0% found this document useful (0 votes)
14 views24 pages

Understanding Public Policy

The document discusses the evolution of public policy and planning in India, highlighting the transition from the Planning Commission to NITI Aayog, which was established in 2015 to enhance cooperative federalism and strategic policy-making. It outlines the historical influences on India's planning model, including socialist ideologies and the impact of early nationalist thinkers, while also critiquing the failures of past economic strategies, particularly the reliance on import substitution industrialization. The document emphasizes the need for effective planning to address key economic constraints and improve living standards, noting significant poverty reduction during the 10th and 11th Five-Year Plans.

Uploaded by

akshita.2023.71
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
14 views24 pages

Understanding Public Policy

The document discusses the evolution of public policy and planning in India, highlighting the transition from the Planning Commission to NITI Aayog, which was established in 2015 to enhance cooperative federalism and strategic policy-making. It outlines the historical influences on India's planning model, including socialist ideologies and the impact of early nationalist thinkers, while also critiquing the failures of past economic strategies, particularly the reliance on import substitution industrialization. The document emphasizes the need for effective planning to address key economic constraints and improve living standards, noting significant poverty reduction during the 10th and 11th Five-Year Plans.

Uploaded by

akshita.2023.71
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 24

‭Regardless of the form of governance—whether monarchical or aristocratic, totalitarian or‬

‭democratic—public policies have been formulated and implemented across almost all systems of‬
‭governance. Since the primary objective of politics and administration is to achieve good governance‬
‭and the good life, the study and analysis of public policy becomes especially significant. Marshall‬
‭DeMonk defines policy as a consciously accepted code of conduct that guides administrative‬
‭decisions. It is noteworthy that the policy-making process has always been an essential element of‬
‭political and administrative activities. From this perspective, public policies are as old as‬
‭governments themselves.‬

‭Thomas R. Dye, in his seminal work‬‭Understanding Public Policy‬‭(1975), defines public policy as those‬
‭decisions and actions taken—or not taken—by the government. Paul H. Appleby, recognizing the‬
‭interrelation between administration and policy, asserted that “the essence of public administration‬
‭is policy-making.” Public policies are primarily developed by governmental structures and officials,‬
‭although non-governmental organizations and institutions also exert both direct and indirect‬
‭influence on the policy-making process. In essence, public policies are government decisions arising‬
‭from actions undertaken to achieve specific goals and objectives. Understanding the nature of public‬
‭policy requires highlighting some of its key characteristics, as contextualized by Sushant Jha (2015).‬

‭In India, developmental work and schemes have historically been executed according to the‬
‭five-year plans formulated by the Planning Commission, which was established on 15 March 1950.‬
‭However, with changing economic and social dynamics, the Planning Commission was replaced by a‬
‭new institution, the NITI Aayog, which was constituted on 1 January 2015 through a resolution of the‬
‭Union Cabinet. NITI Aayog serves as the principal policy-oriented think tank of the Government of‬
‭India, offering policy direction and guidance. In addition to formulating long-term strategies and‬
‭programs for the government, NITI Aayog provides strategic and technical advice to the Centre as‬
‭well as to the States and Union Territories.‬

‭NITI Aayog serves as a crucial platform for cooperative federalism by bringing states together to‬
‭work in the national interest. As per the NITI Aayog Report (2022), the Honorable Prime Minister‬
‭Narendra Modi currently serves as the Chairman, while Mr. Suman Berry holds the position of Vice‬
‭Chairman (NITI Aayog Report, 2022–2023). The formal conclusion of the Planning Commission's role‬
‭in governance was announced by Prime Minister Modi during his Independence Day address from‬
‭the historic Red Fort on 15 August 2014—India’s 67th Independence Anniversary. In January 2015,‬
‭with the establishment of NITI Aayog, India laid the foundation for a new indigenous ideological‬
‭revolution by forming the National Institution for Transforming India.‬

‭It is important to note that industrialized countries have demonstrated that capitalism is not‬
‭inconsistent with planning. In India (and elsewhere), the association of central planning with‬
‭socialism is understandable, especially given that Jawaharlal Nehru, India's first Prime Minister, was‬
‭a Fabian Socialist who was significantly influenced by the achievements of the Soviet Union in the‬
‭decades following its 1917 revolution. This socialist influence was also visible in the tenure of Indira‬
‭Gandhi—Nehru’s daughter and India’s third Prime Minister (1967–1977 and again from‬
‭1980–1984)—who amended the Indian Constitution to include the term “socialist republic” in its‬
‭Preamble. It now reads: “We, the People of India, having solemnly resolved to constitute India into a‬
‭sovereign socialist secular democratic republic…” (emphasis added).‬

‭However, there was little substantive evidence of socialism in her policies. Indira Gandhi equated an‬
‭increase in public sector enterprises and the nationalization of private banks in 1969 with socialism.‬
‭Yet, state intervention or ownership alone does not constitute socialism. India was essentially a‬
‭mixed economy—marked by a growing public sector in industry during the first three decades of‬
‭planned development, and a blend of semi-feudalism and capitalism in the organization of agrarian‬
‭relations (Bhaduri 1973; Bharadwaj 1974).‬

‭India’s economy performed reasonably well under the state-driven model during its first fifteen‬
‭years. Between 1951 and 1965, during the first three five-year plans, industry grew faster than‬
‭during the colonial era, primarily due to an import-substitution industrialization (ISI) strategy. This‬
‭was widely considered an appropriate development approach at the time and was adopted by many‬
‭developing countries. However, problems arose when this ISI strategy was retained well beyond its‬
‭effective period—largely due to early socialist-leaning influences and strong anti-colonial sentiment‬
‭(Bhagwati and Panagariya 2012). This prolonged adherence to ISI contributed to the failure of India's‬
‭economic strategy, but it should not be mistaken for a failure of planning per se.‬

‭Many East and Southeast Asian countries also implemented five-year plans, combining ISI with‬
‭export-oriented, labor-intensive industrial strategies. Planning played a vital role in their economic‬
‭"miracles," largely because they ensured the productive use of their most abundant‬
‭resource—labor—through export-driven manufacturing. India, by contrast, neglected this strategy. It‬
‭failed to produce for international markets during a time when the global economy (especially‬
‭Europe, North America, and Japan) was expanding rapidly. Instead, it focused inwardly on its‬
‭domestic market, a strategy that faltered because it was not accompanied by adequate investment‬
‭in agriculture, which would have increased consumer demand for manufactured goods (Chakravarty‬
‭1987).‬

‭The prevailing belief was that institutional agrarian reforms—such as the abolition of the zamindari‬
‭system, imposition of land ceiling laws, and land consolidation—would be sufficient to foster‬
‭equitable growth. However, this proved illusory. The real failure lay in the policy strategy itself, which‬
‭did not correctly identify or address the economy's key constraints—especially the lack of consumer‬
‭demand. Poor strategy and the use of crude policy instruments should not be mistaken for the‬
‭failure of planning as a concept.‬

‭Another serious shortcoming of India’s development model was the neglect of school education and‬
‭public/preventive healthcare. These were not failures of planning itself, but rather catastrophic‬
‭failures of the strategies employed within the planning framework. Nonetheless, one of the clear‬
‭successes of early planning in India was the growth of heavy industry and capital goods sectors‬
‭under state ownership—similar to developments in the Soviet Union and China. These initiatives led‬
‭to the establishment of various industries in which private investors had shown little interest.‬

‭Although the Planning Commission had been in decline well before the current government’s‬
‭resounding electoral victory, its formal end was marked by the Prime Minister’s Independence Day‬
‭speech from the Red Fort. The creation of NITI Aayog in January 2015 signaled the beginning of a‬
‭new era in India’s policy-making, grounded in indigenous thinking and strategic planning.‬

‭Here is a refined version of your text. All details and facts have been preserved while improving‬
‭clarity, structure, grammar, and readability:‬

‭In the popular imagination, national planning in India is closely associated with the names of‬
‭Jawaharlal Nehru and P.C. Mahalanobis, often evoking images of Soviet-style centralization.‬
‭However, from a historical perspective, the roots of planning in India are deeply indigenous, dating‬
‭back to 19th-century nationalist thinkers like Dadabhai Naoroji, R.C. Dutt, and Mahadeo Govind‬
‭Ranade. These early intellectuals emphasized state-led industrialization as essential for eradicating‬
‭national poverty. They argued that private initiative alone was insufficient to generate the scale of‬
‭economic stimulus required and highlighted the state's role in mobilizing savings, expanding‬
‭banking infrastructure, and promoting higher education.‬

‭Socialist ideas gained traction within the Indian National Congress after the Russian Revolution. At‬
‭its 1931 Karachi session, the Congress officially adopted the goal of a “socialist pattern of‬
‭development” for India. Nehru and Subhas Chandra Bose, both rising young leaders, were‬
‭particularly committed to this vision. After becoming Congress president at the Haripura session in‬
‭1938, Bose established the National Planning Committee on December 17, 1938, appointing Nehru‬
‭as its chairman.‬

‭As the first Prime Minister of independent India, Nehru sought to design an economic future that‬
‭would ensure prosperity, internal stability, and national security. To him, the Soviet Union’s rapid‬
‭industrialization from 1928 to 1952 appeared far more promising than the slower, centuries-long‬
‭Industrial Revolution of Western Europe. Thus, Indian planning in the 1950s was undeniably‬
‭influenced by the Soviet model, though it was not limited to this.‬

‭Nehru’s thinking drew from four principal influences:‬

‭1.‬ ‭The Soviet planning experiment‬‭, particularly the first Five-Year Plan (1928–1933);‬

‭2.‬ ‭Western development economics‬‭, which gained prominence in the 1950s and focused on‬
‭market imperfections, surplus labor, increasing returns, and fixed investments;‬
‭3.‬ ‭Elements of Gandhian thought‬‭, particularly in areas where Nehru and Gandhi shared‬
‭views on national welfare, despite ideological differences; and‬

‭4.‬ ‭Indigenous economic thinkers and early Indian economists‬‭, who shaped his‬
‭understanding of India's specific challenges.‬

‭Planning, in its broadest sense, is a universal activity practiced by both the public and private‬
‭sectors. Private firms create strategic plans for growth, while states engage in planning‬
‭infrastructure, towns, and economic development. John Hackett (2011) defines economic planning‬
‭as “the process by which key economic decisions are made or influenced by central governments,”‬
‭contrasting it with laissez-faire economics that relies on market forces.‬

‭Economic planning varies by degree of state intervention. Taruna Rajora distinguishes between‬
‭forms such as‬‭planning by direction‬‭,‬‭planning by inducement‬‭,‬‭perspective planning‬‭,‬‭indicative planning‬‭,‬
‭democratic planning‬‭,‬‭fixed planning‬‭,‬‭centralized‬‭, and‬‭decentralized planning‬‭. The form depends on the‬
‭political-economic system—capitalist, socialist, or mixed.‬

‭From the 1920s onward, the Soviet Union embraced centralized planning. After World War II, most‬
‭developing and even some Western countries adopted explicit planning mechanisms. By the late‬
‭1960s, a majority of nations operated under some form of national economic plan. However, the‬
‭rise of neo-liberal ideology in the 1980s, marked by structural adjustment programs imposed by the‬
‭World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), led to a decline in planning institutions. In‬
‭many over-indebted countries of Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa, the role of state planning‬
‭diminished drastically. With the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991, planning fell into further‬
‭disrepute globally, often seen as partly responsible for that regime's failure.‬

‭Nevertheless, every East Asian “miracle” economy—from Japan and South Korea to Taiwan and‬
‭China—has consistently employed Five-Year Plans. China, despite its market reforms beginning in‬
‭1979, has maintained a strong planning apparatus. Its State Planning Commission, renamed the‬
‭National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) in 2003, remains central to economic and‬
‭social strategy. It not only formulates Five-Year Plans and annual plans but also plays a pivotal role in‬
‭implementation and acts as the key policymaking think tank for both the Communist Party of China‬
‭(CPC) and the State Council.‬

‭In Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan, governments played a crucial role in addressing “coordination‬
‭failures” in the economy by facilitating private sector development. These nations demonstrated‬
‭that successful planning could coexist with a vibrant market economy.‬

‭India adopted a mixed economy model where public and private sectors coexisted, but the‬
‭state—through the Planning Commission (PC)—played the leading role in allocating resources‬
‭across sectors. However, by the late 1980s, the PC was increasingly seen as irrelevant, relegated to‬
‭approving public investments and vetting major projects. Its strategic vision had largely vanished.‬

‭This began to shift in the 2000s. The Eleventh and Twelfth Five-Year Plans renewed focus on‬
‭inclusive growth, environmental sustainability, and industrial policy. Despite a change in institutional‬
‭nomenclature, the need for planning persisted. As Pronab Sen observed, even though the term‬
‭“plan” was avoided, the newly formed NITI Aayog was tasked with developing a 15-year vision, a‬
‭7-year strategy, and a 3-year action plan. Only the latter was prepared in 2017; the other two‬
‭documents did not materialize. Nevertheless, as of late 2019, a new 15-year vision to 2035 was‬
‭reportedly under development.‬

‭The overarching goal remained economic and social development, but the approach evolved.‬
‭Planning was evaluated by its success in improving living standards, building a productive base, and‬
‭advancing public health, sanitation, and education.‬

‭Living standards had stagnated in colonial India, but the GDP growth rate achieved during the first‬
‭five plans (1951–52 to 1979–80), including three Annual Plans (1966–1969 and 1979–80), averaged‬
‭3.5% per annum. This figure—coined the “Hindu rate of growth” by economist Raj Krishna—was‬
‭modest compared to East Asia, but comparable to China at the time. However, poverty reduction‬
‭remained minimal during this period. The population rose steadily while GDP growth lagged, leading‬
‭to a significant increase in the absolute number of poor, as defined by the Planning Commission’s‬
‭Lakdawala poverty line.‬

‭It was only during the 10th and 11th Plans (2003–2014) that significant poverty reduction occurred.‬
‭GDP growth averaged an unprecedented 8% annually from 2004–05 to 2013–14. For the first time,‬
‭the number of people living below the poverty line dropped sharply—from 406 million in 2004–05 to‬
‭268 million in 2011–12, based on the Tendulkar poverty line.‬

‭Regarding the objective of “building the productive machine,” success in industrial diversification‬
‭was notable. As T.N. Ahluwalia (1997) observed, the share of consumer goods in industrial output‬
‭fell from 50% in 1956 to 30% by 1980–81, while capital goods rose from under 5% to 15% in the‬
‭same period. Another major achievement was resource mobilization. According to World Bank data‬
‭from the early 1980s, India ranked high among low-income countries in savings rates—behind only‬
‭China and Indonesia—although this was primarily driven by private, not public, savings.‬

‭However, there were multiple failures in planning when it came to "building a productive machine."‬
‭The Mahalanobis model, which formed the basis of the import substitution industrialization (ISI)‬
‭strategy in the Second Five-Year Plan (1956–1961), notably neglected the role of foreign trade. As‬
‭Ahluwalia rightly points out, the ISI strategy made no reference to relative costs. Moreover, the‬
‭model assumed that the government would have total control over consumption. Another key‬
‭assumption was that the capital goods sector would generate surpluses and contribute “increasingly‬
‭towards resource mobilisation for further development in fresh fields,” as stated in the Industrial‬
‭Policy Resolution of 1956. These assumptions collectively formed the Indian planning strategy for‬
‭industrialization. In hindsight, they proved to be costly—especially the neglect of foreign trade.‬

‭The import intensity of industrialization was severely underestimated, leading to a chronic shortage‬
‭of foreign exchange. With exports remaining low, India could not finance industrialization through‬
‭imported equipment. Just when East Asian countries were capitalizing on growing post-war‬
‭international demand, India’s policymakers clung to a mindset of export pessimism. This, along with‬
‭an over-reliance on import substitution—despite unfavorable relative costs—undermined India's‬
‭industrial strategy. This export pessimism was rooted in the Prebisch-Singer thesis, which warned of‬
‭declining terms of trade for developing countries.‬

‭This approach also had other drawbacks. It limited labor absorption and led to a slow increase in the‬
‭supply of consumer goods in the short and medium term. As Ahluwalia (1997: 260) noted, by the‬
‭mid-1960s it was becoming increasingly clear that the premise of export pessimism was flawed.‬
‭Many developing economies changed course during this period—but India, along with several Latin‬
‭American countries, continued to hold onto this pessimism, making it a self-fulfilling prophecy.‬
‭Ahluwalia also highlighted the disregard for the infant industry argument, which advocates for‬
‭time-bound and calibrated protection of new industries. Instead, protection was granted‬
‭indiscriminately to any industry that established domestic capacity, with no consideration of‬
‭comparative advantage or performance.‬

‭From the First Five-Year Plan onwards, planning emphasized the role of small-scale industries (SSIs)‬
‭in industrialization. The Planning Commission justified this focus for three main reasons: (a) SSIs,‬
‭especially cottage and village industries like handlooms and handicrafts, would generate‬
‭employment; (b) they would prevent concentration of economic power; and (c) they would ensure‬
‭regional dispersal of industry. The state promoted small enterprises while restricting the growth of‬
‭large ones through production licensing.‬

‭Initially, the first three Plans focused on promoting SSIs. However, starting in 1967, the focus shifted‬
‭to protecting them from competition by reserving specific products for SSIs. By the Fourth Plan‬
‭(1969–1974), this approach was firmly in place, and by 1991, 836 products were reserved for SSIs.‬
‭Financial incentives and protective measures, while well-intentioned, discouraged SSIs from scaling‬
‭up, leading to the emergence of a “missing middle” in Indian industry (Mehrotra et al., 2014). This‬
‭contributed to the growing informality in both industry and services. Instead of evolving into‬
‭medium-sized enterprises, millions of micro-enterprises remained small, informal, and outside the‬
‭tax net. These enterprises relied on low technology, offered low wages, and were trapped in a cycle‬
‭of low productivity and low growth.‬

‭A better strategy would have been an integrated approach that simultaneously encouraged both‬
‭small- and large-scale industries, as suggested in the Second and Third Plans and reaffirmed in the‬
‭Sixth and Seventh Plans. This dual-track strategy, successfully employed in Japan, was never truly‬
‭implemented in India.‬
‭Efforts to achieve regional dispersal of industry through planning were also largely ineffective due to‬
‭inappropriate instruments. Ahluwalia (1997) observed that the early Plans rightly emphasized‬
‭infrastructure development as the basis for dispersing industry. However, this approach was later‬
‭replaced with industrial licensing and, worse, with financial incentives during the Fourth Plan to‬
‭attract industry to backward regions. Without adequate infrastructure, these incentives failed to‬
‭produce meaningful results.‬

‭Planning was particularly weak in the social sectors—health, sanitation, and education. Drèze and‬
‭Sen (2013) have chronicled India's poor performance in these areas. In contrast, another planned‬
‭economy—China—achieved far superior social indicators over its first three decades of planning‬
‭(1949–1979). In India, weak strategies and poorly chosen instruments led to severe deficiencies.‬
‭Sanitation, for instance, was seriously neglected. By 2014, half of India’s population defecated in the‬
‭open, accounting for 60% of the global population doing so—despite India comprising only 17% of‬
‭the world’s population. This led to rampant oral–faecal contamination, contributing to some of the‬
‭world's worst rates of malnutrition, worse even than Sub-Saharan Africa.‬

‭As of 2015–2016, India’s child malnutrition rate was 36%, and stunting was at 39%, with India‬
‭accounting for half of the world’s undernourished children. Adult malnutrition was also high at 21%.‬
‭Yet, government spending on health remained just 1.15% of GDP in 2017. Human capital formation‬
‭was similarly neglected: by 2011, India had nearly 310 million illiterate people—almost equal to its‬
‭total population in 1947.‬

‭While these failures cannot be blamed solely on the Planning Commission, it did become more‬
‭involved in social policy after 1991. Economic growth post-liberalization led to increased tax‬
‭revenues, allowing for higher spending on centrally sponsored schemes (CSSs). These included the‬
‭National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme and targeted health and education programs.‬
‭Designed in consultation with central ministries, these schemes were a hallmark of the PC’s social‬
‭role. However, their “one-size-fits-all” design ignored growing disparities among states in social‬
‭outcomes.‬

‭This expanded role of the Planning Commission came after the 1991 economic reforms. But‬
‭ironically, as social planning gained importance, the more powerful economic ministries—especially‬
‭the Ministry of Finance—came to dominate policymaking. This was unfortunate, as effective human‬
‭development depends on coordinated interventions across health, nutrition, education, sanitation,‬
‭and family planning (Mehrotra and Delamonica 2007; Mehrotra and Jolly 1997; Mehrotra 2016). The‬
‭absence of such coordination has undermined India’s human development outcomes. A revitalized‬
‭Planning Commission—or its successor, NITI Aayog—must take up this coordinating role.‬

‭Despite its limitations, the Planning Commission had two periods of significant influence: the early‬
‭years of industrialization, and the post-1991 period of social policy expansion. It is understandable‬
‭that a government with a new mandate would wish to leave its mark on the country’s institutional‬
‭framework. The creation of NITI Aayog (National Institution for Transforming India) marked both a‬
‭break from the past and the culmination of a gradual shift already underway.‬

‭Critics had long seen the Planning Commission as a rigid, bureaucratic body. The most dramatic‬
‭challenge to the planning regime came with the 1991 economic liberalization, which sought to‬
‭replace the state-dominated system with a market-driven one. Planning, once seen as central to‬
‭India’s economic strategy, now appeared incompatible with the opening up of the economy to‬
‭private enterprise and the removal of licensing controls. Yet, despite the radical shift in policy, the‬
‭institutional transformation from PC to NITI Aayog took nearly 25 years to materialize.‬

‭Emanating from the 1950 Planning Commission Resolution (PCR), the Planning Commission (PC)‬
‭gradually assumed three core functions over time:‬
‭(a) formulating Five-Year Plans (Function 2),‬
‭(b) allocating financial resources for the Plans (Function 3), and‬
‭(c) determining policies and programs, in coordination with Union ministries, consistent with the‬
‭Plan (Function 7), including appraisal of programs (Function 6).‬

‭For nearly 65 years, these remained the PC's central responsibilities—until it was abruptly disbanded‬
‭at the end of 2014. The PC typically allocated around 26% of the Union budget. This budgetary‬
‭allocation comprised three components: central sector schemes, centrally sponsored schemes, and‬
‭block grants. The remaining 75% of the Union budget—classified as the non-Plan component (e.g.,‬
‭subsidies, interest payments, and other committed expenditures)—was managed by the Ministry of‬
‭Finance.‬

‭Importantly, there was also consensus that the PC should refrain from short-term forecasts (e.g.,‬
‭quarterly revisions of growth or inflation). Instead, its focus should be on medium-term structural‬
‭issues. This structural focus aligns with the vision of the PC (and its successor) as the body‬
‭responsible for outlining the contours of industrial strategy, while implementation remains the‬
‭domain of line ministries such as the Department of Industrial Policy and Promotion, Department of‬
‭Commerce, Ministry of MSMEs, and the Department of Heavy Industries.‬

‭Hence, any future planning institution must prioritize industrial development, with its modelling‬
‭activities serving this strategic goal.‬

‭For over six decades, the Planning Commission held a venerable position in India’s economic and‬
‭political architecture—largely due to its foundation and early leadership under Jawaharlal Nehru. Its‬
‭prominence was rooted in a time when the state dominated the economy and a single political party‬
‭held sway across both the Centre and the states.‬

‭Over time, however, these foundational advantages eroded. Though the PC played a central role in‬
‭the initial industrial "big push," its prolonged emphasis on state-led heavy industry, in the Soviet‬
‭mold, led to relatively sluggish industrial and economic growth—especially when compared to the‬
‭rapid progress of East Asian nations.‬

‭Eventually, demands grew for a greater role for the market and private sector, culminating in the‬
‭landmark economic liberalization of 1991. This policy shift reduced the prominence of public‬
‭investment and the role of the PC. Simultaneously, India’s states began asserting themselves more‬
‭forcefully in economic governance, further diminishing the PC’s influence.‬

‭Despite these challenges, the PC made a concerted effort to adapt. Four major shifts characterized‬
‭its transformation over the 25 years following liberalization:‬

‭1.‬ ‭From comprehensive to‬‭indicative planning‬‭,‬

‭2.‬ ‭From‬‭state hegemony‬‭to accommodation of‬‭private sector expansion‬‭,‬

‭3.‬ ‭From planning for a‬‭producer state‬‭to that of a‬‭quasi-welfare state‬‭, and‬

‭4.‬ ‭From centralized control to‬‭coordinated planning‬‭within a framework of cooperative‬


‭federalism.‬

‭However, these adaptations did not satisfy growing criticisms. Ultimately, the PC was abolished in‬
‭2014 and replaced in 2015 by the‬‭NITI Aayog‬‭, envisioned as a think-tank rather than a‬
‭resource-allocating authority. This institutional overhaul followed a historic electoral victory that‬
‭brought a new government to power—one with a stronger orientation toward federalism and a‬
‭commitment to empowering states.‬

‭Crucially, the real driver behind this transformation was not any irremediable flaw within the PC, but‬
‭the‬‭cumulative rise in state power‬‭. This shift was most clearly reflected in the‬‭Fourteenth‬
‭Finance Commission’s‬‭recommendation to increase the states’ share in national tax revenues from‬
‭32% to 42%‬‭—a landmark move that significantly enhanced state autonomy.‬

‭While this decentralization is politically popular, it is worth noting a paradox: many states—often‬
‭governed by political dynasties or plagued by corruption—have shown‬‭reluctance to devolve‬
‭power further‬‭, especially to local bodies. In this context, the‬‭Goods and Services Tax (GST)‬‭holds‬
‭promise. By fostering a unified national market, the GST may promote greater integration and‬
‭coordination within India’s federal structure.‬

‭The Planning Experience in India‬

‭In recent years, there has been a tendency to view India’s development strategy as a continuous,‬
‭undifferentiated process, with little substantive variation from one plan to another. Nothing could‬
‭be further from the truth. Indian development strategies have evolved significantly across different‬
‭Five-Year Plans, shaped by the prevailing economic conditions and the challenges of the time. While‬
‭some of these changes were bold and innovative, others were more modest—but change was a‬
‭constant.‬

‭The First Five-Year Plan was more an agenda for national reconstruction than a true economic plan.‬
‭Emerging from the trauma of Partition, it focused on stabilizing a damaged economy. The Second‬
‭Five-Year Plan, however, marked the beginning of structured economic planning. Its primary‬
‭objective, set by political mandate, was to maximize the GDP growth rate within the limits of‬
‭available resources. At the time, the main constraint was the low domestic savings rate.‬
‭Conventional growth theories offered little optimism for rapid improvement.‬

‭The decision to treat the savings rate not merely as a constraint but also as an explicit objective was‬
‭influenced by Professor P.C. Mahalanobis—a technocrat rather than a politician. The emphasis on‬
‭building heavy industries through public investment served the dual purpose of industrialization and‬
‭increasing the economy’s savings rate. This approach was innovative and reflected the political‬
‭leadership’s confidence—especially that of Prime Minister Nehru—in the analytical capabilities of‬
‭technocrats. Planning began to be conceived over multiple time horizons: a 15-year perspective‬
‭plan, a five-year operative plan, and annual plans for detailed resource allocation.‬

‭By the time of the Third Plan, India faced growing balance of payments issues and a decline in global‬
‭primary product prices, prompting a strategic shift. A new constraint—foreign exchange—emerged,‬
‭alongside the existing savings constraint. Two approaches were considered: increasing exports or‬
‭reducing imports through domestic production. Boosting exports risked undermining the long-term‬
‭goal of raising the savings rate. Thus, the plan adopted‬‭import substitution‬‭as a strategy for‬
‭industrial growth. This aligned with both political aspirations for self-reliance and prevailing‬
‭economic theories skeptical of export-led growth. Despite its mixed legacy, this strategy garnered‬
‭considerable attention and was emulated by many developing countries.‬

‭Two key institutional developments also occurred during this period. First, the federal nature of‬
‭India’s Constitution necessitated decentralized planning. States were expected to prepare their own‬
‭plans within the framework of the national plan, supported technically by the Centre. Second,‬
‭import substitution required greater government intervention in industrial planning, leading to‬
‭detailed sectoral blueprints based on input–output models—even for private sector capacity‬
‭creation.‬

‭The Fourth Plan followed a period of economic hardship. Between 1965 and 1967, India experienced‬
‭severe droughts and food shortages. Simultaneously, foreign aid, including food assistance, was‬
‭withdrawn following the 1965 Indo-Pakistan War. These events brought‬‭food security‬‭to the‬
‭forefront of planning. The need to ensure adequate wage goods introduced a third constraint into‬
‭growth theory—the‬‭wage-goods constraint‬‭. Consequently, the Centre took a more active role in‬
‭agricultural development, a domain traditionally reserved for states. The Fourth Plan also‬
‭introduced early concepts of‬‭environmental sustainability‬‭, a theme that would only gain global‬
‭traction decades later.‬

‭The Fifth Plan was pivotal in recognizing that economic growth and industrialization alone would not‬
‭improve living standards for the poor. This led to a political shift in strategy, exemplified by Indira‬
‭Gandhi’s powerful slogan:‬‭"Garibi Hatao" (Remove Poverty)‬‭. The plan introduced the concepts of‬
‭minimum needs‬‭and targeted‬‭anti-poverty programmes‬‭. It also marked a departure from the‬
‭Mahalanobis model, reverting to the‬‭Harrod–Domar model‬‭, suggesting that savings had ceased to‬
‭be the dominant constraint and could once again be treated as a constraint rather than an objective.‬

‭The Sixth Plan explicitly acknowledged that the previous strategy had successfully raised the‬
‭national savings rate, making it no longer a binding constraint. Signs of‬‭excess industrial capacity‬
‭began to appear, prompting a strategic shift toward infrastructure and reduced focus on heavy‬
‭industries. This plan initiated a more‬‭technocratic‬‭approach, emphasizing realistic, rather than‬
‭visionary, targets—a trend that continued over the next three plans. During this time, political‬
‭enthusiasm for planning began to wane.‬

‭The Seventh Plan consolidated this shift and is often referred to as the‬‭"infrastructure plan"‬‭. It also‬
‭marked the beginning of a‬‭policy re-evaluation‬‭, with gradual movement toward a more‬‭liberal‬
‭trade regime‬‭and away from import substitution. Unlike earlier strategies, this change was‬
‭politically driven—spearheaded by Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi—though technocrats were‬
‭responsible for translating it into an operational framework. In retrospect, the associated risks were‬
‭not fully appreciated.‬

‭The Eighth Plan was disrupted by the‬‭1991 foreign exchange crisis‬‭, intensified by the Gulf War,‬
‭which led to wide-ranging‬‭economic reforms‬‭during a two-year plan holiday. This plan was India’s‬
‭first attempt at planning in a‬‭market-oriented economy‬‭. While the transition was incomplete, the‬
‭economy performed unexpectedly well, achieving an average annual growth of‬‭6.7%‬‭.‬

‭Despite methodological improvements, the‬‭Ninth Plan‬‭failed to sustain this momentum. It made‬


‭significant adjustments to reflect new realities, recognizing that‬‭private investment‬‭was central to‬
‭achieving plan targets, and that it depended heavily on a well-functioning‬‭financial sector‬‭. For the‬
‭first time,‬‭financial constraints‬‭were identified as distinct from savings constraints. Weak financial‬
‭institutions could inhibit the productive use of available investible resources. Another major shift‬
‭was the recognition that‬‭aggregate demand‬‭—rather than resource availability—could become a‬
‭growth constraint, necessitating the integration of‬‭fiscal policy‬‭into the planning framework.‬
‭However, this insight was not fully acted upon. Fiscal pressures from implementing the Fifth Pay‬
‭Commission’s recommendations led to a sharp decline in public investment, triggering an economic‬
‭slowdown. A series of agricultural failures and tight monetary policy compounded the problem.‬

‭The‬‭Tenth Plan‬‭marked a return to‬‭visionary planning‬‭after a long period of incrementalism.‬‭It set‬


‭ambitious goals:‬‭doubling per capita income‬‭in 10 years and‬‭creating 100 million jobs‬‭. This‬
‭reflected the growing challenge of providing employment to a rapidly expanding workforce, driven‬
‭by‬‭demographic changes‬‭. Although population growth was slowing, the working-age population‬
‭had peaked during the Ninth Plan. However, employment growth had fallen sharply since the 1990s.‬
‭If this trend continued, about 2.5 million people would be added to the ranks of the unemployed‬
‭each year—an unsustainable scenario. Recognizing regional disparities in labour force growth and‬
‭economic opportunity, the plan emphasized‬‭balanced regional development‬‭and included, for the‬
‭first time, a‬‭separate volume on state-level planning‬‭.‬

‭The‬‭Eleventh Plan‬‭built on the Tenth Plan’s emphasis on employment and infrastructure, and‬
‭introduced the idea of‬‭inclusive growth‬‭. It prioritized‬‭human development‬‭, especially in health‬
‭and skills. This foresight proved crucial, as skill shortages became widespread with the economy‬
‭growing at 9% annually. Despite rising incomes in rural areas, underemployment of unskilled and‬
‭semi-skilled workers remained a problem, prompting the plan to focus on expanding‬‭alternative‬
‭employment in rural areas‬‭. However, the Centre’s deeper involvement in areas traditionally‬
‭reserved for states became increasingly apparent. The plan’s trajectory was disrupted by the‬‭global‬
‭financial crisis of 2008–09‬‭and a‬‭severe drought in 2009‬‭, which hampered growth momentum.‬
‭Rising rural incomes led to greater demand for non-cereal foods, but inadequate supply caused‬
‭persistent food inflation‬‭.‬

‭The‬‭Twelfth Plan‬‭was formulated in an unfavourable environment. The global recovery was slow,‬
‭and India's growth had decelerated.‬‭Corporate investment‬‭—which had previously driven‬
‭growth—was weakening due to tight monetary policy and regulatory hurdles. By now, India’s‬
‭economy was deeply integrated with the global economy, and its fortunes could not be shaped in‬
‭isolation. Thus, this plan focused less on new initiatives and more on‬‭coherence in development‬
‭policy‬‭. Its basic priorities—such as employment, infrastructure, and human‬
‭development—remained largely unchanged from the Eleventh Plan.‬

‭The Lessons‬

‭The main learning from this experience is that the NITI Aayog needs to devote as careful‬
‭thought to the planning process as to formulating the strategic plan itself. This is not a‬
‭technical exercise, and involves a deep understanding of people and of organizational‬
‭behaviour. Some of the features of this process can be summarized as follows:‬
‭1. The prime minister should articulate the broad vision for the country, and not merely‬
‭endorse a suggestion put up by the bureaucracy.‬
‭2. The NITI Aayog should work out the components of this vision in terms of the objectives‬
‭and targets, and obtain full support of the prime minister. It may also be desirable to place‬
‭these before the Governing Council of the NITI Aayog for its endorsement.‬
‭3. The broad strategy for attaining the expanded vision should be worked out within the‬
‭NITI Aayog, keeping in mind the interrelationships and synergies that may exist among the‬
‭various objectives. This strategic plan should confine itself to strategy and not extend itself‬
‭to detailed design, which should be left to the lower tiers. This involves laying out the‬
‭objectives, the targets, the time path, and the resources. All else is detail, which is best‬
‭done by others.‬
‭4. In framing the implementation or action plan, the NITI Aayog should clearly specify which‬
‭interventions should be designed and controlled by the central ministries and which should‬
‭be left to the state governments with only financial support from the centre.‬
‭5. In the course of formulating the strategic plan, there will inevitably be serious differences‬
‭of opinion between the NITI Aayog and the ministries/ state governments. These‬
‭differences need to be resolved before the strategic plan is finalized. The resolution can‬
‭only be done at a level higher than that of the Aayog, and this role has to be played by the‬
‭chief executive officer (CEO).‬
‭6. Last, but not least, the NITI Aayog should consciously guard against developing hubris,‬
‭which inevitably leads to micro-prescriptions – the bane of the erstwhile Planning‬
‭Commission.‬

‭Becoming a Knowledge Bank‬

‭The original‬‭Planning Commission Report (1950)‬‭did not envision the Planning Commission (PC)‬
‭evolving into a‬‭knowledge hub‬‭. Yet this was a natural role that should have emerged over‬
‭time—but didn’t. In 1950, most Indian states were at comparable levels of income and development.‬
‭Over time, however, some states progressed rapidly while others lagged. These divergent‬
‭experiences made Indian states a‬‭laboratory of development practice‬‭, rich with lessons that could‬
‭have been shared.‬

‭No institution was better positioned than the PC to collect and disseminate successful policies and‬
‭programmes. Doing so would have required domain expertise to identify best practices and engage‬
‭effectively with states. Unfortunately, this role was never embraced—partly because its value went‬
‭unrecognized, and partly due to the‬‭decline of domain expertise‬‭within the Commission's senior‬
‭bureaucracy. As a result—and likely for additional unstated reasons—the Planning Commission was‬
‭ultimately‬‭superseded in 2014‬

‭Why Planning? The Contemporary Argument (Refined)‬

‭When the Planning Commission (PC) was dismantled, the government offered no substantial‬
‭justification—only simplistic claims. Chief among them was that India, as an open economy in a‬
‭globalized world, no longer needed a centralized, "Soviet-style" planning institution. This argument is‬
‭flawed for several reasons.‬
‭First, the Planning Commission never practiced Soviet-style centralized planning, even during the‬
‭Mahalanobis era. A significant portion of India’s economy has always been privately driven. More‬
‭importantly, the nature of Five-Year Plans evolved significantly over time—from prescriptive to‬
‭indicative planning, as several contributors to this volume have noted.‬

‭Second, while markets are undeniably important, they also fail. Traditional arguments for state‬
‭intervention to correct market failures remain valid. In India's context, a large segment of the‬
‭population cannot meaningfully participate in the market economy. Addressing their needs cannot‬
‭be achieved through fragmented "schemes"; it demands a cohesive and integrated plan. A planning‬
‭institution must work alongside markets—strengthening them where they are weak and‬
‭supplementing them where they fall short. This remains a compelling rationale for planning,‬
‭regardless of the prevailing enthusiasm for market-based solutions—ironically championed by many‬
‭senior bureaucrats themselves.‬

‭Planning is also essential for inclusive development and for realizing the full potential of India’s‬
‭demographic dividend‬‭. This window of opportunity will‬‭remain open for only two more decades. A‬
‭well-crafted national plan is necessary to guide investments in health, education, and employment‬
‭to harness this demographic shift effectively.‬

‭A second compelling reason for maintaining a strong central planning institution is the need to‬
‭sustain‬‭high GDP growth‬‭over a prolonged period. Between‬‭2003–04 and 2011–12, India achieved‬
‭an average growth rate of 8.4% (at factor cost, 2004–05 base year). Since then, growth has been‬
‭volatile and generally below potential, rarely exceeding 7% annually (at 2011–12 market prices).‬
‭Sustained, high growth is critical to capitalize on India’s demographic advantage and avoid the fate‬
‭of many middle-income countries.‬

‭East Asian economies‬‭, notably South Korea and Taiwan,‬‭sustained rapid growth for 15–20 years;‬
‭China‬‭did so for over three decades—an achievement‬‭unparalleled in economic history. Their‬
‭success in navigating the so-called‬‭middle-income‬‭trap‬‭was due in large part to active, adaptive‬
‭industrial policies driven by strong planning institutions, such as China’s State Planning Commission.‬

‭The middle-income trap, as described in the 2018 Economic Survey, is akin to a pair of scissors. On‬
‭one blade, rising wages push countries out of low-cost manufacturing sectors, which are taken over‬
‭by poorer, cheaper economies like Vietnam, Bangladesh, and Cambodia. On the other blade, these‬
‭middle-income countries often lack the institutional, technological, and human capital to transition‬
‭into higher-value sectors. Squeezed from both above and below, they struggle to progress beyond‬
‭middle-income status.‬

‭The global context post-2008 presents additional challenges. Global growth rates have‬
‭declined—from 4.3% in the decade preceding the financial crisis to 2.9% in the decade following it.‬
‭For late industrializers like India, four key post-crisis trends may further undermine long-term‬
‭growth prospects:‬
‭1.‬ ‭Retreat from globalization‬‭: India must maintain export and GDP growth despite rising‬
‭protectionism and a slowdown in global trade integration. Earlier convergers, such as Japan,‬
‭South Korea, and China, benefited from a surge in world trade, enabling them to grow‬
‭exports at over 15% annually during their convergence phases. Since 2011, however, the‬
‭world trade-to-GDP ratio has fallen, limiting India's ability to replicate this model.‬
‭Nonetheless, India's low service-sector wages and the fragmentation of global value chains‬
‭present some ongoing opportunities for export-led growth.‬

‭2.‬ ‭Stagnant manufacturing sector‬‭: Manufacturing is crucial‬‭for structural transformation due‬


‭to its capacity for‬‭unconditional convergence‬‭with‬‭global productivity levels (Rodrik, 2015).‬
‭Yet India’s manufacturing-to-GDP ratio has hovered below 17% for over 25 years since‬
‭liberalization began in 1991. The advent of‬‭Industry‬‭4.0‬‭further complicates matters. A‬
‭robust‬‭industrial policy‬‭—outlined in Chapter 11—is‬‭vital to raise productivity and support‬
‭manufacturing growth.‬

‭3.‬ ‭Low human capital‬‭: Unlike early industrializers, India‬‭failed to provide widespread basic‬
‭education early in its development journey. This failure now hinders structural‬
‭transformation, especially in an era where‬‭technology‬‭increasingly favors skilled labor‬‭.‬
‭The convergence of educated but relatively unskilled labor with manufacturing—central to‬
‭East Asia’s growth—is missing in India. As the Economic Survey rightly notes, building a‬
‭learning society‬‭(Stiglitz, 2014) is essential, requiring‬‭adaptable and continuously upskilled‬
‭human capital.‬

‭4.‬ ‭Climate-change-induced agricultural stress‬‭: Agriculture,‬‭a backbone of India’s rural‬


‭economy, is increasingly vulnerable. Although agricultural growth averaged just over 4%‬
‭between 2004 and 2014, it dropped to 2.7% between 2014 and 2018. A long-term study‬
‭(Mallya et al., 2016) found that drought severity and frequency have increased in India.‬
‭Agricultural productivity growth has stagnated at around 3% annually over the last 30 years.‬
‭Climate variability could reduce farmer incomes by 20–25% in rain-fed regions,‬
‭compounding rural distress.‬

‭BACKGROUND OF NITI AAYOG‬

‭After gaining independence from colonial rule in 1947 AD, a serious challenge before‬
‭India was what type of governance system it should adopt to ensure the development‬
‭of India. In such a situation, India considered it inappropriate to adopt a purely socialist‬
‭model and also did not consider a completely capitalist form of governance appropriate.‬
‭Therefore, according to its needs, even in this mixed form of governance, India was‬
‭more inclined towards socialism rather than capitalism.‬
‭During this period, India had kept its socialist inclination towards the then, Soviet‬
‭Union and India had adopted the format of five-year plans on the basis of the governance‬
‭system of the, then Soviet Union and had dreamed of the development of the country‬
‭on this basis. To fulfill this dream related to the development of India, the then‬
‭Government of India formed an executive body named - “Planning Commission, it‬
‭was formed on 15 March 1950 under the leadership of the first Prime Minister of‬
‭India, Jawaharlal Nehru, by the then Government of India was done through executive‬
‭order. Thus, the Planning Commission was an executive institution.‬
‭The Planning Commission was given the main task of preparing five-year plans‬
‭related to the development of the country. Apart from this, the Planning Commission‬
‭also recommended to the government how much financial assistance should be given‬
‭by the Center to the states for the implementation of those five-year plans. On this‬
‭basis, it can be said that the Planning Commission was an important institution to‬
‭ensure the development of the country.‬
‭In the year 2014, the NDA government formed under the leadership of Prime‬
‭Minister Modi, through a new executive order in January 2015, abolished the already‬
‭existing Planning Commission and formed NITI Aayog in its place.‬
‭Structure of NITI Aayog: Through a resolution of the Council of Ministers on 1 January 2015,‬
‭the Government of India constituted NITI Aayog. The Prime Minister is the Chairman of NITI‬
‭Aayog. The Governing Council will include the Chief Ministers‬
‭of all the states and the Lieutenant Governors of all the Union Territories. Regional‬
‭Councils (State will be established to deal with area specific problems. They will be‬
‭convened by the Prime Minister and will include the Chief Ministers and Lieutenant‬
‭Governors of all Union Territories in that region, and will be chaired by the Chairman‬
‭of NITI Aayog or his nominee. The Prime Minister can call experts and special invitees‬
‭through nomination.‬

‭Ultimately, the formal organization of NITI Aayog will consist of:‬


‭●‬ ‭The Vice President is appointed by the Prime Minister.‬
‭●‬ ‭Full time members‬
‭●‬ ‭Part-time Members (two from the best research universities or organizations in‬
‭ex-officio capacity and and also will be on rotation basis)‬
‭●‬ ‭Ex-Officio Members:- Maximum four members of the Union Council of‬
‭●‬ ‭Ministers who will be nominated by the Prime Minister.‬
‭●‬ ‭The primary functions of NITI Aayog can be divided into four broad categories.‬
‭●‬ ‭Amended Entry 49 of the Business Allocation Rules, 1961 (Annexure 1.3) envisages‬
‭the detailed tasks to be carried out under each of these heads.‬
‭●‬ ‭To promote cooperative federalism.‬
‭●‬ ‭Working as a resource center and knowledge center‬
‭●‬ ‭Policy-making and program design‬
‭●‬ ‭Monitoring and evaluation‬

‭In terms of governance structures, the changing needs of our country point to‬
‭the need to establish an institution that will act as a think tank of the government – a‬
‭directional and policy dynamos.‬

‭2.4 DEVELOPMENT: TWO CENTERS‬

‭Development:- In Sanskrit, the word ‘Niti’ means morality, behavior, guidance etc.‬
‭But in the present context it means policy and policy means “National Institute for‬
‭Transforming India”. This is the main policy making body of the country which is‬
‭expected to promote the economic growth of the country. Its goal is to build a strong‬
‭state which will help in building a dynamic and strong nation. This helps India to emerge‬
‭as a major economy of the world. The formation of NITI Aayog has two centers which are‬
‭called “Team India Hub” and “Knowledge and Innovation Hub”.‬

‭1. Team India Hub: Through this, Indian states is partner with the central‬
‭government. Promotes cooperative federalism and designs policy and program‬
‭framework. It provides the required coordination and support framework to‬
‭NITI Aayog in its engagement with states.‬

‭2. Knowledge & Innovation Hub: This builds the think tank capabilities of the‬
‭institute. It ensures to fulfill the mandate of maintaining a state-of-the-art resource‬
‭centre, creating a repository of research on good governance and best practices‬
‭in sustainable and equitable development as well as helping in their dissemination‬
‭to stakeholders. To provide advice and encourage partnerships between key‬
‭stakeholders and national, international like-minded think tanks as well as‬
‭academic and policy research institutions. Both the hubs are headed by the‬
‭Chief Executive Officer of NITI Aayog (NITI Aayog Report, 2016)‬

‭2.5 PHILOSOPHY OF NITI AAYOG‬


‭Philosophy of NITI Aayog:- While the Prime Minister said goodbye to the Nehru era‬
‭economic policies by abolishing the Planning Commission, he has laid the foundation‬
‭of a new indigenous ideological revolution by creating “NITI Aayog” in January 2015,‬
‭which will integrate development with the global symbols of capitalism, communism‬
‭and liberalism and will move towards analyzing and implementing it completely in‬
‭accordance with nationalist and Indian philosophy.‬
‭Under this, India’s development model will be based on the philosophy of six‬
‭Indian personalities - Mahatma Gandhi, Swami Vivekananda, Bhimrao Ambedkar,‬
‭Pandit Deendayal Upadhyay, Tamil poet Thiruvallur, Assamese saint Sankardev. The‬
‭important philosophy of NITI Aayog is based on the formula of Gandhiji:- “Continuous‬
‭development is the law of life and the person who always tries to maintain dogmatism‬
‭leads himself astray. Similarly, the intention of the government has become clear from‬
‭Dr. Bhimrao Ambedkar’s formula ‘centralizing powers is imprudent’. The priority of‬
‭the Commission has been made clear from the statement of Tamil saint Thiruvalluvar,‬
‭“There is nothing more terrible and painful than poverty and the sting of poverty takes‬
‭away the excellence of a person and his nobility”. For the first time, The statement of‬
‭poet Sankardeva’s treatise Kirtanghosh, “Seeing every living being as equal to one’s‬
‭soul is the greatest means of attaining salvation” clearly depicts the ultimate goal of the‬
‭government’s plans for the first time and in achieving this goal, Deendayal Upadhyay’s‬
‭‘Antyodaya Darshan’ ‘ Which emphasizes on the upliftment of the poor to provide‬
‭them the fruits of development, has been included in the ideological background of‬
‭NITI Aayog (Anuj Kumar Aggarwal, 2015).‬

‭2.6 MAIN POINTS OF NITI AAYOG‬

‭Main points of NITI Aayog:-‬

‭x Completely based on Indian philosophy‬


‭x Based on rural poor as well as youth, new middle class, non-resident Indians‬
‭and urbanization, urbanization was considered an opportunity.‬
‭x Spread of this philosophy equally in policy making of both Center and States.‬
‭x Will absorb all the positive things from around the world because no single model‬
‭accepted from other models can fit the Indian scenario.‬
‭x The role of the government will be as an assistant (enabler) of the public.‬
‭x Importance of the service sector in the economy.‬
‭x Emphasis on information technology and various types of connectivity to realize‬
‭the concept of a global village.‬
‭x More focus on the neo-middle and middle class.‬
‭x Emphasis on increasing the role of NRIs in terms of professional management‬
‭and technology.‬
‭x Appointment of Chief Executive Officer in place of Secretary to work in‬
‭accordance with the corporate culture (Anuj Kumar Aggarwal, 2015).‬

‭2.7 OBJECTIVES AND CHARACTERISTICS OF NITI AAYOG‬


‭The NITI Aayog serves as the apex public policy “think tank” of the Government of‬
‭India. It is nodal agency is mandated to facilitate the participation of the state‬
‭governments of India in the economic policy making process using a bottom-up‬
‭approach. It has been entrusted with the task of catalyzing greater development through‬
‭medium and cooperative federalism. Its main objectives and features are as follows:-‬

‭x To develop a common vision of national development priorities, areas and‬


‭strategies through active participation of States.‬
‭x To promote cooperative federalism through initiatives and mechanisms for‬
‭structured cooperation with States on an ongoing basis, recognizing that strong‬
‭States create strong nations.‬
‭x To develop mechanisms to prepare credible plans at the village level and‬
‭progressively disseminate these to higher levels of government.‬
‭x To ensure that national security interests are integrated into the economic strategy‬
‭and policy of the sectors specifically designated.‬
‭x To pay special attention to those sections of our society who may be at risk of‬
‭not benefiting adequately from economic progress.‬
‭x To formulate strategic and long-term policy and program frameworks and‬
‭initiatives and monitor their progress and impact. Lessons learned through‬
‭monitoring and feedback will be used to make innovative improvements including‬
‭necessary mid-term revisions.‬
‭x Advising and encouraging partnerships between key stakeholders and like minded‬
‭national and international “think tanks” as well as academic and policy‬
‭research institutions.‬
‭x To create knowledge, innovation and entrepreneurial support systems through‬
‭a collaborative community of national and international experts, practitioners‬
‭and other stakeholders.‬
‭x To provide a forum to address inter-sectoral and inter-departmental issues with‬
‭a view to accelerating the implementation of the development agenda.‬
‭x To maintain a state-of-the-art resource centre, to be a repository of research‬
‭on good governance and best practices for sustainable and equitable‬
‭development and also to help disseminate the same to stakeholders.‬
‭x Proactively evaluate and monitor the implementation of programs and initiatives,‬
‭including identifying needed resources, to enhance the chances of success in‬
‭delivering services.‬
‭x Emphasis on technology upgradation and capacity building for implementation‬
‭of programs and initiatives.‬
‭x To undertake such other activities as may be necessary to implement the national‬
‭development agenda and achieve the above objectives (Niti Aayog Report,‬
‭2023).‬
‭NITI Aayog is developing itself into a state-of-the-art resource center with the‬
‭necessary knowledge and skills that will enable it to act quickly, promote research and‬
‭innovation, provide strategic policy vision for the government and deal with emergent‬
‭issues. It is supported by a Liaison Office i.e. Development Monitoring and Evaluation‬
‭Organization (DMEO), a flagship initiative i.e. Atal Innovation Mission (AIM) and an‬
‭autonomous body i.e. Institute of Labor Economics Research and Development‬
‭(NILERD).‬

‭2.8 SCOPE OF WORK OF NITI AAYOG‬

‭Subsidiary bodies or work areas of NITI Aayog help in smoothly running the work‬
‭required by the organization, work areas are:-‬
‭1. Administration and supporting units‬
‭2. Agriculture and allied sector‬
‭3. Aspirational District Program Cell‬
‭4. Communication and Social Media Cell‬
‭5. Data Management and Analytics and Frontier Technologies‬
‭6. Economics and Finance Room‬
‭7. Education‬
‭8. Governance and Research‬
‭9. Governing Council Secretariat and Coordination‬
‭10. Infrastructure-Energy‬
‭11. Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises‬
‭12. Natural Resources and Environment and Island Development‬
‭13. Project Appraisal and Management Division‬
‭14. Rural Development‬
‭15. Science and Technology‬
‭16. Social Sector-I (Skill Development, Capability and Employment and Urban‬
‭Development)‬
‭17. Social Sector-II (Health and Nutrition and Women and Child Development)‬
‭18. State Finance and Coordination‬
‭19. Sustainable Development Goals‬
‭20. Water and land resources‬

‭2.9 SEVEN PILLARS OF EFFECTIVE GOVERNANCE BY NITI AAYOG‬

‭1. Pro-People: It fulfills the aspirations of the society as well as the individuals.‬
‭2. Pro-active: Proactivity in anticipation and response to citizen needs.‬
‭3. Participation: Inclusion of Citizenship.‬
‭4. Empowerment: Especially to include women by empowering them in all aspects.‬
‭5. Inclusion of all: Inclusion of all people irrespective of caste, creed and gender.‬
‭6. Equality: Providing equal opportunities to everyone, especially the youth.‬
‭7. Transparency: Making government visible and accountable (Sources,‬
‭PIB.NIC.IN)‬

‭“NITI Aayog oversees the monitoring and adoption of Sustainable Development‬


‭Goals (SDGs) and promotes competition and cooperative federalism among states‬
‭and government undertakings. It is a policy think tank of the Government of India‬
‭whose objective is to “promote coordination and participation in the economic policy‬
‭making process by the state governments of India.” The Prime Minister serves as the‬
‭ex-officio Chairman of NITI Aayog. NITI Aayog can provide an important directional‬
‭and strategic input regarding India’s developmental processes. The centre-to-state,‬
‭one-way flow of policy, the hallmark of the Planning Commission era, has been replaced‬
‭by a genuine and sustained partnership with and between Indian states. “Public policy”‬
‭is mainly a means of directing social actions according to some predetermined goals. In a‬
‭sense, public policy is a directional means of achieving goals driven by ‘ideology’ that‬
‭usually arise from dialectical interactions between governments and the governed.‬
‭Planning Commission has been replaced by ‘National Institute for Transforming India’‬
‭or ‘NITI’ in short. What are the differences from “plan” to “policy”? First and foremost,‬
‭it meant an initiative towards institutional change to transform “policy” and “India”‬
‭from Soviet-inspired national development (five-year) plans. Paragraph three of the‬
‭Cabinet resolution states: We need “‬‭institutional reforms in governance and dynamic‬
‭policy changes that can sow and nurture change on a large scale”‬‭(Virmani, A. 2015).‬

‭The primary objective of NITI Aayog is to promote economic growth and development‬
‭in India by providing strategic and technical advice to the Central and State‬
‭Governments. This includes national and international imports on economic fronts,‬
‭dissemination of best practices from within the country as well as other countries,‬
‭assimilation of new policy ideas and specific issue-based support.‬

‭2.10‬‭FUNCTIONS AND ROLE OF NITI AAYOG‬

‭NITI Aayog formulated its objectives keeping in mind the national objectives as well‬
‭as through the approach of national development along with the active participation of‬
‭the states. Following are the main functions of NITI Aayog:-‬
‭1. Cooperative Federalism:- It will promote cooperative federalism through‬
‭structured support initiatives and mechanisms on an ongoing basis with the states,‬
‭recognizing that strong states make a strong nation.‬
‭2. Credible Plans:- It will develop mechanisms to make credible plans at the village‬
‭level and disseminate them to higher levels of the government.‬
‭3. National Security:- National security issues will be considered and coordinated‬
‭with any specific issues in economic strategy and policy.‬
‭4. The Weaker Section:- NITI Aayog will give special emphasis on the weaker‬
‭sections of the society.‬
‭5. Policy & Strategy Formulation and Their Monitoring:- Policy and strategy will‬
‭be formulated by the Commission and monitoring and feedback will be provided‬
‭to encourage innovations and necessary midcourse reforms.‬
‭6. Partnerships:- It will make provisions to provide advice and promote partnerships‬
‭Academic and policy research institutions will be encouraged to work together to come up‬
‭with new ideas.‬
‭7. Experts:- It will have this support system which will initiate creativity and‬
‭entrepreneurship by uniting national and international experts from different fields.‬
‭8. Resolution Platform:- A platform will be set up to resolve inter-regional and‬
‭inter-departmental disputes to enhance the level of execution of developmental‬
‭projects and activities.‬
‭9. Resource Centre:- A state-of-the-art resource center will be set up which will‬
‭be a repository of research on good governance and best practices in sustainable‬
‭development across all sectors and departments and will help stakeholders access‬
‭information.‬
‭10. Assessment & Evaluation:- Timely monitoring and evaluation of programs is‬
‭necessary for effective and timely implementation of policies. Along with this, it‬
‭is also helpful in estimating the required money and other resources.‬
‭11. Technical Upgradation:- Special attention should be given to upgrading‬
‭technology in all sectors, so that projects can be better implemented.‬
‭NITI Aayog will aim to consolidate the vast pool of scientific and highly intelligent‬
‭resources by adopting the approach of helping the tribal Indian community. To become‬
‭a major power on the global economic stage, it will have to register its presence by‬
‭participating in all such summits. Use of modern technology in all sections of the society‬
‭has to be made a goal. The centre-to-state one-way flow of policy that characterized‬
‭the Planning Commission era has been replaced by increased participation of Indian‬
‭states, and a genuine and sustained partnership between them. ‘Public policy’ is mainly‬
‭a means of directing social actions according to some clearly defined goals. Thus,‬
‭public policy is “a directional means of achieving ideology-driven goals that usually‬
‭arise from dialectical interactions between governments and the governed” (Pandey,‬
‭A., Shukla, S.P. 2022).‬
‭On January 1, 2015, the Cabinet passed a resolution to establish the National‬
‭Institution for Transforming India (NITI Aayog). This marked the end of the erstwhile‬
‭Planning Commission, which had played an important role in the country’s economy‬
‭from very low initial conditions to a high growth path for more than six and a half‬
‭decades. What prompted the NDA government to replace Planning Commission with‬
‭NITI Aayog? What are its initiatives in the last four years? Was it inevitable to dissolve‬
‭the Planning Commission and create a new institution to do what NITI Aayog is doing?‬

‭MAJOR INITIATIVES‬
‭1)‬ ‭Atal Innovation Mission:- Atal Innovation Mission (AIM) is a major initiative of‬
‭the Government of India with the aim of promoting the culture of innovation and‬
‭entrepreneurship in the country. Since its inception in 2016, AIM has established‬
‭more than 10,000 Atal Tinkering Labs, 69 Atal Incubation Centres, 14 Atal‬
‭Community Innovation Centers and launched 24 Atal New India Challenges‬
‭across sectors (Niti Aayog Report, 2023). Atal Community Innovation Centers‬
‭are a means to drive innovation towards achieving Sustainable Development‬
‭Goals through new solutions in deprived areas of the country. Atal Community‬
‭Innovation Center (ACIC) program was launched on 31 July 2019 under Atal‬
‭Innovation Mission, a program of NITI Aayog to promote innovation in India.‬
‭2)‬ ‭Aspirational Districts Programme:- The objective of this program started in the‬
‭year 2018 is to identify the socially and economically backward districts of the‬
‭country and help in their overall development. Under this program, the progress‬
‭of the districts is evaluated by NITI Aayog and they are given ranking. Since its‬
‭inception, the program has studied ways to enable convergence of its three‬
‭approaches: district, state and central level initiatives; To facilitate collaboration‬
‭between civil society organizations, communities and district administration‬
‭towards a common goal and preparing strategy to promote a healthy spirit of‬
‭competition by releasing monthly ranks based on the performance of the districts‬
‭etc. to reduce conflict with the districts (NITI Aayog Report, 2022)‬
‭3)‬ ‭Nutrition Campaign Program:- Nutrition Campaign was implemented in March‬
‭2018. The objective of that campaign is to reduce the problems like malnutrition,‬
‭anemia in women and low birth weight of children in the country. This mission is‬
‭under women and child development. NITI Aayog has played an important‬
‭role in conceptualizing and organizing National Nutrition Month and Nutrition‬
‭Fortnight across the country in the months of March and September 2019. The‬
‭objective of celebrating Nutrition Month is to spread the message of nutrition to‬
‭every corner of the country. Poshan Maah 2019 had five components: Child’s‬
‭First 1,000 Days, Diarrhea-Free India, Diarrhea Prevention, WASH (or‬
‭Washing, Sanitation and Hygiene) and Nutritious India (NITI Aayog, 2020).‬
‭4)‬ ‭Zero Campaign:- NITI Aayog in collaboration with Rocky Mountain Institute‬
‭launched Zero Campaign in September 2021, which is an initiative to promote‬
‭zero pollution vehicles by working with consumers and industry. The campaign‬
‭aims to accelerate the adoption of electronic vehicles in the urban delivery‬
‭segment and sensitize consumers about the benefits of leaving zero pollution‬
‭(NITI Aayog Annual Report, 2022).‬
‭5)‬ ‭Women Entrepreneurship Platform:- The Women Entrepreneurship Platform‬
‭(WEP) is the first of its kind integrated-access portal to enable women of India‬
‭to realize their entrepreneurial aspirations. The idea of such a platform was first‬
‭mooted by NITI Aayog CEO Abitabh Kant, who announced its establishment‬
‭at the conclusion of the eighth Global Entrepreneurship Summit held in‬
‭Hyderabad in 2017, the theme of which was ‘Women First, Prosperity for All’‬
‭(NITI Aayog Report, 2020)‬

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy