IFM Lecture10
IFM Lecture10
That is, if the spot exchange rate turns out to be $0.80/AUD, the
buyer and seller neither makes money nor loses money.
American Option-Pricing Relationships
• American options will satisfy the following basic pricing relationships
at time t prior to expiration:
!! ≥ Max &$ − (, 0 +! ≥ Max ( − &$ , 0
• The above equations state that the American call and put premiums
at time t will be at least as large as the immediate exercise value, or
the intrinsic value, of the call or put option
• A longer-term American option will have a market price at least as
large as the short-term option.
American Option-Pricing Relationships
• Difference between the option premium and the option’s intrinsic
value is nonnegative and is sometimes referred to as the option’s
time value.
• For example, the time value for an American call option is:
!! − Max &$ − (, 0
• The time value exists because the option may move more in-the-
money, and thus become more valuable, as time elapses.
Market Value, Time Value, and Intrinsic Value
of an American Call Option
European Option-Pricing Relationships
• Pricing boundaries for European put and call premiums are more complex.
• Consider two portfolios:
• Portfolio A involves purchasing a European call option (with exercise price % and
premium &! ) and lending (or investing) an amount equal to the present value of
the exercise price, E, at the U.S. interest rate, '$ , which we assume corresponds to
the length of the investment period.
• Cost of this investment is: !! + #/(1 + '$ )
• Payoffs of the call option:
• If #! ≤ %, call owner will let call option expire worthless.
• If #! > %, call owner will exercise the call, and exercise value will be #! − % > 0.
• Payoffs of the risk-free loan:
• % regardless of which state occurs at time ).
#, ,# ≤ #
Payoff of the Por8olio A = *
,# , ,# > #
European Option-Pricing Relationships
• Consider two portfolios (continued):
• Portfolio B consists of lending the present value of one unit of foreign currency, (,
at the foreign interest rate, '* , which we assume corresponds to the length of the
investment period.
• Cost of this investment is: S$ /(1 + '% )
,# , ,# ≤ #
• Payoffs of the risk-free loan: Payoff of the Por8olio B = *
,# , ,# > #
• #! regardless of which state occurs at time ).
Based on these two equations, it can be determined that, when all else
remains the same, the call premium *# (put premium, +# ) will increase:
• The larger (smaller) is the exchange rate, !$ .
• The smaller (larger) is the exercise price, #.
• The smaller (larger) is the foreign interest rate, ,% .
• The larger (smaller) is the dollar interest rate, ,$ .
• The larger (smaller) ,$ is relative to ,% .
European Option-Pricing Relationships
• From the IRP relationship, -! = !$ (1 + ,$ )/ 1 + ,% , European call
and put prices on spot foreign exchange can be restated as:
3#
(1 + '$ )
), % (9+ − %)
&! ≥ Max − ,0 &! ≥ Max ,0
(1 + '* ) (1 + '$ ) (1 + '$ )
% ), (% − 9+ )
8! ≥ Max − ,0 8! ≥ Max ,0
(1 + '$ ) (1 + '* ) (1 + '$ )
Problem 3
Solution 3
• Intrinsic value of an American call option: Max $" − &, 0
• "$ = 92.04; ) = 93;
• Max 92.04 − 93, 0 = 0
• Intrinsic value of an American put option: Max & − $" , 0
• Max 93 − 92.04, 0 = 0.96 cents per 100 yen.
• Time value of an American call option: )# − Max $" − &, 0
• !! = 2.10
• Time value = 2.10 − Max 92.04 − 93, 0 = 2.10 cents per 100 yen.
• Time value of an American put option: *# − Max & − $" , 0
• 3! = 2.20
• Time value = 2.20 − Max 93 − 92.04, 0 = 1.24 cents per 100 yen.