elastic with respect to
income in the United States than they are in many of its trading partners.11 The devel-
oping countries and Japan have lower income elasticities.
One implication that follows for developing countries and any other countries
exporting goods that face highly income-elastic demand is that their incomes tend to
be procyclical: When the world is in recession, demand for their goods tends to fall
more than demand for goods produced by other countries, and so their incomes fall
more than proportionately. The high variability in income is particularly severe for
developing countries producing a single commodity, such as copper or oil, that serves
as an intermediate input in other countries’ production processes with little scope for
substitution.
A second implication would also follow if these elasticities were assumed to apply
to long-run, as well as short-run, changes in income: There will be a long-run secular
trend in the trade balance in favor of these countries and against the United States, and
other producers of manufactured goods, who face demand that is less income-elastic.
Indeed, this could be part of the explanation for the long-term trend toward deficit in
the U.S. trade balance reported in Figure 17.6.
It has been suggested, however, that the long-term income elasticities are in reality
not as high as the short-term elasticities when care is taken to separate long-term
growth in income from exogenous trends such as increased supply capacity in the
newly industrialized countries. Some have discerned a secular trend in trade adverse to
the raw materials produced by developing countries. The NIEs, such as Hong Kong,
Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan,12 have achieved strong trade positions through
policies of growth led by exports––not of traditional raw materials but of manufac-
tured goods, beginning with labor-intensive manufactures such as textiles and elec-
11
Some empirical evidence on how the income elasticities of import demand vary across countries was pre-
sented in a famous paper by Hendrik Houthakker and Stephen Magee, “Income and Price Elasticities in
World Trade,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 51, no. 2 (1969): 111–124.
12
These four entities are sometimes called newly industrialized economies, or NIEs, instead of NICs, in defer-
ence to the People’s Republic of China, which retook responsibility for the British colony of Hong Kong in
1997 and has never recognized the independence of Taiwan.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 321
tronics. The pattern that fits them best—and now China—is the product cycle.13 For
any given technology, a secular trend exists against the United States and in favor of
those countries able to adopt the technology to produce the same goods at lower cost.
Yet the United States and other technological leaders have always innovated and
stayed one step ahead, at least up until now.
17.6 Summary
This chapter added a second factor, national income, or GDP, to the exchange rate in
the determination of the trade balance.When income increases, the demand for imports
increases, and that, in turn, works to decrease the trade balance. Because the trade bal-
ance is a component of income, the determination of both variables must be considered
simultaneously.
Because we have maintained the assumption that the prices of domestic goods are
fixed (in terms of domestic currency), the resulting model is Keynesian: Changes in
demand are reflected in output, not in prices. This assumption is more realistic in the
short run than the long run.
The most important conclusions were evident even in the simplest form of the
model where the level of foreign income is held constant. This form is realistic given
the assumption that the domestic country is too small to affect foreign income. The first
conclusion concerned changes in government spending: (1) Such changes have a multi-
plier effect on national income because at each round of spending some proportion of
the income earned is passed on in a new round of spending; but (2) the effect on
income is smaller than in closed-economy textbooks because at each round of spend-
ing some income leaks out of the country in the form of higher import spending and a
higher trade deficit. Feedback effects via foreign income, which only need be taken
into account if the home country is large, work to increase the effect of an expansion
on domestic income.
The next conclusions concern devaluations: (3) If the Marshall-Lerner condition is
met, a devaluation will raise the trade balance, as in Chapter 16,14 and this in turn will
improve income because of the multiplier, but (4) because the higher income means
higher imports, the increase in the trade surplus will be less than it was when income
effects were omitted.
Other important questions can also be explored with the simple Keynesian model.
(5) When a country makes an exogenous transfer to its trading partner (reparations, for-
eign aid, or interest payments), it will generally experience an improvement of its trade
balance that is smaller than the amount of the transfer; thus, its total current account will
deteriorate (at a given exchange rate). Chapter 18 will consider further applications.
13
See the discussion of the product cycle in Chapter 9.
14
The appendix to Chapter 18 explores a qualification to this conclusion that arises if saving depends on the
terms of trade the “Laursen-Metzler-Harberger” effect.
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 322
CHAPTER PROBLEMS
1. In the Keynesian multiplier process, at each round of spending some proportion of the
income is passed on by its recipients as a new round of spending. The number of rounds
is infinite. Does this mean that the total effect on income is infinite? Why not?
2. The multiplier is greater than 1 if s 1 m , 1. Does this condition hold? Do you think
M , C or M . C? Why?
3. Look carefully at the geometry of Figure 17.1.
a. What is DG divided by Y0C, that is, by the horizontal distance from point Y0
to point C? (Remember the definition of the slope of a line.) Then what is
Y0C / DG? What have you just shown about the fiscal multiplier in a closed
economy?
b. What is the vertical distance D2D, expressed relative to DY? What is the distance
D1D, expressed relative to DY? Now take the sum of the two vertical distances:
What is D1D2 / DY? Then what is DY / DG? What have you just shown about the
multiplier in an open economy? How does it compare to the answer in (a), and
why, intuitively?
4. Would you expect the multiplier to be highest in Australia, Luxembourg, or Singapore?
5. Consider an increase in a country’s budget deficit.
a. What must happen to private saving, investment, or the current account, according
to the national saving identity?
b. In the Keynesian model (leaving out any interest rate effects on investment),
which of these alternatives, or what combination of them, results from a tax cut?
What is the answer if investment is allowed to depend on the interest rate (as at
the end of Chapter 18)?
(For parts c–e, assume tax revenue depends on income, as in footnote 5 or
Problem 1 of Chapter 18.)
c. If there is a recession because of an exogenous fall in C, what is the effect on the
budget deficit? Are the effects on private saving and the trade balance the same
as in 5b?
d. If there is a recession because of an exogenous fall in exports, what are the effects
on the budget deficit, saving, and the trade balance?
e. Are your answers to question b consistent with your answer regarding the
national saving identity in question a?
6. This question concerns the Keynesian model.
a. Recall that the definition of equilibrium is that output supplied is equal to output
demanded:
Y 5 A 1 TB
where Y 5 Output
A 5 Aggregate Demand, and
TB 5 Trade Balance
CAVE.6607.cp17.p307-326 6/6/06 12:04 PM Page 323
Yd 5 Y 2 TP
TB 5 X 2 M 2 mYd ; and
NS 2 I 5 CA 5 TB 2 T
Solve for:
a. DYd. This is the change in disposable income, equal to the change in output minus
the change in the transfer.
b. DTB.
c. DCA. Is the transfer undereffected or overeffected, or does it depend on the
parameters?
8. This question concerns the two-country model.
a. Solve Equations 17.12 and 17.13 simultaneously, to determine Y.
b. Use Equations 17.16 and 17.14 to solve for the effect of a spending rise on the
trade balance:
DTB DTB DY
5
DA DY DA
9. In Section 17.4 we applied the transfer problem to a small country, but the problem is
more often applied to two countries of approximately equal size (such as France and
Germany).
a. The transfer, DT, can be viewed as an exogenous decrease in the income of the
transferring country and an exogenous increase in the income of the recipient
country. The answer to 8b gives the effect of the first factor on the trade balance,
and the analogous equation for the foreign country gives the effect of the second
factor. Show that
DTB ms* 1 m*s
5
DT s*s 1 ms* 1 m*s
b. Is the ratio necessarily less than 1? What if the marginal propensities to save are
zero? How would the special case when the domestic country is so small that the
foreign country spends almost nothing on its goods look?
c. Show the effect on the current account, DCA 5 DTB 2 DT. Does the current
account of the transferor improve or worsen?
Goldstein, Morris, and Mohsin Khan. “Income and Price Effects in Foreign Trade.” In
Ronald Jones and Peter Kenen, eds., Handbook of International Economics, Vol. II
(Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1985), Chapter 20, pp. 1041–1105. Econometric estimates of
the elasticities of demand for imports and exports, including the distinction
between short- and long-run elasticities of demand with respect to income.
Hooper, Peter, and Jaime Marquez. “Exchange Rates, Prices and External Adjustment
in the United States and Japan.” In Peter Kenen, ed., Interdependence and the
Macroeconomics of the Open Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1995). Empirical analysis of the U.S. trade deficit and Japanese surplus.
Sachs, Jeffrey. “The Current Account and Macroeconomic Adjustment in the 1970s,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 (1981), pp. 201–268. A clear exposition
of the current account as the outcome of a two-period saving decision (as in the
appendix to Chapter 22), with special reference to the oil shocks of the 1970s and
countries’ responses.
APPENDIX
Appendix 325
FIGURE 17.A.1 Y
Simultaneous Solution for Both
Countries’ Incomes Effect of Y on Y*
TB = 0
D
A relationship runs from domestic income,
Y, to foreign income, Y*. A domestic D
expansion shifts the domestic line up so D Effect of Y* on Y
that the new intersection occurs at D9.
The increase in Y is greater than in the
small-country model—which ignored
the repercussion effect of higher income B
abroad (point D).
0 Y*
ure 17.A.1 to show it on the same axes as Figure 17.5. Equilibrium income for each
country is indicated graphically at the intersection of the two lines, point B.
Consider now an increase in domestic spending. In terms of Figure 17.5, the domes-
tic income line shifts up vertically by the amount of the simple open-economy multi-
plier (the amount Y would rise if we were still holding Y* constant). The expansion
results in a move to the new intersection at D9, whereas the intersection would be at
point D if foreign income, Y*, were kept constant. Why? As we learned in Section 17.5,
the multiplier is larger in the two-country model because of the repercussion effect.
Figure 17.A.1 can also be used to illustrate the point about an adverse trend in the
U.S. trade balance. The line that gives U.S. income, Y (as a function of foreign income,
Y*), shifts out faster than the line that gives foreign income (as a function of U.S.
income). In terms of Equations 17.12 and 17.13, A increases faster than A*. The inter-
section moves up faster than it moves to the right. At point D0 it lies above the trade
balance equilibrium schedule (the slope of which is m* / m, as we can see by setting
DTB 5 0 in Equation 17.15). The United States goes into deficit because its imports go
up faster than do those of its trading partners.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 327
The section on
CHAPTER 18
the liquidity trap
(p.341) has an
Spending and the Exchange update for ZLB..
C
hapter 17 developed the Keynesian model for determining income and the trade
balance in an open economy. In this chapter we consider some further applica-
tions of the same model, including how governments can change spending in
pursuit of two of their fondest objectives—income and the trade balance. We begin
with the question of how changes in spending are transmitted from one country to
another. Throughout, we focus particularly on the role that changes in the exchange
rate play in the process. We bring together the analysis of flexible exchange rates from
Chapter 16 with the analysis of changes in expenditure from Chapter 17.
in the small-country model. Recall that the multiplier here is smaller than in the
closed-economy multiplier because some of the change in aggregate demand “leaks
out,” or is transmitted to the rest of the world. An external disturbance such as a fall in
export demand, DX, changes income by the same amount.
DY 1
5 (18.2)
DX s1m
327
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 328
328 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
In this case some of the foreign change in aggregate demand is transmitted through the
trade balance to the home country.
The two-country model would serve as well here. The domestic spending multi-
plier would be a little higher, as in Equation 17.14, because some import leakage
returns in the form of exports. The same applies to the export multiplier. The important
point is that under fixed rates, disturbances are generally transmitted positively from
the country of origin to the trading partners via the trade balance.
FIGURE 18.1
Insulation Under Floating Exchange Rates
Panel (a) shows how domestic disturbances are “bottled up” inside the country. A fall in
investment, I, has a greater effect on income under a floating rate than under a fixed rate
because the currency appreciates and discourages net exports. Panel (b) shows how the country
is “insulated” from foreign disturbances. A fall in foreign demand causes the domestic currency
to depreciate, which stimulates net exports.
(a) Internal Disturbance Under Floating Rates (b) External Disturbance Under Floating Rates
TB TB
NS – I ′
NS – I NS – I
+ +
0 Y 0 Y
– –
X–M X–M
X ′′ – M X′ – M
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 329
lated and exports discouraged, and the X 2 M line shifts down. The shift will be what-
ever is required to restore the trade balance to equilibrium. The required change in the
exchange rate could be computed if the trade elasticities were known.
Whatever the exchange rate change, the ultimate effect is such that the trade bal-
ance remains at zero: DTB 5 0. From Equation 17.6,
DTB 5 DX 2 mDY
DI 1 DX
DY 5
s1m
D I 1 mDY
5
s1m
DI
DY 5 s (18.3)
Compare this to the multiplier under fixed rates shown in Equation 18.1. The internal
disturbance has a greater effect under floating rates than under fixed rates. The distur-
bance induces an exchange rate change that reinforces the effect on aggregate
demand. In fact, the disturbance has the full closed-economy multiplier effect. The rea-
son is that when the exchange rate fluctuates to keep the trade balance at zero, it
reproduces the effect of a closed economy. All disturbances are bottled up inside the
country rather than being partially transmitted abroad. The point can also be shown
graphically. The X 2 M line becomes irrelevant. Equilibrium income is determined
wherever the NS 2 I line crosses the zero axis because the floating exchange rate auto-
matically ensures that the X 2 M line crosses there as well. Because the NS 2 I line
has slope s, a disturbance that shifts it up by DI reduces income by DI /s.
Now consider the case of an external disturbance. A downward shift of the X 2 M
line, as in Figure 18.1(b), would cause a fall in income and a trade deficit on a given
exchange rate. The incipient trade deficit causes the currency to depreciate automati-
cally, however, shifting the X 2 M line back up until balanced trade is restored. At this
point the effect on income is eliminated as well: DY 5 0. The floating exchange rate
insulates the economy against foreign disturbances. Again, by adjusting to keep the
trade balance at zero, it reproduces a closed economy.
To sum up, floating rates (in the absence of capital flows) restrict the effects of dis-
turbances to the country of origin. This result suggests one possible basis on which a
country could choose between fixed and floating exchange rates. If the goal is to mini-
mize the variability of domestic output, then the absence of international transmission
is desirable to the extent that disturbances originate abroad because the home country
is insulated from them. Floating would be better than fixed. However, the absence of
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 330
330 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
Expenditure-switching policies are those that, for any given level of expenditure,
work to improve the trade balance by switching expenditure away from foreign goods
and toward domestic goods. In the case of domestic expenditure, the result is a fall in
imports. In the case of expenditure by foreigners, the result is a rise in exports to them.
The expenditure-switching policy focused on so far is devaluation, as in Figure 17.2 and
Equation 17.11.
Expenditure-reducing and expenditure-switching policies are equally valid ways
of eliminating a trade deficit. The most important difference between the two is that
the former accomplishes this by reducing income and employment, whereas the latter
does so by—or, more precisely, with the effect of—raising income and employment.
1
“Beggar” is used as a verb here, meaning “to impoverish.”
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 332
332 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
Partly as a consequence of the success of the GATT (now the WTO), protection
has shifted emphasis away from tariffs and toward other direct controls on trade, that
is, toward nontariff barriers. One nontariff barrier is the quantitative restriction or
quota. Some quotas, those imposed on industrialized countries on imports of textiles
from labor-abundant countries, were abolished in 2005 under the terms of the Uruguay
Round of negotiations concluded in 1994.
The economic analysis of an import quota is similar to the analysis of a tariff, in
that a quota raises the domestic price. The two would be practically equivalent if the
government auctioned off the licenses to import, so that the revenue accrued to the
domestic government instead of to the importers fortunate enough to get the licenses.
In practice, governments rarely auction off quotas. In the case of a tariff, the fact that
the revenue goes to the domestic government is an obvious advantage from the
national viewpoint, relative to a voluntary export restraint where the “revenue” goes to
the foreign country. If the alternative is a domestically imposed quota, then the rev-
enue generally accrues to domestic residents, as with a tariff. From a macroeco-
nomic viewpoint, however, there is still an important difference between a tariff,
under which the revenue accrues to the domestic government, and a quota, under
which the revenue accrues to the domestic private sector. An increase in tariffs, like
any tax increase, reduces the private sector’s disposable income and constitutes a con-
tractionary fiscal policy. Thus it has an expenditure-reducing side in addition to the
expenditure-switching side and may have a bigger effect on the trade balance than
would a domestically imposed quota.
Another nontariff barrier used sometimes when a government has a pressing trade
balance crisis is advanced deposits on imports. An importer must place on deposit with
the government a certain amount of money for a certain length of time, such as six
months, without interest. The effect is the same as a tariff equal in amount to the inter-
est on the deposit lost by the importer. Like a tariff, this barrier withdraws money from
circulation and thus has an expenditure-reducing effect, in addition to the expenditure-
switching effect.
The topic here is barriers to trade; barriers to capital flows will be discussed later.
Nevertheless, one device for discouraging the outflow of money bears mentioning: the
two-tier exchange rate. Suppose that South Africa is experiencing a substantial outflow
of capital and downward pressure on the price of its currency. Because it wants to
avoid worsening its inflation, as would follow if it devalues the South African rand, the
central bank maintains its fixed exchange rate for current-account transactions but
requires parties making capital-account transactions to use the competitive foreign
exchange market. There the exchange rate is left free to find its own level. Those clam-
oring for foreign currency to buy foreign assets—that is, to export capital from South
Africa—find the supply limited to the flow of currency made available by foreign resi-
dents desiring to export capital to South Africa. Capital exports and imports would be
equated by the market-determined exchange rate for capital transactions, and no net
international capital transfers could take place. This device could similarly be used to
avert a revaluation when a country is experiencing capital inflows. The two-tier foreign
exchange market is difficult to administer because it requires elaborate controls. If the
price of the South African rand is higher in the competitive market for capital-account
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 333
transactions, those exporting capital to South Africa have an incentive to gain access to
its currency at the cheaper rate for current-account transactions. In addition, South
African importers who must buy foreign exchange at the (for them) less favorable
current-account rate have an incentive to sell South African rand to buyers in the
capital-account market. Controls must keep these parties apart if the system is to work.
Capital controls can impair economic efficiency because they keep capital from
moving to where it earns a higher return. If the difference in returns faced by the
lender is also a difference in real social productivity, the control imposes a welfare cost.
One cannot be dogmatic, though, about the welfare costs of capital controls because
governments use the interest rate—the return to capital—extensively as a policy vari-
able. When the central bank is influencing the price of credit, the connection between
the market price and social productivity of capital is no longer certain.
Another barrier that has been used by developing countries is multiple exchange
rates. The government charges a higher price for foreign exchange when it is used to
purchase luxury consumer goods than when it is used to purchase, for example, capital
goods or—considered most essential of all—spare parts and fuel.
2
The general principle originated with Jan Tinbergen. The application to the open economy was developed by
James Meade. The application of the principle to an economy with international capital mobility, which we
study in Chapter 22, was developed by Robert Mundell. All three won Nobel Prizes.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 334
334 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
FIGURE 18.2
Dilemma: External Balance or Internal Balance?
Panel (a) shows how the government, using just fiscal policy, can attain either a zero trade balance
at point X or full employment at N, but not both. Panel (b) shows how the government, using just
exchange rate policy, again can attain either one goal at B or the other at N, but not both.
TB TB
NS – I
+ NS ′ – I + NS – I
0 Y 0 Y
– X Y – X Y B
X′ – M
N N
X–M X–M
Obviously, to attain balance in both sectors, both policies must be used together. The
case depicted in Figure 18.2 requires an intermediate exchange rate policy together
with an intermediate fiscal policy.
Heavy use has been made of Figure 18.2, the diagram of income and the trade bal-
ance, with one schedule that holds for a given level of government expenditure and
another that holds for a given level of the exchange rate. Now the situation will be
inverted, shifting to a diagram of expenditure and the exchange rate, with one schedule
that holds for a given level of income and another that holds for a given level of the
trade balance. Same model, new graph.
Assume that, by coincidence, the starting point is a position of both external and
internal balance, point A in Figure 18.3(a). To begin, consider external balance. If the
government increases expenditure, it must also devalue to maintain external balance,
as at point B. Otherwise, it will go into deficit. For trade balance equilibrium to hold,
G and E must vary together: Higher expenditure must be accompanied by a higher
exchange rate. This means that the combinations of G and E that imply external bal-
ance in Figure 18.3(b) are represented by an upward-sloping line: the BB schedule.
It is quite likely that the economy is at a point off the line BB. At any point, F, that
is below and to the right of BB, E is too low or G too high for external balance. This is
a point of trade deficit. Total expenditure is too high, or too large a fraction of expendi-
ture falls on foreign goods. It is necessary to reduce expenditure (cut G) or switch
expenditure toward domestic goods (raise E) to return to balanced trade. Similarly, at
any point, S, above and to the left of BB, E is too high or G too low, for external bal-
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 335
FIGURE 18.3
Policy Combinations That Give External Balance
After a fiscal expansion, there must also be a devaluation if the trade balance is to be restored to
its original level. In panel (a), the axes represent the policy goals. In panel (b), the axes represent
the policy instruments.
(a) (b)
TB E
NS – I BB
S
B
NS ′ – I
+
Y Deficit
0 Y A F
– A B
F
X′ – M
X–M
0
G
336 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
FIGURE 18.4
Policy Combinations That Give Internal Balance
After a fiscal expansion there must also be a revaluation of the currency if the level of output is
to be restored to its original level. In panel (a), the axes represent the policy goals. In panel (b),
the axes represent the policy instruments.
(a) (b)
TB E
Y
NS ⫺ I
NS ⬘ ⫺ I
⫹ F
Y A Excess
0 Y
demand
⫺ A
F U N
Y
N
X⬘ ⫺ M X⫺M 0
G
Figure 18.5 shows the BB and YY schedules together, in a graph known as the
Swan diagram.3 There are four zones. Zone I indicates a combination of trade deficit
and excess demand, Zone II a deficit and unemployment, Zone III a trade surplus and
unemployment, and Zone IV a surplus and excess demand. There is only one point of
full equilibrium, A. Again, both tools are needed to attain it. For example, many coun-
tries find themselves at a point like P1: deficit and unemployment. They could raise G
to reach full employment at the expense of a greater deficit or cut back G to attain bal-
anced trade at the expense of greater unemployment. The correct strategy is to cut G
and devalue, attaining internal and external balance simultaneously at A. Of course,
policy-making is not always this easy in practice. For example, the symptoms at point
P2 are the same, deficit and unemployment, and yet the correct strategy here is to
devalue and raise G. In practice, this might only be discovered by experimentation:
devaluing and then waiting to see what happens before deciding whether to change
expenditure. (Appendix B carries this analysis further.)
3
The Swan diagram was invented by Trevor Swan, “Longer-run Problems of the Balance of Payments,” 1955;
reprinted in R. Caves and H. Johnson, eds., Readings in International Economics (Homewood, IL: Richard
Irwin, Inc., 1968): pp. 455–464. It was further developed in W. Max Corden, “The Geometric Representation of
Policies to Attain Internal and External Balance,” Review of Economic Studies, 28 (1960): pp. 1–22.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 337
FIGURE 18.5 E
The Swan Diagram of Y
Internal and External B
Balance IV
The BB schedule shows the
combinations of spending, G,
and the exchange rate, E, that Excess
give the desired trade balance. N1 demand
B1
The YY schedule shows the Surplus
combinations that give the
desired level of output. Only
by deliberately using both III A I
independent policy instruments
could the government attain B2
both policy goals at point A. N2
Unemployment
II
Trade deficit
B
P2 P1 Y
0
G
338 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
FIGURE 18.6 TB
Effect of a Fall in the Interest Rate, I NS – I 1
X–M
i1
i2
IS
0 Y1 Y2 Y
alternative assets, represented by the interest rate. Yet even though money pays no
interest, people must hold some to undertake transactions. The demand for real money
balances is thus an increasing function of real income. If income were to go up, and
nothing else changed, the demand for money would go up. For a given real money sup-
ply, to maintain equilibrium in the financial markets (demand equals supply) something
else must change: The interest rate must rise to make bonds more attractive and money
less attractive. Only then will money demand be equal to the existing money supply.
Thus the lower part of Figure 18.7 traces a positive relationship between the interest
rate and income, describing equilibrium in the financial market. For a given real money
supply, the two variables must move together, precisely because they have offsetting
effects on money demand. This relationship is the familiar LM curve. The intersection
of the two curves, IS and LM, gives the equilibrium level of income and interest rate.
Notice that there is a unique critical level of income that implies a zero trade bal-
ance, Y1, in the upper panel of Figure 18.7. Anywhere to the right of Y1 is a point
of trade deficit because imports are too high. Anywhere to the left of Y1 is a point of
surplus because imports are too low. An expenditure-switching policy that shifts the
X 2 M line will change the critical level of income consistent with TB 5 0.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 339
FIGURE 18.7 TB
Monetary Expansion NS – I
X–M
i TB = 0
LM
LM ′
Deficit
M
IS
0 Y1
Y
Monetary Expansion
The following analysis will begin from a point where the equilibrium level of income
given by the IS-LM intersection also implies a zero trade balance, point E in Fig-
ure 18.7. We will consider in turn the effects of three policy changes: a monetary expan-
sion, a fiscal expansion, and a devaluation.
The monetary expansion shifts the LM curve to the right. For the higher money
supply to be willingly held, either the interest rate must fall or income must rise. In fact,
both happen; the interest rate falls and stimulates investment and thus income. The
new equilibrium occurs at point M. Because this is to the right of the TB 5 0 point,
clearly the higher level of expenditure stimulated by the expansion has pushed the
country into trade balance deficit.
340 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
FIGURE 18.8 TB
Fiscal Expansion with Crowding-Out
of Investment
An increase in spending shifts the IS curve
to the right by the amount of the simple +
E
Keynesian multiplier. However, the actual 0 Y
increase in income is somewhat less than F
–
this, at point F, because an increase in the
demand for money drives up the interest rate
and crowds out investment.
X–M
i TB = 0
LM
Deficit
F
E
∆G
s+m
IS ′
IS
0
Y
income. In fact, the distance that the fiscal expansion shifts the IS curve to the right can
be precisely stated. The simple Keynesian multiplier analysis of Section 17.1 showed
that, for a given interest rate, income increases by DY 5 s 11 mDG (Equation 17.9).
Previously, that formula was the complete answer to the question of how much income
increases because the interest rate was assumed to be constant. Now it only answers
the question of how much the curve shifts because the interest rate is no longer neces-
sarily constant. The increases in expenditure and income raise money demand, forcing
the interest rate up, which in turn discourages private investment. The new equilibrium
occurs at point F. Income is still higher than at point E, but some of the effect of the fis-
cal expansion has been offset by the crowding-out of investment. The overall effect on
income is somewhat less than the full open-economy multiplier effect.4
4
The NS 2 I schedule has not been explicitly drawn in the upper half of Figure 18.8. It initially runs through
point E. Then the fiscal expansion shifts it to the right, by DG / (s 1 m), and the increase in i immediately shifts
it part of the way back to the left. It ends up intersecting the X 2 M line at point F.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 341
Notice that the economy is again in trade deficit at point F because of higher
imports. In this model, monetary and fiscal expansions operate in the same way. Both
raise expenditure, thus raising income and worsening the trade balance. They differ
only in their implications for the composition of the given level of output, a monetary
expansion favoring private investment and a fiscal expansion favoring government
spending (or, in the case of a tax cut, favoring consumer spending).
1-page attachment on ZLB
The Liquidity Trap and Japan in the 1990s appears at bottom of page.
The Keynesian model omits such concerns as inflation and government borrowing.
Many a country has justified a fiscal expansion as a supposedly temporary measure
aimed at counteracting a recession, only to be stuck for years thereafter with an unsus-
tainable buildup in debt, entrenched inflation, and high interest rates. For such reasons,
the Keynesian model is generally regarded as a poor guide to fiscal policy-making in
practice, perhaps even as obsolete.
The example of Japan in the 1990s, however, illustrates that the Keynesian model
is still relevant. Bubbles in the Japanese stock and real estate markets in the late 1980s
collapsed after 1990, leading to a period of deflation, unemployment, and slow growth.
Despite a decade of recession, almost reminiscent of the Great Depression of the
1930s, goods prices in Japan did not decline enough to restore equilibrium.
Furthermore, the response of the Japanese economy to monetary and fiscal policy
suggested that it may have been caught in a rare case of a liquidity trap. In an effort to
stimulate the economy, the Bank of Japan lowered interest rates, virtually to zero. After
that, further reductions in interest rates were not possible. This is the definition of a liq-
uidity trap; further increases in the money supply are simply absorbed by the public
without bringing about a reduction in the interest rate. In terms of Figure 18.8, the
LM curve becomes completely flat, like the horizontal dotted line that runs through
point E.
The liquidity trap has two strong implications for policy. First, monetary policy
becomes ineffective. A monetary expansion still “shifts the LM curve to the right,” but
because the curve is flat in this range, there is no stimulus to the demand for goods.
Thus the Bank of Japan declared in the late 1990s that no further stimulus to output
was possible. Second, fiscal policy becomes more effective. Because the LM curve is
flat, there is no increase in the interest rate to crowd out private spending as at point F;
instead the full multiplier effect shows up.
In 1997 the government of Japan raised taxes, out of concerns that accumulating
fiscal deficits were saddling the next generation with rising levels of debt. Unfortu-
nately the immediate effect was to reduce consumption and send the economy into a
renewed recession. The multiplier effect was alive and well.
342 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
FIGURE 18.9 TB
Devaluation with Crowding-Out
A devaluation shifts the IS curve to the right D
by the amount of the simple Keynesian L
multiplier (at point L). However, the actual +
E
increase in income is somewhat less than 0 Y
this because investment is crowded out –
at D. The trade balance improves. X′ – M
X–M
i ( TB = 0) ( TB = 0) ′
LM
D Surplus
L
E
∆X
s+m
IS ′
IS
0
Y
positive amount, called DX. For any given level of investment, equilibrium occurs at a
higher level of income. Thus, for any given interest rate, the equilibrium point in the
lower panel of Figure 18.9 shifts to the right. From Section 17.1, it is even possible to
state by how much it shifts to the right: For a given interest rate, DY 5 s 11 mD X. The
actual overall effect on Y is less, as can be seen at the new IS-LM intersection, point D.5
Like the increase in demand from the government sector, the increase in demand from
the foreign sector raises output, but the effect is partly offset by the investment
crowded out by higher interest rates.
Despite the move to the right, point D brings a trade surplus, not a trade deficit. As
shown in the upper panel in Figure 18.9, the critical level of income that implies a zero
trade balance has shifted to the right. Furthermore, the TB 5 0 line has shifted to the
right by more than the IS curve. How do we know this? Imagine for a moment a per-
5
In terms of the upper panel, the NS 2 I schedule has shifted to the left (again because of the increase in i), so
that it intersects X9 2 M at D.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 343
fectly flat LM curve (the liquidity trap), such that the devaluation causes a move to
point L. Section 17.1 showed that the trade balance would improve, by
DTB 5 DX 2 mDY
1
5 DX 2 m DX
s1m
s
5 DX . 0
s1m
The marginal propensity to import times the increase in income is only a partial offset to
the improvement in the trade balance. When the LM curve has some slope, the change
in the trade balance is still DTB 5 DX 2 mDY, but now crowding-out means that DY is
smaller than the simple multiplier formula indicates. The marginal propensity to
import has even less of an offsetting effect on the trade balance. If there is a surplus at
L, there is an even greater surplus at D. This proves that the vertical TB 5 0 line shifts
right by more than income increases, leaving D to the left of the new line.6 Intuitively,
income would not have increased in the first place if devaluation did not, on net, stimu-
late the trade balance.
This section has shown how the effectiveness of fiscal expansion or devaluation in
stimulating demand is reduced by crowding-out, and how monetary expansion is an
alternative policy for stimulating expenditure. Most of this closely resembles material
covered in an intermediate, closed-economy macroeconomics course. Opening the
economy up to foreign trade has merely appended the trade balance as a function of
income.
18.4 Summary
This chapter used the Keynesian model developed in Chapter 17 to study two types of
exogenous policy changes: expenditure-switching policies such as devaluation, and
expenditure-reducing (or expenditure-increasing) policies such as government spend-
ing. It also examined the effects of changes in such policy instruments on the two policy
targets: internal balance (GDP at the full-employment level, for example) and external
balance (the trade balance at zero, for example). A general principle was demon-
strated: If a country is to attain both policy targets, the government must use two inde-
pendent policy instruments, such as fiscal policy and the exchange rate.
A second lesson concerned the regime of floating exchange rates, in which the
value of the currency adjusts automatically to equilibrate the balance of payments.
Under a regime of fixed rates, disturbances are transmitted from one country to
another. However, a regime of floating rates helps insulate countries from each other’s
disturbances because the exchange rate ensures that the balance of payments is zero.7
6
The TB 5 0 schedule shifts to the right by DX / m. (In other words, only if mDY 5 D X is TB unchanged.)
However, as can be seen in the figure, the IS curve shifts to the right by a smaller amount: D X / (s 1 m).
7
This chapter continues to assume the absence of international financial flows, so the overall balance of pay-
ments is the same as the trade balance. Part V will introduce capital flows; one consequence will be that float-
ing exchange rates do not provide complete insulation.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 344
344 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
A third lesson was that crowding-out effects via the domestic interest rate, which
must be taken into account if the central bank keeps the money supply constant,
decrease the effect of a fiscal expansion on domestic income.
The chapter concluded by introducing monetary policy into the model for the first
time, thus leading to the subject of Chapter 19.
Chapter 19 will return to the IS-LM graphs to analyze the effects of reserve flows,
and Chapter 22 will explore the effects of international capital mobility. Chapter 22 will
also present greater synergy between the financial markets and the foreign sector. The
existence of a balance-of-payments surplus or deficit will ultimately have much wider
implications for the entire economic system in those chapters.
CHAPTER PROBLEMS
1. Output is given by
Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1 TB
where consumption (C), disposable income (Yd), investment (I), government expendi-
ture (G), and the trade balance (TB) are given as follows:
C 5 C 1 (1 2 s)Yd
Yd 5 Y 2 tY
I5I
G5G
TB 5 X 2 (M 1 mYd)
This model differs from Section 17.1 by the introduction of t, the marginal tax rate.
a. i. Solve for the equilibrium level of income Y0 as a function of exogenous
variables.
ii. What is the open-economy fiscal multiplier, DY0 / DG? Is it larger or
smaller than the multiplier in a closed economy, 1 / s? What is the intuitive
explanation?
iii. Is the multiplier larger or smaller than the open-economy multiplier in
Section 17.1? What is the intuitive explanation?
iv. What is the effect on the trade balance, DTB / DG?
b. Assume that export demand increases exogenously by DX—for example,
because of a devaluation that raises exports by DX 5 eDE (think of e as the
export elasticity times X / E)—and has no direct effect on imports in domestic
currency (import elasticity is 1).
i. What is the effect on income, DY / DX?
ii. What is the effect on the trade balance, DTB / DX? How does this answer
compare with the elasticities approach and why?
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 345
iii. Assume (just for this question) that floating exchange rates are in effect so
that E always increases by the amount necessary to guarantee TB 5 0. What
is the floating-rate fiscal multiplier, DY0 / DG? How does it compare with the
fixed-rate and closed-economy multipliers in Problem a(ii)? What is the effect
of a fiscal expansion on the exchange rate, DE / DG?
2. This question concerns the relative virtues of the regimes of fixed and floating exchange
rates in automatically stabilizing real growth in the economy. Assume that the goal is to
minimize Variance (DY) in the presence of domestic disturbances DA and foreign dis-
turbances DX (which are assumed to be independent of each other). The variance is a
measure of variability that has the following three properties in general.
Variance (au) 5 a2 Variance (u)
Variance (b 1 v) 5 Variance (v)
Variance (u 1 v) 5 Variance (u) 1 Variance (v)
where a and b are parameters, or exogenous variables, and u and v are independent
disturbances. Assume the simple Keynesian model of Section 17.1.
a. i. How does Variance (DY) depend on Variance (DA) and Variance (DX) under
fixed exchange rates?
ii. Under floating exchange rates?
b. i. Which regime would be preferable if the variance of foreign disturbances is
much larger than the variance of domestic disturbances?
ii. Which would be preferable if the two kinds of disturbances are similar in
magnitude, and the country is very open (m is large)? Which is a better candi-
date for a fixed exchange rate, Australia or Luxembourg?
3. Compute the ratio of the slope of the internal balance line, YY, to the slope of the
external balance line, BB:
(Hint: The numerator refers to the change in E that is required to offset a given change
in G, in such a way as to leave Y at the original level of Y; it is given by
^
DY DY
2
DG DE
The logic applies analogously to the denominator.) How is this ratio relevant to the
assignment problem of Appendix B?
4. Choose a country. Read recent articles about its macroeconomy in the Financial Times
or the Economist. Where on the Swan diagram (Figure 18.5) do you think this country
falls?
Extra Credit
5. In this question the interest rate is allowed to vary. (Think of it as having been held con-
stant by monetary policy in the preceding problems.) In the preceding model, replace
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 346
346 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
APPENDIX A
Appendix A 347
348 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
FIGURE 18.A.1 TB
Increase in the NS – I
Exchange Rate with
the Laursen-Metzler-
Harberger Effect
As usual, the devaluation
shifts the X 2 M line up. NS ′ – I
If the saving rate depends
not just on income
measured in domestic
terms, Y, but also on the +
terms of trade, then the 0 Y
NS 2 I line shifts down as – A
households seek to protect L
their standard of living.
X′ – M
X–M
8
The condition for a devaluation to improve the trade balance was originally derived by Arnold Harberger,
“Currency Depreciation, Income and the Balance of Trade,” Journal of Political Economy (February 1950):
1147–1160.
9
The transmission of disturbances that occurs despite floating exchange rates was the motivation behind the
original paper, Svend Laursen and Lloyd Metzler, “Flexible Exchange Rates and the Theory of Employment,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, 32 (November 1950): 281–299.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 349
Appendix A 349
FIGURE 18.A.2 TB
External Disturbance NS – I
Under a Floating
Exchange Rate NS ′ – I
In the presence of the
Laursen-Metzler-Harberger
effect, a fall in foreign
demand can actually raise
domestic output. The
reason is that the domestic
currency depreciates, +
which causes saving to 0 Y
shift down. – A C
X′ – M
X–M
true that a floating exchange rate completely insulates domestic output and employ-
ment from foreign disturbances. As before, a fall in exports due, for example, to a for-
eign contraction, leads to a depreciation to prevent the trade deficit that would
otherwise emerge at point B in Figure 18.A.2. In the standard Keynesian model, the
depreciation would increase exports and reduce imports, causing a return (instanta-
neously) to point A. With the Laursen-Metzler-Harberger effect, however, the wors-
ened terms of trade cause saving to fall. Thus the NS 2 I line shifts down, and a further
depreciation is necessary if the trade balance is to avoid going into deficit. Equilibrium
occurs when the depreciation is sufficient to restore the trade balance to zero despite
the fall in saving, point C in Figure 18.A.2. This point occurs at a higher level of income
than A, even though the chain of events began with a contraction of foreign income.
The disturbance is transmitted in reverse.
350 Chapter 18 ■ Spending and the Exchange Rate in the Keynesian Model
to consume out of a temporary change in income. The latter will be close to zero in the
limit of a very short-lived change in real income, which has no effect on a rational indi-
vidual’s expectation of lifetime wealth or permanent income, and thus no effect on con-
sumption plans.10
It is reasonable to think of standard Keynesian propensities to consume and save
as applying in the intermediate case, in which a change in real income is observed but is
not known to be necessarily either temporary or permanent. Thus the Laursen-
Metzler-Harberger effect applies in this general, intermediate case. It should be modi-
fied, however, if there is additional information on the permanence of the change.11
One illustration was the sharp increase in the price of oil in 1973. For an oil-
importing country, this was an adverse shift in the terms of trade analogous to a deval-
uation. One might have expected all oil-importing countries to incur large trade
deficits because of the increase in their oil import bills. Yet the industrialized country
that ran the largest deficit was Norway, which had North Sea oil reserves it could
develop in the future. The Norwegians knew that their real income loss was temporary
and that they would be wealthier in the long run. Accordingly, they reduced saving rel-
ative to investment, borrowing from the rest of the world to finance the development
of their oil reserves. Norway’s current-account balance declined by 7 percent of GDP
from the period 1965 to 1973 to the period 1974 to 1979. Other oil importers who had
little prospect that their loss in real income would be temporary had no choice but to
adjust. The United States and Germany each had no change in their current-account
positions between the two periods. They increased exports of other goods to pay for
the higher oil import bill.
APPENDIX B
10
These ideas regarding the consumption function began with Milton Friedman’s permanent income hypothe-
sis and Franco Modigliani’s life-cycle hypothesis. The appendix to Chapter 21 shows that a country of optimiz-
ing consumers will borrow from abroad if it can expect income to be higher in the future than today.
11
The theory is updated to include explicit intertemporal utility maximization by consumers in Maurice
Obstfeld, “Aggregate Spending and the Terms of Trade: Is There a Laursen-Metzler Effect?” Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 96 (May 1982); and Lars Svensson and Assaf Razin, “The Terms of Trade and the Current
Account: The Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect,” Journal of Political Economy, 97, no. 1 (February 1983):
97–125. The first paper makes strong enough assumptions to rule out the Laursen-Metzler-Harberger effect.
CAVE.6607.cp18.p327-352 6/6/06 12:09 PM Page 351
Appendix B 351
Consider the consequences of assigning external balance to the central bank and
internal balance to the treasury. Call this assignment Rule 1. Whenever the trade bal-
ance is in deficit, the bank raises E; whenever it is in surplus, the bank lowers E.
Whenever output falls short of full employment, the treasury raises G; whenever it
exceeds full employment, the treasury lowers G. The analysis will be pursued here in
discrete time. Assume that the two agencies take turns. For example, the budget is
drawn up and enacted only at yearly intervals, and the exchange rate is changed only in
periodic devaluations or revaluations.
Start from point P1 in Figure 18.5. Let the central bank go first. Because of the
trade deficit, Rule 1 tells the bank to devalue until balanced trade is reached at B1.
Now the stimulus to net exports has moved the economy into the region of excess
demand. When it is time to set the annual budget, Rule 1 tells the treasury to contract
until internal balance is attained at N1. However, the reduction in expenditure has cre-
ated a trade balance surplus. The rule tells the central bank to revalue until balanced
trade is restored at B2. Now, however, unemployment means that the treasury will
expand until reaching full employment again at N2. Once again, a trade deficit tells the
central bank to devalue, and the counterclockwise cycle repeats.
As the graph is drawn, the line spirals in on the equilibrium point, A, where the
goal of simultaneous balance in both sectors is achieved. The reason for spiraling in
rather than spiraling out is that the YY schedule is steeper (in absolute value) than
the BB schedule. This claim can be demonstrated by making the slopes more extreme.
Try this yourself: Draw the external balance schedule to be much steeper than the
internal balance schedule. When Rule 1 tells the treasury to contract because of excess
demand at point B1, the trade surplus that opens up is larger than the initial imbalance.
When the central bank revalues, the country moves farther away from internal balance
than it was previously. This system is unstable, moving farther and farther from full
equilibrium.
Now try Rule 2. External balance is assigned to the treasury. Whenever the trade
balance is in deficit, the treasury cuts G; whenever it is in surplus, the treasury raises G.
Internal balance is assigned to the central bank. Whenever output falls short of full
employment, the central bank raises E; whenever it exceeds full employment, the bank
lowers E. Starting from a point such as P1, a reduction in G leads to unemployment, an
increase in E, and so forth. The path now progresses around the graph clockwise, not
counterclockwise as under Rule 1. If the YY schedule is the steeper one, as in Figure
18.5, there is a spiral out. Rule 2 does not work. Yet if the BB schedule is steeper, there
is a spiral in to equilibrium. Rule 2 works.
Thus the selection of the assignment rule should be based on the relative slopes of
the schedules. Which case is more likely, a YY schedule that is steeper than the BB
schedule, or one that is flatter? Problem 3 at the end of the chapter involves computing
the relative slopes of the two lines. It turns out that the YY line is steeper only if the
economy is not very open to imports. In that case Rule 1 should be used: Fiscal policy
should be used for internal balance. Otherwise—that is, for an economy that is highly
open—fiscal policy should be assigned to external balance. Intuitively, if the marginal
propensity to import is high, then expenditure-reducing policies are an effective way of
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 353
CHAPTER 19
I
n Chapter 16, we considered the impact of changes in the exchange rate alone on the
balance of payments. In effect, income was held constant. In Chapter 17 we allowed
income to vary. Similarly, the interest rate was held constant in Chapter 17; then it
too was allowed to vary in Chapter 18. Chapter 19 will continue this pattern of letting
additional macroeconomic variables vary by introducing the price level, which was
assumed constant in the preceding chapters.
The determination of the price level, a monetary variable, had been relatively
neglected until its central importance was pointed out by economists of the monetarist
school of thought. This chapter considers not only changes in the price level but also
changes in a second monetary variable: the central bank’s holdings of international
reserves. These two variables are fundamental to the monetary approach to the bal-
ance of payments. The monetary approach was originally developed in the 1960s, in
large part at the University of Chicago but also at the International Monetary Fund. Its
central point was that the balance of payments is a monetary phenomenon. The mone-
tary approach to the balance of payments was and is often used by the IMF staff when
they must figure out why a country is running a balance-of-payments deficit and what
should be done about it.
353
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 354
354 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
MB ; Res 1 NDA
where MB is the monetary base, Res is reserves, and NDA is net domestic assets, also
known as domestic credit. This definition of the monetary base is identical to the first
because the assets on the bank’s balance sheet must—by the rules of accounting—
add up to the same sum as the liabilities. (As noted earlier, the equality sign is drawn
with three lines for accounting identities.) As detailed in Chapter 15’s discussion of the
balance-of-payments accounts, a country’s overall balance of payments is the same
thing as the current period’s change in the central bank’s international reserves.2
BP ; DRes
If reserves fall in a given year (because the balance-of-payments deficit, DRes, is nega-
tive), and net domestic assets, NDA, are unchanged, then the monetary base, MB, falls
by the same amount.
1
The effect on the level of reserves is the same whether the balance-of-payments deficit arises in the trade bal-
ance or in the private-capital account. That is why we talk of the monetary approach to the balance of pay-
ments, rather than the monetary approach to the balance of trade. Nevertheless, this chapter will continue to
omit capital flows and so will restrict the discussion to the determination of the trade balance. Chapter 22 will
show how the monetary approach to the balance of payments changes in the presence of international capital
movements.
2
Assume here that the country’s currency is not held by other countries’ central banks, so their actions are not
relevant.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 355
The central bank sterilizes the reserve outflow if it prevents it from reducing the
domestic money supply. The most standard way of doing this is to create money by
expanding domestic credit at the same rate as the reserve outflow is contracting the
money supply, so there is no net effect. If DNDA 5 2DRes, then DMB 5 0. In the
United States, when the Federal Reserve wishes to expand domestic credit, it does so
through open market operations in which it buys U.S. Treasury securities on the private
market. In this way, any changes in the Federal Reserve’s holdings of reserves are ster-
ilized immediately.
When a country runs a balance-of-payments surplus, its central bank is necessarily
selling its own currency in the foreign exchange market, thus adding to its stock of
international reserves. Again, the central bank sterilizes the reserve inflow if it pre-
vents the increase in reserves from increasing the domestic money supply. The most
obvious way of doing this is to extinguish money by contracting domestic credit so that
no net effect on the total monetary base results. In the United States, the Federal
Reserve sells U.S. Treasury securities on the private market.
Most countries do not have as highly developed bond markets as does the United
States, and open market operations are less feasible. For these countries, expanding
domestic credit may be accomplished by buying securities directly from the treasury,
and so monetizing the budget deficit, or else by extending credit to domestic commer-
cial banks or other enterprises, especially any that may be owned by the government.
In some developing countries, the central bank lends money directly to such enter-
prises as public utilities, industrial development banks, and agricultural cooperatives.
Contracting domestic credit means cutting back on loans to the government, state-
owned enterprises, or the banking system. However, it is usually difficult to control the
budget deficit of the government or state-owned enterprises on short notice. In devel-
oping countries and other countries where the central bank is obligated to finance
these deficits, domestic credit is not a viable tool for sterilization, that is, for offsetting
reserve flows on a short-run basis. An alternative possibility is to allow the high-
powered money supply or monetary base—the liabilities of the central bank—to
change, but to offset the effect on monetary aggregates such as M1. M1 represents the
liabilities of the entire consolidated banking system, including not only claims on the
central bank (such as currency) but also claims on commercial banks (such as checking
accounts). Even on a relatively short-term basis, the central bank can regulate the
amount of credit banks extend to the public—for example, by varying the reserve
requirements to which banks are subject.
In many countries where the central bank has little short-run control over domes-
tic credit, reserve flows simply are not sterilized. In the nineteenth century this was
mostly true of countries that participated in the gold standard. If money is directly
backed with gold, then balance-of-payments deficits are necessarily financed by gold
sales that reduce the domestic money supply: They cannot be sterilized via offsetting
changes in the liabilities of either the central bank or the private banking system.3 A
handful of economies—Hong Kong, Estonia, Lithuania, and Bulgaria—have adopted a
3
Appendix A to this chapter explains the gold standard at somewhat greater length.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 356
356 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
4
For a balanced description, see John Williamson, “What Role for Currency Boards?” Policy Analyses in
International Economics, 40 (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1995).
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 357
Can one imagine, that it had ever been possible, by any laws, or even by any art or
industry, to have kept all the money in Spain, which the galleons have brought from
the Indies? Or that all commodities could be sold in France for a tenth of the price
which they would yield on the other side of the Pyrenees, without finding their way
thither, and draining from that immense treasure? What other reason indeed is there
why all nations, at present, gain in their trade with Spain and Portugal; but because it
is impossible to heap up money, more than any fluid, beyond its proper level?
—David Hume: On the Balance of Trade
358 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
FIGURE 19.1 TB
NS – I
Effects of a Monetary Expansion
over Time
In the short run, an increase in the money NS – I ′
supply raises output and worsens the trade +
E
balance. If the loss of reserves is not sterilized, 0 Y
however, then the money supply falls over – M
time and output returns to its original level
at E.
TB
i TB = 0
LM
LM ′
Deficit
M
IS
0 Y1 Y
Conversely, a monetary contraction reduces income and improves the trade balance in
the short run but has no effect in the long run. Only continuing growth in the money
supply (in excess of growth in money demand) could cause a continuing deficit.
Indeed the application to price and wage rigidity constitutes Mundell’s income mecha-
nism, developed in the preceding section.
The alternative view, entailed by PPP, is that prices are perfectly flexible and so
markets clear. This assumption is shared by the monetarists and their successors—
those who believe in real business cycles and proponents of other branches of new clas-
sical macroeconomics. These believers in price flexibility adopt the nonsterilization
assumption, but they have a slight quarrel with Hume’s price specie-flow mechanism.
Hume said that a monetary expansion will raise prices and worsen the trade balance,
which will lead to an outflow that in the long run returns the prices to their original
level. The alternative view asks how prices can be higher in one country than another
even in the short run. Why would consumers buy any goods at all from the country with
the higher prices? Would it not suffer an instantaneous trade deficit of unlimited size?
PPP: Definitions
Purchasing power parity, or PPP, is simply the name for the following equation:
P 5 EP*
where E is the exchange rate, and P and P* are the domestic and foreign price levels,
respectively. It could also be written,
E 5 P / P*
We are not ready to draw any conclusions about causality, about whether changes in E
cause changes in P or the other way around. PPP is just a condition, not in itself a com-
plete theory of determination of the price level or the exchange rate.
The equation has a long history. Many economists consider it discredited. Certainly
it is inconsistent with the Keynesian model, in which price levels are not free to adjust
whenever the exchange rate changes. However, some consider it a necessary and logi-
cal consequence of economic rationality. The right answer depends on how one defines
P and P*.6
5
Jacob Frenkel and Harry Johnson, “The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments: Essential Concepts
and Historical Origins,” in Jacob Frenkel and Harry Johnson, eds., The Monetary Approach to the Balance of
Payments (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1976), p. 25.
6
For a survey of PPP, see Kenneth Rogoff, “The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle,” Journal of Economic
Literature, 34, no. 2 (1996): 647–648.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 360
360 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
of Assumption 3 in Section 16.1), we took as given that the price of BMWs in the
United States was simply the euro price times the dollar/euro exchange rate. In other
words, we assumed that arbitrage enforced the law of one price for BMWs, and we will
continue to do so, notwithstanding the anomaly just noted.
This is not as strong as the assumption that the price of American-made auto-
mobiles is equal to the euro price of German automobiles times the exchange rate.
Buicks and BMWs are, after all, different products. Arbitrage between the two does not
operate, given the reasonable assumption that consumers view American and German
automobiles as different products. This fact allows U.S. manufacturers to set their prices
in dollars with some degree of rigidity (at least in the short run), and at the same time
allows German manufacturers to set theirs in euros.
1. Tariffs and transportation costs create a band in which prices can fluctuate
before arbitrage becomes profitable. Only if the price in one country exceeds the price
in the other by more than the size of any tariffs, other trade barriers, and shipping costs,
will arbitrage start to operate. We might rescue the law of one price by claiming that a
7
It is difficult to get the data necessary for computing absolute PPP; we cannot use standard statistics on price
indices that governments publish as we can when computing relative PPP. It means sending a team of
researchers to different countries to sample the prices of a standardized set of goods. Absolute price indices
are reported in the Penn World Tables. See Irving Kravis and Robert Lipsey, “Toward an Explanation of
National Price Levels,” Studies in International Finance, 52 (1983).
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 362
362 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
bushel of wheat delivered in New York City at noon on a particular day is a different
good than a bushel of wheat delivered in London, or delivered on a different day.
(Contracts for spot or forward delivery of agricultural and mineral commodities do, in
fact, specify time and place, and the price can vary accordingly, especially if there are
substantial tariffs or transportation costs.) In any case, PPP is defined to apply to price
indices that aggregate together, not only wheat, but all goods, so these geographical
factors clearly allow deviations from PPP. Figure 19.2(a) represents these deviations as
fluctuations of the real exchange rate within a band. The width of the band should be
twice the magnitude of tariffs and transportation costs.
2. Permanent shifts in the terms of trade between traded goods take place, such as
the upward shift that occurred between oil and manufactured goods in 1973 and 1979,
the reverse shift that occurred in 1986 and 1998, or the return of high oil prices after
2004. Oil and manufactured goods can have very different weights in the price indices
of the two countries, particularly if we consider producer price indices rather than
CPIs. An oil-producing country, for example, will experience a real appreciation of its
currency when the relative price of oil goes up, whether in the form of a nominal
appreciation of the currency or in the form of an increase in the producer price index,
P. If the oil price goes up by 50 percent and oil has a weight that is 20 percentage points
higher in an oil-exporting country than in another country, then the effect on the real
exchange rate will be 10 percent. To take another example, automobiles could have the
same weight in two countries’ price indices, but if Japan produces smaller, more fuel-
efficient cars, then it is likely to experience a real appreciation in the event of an oil
price increase that causes demand to shift toward its products.
In the case of tariffs and transportation costs, when the real exchange rate nears
the top of the band it cannot go much farther. However, in the case of permanent shifts
in the terms of trade, no natural limit exists on how far the real exchange rate can drift
in one direction or the other. In the absence of any particular theory predicting changes
in the terms of trade, the real exchange rate can move up from its current position as
easily as down. Accordingly, in Figure 19.2(b), the shifts in the terms of trade are shown
as “permanent”: When a change in the real exchange rate is observed, there is no way
to know whether it will in the future continue to move further in the same direction or
will reverse itself. When changes in a variable such as the real exchange rate are not
predictable, we say that the variable follows a “random walk,” like a drunken reveler
walking down an empty street. This description is just a statement of our ignorance
of what the real exchange rate will do, however; it does not take the place of an eco-
nomic theory.
3. Even if the traded goods baskets are identical in both countries, if the indices
include prices of nontraded goods and services, which cannot be arbitraged internation-
ally, PPP may fail. If the prices of nontraded goods in each country happen to move
proportionately to the prices of traded goods, then PPP will still hold. If there are shifts
in the relative prices of traded goods and nontraded goods, PPP will fail. (Models with
nontraded goods are discussed at greater length in Chapter 20.)
Consider the real exchange rate defined in terms of consumer price indices.
Ereal 5 E(CPI* / CPI) (19.1)
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 363
FIGURE 19.2
Patterns of Deviation from Purchasing Power Parity
(a) Tariffs and transportation costs create a band within which the real exchange rate can fluctuate. (b) Permanent
shifts in the terms of trade move the real exchange rate unpredictably. (c) A long-term trend in the relative price of
nontraded goods (e.g., upward in a rapidly growing country) will cause a trend in the real exchange rate. (d) The
real exchange rate works its way back to equilibrium after a devaluation as goods prices adjust, but the process
can be slow.
EP*/P EP*/P
0 Time 0 Time
(c) Trend in Relative Price (d) Slow Adjustment of Goods Prices
of Nontraded Goods
P rising
P falling
Revaluation
0 Time 0 Time
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 364
364 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
In each country, a weighted average of nontraded goods and traded goods constitutes
the CPI. The real exchange rate will change if the relative price of non-traded goods
(i.e., the price of nontraded goods in terms of traded goods) changes in either the for-
eign country or the domestic country.8 For example, the Japanese yen had come to
appear highly overvalued in real terms by 1995. The long-term trend in the yen over
the preceding half century had shown a strong real appreciation, in part because of an
increase within the Japanese price index of the prices of housing and other nontraded
goods and services (including golf-club memberships, a nontraded good particularly
important in Japan!).
Bela Balassa and others have identified a pattern based on differential economic
growth (the famous “Balassa-Samuelson effect”).9 Growth of a country’s income is
associated with increased productivity in traded goods, which then fall in price relative
to nontraded goods. In other words, the relative price of nontraded goods in terms of
traded goods rises. Growth also may cause a rise in the relative price of nontraded
goods and services if they are superior goods in consumers’ demand functions.10 Either
way, because the prices of traded goods are tied to world prices, a rise in the relative
price of nontraded goods can only mean an increase in the price of nontraded goods
relative to world prices. Therefore, the CPI, which includes nontraded goods, rises rela-
tive to world prices. The domestic currency will appear to appreciate by PPP calcula-
tions. The real exchange rate, E(CPI* / CPI), will appear to fall (i.e., either E will fall or
CPI will rise). That is why countries with strong growth rates tend also to have upward
trends in their relative prices and therefore in the real foreign exchange value of their
currencies, as is shown in Figure 19.2(c). In other words, such countries often show
downward trends in their real exchange rates.11
4. In Chapter 16, lags caused by imperfect information, contracts, inertia in con-
sumer habits, and so forth, rendered elasticities lower in the short run than in the long
run. This implies that two goods that are highly substitutable in the long run may be
very imperfect substitutes in the short run. This low degree of substitutability allows
prices to be “sticky” and allows large deviations from PPP in the short run without
inducing large-scale international arbitrage. For example, following a devaluation or
revaluation, firms do not readjust their prices fully but absorb the (finite) increase or
decrease in demand by varying the quantity sold. If the goods are close substitutes in
the long run, then prices will adjust to PPP eventually; if they did not adjust, demand
8
Refer to Problem 2c at the end of the chapter.
9
Bela Balassa, “The Purchasing Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal,” Journal of Political Economy, 72
(1964): 584–596; Paul Samuelson, “Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems,” Review of Economics and Statistics
(May 1964): 145–154. This is the sort of “real trade theory” explanation for changes in the real exchange rate
that we would like to have, as opposed to the agnostic position that is content with describing the real
exchange rate as following a random walk.
10
“Superior” goods are goods that experience a relative increase in demand when real income increases. Jeffrey
Bergstrand, “Structural Determinants of Real Exchange Rates and National Price Levels: Some Empirical
Evidence,” American Economic Review, 81, no. 1 (March 1991): 325–334.
11
Evidence in time-series data is found to support the Balassa hypothesis in Jose De Gregorio, Alberto
Giovannini, and Holger Wolf, “International Evidence on Tradables and Nontradables Inflation,” European
Economic Review, 38, no. 6 (June 1994): 1225–1244. Such studies look at relative PPP. Cross-country evidence
on absolute PPP is summarized by Irving Kravis and Robert Lipsey, “National Price Levels and the Prices of
Tradables and Nontradables,” American Economic Review, 78, no. 2 (May 1988): 474–478; it too shows that the
price of non-traded goods relative to traded goods increases with the level of the country’s per capita income.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 365
levels might rise or fall without limit. Figure 19.2(d) illustrates the process. If a sudden
increase in the nominal exchange rate occurs, with prices fixed in the short run it trans-
lates fully into an increase in the real exchange rate. This real depreciation stimulates
the demand for domestic goods, putting upward pressure on prices. As prices gradually
rise, the real exchange rate comes back down toward its long-run equilibrium. How-
ever, it is always possible that before equilibrium is reached, another sudden exchange
rate change will occur.
The precise nature of the microeconomics of sticky prices is not well understood,
but the empirical evidence is clear, as we will see in the following section. Of these four
ways in which PPP can fail, all contain some truth, but the last is the one with the most
macroeconomic content. From now on, any reference to the possibility of short-run
failure of PPP will usually be a reference to the macroeconomic, sticky-price interpre-
tation. Although permanent changes in the real exchange rate because of productivity
differences and other real factors do occur, they tend to be slow long-term trends.
Short-run deviations from those trends are the sort of PPP failure that we will be exam-
ining at length.
12
If you are familiar with the statistical concept of the variance, the standard deviation is simply the square
root of it.
13
Monthly variability in major exchange rates tripled after 1973. We have concentrated here on the U.K. case
rather than the Japanese one, or others, because the time series of data extends unbroken much further back
in history.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 366
366 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
FIGURE 19.3
Two Hundred Years of Purchasing Power Parity Between the Dollar and the Pound
Changes in the real exchange rate are not purely random. Rather, it tends to regress slowly
toward its long-run equilibrium (until a new disturbance comes along). In the case of the United
States and United Kingdom, the long-run equilibrium appears to have been constant.
2.25
2.00
1.75
1.50
1.25
1.00
1790 1820 1850 1880 1910 1940 1970 2000
Sources: 1790–1990 James Lothian and Mark Taylor, “Real Exchange Rate Behavior: The Recent Float
from the Perspective of the Past Two Centuries,” Journal of Political Economy 104, 484–509 (1996);
and for 1990–2005: IFS (International Financial Statistics) and Federal Reserve.
Another explanation is that the greater variability in real exchange rates after 1973
was related to the greater magnitude of real worldwide disturbances, such as oil shocks,
and would have happened even under a regime of fixed exchange rates (in which case
the variability would have shown up in the price levels). This alternative view holds that
changes in the nominal exchange rate do not cause changes in the real exchange rate,
but that both occur in response to exogenous real disturbances such as productivity
changes.14 One problem with this view is that no one has identified these real shocks. It
would seem if there were a change in productivity or consumer tastes that applied to
hundreds of different industries in a country, such that all of them experience an
increase in price when the currency appreciates (relative to their counterparts in for-
eign countries), then we should be able to identify what that change is. A few cases, in
fact, do suggest explanations. The rapid fall in the value of the yen and the mark against
the dollar when the price of oil quadrupled at the end of 1973 surely resulted because
those two countries’ economies depended more on imported oil than the U.S. economy
14
Such theories have been constructed, for example, by Alan Stockman, “The Equilibrium Approach to
Exchange Rates,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond (March–April 1987): 12–31.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 367
FIGURE 19.4
Nominal and Real Exchange Rates Both Became More Volatile After 1973
0.10
Percentage Change
0.05
–0.05
–0.10
–0.15
1957 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005
0.10
Percentage Change
0.05
–0.05
–0.10
–0.15
1957 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 368
368 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
did. It is hard to see what changes in worker productivity or consumer tastes could
possibly explain the 50-plus percent real appreciation of the dollar between 1980 and
1985, however, and its reversal over the following three years, or the similar 1990–1995
real appreciation of the yen and its reversal over the subsequent three years.
One way to check if the comparison of the fixed-rate and floating-rate periods
might be contaminated by larger supply shocks after 1973 than before is to look at
Canada, the one country to have a floating exchange rate in the 1950s. The real
exchange rate in Canada was highly variable at the time, whereas those in fixed-rate
countries were much less so. Evidently the floating-rate regime made the difference.
Another piece of evidence is offered by the case of Ireland. From 1957 to 1970 the
Irish currency was pegged to the pound, and thereby to the dollar and mark as well,
until the currencies began to float against each other. From 1973 to 1978 the Irish cur-
rency was again pegged to the pound, which meant it floated against the dollar and
mark. Then from 1979 onward Ireland was in the European Exchange Rate Mecha-
nism, and the currency—the punt—was thereby tied to the mark, which meant it
floated against the dollar and pound. In each of the three periods, the choice of nominal
exchange rate regime for the punt corresponds very well with the observed degree of
real exchange rate variability vis-à-vis each of the three trading partners. Stickiness of
prices explains the pattern. Otherwise it would be quite a coincidence that real variabil-
ity vis-à-vis the mark, say, should fall and vis-à-vis the pound should rise at precisely the
same moment that the nominal variabilities, respectively, fall and rise as well.15
A third way of evaluating whether real exchange rate variability is related to the
exchange rate regime is to consider earlier historical experience. History demonstrates
that the variability of real exchange rates was larger under floating-rate regimes than
under fixed-rate regimes, not just during the period after World War II, but before the
war as well.16
These findings would be difficult to explain with perfectly flexible goods prices. It
seems more likely that prices are sticky and that nominal exchange rate variability is
indeed a primary source of real exchange rate variability. Estimates on the yearly
U.S.–U.K. data indicate that fluctuations in the nominal exchange rate are 84 percent
reflected as fluctuations in the real exchange rate (1973–2005).
There have been some studies of PPP, or the law of one price, for disaggregated
categories of goods matched across countries that are the smallest, most narrowly
defined, SITC (Standardized International Trade Classification) categories. These stud-
ies find large deviations even on these disaggregated data. This need not be interpreted
as a failure of economic rationality or the law of one price. One partial explanation is
that most foreign trade takes place under 30- to 90-day contracts, so prices cannot be
readjusted for 30 to 90 days after a disturbance. More fundamentally, manufactured
goods of different firms are actually different goods, as was noted earlier.17
15
Michael Mussa, Exchange Rates in Theory and in Reality, Essays in International Finance, 179 (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, December 1990).
16
Alan Taylor, “A Century of Purchasing Power Parity,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 84 (2002):
139–150.
17
Charles Engel, “Real Exchange Rates and Relative Prices: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 32 (1993): 35–50.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 369
Even goods that are marketed in the same location and differ in little more than
brand name—for example, a Japanese television set and the identical item manufac-
tured by the identical firm but under an American label—violate the law of one price.
Different manufacturers vary with respect to reputation or warranty offered, and dif-
ferent retailers vary with respect to their sales and maintenance service. Long-term
customer relationships are thought to be particularly important in Japan and give rise
to what are sometimes called implicit contracts: A Japanese corporation will hesitate
before raising prices when there is excess demand, in the anticipation that this will
build loyalty among customers, who will continue to buy from it in other periods of
excess supply.
This point recalls a distinction between homogeneous “auction goods”—for which
the law of one price holds instantaneously and worldwide, and heterogeneous “cus-
tomer goods”—for which the law of one price fails, at least in the short run. Auction
goods are usually basic commodities such as agricultural and mineral products, whereas
customer goods are usually heterogeneous manufactured goods that bear brand names.
The rapidly evolving semiconductor industry provides an example of each kind of
good. So-called commodity chips tend to be all the same regardless of the producer and
are sold in perfectly competitive markets resembling those for agricultural or mineral
commodities. Specialty chips are designed to fulfill more specific functions and tend to
fit better the description of customer goods.
If PPP holds in the long run but not in the short run, the obvious empirical ques-
tions become: How long is the short run? How quickly do deviations from PPP disap-
pear? The speed with which the real exchange rate adjusts back toward its long-run
equilibrium has been estimated at about 15 percent a year: The best guess in a given
year as to what will be the gap between the real exchange rate and its long-run equilib-
rium is 85 percent of what it was in the preceding year. After two years, 72 percent of
the gap will remain (.852 5 .72), and so forth. After four years, 52 percent of the gap
will remain (.854 5 .52). In other words, the half-life has been estimated at about four
years. This speed of adjustment is not implausibly slow, but it is sufficiently slow as to
be difficult to detect statistically in the data, given that large new disturbances come
along frequently. This is especially true if only a few years of data are available. We
must look at a long time period, such as the 200 years of data in Figure 19.3, for clear
manifestation of the tendency of the real exchange rate to return to equilibrium.18
18
Hyperinflation is one context in which PPP in a sense works well empirically (because the long run in effect
“telescopes” into a few years). This is explained in Section 19.3.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 370
370 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
in the wake of the breakup of the Soviet Union in the early 1990s. The source is usually
simple enough: a government that has control of a printing press but controls little else.
Often it is a weak government printing money to fight a war.
In January 1994 the inflation rate in what remained of Yugoslavia (essentially
Serbia) reached 313,563,558 percent per month, almost equaling the preceding record,
which had been set by Hungary in 1945–1946. As with any hyperinflation, residents
tried desperately to buy marks or dollars, anything to avoid holding the domestic cur-
rency. Reporting at the peak, a Belgrade newspaper described the situation: “Yesterday
[morning] the price of the [Deutsche] mark on the black market was 2.0 million dinars,
and around 3:00 P.M. it was 2.5 million dinars. Belgrade dealers were reluctant to sell
marks, as they expected the exchange rate to reach 5 million dinars (per DM) by the
evening.”19
As mentioned in footnote 18, hyperinflation is one context in which PPP in a sense
works well empirically. Table 19.1 reports cumulative increases in the price level and in
the exchange rate for some memorable hyperinflations of the twentieth century. They
TABLE 19.1
PPP in Great Hyperinflations of the Twentieth Century
P final E final
Country Period P initial E initial
Austria 10 / 1921–9 / 1922 93 29
Germany 7 / 1922–12 / 1923 179 3 108 141 3 108
Poland 1 / 1923–1 / 1924 699 491
Hungary 3 / 1923–2 / 1924a 44 12
Hungary 8 / 1945–7 / 1946 381 3 1025 304 3 1025
Nat. Chinab 9 / 1945–5 / 1949 105 3 109 119 3 109
Bolivia 4 / 1984–9 / 1985 974 2,129
Peru 9 / 1988–8 / 1990 7,242 11,600
Argentina 4 / 1989–3 / 1990 204 294
Brazil 11 / 1989–3 / 1990 12 8
Ukraine 4 / 1991–12 / 1993 4,772 799
Belarus 4 / 1991–2 / 1992 8 6
The Congo 10 / 1991–9 / 1994 237,499 284,519
Tajikistan 1 / 1992–12 / 1993 1,088 743
Serbia 2 / 1992–1 / 1994 366 3 1020 8.3 3 1020
Armenia 9 / 1993–5 / 1994 139 99
a
Cumulative rise in exchange rate in Hungary is from average of March 1923 to average of March 1924.
b
China’s exchange rate change is the change in the price of gold rather than a direct exchange rate.
Sources: P. Cagan, “The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation,” in Milton Friedman, Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1956); Bogetic, Dragutinovic, and Petrovic, “Anatomy of Hyperinflation,” Economic Review and Inter-
national Financial Statistics, IMF; T. Sargent, “The Ends of Four Big Inflations,” in Robert Hall, Inflation: Causes and Effects (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1982); D. Paarlberg, An Analysis and History of Inflation (New York: Praeger, 1993); T. Hu, “Hyperinflation
and the Dynamics of the Demand for Money in China, 1945–1949,” Journal of Political Economy (January/February 1971); International
Monetary Fund.
19
The report was dated January 16, 1994, soon before a successful stabilization. As reported by Z. Bogetic,
D. Dragutinovic, and P. Petrovic, “Anatomy of Hyperinflation and the Beginning of Stabilization in Yugoslavia,
1992–1994,” World Bank (September 1994).
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 371
FIGURE 19.5
PPP in Great Hyperinflations of the Twentieth Century
E final/E initial
1030
Hungary '45–46
1024
Serbia '92–94
1018
Nicaragua '86–89
1,000,000
Zaire '91–94
Peru '88–90
Georgia '92–94
Armenia '93–94 Ukraine '91–93
Brazil '89–90 Poland '23–24
Austria '21–22
1
1 1,000,000 1012 1018 1024 1030
Belarus '91–92 Hungary '23–24 P final/P initial
are expressed as multiples—that is, the level at the end of the period divided by the level
at the beginning. In most of the hyperinflations reported, the increase in the exchange
rate was roughly of the same order of magnitude as the increase in the price level. Fig-
ure 19.5 graphs the cumulative change in the price level and exchange rate for each of
these hyperinflations. The points lie impressively close to the 45° line, supporting PPP.20
Yet there is another sense in which PPP works poorly during a hyperinflation. We
can see from Table 19.1 that the cumulative rise in the exchange rate never matches the
20
Similarly, Jacob Frenkel found that an OLS regression testing the time series relationship between the
exchange rate E and the relative price level P/P* in the German hyperinflation of 1920 to 1923 produced a
coefficient close to one. “Purchasing Power Parity: Doctrinal Perspective and Evidence from the 1920’s,”
Journal of International Economics, 8, no. 2 (May 1978): 169–191.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 372
372 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
rise in the price level exactly. It is not uncommon for one variable to go up twice as
much as the other—a movement in the real exchange rate of 100 percent—or by more.
The explanation for these seemingly conflicting findings is that PPP holds fairly
well in the long run, but large short-run errors can push the exchange rate and the price
level away from PPP. In a hyperinflation, the long run arrives quickly. In terms of
Figure 19.5, the deviations from the 45° line are dwarfed by the magnitudes of the
hyperinflations.21 In short, as an explanation of the level of the nominal exchange rate,
PPP works well in hyperinflations. As a theory of the real exchange rate, it does not. We
examine these hyperinflations further in Chapter 27.
21
This is a standard “errors in variables” problem in econometrics. N. Davutyan and J. Pippenger, “Purchasing
Power Parity Did Not Collapse During the 1970s,” American Economic Review, 75, no. 5 (December 1985):
1151–1158.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 373
currency without fearing an instantaneous large loss of demand when there are adverse
changes in the exchange rate or in the prices charged by foreign competitors. This was
the sort of country we considered in Chapters 16 through 18. But we now consider a
different kind of country.
Many countries are so small in world markets that they have little monopoly
power in their export goods and must take prices of export goods as exogenous, or
fixed in terms of foreign currency. In the case of agricultural and mineral commodities
and other auction goods, the output of different countries often can be considered per-
fect substitutes. Sugar or tin, for example, is basically the same regardless of where it is
produced. In addition, if the country doesn’t happen to produce a large proportion of
the world output of the agricultural or mineral product, then it is safe to assume it
accepts the world price. In other words, if it tried to charge more than the going price, it
would quickly find itself without customers. In the case of manufactured goods, some
labor-intensive products such as textiles are sufficiently similar among a wide range of
countries that their prices too can be taken as essentially given on world markets. Then
the analysis returns to the definition of a small country used in the first half of the
book: a country that is too small in international markets to affect world prices.
As these examples show, developing countries are more likely to take export prices
as given than are larger industrialized countries. (Note, however, that the assumption
that the country can sell any quantity it wants on the world market at the going price
can go wrong for another reason: Major customers may apply country-by-country
quotas to purchases of the commodity. Industrialized countries maintain such quotas
against sugar, for example.)
If a country is so small that it takes not only its import prices as given but its export
prices as well, then it is possible to aggregate the two kinds of goods together at their
(given) relative price. The composite commodity thereby created is referred to as
traded goods. Under the assumption that the small open country can buy or sell all of
the traded goods it wishes to, the trade balance becomes the quantity of traded goods it
chooses to produce minus the quantity it chooses to buy. With this analysis, the ques-
tion of how a given trade balance breaks down into imports and exports is left unan-
swered. The approach just tells us the overall trade balance, which is the variable we
are usually interested in.
In reality, the relative prices of some of the goods within this composite commod-
ity—the traded good—will sometimes change. When this happens, it will not be useful
to talk in terms of traded goods in the aggregate. Worldwide changes in the relative
price of oil, as occurred in 1973 and 1979 (upward), 1986 and 1998 (downward), and
2005 (again upward), are an important example. But such developments are usually
taken to be exogenous. For purposes of studying changes that do not affect the terms of
trade, such as changes that originate in macroeconomic policy, this aggregation will be
useful. The next chapter will also continue to aggregate all traded goods.
374 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
that a devaluation can no longer affect the balance of payments. But this is not correct.
Here we briefly consider the real balance effect resulting from a devaluation.
Consider a 10 percent devaluation. Not only do the prices of imports follow the
price of foreign exchange E up by the same 10 percent, but under the assumption of
PPP, all prices rapidly go up by the same amount. When the price level P rises 10 per-
cent, if the nominal money supply is unchanged, then the real money supply M / P falls
by 10 percent. This is called the real balance effect because M / P is sometimes called
real money balances.
Nothing has happened to change money demand, so we now have excess demand
for money. Individuals respond by cutting back purchases of internationally traded
goods, thereby improving the trade balance. Thus is the improvement accomplished
with no change in the terms of trade. (Individuals also cut back purchases of interna-
tionally traded assets, if capital flows are in the model. Recall from the opening of this
chapter that its subject is the Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, not just
the Balance of Trade.)
As with the Hume and Mundell flow mechanisms of Section 19.1, the balance of
payments surplus sets in motion developments that are self-correcting. The surplus
implies that reserves are flowing into the country. Under a system of nonsterilization,
the money supply gradually rises. This endogenous monetary expansion, in turn, gradu-
ally reverses the fall in purchases of goods (and assets). The balance of payments
declines, eventually returning to zero.
Appendix C to this chapter presents this model algebraically and graphically. It
illustrates the effects not just of a devaluation, but of three other experiments as well: a
monetary expansion, inflation in the rest of the world, and supply-led domestic growth.
(The model is useful for thinking about how the global system operated under the gold
standard and Bretton Woods systems, the subject of Appendix A.) The common
denominator throughout the experiments, and throughout the chapter, is that effects
on the balance of payments are temporary and self-equilibrating.
19.5 Summary
This chapter introduced two new concepts into our study of economies that operate
under fixed exchange rates. The first concept was the flow of international reserves into
or out of a country through the balance of payments. This reserve flow changes its
monetary base endogenously over time if the central bank either cannot or does not
choose to sterilize (offset or neutralize). Such changes in the monetary base then have
further implications over time for the economy. The second concept was purchasing
power parity (PPP). The first of the two concepts is the one that defines most the mon-
etary approach to the balance of payments.
We studied the effects of two policy experiments: a change in the money supply
and a devaluation. An increase in the money supply creates an excess supply of money,
which leads to a higher level of private expenditure and a balance-of-payments deficit
in the short run, the same as at the end of the preceding chapter. The difference is that
under the nonsterilization assumption, the balance-of-payments deficit implies that the
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 375
level of the money stock falls over time, which in turn gradually undoes the increase in
expenditure and the balance-of-payments deficit. A devaluation leads to a balance-of-
payments surplus in the short run, again as in previous chapters. The level of the money
stock rises over time, which in turn gradually undoes the balance-of-payments surplus.
Whatever the policy experiment, in the long run the balance of payments must be zero
under the monetary approach, so that the stock of reserves is no longer changing.
These results apply regardless of what is assumed about the second concept associ-
ated with the monetary approach to the balance of payments: purchasing power parity
(PPP). PPP states that the domestic price level is given by the exchange rate times the
foreign price level. There are a number of reasons why this relationship can fail in the-
ory, why the real exchange rate is not constant. The most important, at least in the short
run, is that prices are “sticky,” meaning that prices require time to adjust after a change
in the nominal exchange rate. Thus the fixed-price assumption (which we made in
Chapters 16 through 18 and will return to in Chapter 22) is realistic for the short run.
Nevertheless, in the last part of the present chapter we explored the implications of the
assumption of price flexibility and PPP. One motivation is to think about the long run.
Another motivation is to think about very small, open economies.
In the small open economy model a devaluation translates directly into a propor-
tionate increase in the domestic price level, so no change occurs in the real exchange
rate. Nonetheless, there is an effect on the balance of payments, through what is called
the real-balance effect. The increase in the price level reduces the real money balances
held by the public. In response to the resulting excess demand for money, people cut
back on expenditure, which in turn leads to the improvement in the balance of pay-
ments. The next chapter will include some additional effects that devaluations have for
small, open countries, especially developing countries. In particular, it will introduce
nontraded goods into the monetary model.
CHAPTER PROBLEMS
1. What effect does a revaluation of the currency upward have on income and the trade
balance, in the short run and in the long run? Answer diagrammatically for each of the
two monetary models.
a. The monetary model with fixed goods prices (Section 19.1).
b. The monetarist model with purchasing power parity (Section 19.4).
2. The real exchange rate is defined to be E (CPI* / CPI).
a. If PPP holds, what is the rate of change of the CPI when the foreign inflation rate
is 3 percent per year and
i. the nominal exchange rate is fixed?
ii. the domestic currency is depreciating at 7 percent per year?
iii. the domestic currency is appreciating at 3 percent per year?
b. Assume that PPP holds, the foreign price level is fixed, the parameter K mea-
sures the sensitivity of desired money balances to nominal income, and the
parameter d measures the sensitivity of the balance of payments to the excess
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 376
376 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
Extra Credit
Problems 4 and 5 deal with the monetary approach to the balance of payments. The
rate of change of the money supply is given by the balance of payments.
H 5 TB
Problem 4 maintains the fixed-price assumption of the Keynesian model of Chap-
ter 17. Problem 5 goes to the opposite extreme, fixed output.
4. Assume the model of Problem 5 in the problem set for Chapter 18.
a. Continuing Problem 5b, what is the initial, short-run effect of a fiscal expansion on
the balance of payments: DTBSR / DG? What happens over time? What is the effect
on income in the long run, defined as the time when the money supply is no longer
changing (H 5 0): DYLR?
b. Continuing Problem 5d from Chapter 18, what is the initial effect of a monetary
expansion on the balance of payments: DTBSR / D( M/P)? What is the effect on
income in the long run: DYLR?
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 377
5. Think of the balance of payments, now equal to the desired rate of accumulation of
money balances, as a function of the gap between the actual current money supply, M,
and desired (long-run) money, Md, where the latter is proportional to nominal GDP:
H 5 2d(M 2 Md)
1
Md 5 v PY
P 5 EP*
where the small open economy assumption (that the world price level P* is
exogenous) is adopted, along with the assumption that income is exogenous
because flexible prices guarantee full employment (Y 5 Y).
Returning to the monetarist notation of Problem 5a, what is the effect of a
devaluation, DE, on the balance of payments in the short run? In the long run?
378 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
model of the income-flow mechanism (although this paper, like much of the book,
allows for capital mobility, and thus is most relevant for our Chapter 22).
Wanniski, Jude. “The Mundell-Laffer Hypothesis—A New View of the World Econ-
omy,” The Public Interest, 39 (Spring 1975): 31–52. The author, a former editorial
writer for the Wall Street Journal, offered a heartfelt proclamation of the view that
changes in the exchange rate have no effect on relative prices and therefore no
effect on the trade balance.
APPENDIX A
Appendix A 379
The second aspect of the monetary approach to the balance of payments, the
emphasis on international reserve flows, takes on an especially simplified form in the
case of the idealized gold standard. The idealization leaves out reserves held in the
form of foreign currency and thus treats gold as the only form of international
reserve.22 Furthermore, it leaves out net domestic assets—purchases of domestic bonds
by the central bank—and thus treats gold as the only component of the monetary base.
Finally, it leaves out credit created by the commercial banking system, so that gold is
treated as the only component of the money supply. This need not mean that gold liter-
ally circulates among the public; it is enough if the banking system always holds exactly
the right amount of gold to back up one for one the domestic currency that it issues.
(This is called “100 percent reserve backing,” as opposed to the modern system of
“fractional-reserve backing,” under which the monetary base is only a fraction of the
money supply in the hands of the public.) It follows that under this idealized version of
the gold standard, the central bank could not sterilize international reserve flows even
if it wanted to. The money supply necessarily varies one for one with the country’s
holdings of gold, evaluated at the set price. This appendix will freely use the word gold
interchangeably with reserves, or money.
In truth, domestic credit creation and fractional reserve backing began long before
1914. Central banks did not in fact always allow reserve outflows to translate fully into
monetary contraction as they were supposed to under the rules of the game. It is proba-
bly true, however, that in the nineteenth century central banks made much less of a
practice of sterilizing reserve flows so as to set monetary policy where they wanted it
than they do today. It was only after World War I that central banks began to acquire
responsibility for the deliberate setting of monetary policy to respond to problems such
as unemployment. (One possible interpretation is that the motivation for them to do so
stems from the greater degree of rigidity of wages and prices in the modern era.23)
22
This ignores the fact that under the gold standard, central banks held much of their reserves in the form of
pounds sterling because they knew that the pound was convertible into gold.
23
See Robert Triffin, “Myths and Realities of the So-called Gold Standard”; and Donald McCloskey and J.
Richard Zecher, “How the Gold Standard Worked, 1880–1913,” both reprinted in Eichengreen, The Gold
Standard in Theory and History.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 380
380 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
prefer that the government not have such discretionary power because they do not
trust that it has the good faith and competence to use the power well.)
A second objection is that tying the money supply to gold also prevents the steady
long-term growth in the world supply of money and reserves necessary to satisfy the
transactions demand that comes with growing output and trade. If there is no increase
in the supply of available gold, then money will get tighter and tighter, creating a drag
on world growth. The absence of major discoveries of gold between 1873 and 1896
helps explain why price levels fell dramatically over this period (53 percent in the
United States and 45 percent in the United Kingdom).24 Conversely, the gold rushes in
California in 1849 and in South Africa and Alaska in the late 1890s were each followed
by upswings in the price level of similar magnitude. Clearly, the system did not in fact
guarantee price stability. Opponents of the gold standard ask why one would want to
make the world economy hostage to chance gold discoveries and the other arbitrary
vicissitudes of supply and demand in the world gold market. They also question the
efficiency of a system that requires the use of resources to dig gold out of the ground
laboriously, only to bury it back in the ground at Fort Knox.25
After World War I, it was considered very important to Britain to restore convert-
ibility of the pound into gold. But at what exchange rate? This is the context in which the
idea of purchasing power parity was first debated. A misplaced faith in the ability of
wages and prices to adjust downward easily led the treasury minister,Winston Churchill,
to peg the pound at too high a value, that is, to set too low a price for gold in terms of
pounds. The result was a balance-of-payments deficit and severe contraction that ended
in collapse of the system, rather than in smooth adjustment to the disequilibrium.26
Officially, gold was also the reserve asset of the Bretton Woods system founded in
1944. World growth would have soon run into the constraint of a basically fixed supply
of gold, were it not for the fact that the dollar immediately became the de facto reserve
asset. Central banks held much of their reserves in the form of dollars because the dol-
lar was convertible into gold, in the same way that central banks had earlier held much
24
The deflation of these years inflicted economic hardship, in particular, on American farmers, who had debts
that were set in dollar terms but who produced commodities and owned land whose prices were falling in dol-
lar terms. This was the era of Snidely Whiplash threatening to foreclose on poor Nell’s farm and of the rise of
populism in the American Midwest. The populists wanted the United States to abandon the gold standard so
as to expand the money supply and get prices up. William Jennings Bryan, their candidate for president in
1896, warned that the farmers would not be “crucified on a cross of gold.” Incidentally, the book The Wizard of
Oz was really an allegory about populism. Oz stands for “ounces” (gold). Dorothy is the “innocent” from
Kansas, the Scarecrow represents the farmer, the Tinman is the downtrodden urban worker (with whom the
populists might have hoped to make a political alliance), and the Lion is William Jennings Bryan. Their ene-
mies are the Wicked Witch of the East, representing the East Coast bankers (who were suspected of conspir-
ing to keep money tight) and the Wicked Witch of the West, representing drought (only water can kill her).
25
A good introduction to the topic is provided by Richard Cooper, “The Gold Standard: Historical Facts and
Future Prospects,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1 (1982): 1–45. It includes the latter-day contro-
versy over proposals to return to the gold standard to restore price stability, and the statistics on the price level
swings that in fact characterized the nineteenth century.
26
John Maynard Keynes accurately predicted this outcome of the return to gold in 1925: “The Economic
Consequences of Mr. Churchill,” reprinted in his Essays in Persuasion (New York: Norton, 1963), pp. 244–270.
Much has been written on this interwar period. See Barry Eichengreen, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard
and the Great Depression, 1919–1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 381
Appendix A 381
of their reserves in the form of pounds. This is why the Bretton Woods system was
sometimes called a gold-exchange standard.
Before long, however, the new system came under increasing strain. The reason
was that, beginning in 1958, the United States ran balance-of-payments deficits. Foreign
central banks’ holdings of dollars rose relative to the gold in Fort Knox, and foreigners
(particularly Charles de Gaulle, the gold-conscious leader of France) began to doubt
the ability of the U.S. government to redeem its dollar liabilities in gold. This was the
beginning of the long, drawn-out breakdown of the Bretton Woods system.
The monetarist model can be used to illustrate the emergence of U.S. balance-of-
payments deficits in 1958. Let the countries in the two-country model of the chapter
supplement be the United States and Europe. In the 1950s the European economies
grew more rapidly than the U.S. economy as they recovered from the devastation of the
1940s. Their rapidly growing levels of income led to rapidly growing demand for money.
To acquire international reserves, they had to run balance-of-payments surpluses
against the United States. The model was used in the 1960s to show why the emergence
of U.S. deficits was a natural consequence of the system that had been set up in 1944.
The world monetary system was faced with the “Triffin dilemma.”27 If the United
States was allowed to continue running balance-of-payments deficits, eventually there
would be a crisis of confidence as foreigners all tried to cash in their dollars for gold
before it was too late, and thereby exhausted the U.S. gold reserves. Conversely, if steps
were taken to end the U.S. deficit, then the rest of the world would be deprived of suf-
ficient liquidity in the form of a steadily growing stock of reserves.
Economists and policy makers debated the problem throughout the 1960s. There
were two solutions proposed to increase the world supply of reserves, both of them
radical departures from the system agreed on at Bretton Woods. The first was to
increase the price of gold—that is, to devalue the dollar in terms of gold—thereby rais-
ing the nominal value of the world supply of reserves. The second was to create an arti-
ficial reserve asset, a sort of “paper gold.”
Eventually, both changes were made, although it had not been planned that way.
The artificial asset was the Special Drawing Right, which the members of the Inter-
national Monetary Fund agreed to create in 1968. By the time three batches of SDRs
were phased into use (1970–1972), other events had intervened. In August 1971, in
response to the worsening U.S. balance of payments.28 President Nixon unilaterally
suspended convertibility of the dollar into gold, not just for private residents, but for
foreign central banks as well. When the leading countries met at the Smithsonian Insti-
tution in December 1971 to agree on a new set of exchange rates, the realignments
included a 10 percent devaluation of the dollar against gold. This attempt to shore up
27
Robert Triffin, Gold and the Dollar Crisis (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1960).
28
The year 1971 was the first time since World War II that the United States ran a deficit, not just on the pri-
vate capital account, but on the trade account as well. The U.S. trade surplus had been diminishing steadily
since 1964. The cause was overly expansionary macroeconomic policies, as the Johnson administration—fol-
lowed by the Nixon administration—increased military spending on the war in Vietnam and domestic spend-
ing at the same time, and were reluctant to raise taxes to pay for it. Some have pointed out parallels between
that period and U.S. macro policy from 2001 to 2005.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 382
382 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
the system of fixed exchange rates did not last long, and in March 1973 the system was
abandoned completely. The market price of gold increased twentyfold (in dollars) over
the remainder of the decade.
APPENDIX B
FIGURE 19.B.1 TB
Effects of a Fiscal Expansion over Time
In the short run an increase in spending raises
output and worsens the trade balance. If the
loss of reserves is not sterilized, then the money +
B
supply falls over time and output returns to its 0 Y
original level at B. F
–
TB
i TB = 0 LM ′ LM
Deficit
F
IS ′
IS
0 Y
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 383
Appendix B 383
As in the case of a monetary expansion, the central bank could sterilize the reserve
outflow to keep the money supply constant and remain at F. Under the assumption of
nonsterilization, however, the money supply falls over time. The LM curve shifts back,
income falls, and the trade balance improves. Eventually, income and the trade balance
return to B, where they were before expansion. There is one difference between the
new equilibrium at B and the old equilibrium at E. The interest rate is higher, meaning
that a reallocation of output between sectors has taken place: The government sector
has expanded at the expense of private investment. We thus have another result under
the monetary approach: A fiscal expansion, athough raising income and worsening the
trade balance in the short run, has no effect on either in the long run.
Finally, consider the effects of a devaluation. Figure 19.B.2 is a reproduction of
Figure 18.9. The devaluation shifts out the IS curve. At point D income has increased.
The devaluation shifts the vertical TB 5 0 line farther out than the IS curve, so the
trade balance improves at point D. As a consequence of the trade surplus, reserves are
increasing over time. The central bank could sterilize the reserve inflow to keep the
FIGURE 19.B.2 TB
Effect of a Devaluation over Time
In the short run a devaluation improves D
the trade balance and raises output. If the
inflow of reserves is not sterilized, then +
C
the money supply rises over time and 0 Y
output rises further to C. –
TB ′
i (TB = 0) ′
LM
LM ′
D Surplus
IS ′
IS
0 Y
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 384
384 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
money supply constant and remain at point D, but under the assumption of nonsteril-
ization the money supply rises over time and the LM curve shifts out. Income rises and
the trade balance worsens. Eventually, the trade balance returns to zero, at point C. In
this case, however, income ends up at a permanently higher level. The TB line in the
upper panel of Figure 19.B.2 shows the magnitude of the long-run increase in income.
The line’s slope is 2m, so
1
DYLR 5 m DX.
Intuitively, we can see that money keeps flowing in through the trade surplus until
income has risen enough for increased imports, DM, to cancel out the initial stimulus
of the devaluation, DX. This returns the trade balance to where it was before the
expansion.29 It is interesting to compare the effect of the devaluation to what it would
be in the simpler Keynesian multiplier model (at point F), that is, in the absence of
crowding-out:
1
DX.
s1m
The former is larger. Under the monetary approach to the balance of payments, the
long-run effect is not only greater than the short-run effect, but it is even greater than
the short-run effect without crowding-out. The conclusion that a devaluation is an
effective means of raising income even in the long run is a very “unmonetarist” conclu-
sion; it stems from the Keynesian assumption that prices are fixed. This assumption is
not realistic for the truly long run and is relaxed in Section 19.4.
APPENDIX C
29
The way Figure 19.B.2 is drawn, the long-run interest rate is lower, and therefore I is higher, after the deval-
uation than before. We know that this must be right. Otherwise, with X 2 M unchanged, Y 5 C 1 I 1 G 1
X 2 M could not be higher after the devaluation.
30
The supplement to this chapter relaxes the small-country assumption to look at the two-country version of
the monetary approach to the balance of payments, which is relevant when the country is large enough to
affect the world price level. (As long as world prices are perfectly flexible and PPP holds, it continues to be a
“monetarist” or “new classical” model, as opposed to the Keynesian model previously examined.)
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 385
Appendix C 385
the foreign price level are determined, by Equation 19.2 the domestic price level is also
determined. This method of determining the domestic price level is very different from
the Keynesian way in which it was exogenously set. The difference becomes obvious
when we consider devaluation as in Section 19.4. PPP states that the devaluation is
instantly reflected as a proportionate increase in the domestic price level, whereas in
the Keynesian model the domestic price level did not change.
Desired money balances are proportional to nominal income.31
Md 5 KPY (19.C.1)
Individuals adapt actual money balances to desired money balances through saving (in
excess of investment), represented by H. This part of the book ignores assets other
than money, such as bonds. (They will enter in Part V.) For this reason, saving can only
take the form of additions to holdings of money balances. H is thus equal to the change
in the money stock over time: It tells us how much the money supply is going up per
year. H is assumed proportional to the current gap between the desired money stock
and the actual money stock, M:
H 5 d(Md 2 M)
where d is the speed with which money balances are adjusted. This equation simply says
that individuals act to add to their money balances when money demand minus money
supply is positive. Now we use Equation 19.C.1 to substitute for long-run desired
money balances, Md.
H 5 d(KPY 2 M) (19.C.2)
Under the key nonsterilization assumption of the monetary approach, the rate of
change of the money supply, M, is the same as the rate of accumulation of reserves, the
balance-of-payments surplus, BP. The equation becomes
BP 5 H 5 dKPY 2 dM (19.C.3)
Equation 19.C.3 looks unlike any balance-of-payments expression seen before. An
increase in the money supply has a negative effect on the surplus, as in the last chapter.
Although the Keynesian model was quite specific about the channel through which the
increase in the money supply raises spending (it lowers the interest rate and thus stim-
ulates investment), the monetarist explanation is more general. A monetary expansion
worsens the balance of payments because individuals, when faced with an excess sup-
ply of money, increase spending to adjust their excessive money holdings back down to
the level of their money demand. (These two explanations can be made entirely consis-
tent if investment depends linearly on the interest rate.32)
Another difference between the two models is that the monetary approach says
the outflow occurs through the overall balance of payments, without differentiating
31
M here represents the money stock, not imports as in previous chapters. Desired money balances, Md, refers
to a long-run notion of money demand; it differs somewhat from the short-run notion of money demand in
IS 2 LM, where the interest rate adjusts so that money demand is always equal to money supply, even in the
short run.
32
The reduced form of the linear IS 2 LM system (i.e., with the interest rate substituted out) is the same as the
monetarist formulation. This is chapter Problem 5b.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 386
386 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
between the current account or capital account, whereas the Keynesian approach spec-
ifies that it occurs through the trade balance. However, because we have not yet intro-
duced capital flows, it is difficult to tell the difference.
These differences are not especially important. The crucial difference between the
monetarist and Keynesian models, remember, is price flexibility.
The assumption of perfect wage and price flexibility in the global monetarist
model implies completely inelastic aggregate supply. Because income is always at the
full-employment level, Y 5 Y, the balance of payments in Equation 19.C.3 varies only
with the price level, P, and the money supply, M. Figure 19.C.1 graphs the relationship
between the balance of payments and the price level for a given M, with the balance of
payments measured on the vertical axis, and refers to it as the H schedule.33 As the
equation says, the vertical intercept is 2dM and the slope is dKY. Again, the reason the
schedule slopes upward is that a higher price level means a higher demand for money,
which causes residents to cut back on spending so they can earn the desired money bal-
ances through a balance-of-payments surplus.
The exogenous foreign price level, P*, and the given fixed exchange rate, E,
together determine the domestic price level, P 5 EP*, by Equation 19.2. This price
level, P, is represented in Figure 19.C.1 by a vertical line. Point B in the figure is the
starting point, a position of balance-of-payments equilibrium. Two policy changes will
be considered: monetary policy and devaluation.
FIGURE 19.C.1 BP
Monetary Expansion in the Monetarist
Small-Country Model
H = (δKY )P – δM
An increase in the money supply shifts the
H schedule. With the price level, P, tied down
by PPP, this leads to an excess supply of money
and a balance of payments deficit (BP , 0 at M).
P = EP*
Over time, money flows out of the country and
balance is restored (BP 5 0 at B). H = (δKY )P – δM ′
+
0 P
–
B
33
The symbol H stands for “hoarding,” defined as the accumulation of money through saving.
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 387
Appendix C 387
388 Chapter 19 ■ The Money Supply, the Price Level, and the Balance of Payments
FIGURE 19.C.2 BP
Devaluation in the Monetarist
Small-Country Model P = EP* P = E ′P*
+
0 P
–
B C
equals money demand and the balance of payments is back at zero. The new equilib-
rium after the devaluation features not only a higher price level but a higher money
supply, with both nominal variables having increased in the same proportion as the
exchange rate.
Let us now consider an exogenous increase in the world price level, P*, as might
result, for example, from an expansion in the world money supply. It is instantly trans-
mitted as a proportionately higher domestic price level, P 5 EP*. It acts just like the
devaluation pictured in Figure 19.C.2 so far as the small country is concerned. The
excess demand for money shows up as a temporary balance-of-payments surplus.
Notice again that the favorable effect of the foreign price increase on the balance of
payments does not take place through relative prices, as in the elasticities or Keynesian
approaches, but rather through the effect of the price level on money demand.
Finally, consider an exogenous increase in domestic money demand. Such an
increase in money demand might result, for example, from an exogenous increase in
domestic output, Y. Because this section assumes full employment, the increase in out-
put must come from the supply side: an increase in the capital stock, labor force, or
productivity. In any case, the increase in money demand causes people to cut back
spending so that they can acquire the desired money balances. It acts like the decrease
in money supply previously considered, in that it creates an excess demand for money
and shifts the H schedule up. (More precisely, if the increase in Md comes from an
increase in Y, then it rotates the H schedule in the counterclockwise direction: Refer to
the slope, dKY. The point remains: A higher BP now corresponds to a given P.) The
cutback in spending thus leads to a balance-of-payments surplus. Over time money
CAVE.6607.cp19.p353-390 6/6/06 12:16 PM Page 389
Appendix C 389
flows in through the payments surplus, until equilibrium returns with a higher money
supply and a zero balance of payments, as always.
Notice the sharp contrast to the Keynesian model, in which an increase in income
caused an immediate trade deficit, rather than a surplus. The Keynesian model should
be thought of as correct for income growth induced by increases in spending because it
is a model in which the economy can be below full employment. The present result—
growth causing a payments surplus because of higher money demand—is appropriate
for exogenous supply-induced growth. A prime motivation for the development of the
monetary approach in the 1960s was the observed fact that the fastest growing coun-
tries, such as Japan, Germany, and other European countries, ran balance-of-payments
surpluses while the United States ran a deficit. That the monetary approach could
explain this situation accounted in part for its popularity.34
34
The argument was made by Robert Mundell, “Growth and the Balance of Payments,” in his International
Economics (New York: Macmillan, 1968), Chapter 9. For examples from the current era (in which Japan and
euroland have floating rather than fixed exchange rates and are growing more slowly than before), consider
the cases of China and some other newly industrialized economies of East Asia. They have tended to experi-
ence rapid supply-side growth with surpluses in their balances of payments.
CAVE.6607.supp.pS1-S58 6/7/06 10:39 AM Page S-44
1
The model in this supplement is drawn from the first half of Rudiger Dornbusch, “Devaluation, Money, and
Nontraded Goods,” The American Economic Review, 65, no. 5 (1973): 871–880.
CAVE.6607.supp.pS1-S58 6/7/06 10:39 AM Page S-45
FIGURE 19.S.1 BP
Monetary Expansion in the Monetarist,
M + EM*
Two-Country Model P=
K (Y + Y* )
A monetary expansion of 1 percent will raise
the world price level by c percent, where c is
the domestic country’s fraction of the world’s P=
M ′+ EM*
money supply. As with a small country (where K (Y + Y* )
c 5 0), the expansion shifts the H schedule H = (δKY )P – δM
downward leading to a temporary excess
supply of money and balance-of-payments
deficit. ψ%
H = (δKY )P – δM ′
1%
+
0 P
– A B
horizontally to the right by the same proportion as the increase in the money supply: If
the price level were for some reason to increase by the same proportion as the money
supply, the excess supply of money would remain at zero.
When the country was small, the world price level was unchanged; but now it is
recognized that the monetary expansion will raise the world price level to the extent
that the domestic country is large. Define the domestic country’s share in the world
money supply.
c ; M / (M 1 EM*)
A 1 percent increase in the domestic money supply is a c percent increase in the world
money supply. As shown in Equation 19.S.4, it raises the world price level by c percent,
whether that is measured in terms of domestic currency, P, or foreign, P*. In Figure
19.S.1, the monetary expansion shifts to the right not only the domestic H line but the
price level line as well. This means that the money demand function must be evaluated
at a higher price level, at point M. Under the previous small-country case, c was negli-
gible, and so the price level rose negligibly. There was an increase in the money supply
of, say, 1 percent, with no increase in money demand. Now there is a 1 percent increase
in the money supply with a c percent increase in money demand. There is still an excess
supply of money (equal to 1 2 c percent of the original money supply), and therefore a
balance-of-payments deficit, but they are not as large as in the small-country case.
CAVE.6607.supp.pS1-S58 6/7/06 10:39 AM Page S-47
What is happening in the foreign country? Its money supply has not changed, but
it is faced with a c percent increase in the price level. Therefore, its demand for money
goes up by c percent. It has an excess demand for money (equal to c percent of its
money supply) that is the counterpart of the domestic country’s excess supply of
money, causing a foreign balance-of-payments surplus that is the counterpart of the
domestic country’s balance-of-payments deficit.
Over time, the domestic country loses gold to the foreign country. Under the non-
sterilization assumption, the domestic money supply falls and the foreign money sup-
ply rises. The domestic H schedule shifts upward and the negative foreign schedule,
2EH*, shifts upward as well. The economy follows a sequence of intersections, moving
upward from M along the new price level line. The transfer of money from the home
country to the foreign country gradually alleviates the excess demand in the foreign
country. Long-run equilibrium is reached when both countries return to a zero balance
of payments, at point B. There the supply of money equals the demand for money in
both countries. Because the price level has risen by c percent in both countries and the
demand for money is proportional to the price level, this can only mean that the supply
of money has increased by c percent in both countries. The world money supply has
increased by c percent. In the short run the expansion took place entirely in the
domestic country, but in the long run it is distributed equiproportionately across both
countries.
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 391
CHAPTER 20
I
magine the dilemma faced by the finance minister of a small developing country that
needs to improve its trade balance. Advisers urge that some combination of deval-
uation and contractionary demand policies be adopted. They base their reasoning on
standard macroeconomic models such as the ones developed in the preceding chap-
ters.1 The finance minister has little faith in these models, believing that they were
designed to fit the experience of relatively large industrialized countries, not small
developing countries. But the finance minister also does not believe the simple small-
country monetarist model developed in Chapter 19.2 A bit more realism is required.
This chapter departs temporarily from the central focus of the text to consider an alter-
native model that is particularly appropriate for typical developing countries.
If a country were so open to international trade and so small in world goods mar-
kets that purchasing power parity held, then, by definition, a devaluation could not
change relative prices. As we saw in Section 19.4, a devaluation could affect the trade
balance only through the real money balance effect. Hong Kong and Singapore were
cited as relatively close approximations of such an economy.
Even countries that are small in terms of world trade often have large internal mar-
kets, however. Indonesia and Australia, for example, are probably too small in world
markets to affect their terms of trade, but they are certainly not “small” countries in
other respects. This chapter will continue to consider countries that are sufficiently
small and open that they take the prices of all traded goods (exports and imports) as
determined outside the country and fixed in terms of foreign currency. However, the
existence of goods that are not internationally traded will also be recognized. The dis-
cussion will reveal that, as a consequence, such countries experience relative price
effects when they devalue, along with the real money balance effect already explored.
1
Such recommendations are often highly unpopular politically, especially when they are perceived to be
imposed by the International Monetary Fund (IMF). See Chapter 24 for more on the unpopularity of
devaluations.
2
Blind adherence to PPP (among other things) got the policy makers of the “southern cone” of Latin America
(Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay) into trouble in the late 1970s. Vittorio Corbo and Jaime de Melo, “Liberaliza-
tion with Stabilization in the Southern Cone of Latin America,” World Development, Special Issue, 13, no. 8
(August 1985): 893–916.
391
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 392
392 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
3
A country’s “openness” could be defined as the ratio of its production of traded goods to its total GDP. This
chapter focuses on countries that, although small as in the model of Section 19.4, are not 100 percent open.
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 393
TG
and Pt represent the (nominal) prices of nontraded goods and traded goods, respec-
tively. PN gives the number of units of traded goods required to buy one unit of non-
traded goods. When PN is low, nontraded goods are relatively cheap and the budget
line in Figure 20.1 is steep: A resident can buy a larger quantity of nontraded goods for
any given quantity of traded goods.
In the most general case, many combinations of outputs are “fair game,” including
points that lie inside the production possibility curve. These are points at which the
supplies of labor and other resources are not being fully utilized, so that output of both
goods is less than it could be. In this chapter, however, the discussion will be restricted
to the assumption that labor and other resources are fully employed, as in Chapter 19.
In this case, the quantities of output of the two goods, XN and XT, are given by the point
S, where the line is tangent to the curve. The output quantities are the outcome of sup-
ply decisions that firms make when faced with the prevailing prices. Keep in mind that
output of traded goods includes not only specific products that the home country
might currently be exporting but also specific products that might be imported if the
demand from domestic consumers exceeds domestic output.
394 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
the same as in the small-country model of Section 19.4, the only difference being that
there all goods were traded goods. It is very different, however, from the way we
thought of the trade balance in Chapters 16 to 18—as foreigners’ demand for the export
goods of the home country minus domestic residents’ demand for the imports. In the
present model, with all traded goods aggregated together, it is impossible to say what
determines the level of exports and the level of imports. Fortunately, it is not necessary
to know either level to determine the difference of the two, the trade balance.
What determines the pattern of consumption? Assume, as in Figure 2.7, that we
can draw community indifference curves. Along any given indifference curve, con-
sumers are equally happy with the different possible combinations of nontraded and
traded goods consumed, CN and CT. The slope of the indifference curve is the marginal
rate of substitution between the two; it tells the amount of consumption of nontraded
goods the consumer is willing to give up to get one more unit of traded goods. Indiffer-
ence curves farther from the origin are better, of course, because more consumption
is better than less. The curves are convex because of the diminishing marginal rate of
substitution.
To attain the highest level of welfare available to them, consumers will determine
their quantities purchased, CN and CT at the point on an indifference curve where the
given price line is tangent, that is, where the marginal rate of substitution is set equal to
the relative prices of the two kinds of goods. It is possible that this will be the same
point, S, where production occurs. In that case the quantity of traded goods consumed
will equal the quantity of traded goods produced. If this happens, the trade balance is
zero. If we were to rule out gaps between expenditure and income, thereby ruling out
trade deficits or surpluses, as in most of the first half of the text, we would necessarily
be at S. Indeed, under this restriction, the relative price line would have to be deter-
mined endogenously by the unique point where the production possibility frontier was
tangent to an indifference curve.
Now we allow for countries to “spend beyond their means.” We assume expendi-
ture is at some level, A (measured in terms of traded goods: A ; CT 1 PNCN), that is
greater than the level of income, Y (also expressed in terms of traded goods: Y ; XT 1
PNXN). For example, there may have been an income tax cut or an increase in expendi-
ture on the part of the government that raised A. A and Y are measured along the hor-
izontal axis in Figure 20.2. The budget line is the one that passes through point A, with
consumers assumed to face the same relative prices as producers. (There are no taxes
or subsidies on the goods.) CN and CT are located where the budget line is tangent to
an indifference curve, at point F. This is where consumers attain the highest level of
welfare, given their budget constraint. In Figure 20.2, consumption of both goods
exceeds output. In the case of traded goods, the difference (CT 2 XT), which can be
measured horizontally on the graph, is simply the trade deficit. Consumers are satisfy-
ing their excess demand for traded goods abroad. In the case of nontraded goods, the
difference (CN 2 XN), which can be measured vertically, is the excess demand for non-
traded goods. According to the definition of nontraded, this excess demand cannot be
satisfied abroad but can be thought of as being satisfied out of inventories held by
firms (temporarily, until they run out).
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 395
XT CT Y A TG
Trade deficit
Other conditions could exist in these markets as well: a trade surplus if F occurs
anywhere to the left of S, and an excess supply of nontraded goods if F occurs any-
where below S. The next thing to consider is what determines these points of consump-
tion and output.4
4
Figure 20.2 is known as the Salter diagram because it originated with W. E. G. Salter, “Internal Balance and
External Balance: The Role of Price and Expenditure Effects,” Economic Record (August 1959): 226–238.
Salter, like a number of the other authors who developed the model that features both traded and nontraded
goods, was Australian. Australia fits the model relatively well because the two categories of goods are fairly
clearly drawn. (The model goes by various names: Australian, nontraded goods, dependent economy, and small
open economy.)
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 396
396 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
imports or goods that would otherwise have been exported; in either case the result is a
worsening of the trade balance. When the new spending comes from the private sec-
tor—for example, in response to a tax cut—the deterioration in the trade balance is the
marginal propensity to spend on traded goods times the increase in expenditure. When
it is government expenditure that has increased, the import content could be either
higher (as it usually is in the case of military weapons, construction equipment, or other
capital goods) or lower (as in education or health services). For simplicity, assume that
the government’s marginal propensity to spend on traded goods is generally the same
as that of the private sector.
5
If the price of nontraded goods is fixed in terms of domestic currency because firms supply these goods with
infinite elasticity—the same assumption that we made for domestically produced goods in Chapters 16
through 18—then a devaluation is the only way that the country can increase the relative price of traded
goods. In this case, with nominal prices fixed, we could speak interchangeably of the nominal exchange rate
and the relative price of traded goods.
6
Incidentally, the relative price of traded goods in terms of nontraded goods in small open economies (particu-
larly in Latin America) is sometimes called the real exchange rate. Because others use the term “real exchange
rate” to denote the price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods, we avoid this alternative use of the term.
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 397
basically the same in both sectors. Firms in the nontraded sector now find that the real
wage in terms of their product has risen. They now find it less profitable to produce on
the same scale as previously, so they release labor and contract in size. Under the full-
employment assumption, the workers who lose their jobs in the nontraded sector are
the same ones hired in the expanded traded sector. We continue to move down the
curve until we reach X, the new point of tangency with the relative price line. By read-
ing off the horizontal axis, we can see that the quantity of tradable goods has risen.
The effect of the increase in the relative price of tradables on consumption is not
quite as clear as the effect on production. There is clearly a positive substitution effect:
The steeper relative price line means a move upward along any given indifference
curve to lower levels of consumption of traded goods. However, there is also an income
effect that may go the other way. It depends on what is assumed about the level of
expenditure. The experiment we are examining is an exogenous increase in expenditure
and the associated change in relative prices that would be necessary if balanced trade is
to be restored. In this experiment, when the relative price of traded goods rises, the
expenditure line remains tied down at its new bottom endpoint (expenditure remains
fixed at the new level, A, in terms of traded goods).7 The expenditure line swivels to its
new, steeper slope, the same slope as the new price line facing producers. The new con-
sumption point will be located at a point such as B, where the steeper expenditure line
is tangent to a new indifference curve. This point could be located either to the right or
left of the old point, F. Thus the consumption of traded goods could either rise or fall.
The trade balance is the difference between the production and consumption of
traded goods. Thus, even if consumption fails to fall because of the income effect, the
trade balance would still probably improve because of the unambiguously positive
effect on production. Assume that the production effect and the substitution effect in
consumption are large enough to outweigh the negative income effect in consumption;
therefore, the net effect on the trade balance is positive. The new trade balance is the
distance, measured horizontally, between X and B. If the increase in the relative price
of traded goods is large enough, then it will eliminate completely the trade deficit that
opened up when expenditure was increased. This is the case shown in Figure 20.2: B is
directly over X.
Now consider, on a graph of its own, the relationship between expenditure, A, and
the relative price of nontraded goods, PN, necessary to maintain trade balance equilib-
rium. Figure 20.3 shows expenditure on the horizontal axis and the relative price of
nontraded goods on the vertical axis. Again, S denotes the initial point of both external
balance (a zero trade balance) and internal balance (no excess supply or demand for
nontraded goods). Increased expenditure causes a horizontal move to the right (by
precisely the same distance as the movement of the expenditure point along the hori-
zontal axis in Figure 20.2). Point F lies in a region of trade deficit because expenditure
on traded goods has increased, and a sufficiently large increase in the relative price of
7
Because we are considering changes in relative prices, how we draw the graph depends in part on whether we
define expenditure in terms of traded goods or in terms of nontraded goods. In other words, the precise ques-
tion we are asking is slightly different, depending on whether we hold expenditure constant in terms of one
type of good or the other. Naturally, then, the precise answer is slightly different.
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 398
398 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
FIGURE 20.3 PN
Equilibrium in the Traded
Goods Market
Trade
In the aftermath of an increase in deficit
expenditure, A, if the relative price of F
nontraded goods, PN, is decreased far S
enough, it will eliminate the excess
demand for TG, which is the trade deficit.
Thus equilibrium in the TG market gives
the downward-sloping BB schedule. B BB
traded goods would be needed to restore balanced trade. This is the same as a suffi-
ciently large decrease in the relative price of nontraded goods, represented by a move-
ment vertically downward from point F to point B in Figure 20.3. For each level of A,
there is a corresponding level of PN that is necessary to maintain balanced trade. We
can trace out a whole series of points representing combinations of A and PN, which is
downward sloping, as shown in the graph. We label this curve BB, for balance of trade.
FIGURE 20.4
Increase in Expenditure, Followed by Increase
in Relative Price of Nontraded Goods
Again, an exogenous increase in expenditure, A, beyond Y, moves consumption to F but leaves
output at S if relative prices are unchanged. If the relative price of traded goods is decreased,
it raises output of NTG at X and lowers consumption of NTG at G.
NTG
1
CN F
Excess
demand
X G
XN
S
Y A TG
higher relative price of nontraded goods also means that consumers substitute away
from them into the cheaper traded goods. The income effect, like the substitution
effect, reduces consumption of nontraded goods, as is seen when the relative price line
is rotated downward to the new tangency (line 3 instead of line 1). The income effect is
not ambiguous, as it was when considering the demand for traded goods. CN unambigu-
ously falls at point G.8
If the increase in the relative price of nontraded goods is sufficiently large, then the
upward movement of output and the downward movement of consumption will be suf-
ficiently large that the point X and the point G will be at the same horizontal level: The
excess demand for nontraded goods that opened up when expenditure increased will
have been eliminated. In terms of Figure 20.5, a sufficiently large increase in the rela-
tive price of nontraded goods, PN, returns the country to equilibrium in the domestic
market at point G. There is an entire set of combinations of A and PN, such as S and G,
that give equilibrium in nontraded goods. These points constitute the upward-sloping
internal balance schedule, NN. To recap the reason for the NN schedule’s upward
8
If expenditure had been set in terms of nontraded goods rather than in terms of traded goods, then a change
in relative prices would have an ambiguous effect on the demand for nontraded goods and an unambiguous
effect on the demand for traded goods. This is the method used in the dependent economy model in Rudiger
Dornbusch, Open Economy Macroeconomics, 2nd ed. (New York: Basic Books, 1989).
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 400
400 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
FIGURE 20.5 PN II
Equilibrium in the Nontraded Excess
B Trade N
Goods Market supply
Trade deficit G
In the aftermath of the increase in surplus Excess
expenditure, A, if the relative price of demand
nontraded goods, PN, is increased far
enough, it will eliminate the excess III
F I
S
demand for nontraded goods. Thus Trade
equilibrium in the NTG market gives Excess deficit
the upward-sloping NN schedule. supply
Trade
N Excess surplus B
demand
IV
9
More substantively, the Keynesian model focused on the price of exports in terms of imports, whereas this
chapter uses the price of traded goods in terms of nontraded goods. Swan originally developed his diagram in
the context of the nontraded goods model, not in the context of the Keynesian model. Trevor Swan,
“Economic Control in a Dependent Economy,” Economic Record (November 1956): 239–256.
10
The other major source of financing for government deficits in the Latin American countries was printing
money. A point like G in Figure 20.5 is shown to correspond to a high rate of money growth and inflation, in
Rudiger Dornbusch, “Stabilization Policy in Developing Countries: What Lessons Have We Learned?”,
reprinted in his Dollars, Debts and Deficits (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1986). It would follow that a prereq-
uisite to eliminating inflation is eliminating the budget deficit (while simultaneously undergoing a real devalu-
ation, if seeking to avoid excess supply of domestic goods in zone II, that is, seeking to move to S).
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 401
expenditure and devalue its currency to generate more foreign exchange earnings,
thereby helping to pay the interest bill on the debts that it had incurred. It moved into
region III of the diagram, with a trade surplus and an excess supply of nontraded goods.
Developing countries in Latin America and some other parts of the world were obliged
to increase their trade balances dramatically after 1982 in response to decreased avail-
ability of loans to finance their deficits. In the early 1990s, developing countries were
able once again to finance large trade deficits. Chapter 24 discusses this phase and its
subsequent reversal in the late 1990s.
Reserve Flows
A second possible automatic mechanism of adjustment, which operates in response to
external imbalances, is the flow of international reserves we studied in Chapter 19
under the monetary approach to the balance of payments. As we saw there, the money
supply is one of the policy variables that determines the level of expenditure. When the
country is running a balance-of-payments deficit, at a point like F in Figure 20.5, its
level of reserves is decreasing over time. If the reserve loss translates into a reduction
in the total money supply, then it will exert a contractionary effect on expenditure. A
declining level of expenditure means a gradual movement leftward over time and a
diminishing balance-of-payments deficit. The movement stops at a point on the exter-
nal balance line, BB, because the rate of change of reserves is zero when the balance of
payments is zero. However, if the monetary authorities offset the effect of the reserve
loss on the money supply by expanding domestic credit (i.e., sterilize), then there will
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 402
402 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
FIGURE 20.6 PN
Adjustment with Excess Supply II
of Nontraded Goods
B N
At a point to the left of BB, such as H,
excess supply of nontraded goods puts
Excess
downward pressure on the price of NTG.
supply
Even when the NN schedule is reached,
however, there is still a trade surplus.
If the reserve inflow is not sterilized, III H I
expenditure, A, increases over time. S
N E
IV
B
take time to develop; in that case the surplus should appear in the capital account, as
the country borrows to smooth spending, and in particular to finance imports of capital
goods necessary to develop the resource (e.g., equipment for drilling and pumping, in
the case of oil). Either way, the commodity boom results in a surplus in the balance of
payments.
Sometimes an analogy is drawn between the Dutch disease and other forms of
exogenous inflows, such as unilateral transfers, or capital inflows arising from monetary
stabilization or other sources. Many developing countries have experienced such
inflows intermittently, particularly in three boom periods: 1975 to 1982, 1990 to 1996,
and 2001 to 2006, as we shall see in Section 24.1. Whatever the cause of the reserve
inflows, the difficulty arises when real appreciation of the currency causes a loss of
competitiveness for exports of manufactured goods (or for any other tradable-goods
industry)—excluding, of course, the industry experiencing the export boom that is the
original source of the reserve inflow.
How does a reserve inflow lead to real appreciation of the currency? There are
two possible mechanisms. On the one hand, if the monetary authorities keep the
exchange rate fixed, then the monetary approach to the balance of payments indicates
that the reserve inflow will cause the money supply to swell, which may in turn lead to
increases in wages and the prices of nontraded goods. In this case the real appreciation
takes the form of inflation. On the other hand, the monetary authorities may respond
to the reserve inflow by allowing the currency to appreciate in nominal terms, bringing
about the real appreciation directly. To take an example, the value of Colombia’s cur-
rency tends to move with the international price of its leading export, coffee.
The real appreciation is an increase in the relative price of nontraded goods. In
many countries experiencing a commodity boom, revenues accrue to the government,
either because it owns the resource directly (the norm among oil exporters) or because
it is paid royalties or tax proceeds by the private owners. Typically the government
responds by raising spending, which is another source of increased demand and
upward pressure on the prices of nontraded goods. Not only are resources pulled into
the sector experiencing the commodity boom, but, less obviously, they are pulled into
the production of nontraded goods such as construction. Resources are pulled out of
the production of manufactures and other tradables—those that lie outside the boom-
ing commodity sector.
Even when events like the Dutch disease create difficulties for manufactured
exports, this does not mean that the country as a whole is worse off. A country would be
foolish to turn down a windfall gain on its commodity exports. After all, no country
would welcome a fall in the value of an exportable resource. Examples of sudden falls
in the price of a basic export commodity that lead to real depreciation and (often)
sharp recession include Chile in 1974–1975 (copper), Bolivia in 1985 (tin), and Russia in
1998 (oil).
One of the main respects in which the Dutch disease can indeed be a “disease” is
that the boom may turn out to be more temporary than the government had thought.
When world prices go back down, the country can be left with an atrophied export sec-
tor, “white elephant” investment projects, bloated government payrolls, unwanted real
estate construction, and sometimes even large international debts. The cycle of Dutch
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 404
404 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
11
The model that follows was developed by Rudiger Dornbusch, “Devaluation, Money and Nontraded
Goods,” American Economic Review (December 1973): 875–880.
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 405
payments deficit means that reserves will be steadily flowing out of the country. Under
the assumption that the reserve outflow is not sterilized, the money supply is declining
over time. As the money supply declines, the level of expenditure, A, declines, so there
is a move leftward in Figure 20.5. At the same time, however, PN must decline, so as to
eliminate any incipient excess supply of nontraded goods that would otherwise result
from the declining expenditure and keep the country on the NN schedule. In other
words, the movement is down and to the left, until eventually we return to balance-of-
payments equilibrium at point S. Only when the rate of change of reserves, equal to the
balance of payments, is zero will there be long-run equilibrium. In the long run the
monetary expansion has changed absolutely nothing except the composition of the
central bank’s balance sheet: The original expansion in domestic credit has been offset
by an equal decrease in the central bank’s holdings of international reserves.
406 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
12
The nominal price of nontraded goods, Pn, probably stays about the same in the short run, or rises a little
(less than the nominal price of traded goods). It is even possible, in theory, that Pn falls. It depends on the elas-
ticities of demand and supply of nontraded goods. All that is certain is that the relative price of nontraded
goods, Pn/Pt, falls.
13
To see the increase in the trade surplus graphically, think of successive waves of downward-sloping “iso-
trade-surplus” lines emanating from the BB schedule in Figure 20.6, each one corresponding to a different
level of the trade balance. Point E lies on an iso-trade-surplus line that is farther from BB than is H, so the
trade surplus is larger as a result of the fall in PN.
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 407
20.4 Summary
Most developing countries (and industrialized countries as well) have a substantial
internal market where prices do not adjust instantly in response to a devaluation; in such
countries the PPP model of Chapter 19 is not applicable. However, many such countries
are too small in world markets to be able to set the price of their exports, so neither is the
Keynesian model relevant.This chapter examined the effects of exchange rate and mon-
etary policies in such small open countries with nontraded goods.
The trade balance can be thought of as the country’s excess supply of internation-
ally traded goods. We focused on two key variables: the level of expenditure and the rel-
ative price of nontraded goods (in terms of traded goods). One possibility is that these
variables adjust automatically to ensure equilibrium in the two markets. Whenever
there is a trade deficit, reserves flow out of the country; under the monetary approach
to the balance of payments, the level of expenditure falls until trade balance equilib-
rium is restored. Whenever there is excess supply of nontraded goods, the price of non-
traded goods falls until equilibrium in this market is restored as well.
In practice, these automatic mechanisms of adjustment are likely to work slowly at
best. Thus there is an argument for the government to use its available policy tools
to speed up the process.The government can adjust the level of expenditure by changing
the money supply.The government can adjust the level of the relative price of nontraded
goods by changing the exchange rate and thus changing the price of traded goods.
We saw that a devaluation works to improve the trade balance in a small coun-
try through two effects. In addition to the real balance effect studied in Chapter 19
(whereby the higher price level creates an excess demand for money and leads to a
reduction in spending), there is a second effect. When the price of traded goods goes up
in proportion to the devaluation, the relative price of nontraded goods goes down. In
response, resources shift out of the production of nontraded goods into production of
traded goods. Thus the trade balance improves by more than it would have if the price
of nontraded goods had gone up by the same proportion as the price of traded goods.
In the long run, however, all nominal magnitudes are likely to go up in proportion to
the devaluation, leaving no permanent effect on the trade balance.
CHAPTER PROBLEMS
1. The country of Lampong used to import grain but now produces enough to feed itself.
During the last few years imports have been essentially zero (as have exports). Does
this mean that grain is a nontraded good?
2. You are the governor of the central bank in the country of Salesia, which is running a
large balance-of-payments surplus as the result of recent discoveries of valuable natural
resources. You are worried that the inflow of reserves through the balance-of-payments
surplus is causing excessive growth in the money supply. Indeed, you have already
exceeded the year’s money supply target that you and the International Monetary Fund
team agreed on at the time of their last visit. But you don’t want to allow the currency to
appreciate, causing your exporters in the manufacturing sector to lose competitiveness.
What can you do?
CAVE.6607.cp20.p391-408 6/6/06 12:21 PM Page 408
408 Chapter 20 ■ Developing Countries and Other Small Open Economies with Nontraded Goods
3. You have just been called in to advise the government of Gondar. The country has
been running a large trade deficit for years and is in trouble with its international cred-
itors. Other economic statistics, however, are unreliable. More than the usual number
of people seem to be wandering the capital looking for odd jobs. Also, prices for hotel
rooms, pedicabs on the street, and the local delicacy in the countryside have all fallen
since your last visit. In what quadrant of Figure 20.5 would you tentatively place the
country’s economy?
4. You are the finance minister of Khakistan. The country has started running a balance-
of-payments deficit as the result of a bad harvest in the countryside, but the rest of the
economy appears to be booming. Your foreign advisers suggest that you devalue your
currency to eliminate the payments deficit. Do you agree with this course of action? If
you are worried about inflationary pressures, how should you respond?
5. You are minister of trade in Santa Maria, which is undergoing an acute balance-of-
payments crisis. In desperation you are considering cutting off imports of cotton, which
is the country’s main import because it is used by the large textile industry. Is this a
good idea?
6. You are advising the prime minister of Phoenesia. Traded goods constitute half of
workers’ consumption basket. The other half consists of nontraded goods. The price of
nontraded goods, Pn, is a simple proportionate markup to wages, W. Industry and the
labor unions have agreed on a contract stipulating that two thirds of any increases in
the CPI will be passed through to wages.
a. For every 1 percent nominal devaluation, what is the effect on the price of
nontraded goods?
b. Assume that firms in the traded goods sector show an elasticity of supply (with
respect to Pt / W) of 1.0. If the government wants to increase output of traded
goods by 10 percent, how large an increase in Pt / W is required?
c. Putting together your answers to a and b, how large must the nominal devaluation
be to bring about the desired increase in output of traded goods? How large is the
resulting increase in the wage, W? In the CPI?14
Corden, W. Max. Economic Policy, Exchange Rates, and the International System
(Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 1994). Includes a verbal exposition of the
dependent-economy model of the balance of payments.
Dornbusch, Rudiger. “Devaluation, Money and Non-traded Goods,” American Eco-
nomic Review (December 1973): 871–880. The classic model of the monetary
approach to devaluation in small open economies. Nontraded goods are intro-
duced in the second half of the paper.
14
A simple version of the dependent-economy model along the lines of the calculations laid out in Problem 6
is sometimes known as the Scandinavian model. Nontraded goods are called the sheltered sector (sheltered
from international competition), and traded goods, the exposed or competitive sector.