0% found this document useful (0 votes)
27 views16 pages

Managerial Economics, Optimization Techniques, Chapter 3

Chapter Three of Managerial Economics focuses on optimization techniques for maximizing or minimizing a firm's objective function, utilizing differential calculus and the concept of derivatives. It discusses both unconstrained and constrained optimization methods, including the substitution method and the Lagrange multiplier method, to solve complex decision problems faced by managers. The chapter provides examples to illustrate the application of these optimization techniques in real-world scenarios.

Uploaded by

HAMZA AYUB
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
27 views16 pages

Managerial Economics, Optimization Techniques, Chapter 3

Chapter Three of Managerial Economics focuses on optimization techniques for maximizing or minimizing a firm's objective function, utilizing differential calculus and the concept of derivatives. It discusses both unconstrained and constrained optimization methods, including the substitution method and the Lagrange multiplier method, to solve complex decision problems faced by managers. The chapter provides examples to illustrate the application of these optimization techniques in real-world scenarios.

Uploaded by

HAMZA AYUB
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 16

Managerial Economics Chapter Three

CHAPTER THREE OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES


1. INTRODUCTION
In this chapter, we present methods for maximizing or minimizing the objective function
of a firm or other organizations. The first step in presenting optimization techniques is to
examine ways to express economic relationships (functional relationships and economic
models). The concept of derivative and the rules of differentiation, and their application
in finding optimal solution to firm’s optimization problem (unconstrained or constrained)
is analyzed here.
1.2. OPTIMIZATION ANALYSIS
Optimization (Maximization and Minimization) refers to finding the best way to allocate
resources given an objective function. For example, given the firm’s objective of
maximizing profits (Total Revenue – Total Cost), we determine how much output should
be produced.

DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS: THE DERIVATIVE AND RULES OF DIFFERENTIATION


Optimization analysis can be conducted more efficiently and precisely with differential calculus, which
relies on the concept of the derivative.
1.3. THE CONCEPT OF THE DERIVATIVE
Suppose we have a function y = f(x) the first derivative of the function with respect to x
(denoted as dx/dy) is given by the change in y over the change in x, as the change in x
approaches zero.

1
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

1.4. RULES OF DIFFERENTIATION


Differentiation is the process of determining the derivative of a function, i.e., finding the
change in y for a change in x, when the change in x approaches zero.
 Rule 1: Constant Function Rule

Note that the value of y is constant, and it does not change for any value of x.
 Rule 2: Power - Function Rule

 Rule 3: Sums and Difference Rule

2
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

 Rule 4: Product Rule

 Rule 5: Quotient Rule

3
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

 Rule 6: Chain Rule

4
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Summary of Rules for Differentiating Functions

1.5. USE OF CALCULUS IN OPTIMIZATION


Here the point at which a function is maximum or minimum is determined. We then show
how to distinguish between a maximum and a minimum. Optimization often requires

5
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
finding the maximum or the minimum value of a function (e.g., maximum profit,
maximum revenue, or minimum cost).
1.6. UNCONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION
1). First-Order Condition:
When a function is at maximum or minimum, the first derivative (dx/dy) equals to zero.
This is a necessary condition for a maximum or minimum, but it is not a sufficient condition
to determine if the function is at a minimum or a maximum.
2). Second-Order Condition:
The test for a maximum or a minimum using the second derivative is called the second
order condition. The first and second - order conditions together are sufficient to test for
either a maximum or a minimum point.

Example: 1

Find the level of output, Q, that maximize profit (Π)


Solution

Where the profit function is at maximum, first-order-condition

6
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Second-order condition for maximum:

Since the second derivative of the profit function is -2, we conclude that the profit is
maximized at Q = 8.
Example: 2

7
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Using quadratic formula: ax2 + bx + c = 0

8
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

1.7. CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION


Unfortunately, most decision problems managers faced are not of the unconstrained
variety just discussed. The manager often is required to maximize some objective function
subject to one or more side constraints. A production manager, for example, may be
required to maximize the total output of a given commodity subject to a given budget
constraint and fixed prices of factors of production. Alternatively, the manager might be
required to minimize the total costs of producing some specified level of output. The cost
minimization problem might be written as:

There are generally two methods of solving constrained optimization problems:


1. The substitution method
2. The Lagrange multiplier method

9
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
1. SUBSTITUTION METHOD

The substitution method involves first solving the constraint, say for x, and substituting
the result into the original objective function. Consider, again, the foregoing example.
Example:
The total cost function of a firm that produces its product on two assembly lines is given
as

Solution:

In other words, this problem reduces to one of solving for one decision variable, y, and
inserting the solution into the objective function. Taking the first derivative of the objective
function with respect to y and setting the result equal to zero, we get

Note also that the second-order condition for total cost minimization is also satisfied:

10
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Substituting y = 7 into the constraint yields

Finally, substituting the values of x and y into the original TC function Yields:

2. LAGRANGE MULTIPLIER METHOD


Sometimes the substitution method may not be feasible because of more than one side
constraint, or because the objective function or side constraints are too complex for
efficient solution. Here, the Lagrange Multiplier Method can be used, which directly
combines the objective function with the side constraint(s).
The first step in applying the Lagrange multiplier technique is to first bring all terms to the
right side of the equation.

With this, we can now form a new objective function called the Lagrange function, which
will be used in subsequent chapters to find solution values to constrained optimization:

Note that this expression is equal to the original objective function, since all we have done
is add zero to it. That is, L always equals f for values of x and y that satisfy g. To solve for

11
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
optimal values of x and y, we now take the first partials of this more complicated
expression with respect to three unknowns x, y, and . The first-order conditions therefore
become:

Note that the values for x and y are the same as those obtained using the substitution
method. The Lagrange multiplier technique is more powerful, however, because we are
also able to solve for the Lagrange multiplier, . What is the interpretation of ?
It can be demonstrated that the Lagrange multiplier is defined as

That is, the Lagrange multiplier is the marginal change in the maximum value of the
objective function with respect to parametric changes in the value of the constraint. In the
context of the present example, = -71 says that if we relax our production constraint by,
say, one unit of output (i.e., if we reduce output from 20 units to 19 units), our total cost
of production will decline by 71 Birr. It is important to note that because marginal cost is
a nonlinear function, the value of  may be interpreted only in the neighborhood of Q =
20. In other words, the value of  will vary at different output levels.

Example 1
A profit-maximizing firm faces the following constrained maximization problem:

12
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Determine profit-maximizing output levels of commodities x and y subject to the condition


that total output equals 12 units.

13
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Example 2
Cost minimization

14
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

Example 3

15
Managerial Economics Chapter Three

16

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy