Managerial Economics, Optimization Techniques, Chapter 3
Managerial Economics, Optimization Techniques, Chapter 3
1
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
Note that the value of y is constant, and it does not change for any value of x.
Rule 2: Power - Function Rule
2
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
3
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
4
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
5
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
finding the maximum or the minimum value of a function (e.g., maximum profit,
maximum revenue, or minimum cost).
1.6. UNCONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION
1). First-Order Condition:
When a function is at maximum or minimum, the first derivative (dx/dy) equals to zero.
This is a necessary condition for a maximum or minimum, but it is not a sufficient condition
to determine if the function is at a minimum or a maximum.
2). Second-Order Condition:
The test for a maximum or a minimum using the second derivative is called the second
order condition. The first and second - order conditions together are sufficient to test for
either a maximum or a minimum point.
Example: 1
6
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
Since the second derivative of the profit function is -2, we conclude that the profit is
maximized at Q = 8.
Example: 2
7
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
8
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
9
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
1. SUBSTITUTION METHOD
The substitution method involves first solving the constraint, say for x, and substituting
the result into the original objective function. Consider, again, the foregoing example.
Example:
The total cost function of a firm that produces its product on two assembly lines is given
as
Solution:
In other words, this problem reduces to one of solving for one decision variable, y, and
inserting the solution into the objective function. Taking the first derivative of the objective
function with respect to y and setting the result equal to zero, we get
Note also that the second-order condition for total cost minimization is also satisfied:
10
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
Finally, substituting the values of x and y into the original TC function Yields:
With this, we can now form a new objective function called the Lagrange function, which
will be used in subsequent chapters to find solution values to constrained optimization:
Note that this expression is equal to the original objective function, since all we have done
is add zero to it. That is, L always equals f for values of x and y that satisfy g. To solve for
11
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
optimal values of x and y, we now take the first partials of this more complicated
expression with respect to three unknowns x, y, and . The first-order conditions therefore
become:
Note that the values for x and y are the same as those obtained using the substitution
method. The Lagrange multiplier technique is more powerful, however, because we are
also able to solve for the Lagrange multiplier, . What is the interpretation of ?
It can be demonstrated that the Lagrange multiplier is defined as
That is, the Lagrange multiplier is the marginal change in the maximum value of the
objective function with respect to parametric changes in the value of the constraint. In the
context of the present example, = -71 says that if we relax our production constraint by,
say, one unit of output (i.e., if we reduce output from 20 units to 19 units), our total cost
of production will decline by 71 Birr. It is important to note that because marginal cost is
a nonlinear function, the value of may be interpreted only in the neighborhood of Q =
20. In other words, the value of will vary at different output levels.
Example 1
A profit-maximizing firm faces the following constrained maximization problem:
12
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
13
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
Example 2
Cost minimization
14
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
Example 3
15
Managerial Economics Chapter Three
16