0% found this document useful (0 votes)
2 views

Principle of Manager Economics

The document outlines the structure and content of a textbook on Managerial Economics, which is licensed under a Creative Commons license. It covers various topics including the relevance of economics for managers, key measures and relationships in business, demand and pricing, cost and production, market structures, and the role of regulation. The book aims to provide managers with economic principles and terminology to enhance decision-making and create value within their organizations.

Uploaded by

benjamin201290
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
2 views

Principle of Manager Economics

The document outlines the structure and content of a textbook on Managerial Economics, which is licensed under a Creative Commons license. It covers various topics including the relevance of economics for managers, key measures and relationships in business, demand and pricing, cost and production, market structures, and the role of regulation. The book aims to provide managers with economic principles and terminology to enhance decision-making and create value within their organizations.

Uploaded by

benjamin201290
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 110
Free to share. a Free to use. ABA RAAR eae ase Open Textbooks Free to change. for Hong Kong HERRRE fad Principles of Managerial Economics FRGARE This work is licensed under a Creative Commons-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 Inter national License Original source: The Saylor Foundation http://www saylor.org/site/textbooks/Principles%200f%20Managerial%20Economics.p df Contents Chapter 1 Introduction to Managerial Economics 1.1 What Is Managerial Economics? . . “ 1.2 Why Managerial Economics Is Relevant for Managers wvsnsunnsnnnnnonnennnert 1.3 Managerial Economics Is Applicable to Different Types of Organizations. 1.4 The Focus of This Book..... 1.5 How to Read This Book... Chapter 2 Key Measures and Relationships 2.1 ASimple Business Venture .. 2.2 Revenue, Cost, and PrOfit ...nmmnnnnmnennsnnnnnnensenn 2.3 Economic Versus Accounting Measures of Cost and Profit... 2.4 Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions 2.5 Breakeven Analysis... . 2.6 The Impact of Price Changes...snmsnminnsninannnennnnnnnnnsnnnnnsnee! 2.7 Marginal Analysis. 2.8 The Conclusion for Our Students... - sn 2.9 The Shutdown RULE ..nsmnnmnnninnmnnnnnnnnnennnnnannnnansnenel 7 2.10 A Final Word on Business Objectives... Chapter 3 Demand and Pricing .. 3.1 Theory of the Consumer... . 322s the Theory ofthe Consumer Realistle? snus 3.3 Determinants of Demand. - 3.4 Modeling Consumer Demand .nnnmmnmnnnennnmnnnnnns 3.5 Forecasting Demand... 3.6 Elasticity of Demand. 3.7 Consumption Decisions in the Short Run and the Long Run.. 3.8 Price Discrimination ...mmmnnmnnninnmmnmnnnnnennnmnnmnnennnnnmammnnnnennd Chapter 4 Cost and Production ..... 4.1 Average Cost Curves... 4.2 Long-Run Average Cost and Scale... 4.3 Economies of Scope and Joint Products. 4.4 Cost Approach Versus Resource Approach to Production Planning. 4.5 Marginal Revenue Product and Derived Demand.. 4.6 Marginal Cost of Inputs and Economic Rent wwnnmnnnnnn 4,7 Productivity and the Learning Curv weseanenenennee Chapter 5 Economics of Organization 5.1 Reasons to Expand an Enterprise... 5.2 Classifying Business Expansion In Terms of Value Chains 5.3 Horizontal Integration....... oe oe 50 5.4 Vertical Integration ..nimmmnmnmnnnnnnnnnmnnneinnmnnnnnnmmnnnnsessenn5O 5.5 Alternatives to Vertical integration 5.6 Conglomerates.. 5.7 Transaction Costs and Boundaries ofthe Firm 5.8 Cost Centers Versus Profit Centers 5.9 Transfer Pricing, 5.10 Employee Motivation ..numninnimnninnimnninnnmnnmnninnnnnnnannnsnnn 56 5.11 Manager Motivation and Executive Pay .. Chapter 6 Market Equilibrium and the Perfect Competition Model 6.1 Assumptions of the Perfect Competition Model... . 6.2 Operation of a Perfectly Competitive Market in the Short Rut 6.3 Perfect Competition in the Long Run 6.4 Firm Supply Curves and Market Supply Curve: 6.5 Market Equilibrium... - 6. Shifts in Supply and Demand Curves. 6.7 Why Perfect Competition Is Desirable... 6.8 Monopolistic Competition .w.nnnnmmnnmnnnniinnemnnnnmnnnnnnnannnnnnnen Tl 6.9 Contestable Market Model...... 75 6.10 Firm Strategies in Highly Competitive Markets . Chapter 7 Firm Competition and Market Structure .. 7.1 Why Perfect Competition Usually Does Not HappeNwnnnninnnnnnninnnnnnnenT® 7.2 Monopoly... 80 7.3 Oligopoly and Cartels... 81 7.4 Production Decisions in Noncartel Oligopolies 82 7.5 Seller Concentration. - 84 7.6 Competing in Tight Oligopolies: Pricing Strategies 85 7.7 Competing in Tight Oligopolies: Nonpricing Strategies 87 7.8 Buyer Power. 90 Chapter 8 Market Regulation .. 92 8.1 Free Market Economies Versus Collectivist ECONOMIES .nnssnsnnnnsnnnnnnnnienO2 8.2 Efficiency and Equity 98 8.3 Circumstances in Which Market Regulation May Be Desirable 8.4 Regulation to Offset Market Power of Sellers or Buyers. . 94 8,5 Natural MONOpOly sannennnnininninnnnnennnnnnninennnnnnnanenninnnnnsneS 8.6 Externalities... 196 8.7 Externalty TaKX€S..nnsnenninninnminienninnenininnnninennnnnnnsnennennmnnsnesST 8.8 Regulation of Externalities Through Property Rights. 8.9 High Cost to Initial Entrant and the Risk of Free Rider Producers 8.10 Public Goods and the Risk of Free Rider Consumers .. 8.11 Market Failure Caused by Imperfect Information 8.12 Limitations of Market Regulatior 8.13 References .. Chapter 1 Introduction to Managerial Economics 1.1 What Is Managerial Economics? oH FE i aittie under creative Commons Noncommercial ShareAlike 40 iteration License (hit: reativecommons.orp/licenses/by-ne-sa/4.0)), ‘One standard definition for economics is the study of the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. A second definition is the study of choice related to the allocation of scarce resources. The first definition indicates that economics includes any business, nonprofit organization, or administrative unit. The second definition establishes that economics is at the core of what managers of these organizations do. This book presents economic concepts and principles from the perspective of “managerial economics,” which is a subfield of economics that places special emphasis on the choice aspect in the second definition. The purpose of managerial economics is to provide economic terminology and reasoning for the improvement of managerial decisions. Most readers will be familiar with two different conceptual approaches to the study of economics: microeconomics and macroeconomics. Microeconomics studies phenomena related to goods and services from the perspective of individual decision-making entities—that is, households and businesses. Macroeconomics approaches the same phenomena at an aggregate level, for example, the total consumption and production of a region. Microeconomics and macroeconomics each have their merits. The microeconomic approach is essential for understanding the behavior of atomic entities in an economy. However, understanding the systematic interaction of the many households and businesses would be too complex to derive from descriptions of the individual units. The macroeconomic approach provides measures and theories to understand the overall systematic behavior of an economy. Since the purpose of managerial economics is to apply economics for the improvement of managerial decisions in an organization, most of the subject material in managerial economics has a microeconomic focus. However, since managers must consider the state of their environment in making decisions and the environment includes the overall economy, an understanding of how to interpret and forecast macroeconomic measures is useful in making managerial decisions. 1.2 Why Managerial Economics Is Relevant for Managers eo reativecommens.org/licenses/by-nc sa/A./), Available under Creative Cammans-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:ve Ina civilized society, we rely on others in the society to produce and distribute nearly all the goods and services we need. However, the sources of those goods and services are usually not other individuals but organizations created for the explicit purpose of producing and distributing goods and services. Nearly every organization in our society—whether it is a business, nonprofit entity, or governmental unit—can be viewed as providing a set of goods, services, or both. The responsibility for overseeing and making decisions for these organizations is the role of executives and managers. Most readers will readily acknowledge that the subject matter of economics applies to their organizations and to their roles as managers. However, some readers may question whether their own understanding of economics is essential, just as they may recognize that physical sciences like chemistry and physics are at work in their lives but have determined they can function successfully without a deep understanding of those subjects. Whether or not the readers are skeptical about the need to study and understand economics per se, most will recognize the value of studying applied business disciplines like marketing, production/operations management, finance, and business strategy. These subjects form the core of the curriculum for most academic business and management programs, and most managers can readily describe their role in their organization in terms of one or more of these applied subjects. A careful examination of the literature for any of these subjects will reveal that economics provides key terminology and a theoretical foundation. Although we can apply techniques from marketing, production/operations management, and finance without understanding the underlying economics, anyone who wants to understand the why and how behind the technique needs to appreciate the economic rationale for the technique. We live in a world with scarce resources, which is why economics is a practical science. We cannot have everything we want. Further, others want the same scarce resources we want. Organizations that provide goods and services will survive and thrive only if they meet the needs for which they were created and do so effectively. Since the organization's customers also have limited resources, they will not allocate their scarce resources to acquire something of little or no value. And even if the goods or services are of value, when another organization can meet the same need with a more favorable exchange for the customer, the customer will shift to the other supplier. Put another way, the organization must create value for their customers, which is the difference between what they acquire and what they produce. The thesis of this book is that those managers who understand economics have a competitive advantage in creating value 1.3 Managerial Economics Is Applicable to Different Types of Organizations Under Creative Commons-NonCammercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:lfc reativecommons.org/lcenses/by-nc-sa/4.00, In this book, the organization providing goods and services will often be called a “business” or a “firm,” terms that connote a for-profit organization, And in some portions of the book, we discuss principles that presume the underlying goal of the organization is to create profit. However, managerial economics is relevant to nonprofit organizations and government agencies as well as conventional, for-profit businesses. Although the underlying objective may change based on the type of organization, all these organizational types exist for the purpose of creating goods or services for persons or other organizations. Managerial economics also addresses another class of manager: the regulator. As we will discuss in Chapter 8 "Market Regulation’, the economic exchanges that result from organizations and persons trying to achieve their individual objectives may not result in the best overall pattern of exchange unless there is some regulatory guidance, Economics provides a framework for analyzing regulation, both the effect on decision making by the regulated entities and the policy decisions of the regulator. 1.4 The Focus of This Book eos reativecommons.orp/lcenses/by-nc-sa/a.on, Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetps/c The intent of this book is to familiarize the reader with the key concepts, terminology, and principles from managerial economics. After reading the text, you should have a richer appreciation of your environment—your customers, your suppliers, your competitors, and your regulators. You will learn principles that should improve your intuition and your managerial decisions. You will also be able to communicate more effectively with your colleagues and with expert consultants. As with much of microeconomic theory, many of the economic principles in this book were originally derived with the help of mathematics and abstract models based on logic and algebra. In this book, the focus is on the insights gained from these principles, not the derivation of the principles, so only a modest level of mathematics is employed here and an understanding of basic algebra will suffice. We will consider some key economic models of managerial decision making, but these will be presented either verbally, graphically, or with simple mathematical representations. For readers who are interested in a more rigorous treatment, the reference list at the conclusion of this text includes several books that will provide more detail. Alternatively, a web search using one of the terms from this book will generally yield several useful inks for further exploration of a concept. A note about economic models is that models are simplified representations of a real-world organization and its environment. Some aspects of the real-world setting are not addressed, and even those aspects that are addressed are simplifications of any actual setting being represented. The point of using models is not to match the actual setting in every detall, but to capture the essential aspects so determinations can be made quickly and with a modest cost. Models are effective when they help us understand the complex and uncertain environment and proceed to appropriate action. Ne 1.5 How to Read This Book easg reativecommons.orp/licenses/by-nc-sa/A.)), Avallable under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetps/c Like any academic subject, economics can seem like an abstract pursuit that is of greatest interest to economists who want to communicate with other economists. However, while there is certainly a substantial body of written research that may reinforce that impression, this book is written with the belief that economics provides a language and a perspective that is useful for general managers. All readers have a considerable experience base with the phenomena that economics tries to address, as managers, consumers, or citizens interested in what is happening in their world and why. As you read the book, | encourage you to try to apply the concepts and theories to economic phenomena you have experienced. By doing so, the content of the book will make more sense and you are more likely to apply what you will read here in your future activities as a player in the world of business and economics. Chapter 2 Key Measures and Relationships 2.1 A Simple Business Venture @ezs9 reativecommons.orp/licenses/by-ne-sa/4.0)), vailable under Creative Commons-NonCommercial‘ShareAlike 40 International License (hitp:/c In this chapter we will be covering some of the key measures and relationships of a business operation. To help illustrate these concepts, we will consider the following simple business venture opportunity. Suppose three students like spending time at the beach. They have pondered whether they could work and live at the beach during their summer break and learned that they could lease a small building by the beach with existing freezer capacity and apply for a local license to sell ice cream bars. 2.2 Revenue, Cost, and Profit (oleio} reativecommons.orp/lcenses/by-ncsa/a.on, Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hitp://c Most businesses sell something—either a physical commodity like an ice cream bar or a service like a car repair. In a modern economy, that sale is made in return for money or at least is evaluated in monetary terms. The total monetary value of the goods or services sold is called revenue. Few businesses are able to sell something without incurring expenses to make the sale possible. The collective expenses incurred to generate revenue over a period of time, expressed in terms of monetary value, are the cost, Some cost elements are related to the volume of sales; that is, as sales go up, the expenses go up. These costs are called variable costs. The cost of raw materials used to make an item of clothing would be an example of a variable cost. Other costs are largely invariant to the volume of sales, at least within a certain range of sales volumes. These costs are called fixed costs. The cost of a machine for cutting cloth to make an item of clothing would be a fixed cost. Businesses are viable on a sustained basis only when the revenue generated by the business generally exceeds the cost, incurred in operating the business. The difference between the revenue and cost (found by subtracting the cost from the revenue) is called the profit. When costs exceed revenue, there is a negative profit, or loss. The students in our simple venture realize they need to determine whether they can make a profit from a summer ice cream bar business. They met the person who operated an ice cream bar business in this building the previous summer. He told them last summer he charged $1.50 per ice cream bar and sold 36,000 ice cream bars. He said the cost of the ice cream bars— wholesale purchase, delivery, storage, and so on—comes to about $0.30 per bar. He indicated his other main costs—leasing the building, license, local business association fee, and insurance—came to about $16,000. Based on this limited information, the students could determine a rough estimate of the revenue, costs, and profit they would have if they were to repeat the outcomes for the prior operator. The revenue would be $1.50 per ice cream bar times 36,000 ice cream bars, or $54,000. The variable cost would be $0.30 per ice cream bar times 36,000 ice cream bars, or $10,800. The fixed cost would be $16,000, making the total cost $26,800. The profit would be $54,000 minus $26,800, or $27,200. Based on this analysis, the students are confident the summer business venture can make money. They approach the owner of the building and learn that if they want to reserve the right of first option to lease the building over the summer, they will need to make a nonrefundable $6000 deposit. that will be applied to the lease. They proceeded to make that deposit. A few weeks later, all three students were unexpectedly offered summer business internships at a large corporation. Each student would earn $10,000. However, the work site for the internships is far from the beach and they would be in an office all day. They now must decide whether to accept the internships and terminate their plan to run a business at the beach or turn down the internships. 2.3 Economic Versus Accounting Measures of Cost and Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (http:/f¢ reativecommons.org/lcenses/ay-nc-sa/4.0/) The discipline of accounting provides guidelines for the measurement of revenue, cost, and profit. Having analyses based on generally accepted principles is important for making exchanges in our economy. For example, corporations must produce financial statements to help investors and creditors assess the health of the corporation. Individuals and businesses must produce tax returns to determine a fair measurement of income for taxation purposes. Costs as measured according to accounting principles are not necessarily the relevant measurements for decisions related to operating or acquiring a business. For example, accounting standards dictate that businesses depreciate long-lived assets, like buildings, by spreading the cost over the life of the asset. 'However, from the perspective of the business, the entire expense was incurred when the asset was acquired, even if borrowing was necessary to make the purchase and there will be the opportunity to take increased tax deductions in future years. Likewise, there are other business costs relevant to decision making that may not be considered as costs from the perspective of accounting standards. For example, the owner/operator of a proprietorship invests time and effort in operating a business. These would typically not be treated as expenses on the proprietorship's tax return but are certainly relevant to the owner in deciding how to manage his self-run business. Based on these differences in perspective, itis useful to distinguish accounting costs from economic costs. In turn, since profit is the residue of revenue minus costs, we also distinguish accounting profit from economic profit. Consider our three students who are now in a quandary about whether to sell ice cream bars on the beach or accept the summer internships, and let us see how distinguishing the economic cost/profit from the accounting cost/ profit helps to clarify their decision. There is the matter of the students’ time and energy, which is not reflected in the projection of the $27,200 profit based on last. year’s operation. One way to measure that cost is based on how much they will forfeit 1 The particulars on deprecation can be found in any fnancal accounting text by not using their time in the next best alternative, which in this case is the summer internship. We can consider this forfeited income as being equivalent to a charge against the operation of the ice cream business, a measurement commonly referred to as an opportunity cost. The students’ time has an opportunity cost of $30,000. This should be added to the earlier fixed cost of $16,000, making an economic fixed cost of $46,000, a total economic cost of $56,800, and an economic loss of $2800. So maybe the ice cream business would not be a good idea after all. However, recall that the students have already made a $6000 nonrefundable deposit. This money is spent whether the students proceed to run the summer business or not. It is an example of what is called a sunk cost. Assuming the fixed cost of the business was the same as for the prior operator, the students would have a $16,000 accounting fixed cost to report ‘ona tax return. Yet, from the perspective of economic costs, only $10,000 is really still avoidable by not operating the business. The remaining $6000 is gone regardless of what the students decide. So, from an economic cost/profit perspective, viewed after the nonrefundable deposit but before the students declined the summer internships, ifthe students’ other costs and revenue were identical to the previous year, they would have economic costs of just $50,800 and an economic profit of $3200. Ifa business properly measures costs from an economic perspective, ignoring sunk costs and including opportunity costs, you can conclude that a venture is worth pursuing if it results in an economic profit of zero or better. However, this is generally not a valid principle if you measure performance in terms of accounting profit. Most stockholders in a corporation would not be satisfied if the corporation only managed a zero accounting profit because this means there is no residual from the business to reward them with either dividends or increased stock value. From an economic cost perspective, stockholder capital is an asset that can be redeployed, and thus it has an ‘opportunity cost—namely, what the investor could earn elsewhere with their share of the corporation in a different investment of equivalent risk. * This opportunity cost could be estimated and included in the economic cost. Ifthe resulting profit is zero or positive after netting out the opportunity cost of capital, the investor's participation is worthwhile. 2.4 Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions eae Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetps/c reativecommons.orp/lcenses/by-nc-sa/a.on, In the preceding projections for the proposed ice cream bar venture, the assumption was that 36,000 ice cream bars would be sold based on the volume in the prior summer. However, the actual volume for a future venture might be higher or lower. And with an economic profit so close to zero, our students should consider the impact of any such differences. There is a relationship between the volume or quantity created and sold and the resulting impact on revenue, cost, and profit. These relationships are called the revenue function, cost function, and profit function. These relationships can be expressed in terms of tables, graphs, or algebraic equations. in a case where a business sells one kind of product or service, revenue is the product of 2, Readers Interested in estimating the opportunity cost af investment capital are encouraged to consult a general tex in financial analysis, such as Brigham and Envhardt (2010) the price per unit times the number of units sold. If we assume ice cream bars will be sold for $1.50 apiece, the equation for the revenue function will be R= $1.50, where Ris the revenue and Q is the number of units sold. The cost function for the ice cream bar venture has two components: the fixed cost component of $40,000 that remains the same regardless of the volume of units and the variable cost component of $0.30 times the number of items. The equation for the cost function is C = $40,000 + $0.3 Q, Where Cis the total cost. Note we are measuring economic cost, not accounting cost. Since profit is the difference between revenue and cost, the profit functions will be $1.2 Q - $40,000. Here tis used as the symbol for profit. (The letter P is reserved for use later as a symbol for price.) Table 2.1 Revenue, Cost, and Profit for Selected Sales Volumes for Ice Cream Bar Vent ureprovides actual values for revenue, cost, and profit for selected values of the volume quantity Q. Figure 2.1, provides graphs of the revenue, cost, and profit functions. The average cost is another interesting measure to track. This is calculated by dividing the total cost by the quantity. The relationship between average cost and quantity is the average cost function. For the ice cream bar venture, the equation for this function would be AC = C/Q = ($40,000 + $0.3 Q)/Q = $0.3 + $40,000/9. Figure 2.2shows a graph of the average cost function. Note that the average cost function starts out very high but drops quickly and levels off. ° So $40,000 ~$40,000 10,000 $15,000 $43,000 ~$28,000 20,000 $30,000 $46,000 -$16,000 30,000 $45,000 $49,000 $4,000 40,000 $60,000 $52,000 $8,000 50,000 $75,000 $55,000 $20,000 60,000 $90,000 $58,000 $32,000 Table 2.1 Revenue, Cost, and Profit for Selected Sales Volumes for Ice Cream Bar Venture $100,000 $80,000 $60,000 $40,000 $20,000 50,000 60,000 70,000 $20,000 a Toe Cream Bars $40,000 Figure 2.1 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Business at Price of $1.50 Essentially the average cost function is the variable cost per unit of $0.30 plus a portion of the fixed cost allocated across all units. For low volumes, there are few units to spread the fixed cost, so the average cost is very high. However, as the volume gets large, the fixed cost impact on average cost becomes small and is dominated by the variable cost component. 10 37.00 Average Cost um $3.00 ° 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 60,000 70,000 Tee Cream Bars Figure 2.2 Graph of Average Cost Function for Ice Cream Bar Venture 2.5 Breakeven Analysis @oe reativecommons.org/lcenses/ty-n-sa/4.0), Available under Creative Commons NonCommercial-ShareAlike 40 International License (httpilc A scan of Figure 2.1 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar B usiness at Price of $1.50 shows that the ice cream bar venture could result in an economic profit or loss depending on the volume of business. As the sales volume increases, revenue and cost increase and profit becomes progressively less negative, turns positive, and then becomes increasingly positive. There is a zone of lower volume levels where economic costs exceed revenues and a zone on the higher volume levels where revenues exceed economic costs. ‘One important consideration for our three students is whether they are confident that the sales volume will be high enough to fall in the range of positive economic profits. The volume level that separates the range with economic loss from the range with economic profit is called the breakeven point. From the graph we can see the breakeven point is slightly less than 35,000 units. If the students can sell above that level, which the prior operator did, it will be worthwhile to proceed with the venture. If they are doubtful of reaching that level, they should abandon the venture now, even if, that means losing their nonrefundable deposit. There are a number of ways to determine a precise value for the breakeven level algebraically. One is to solve for the value of Q that makes the economic profit function equal to zero: @ = $1.2 Q - $40,000 or Q = $40,000/$1.2 = 33,334 units. 1" ‘An equivalent approach is to find the value of Q where the revenue function and cost function have identical values. Another way to assess the breakeven point is to find how large the volume must be before the average cost drops to the price level. In this case, we need to find the value of Q where AC is equal to $1.50. This occurs at the breakeven level calculated earlier. A fourth approach to solving for the breakeven level is to consider how profit changes as the volume level increases. Each additional item sold incurs a variable cost per unit of $0.30 and is sold for a price of $1.50. The difference, called the unit contribution margin, would be $1.20. For each additional Unit of volume, the profit increases by $1.20. In order to make an overall economic profit, the business would need to accrue a sufficient number of unit contribution margins to cover the economic fixed cost of $40,000. So the breakeven level would be Q = fixed cost/(price per unit - variable cost per unit) = $40, 000/($1.50 - $0.3¢) = 33,333.3 or 33,334 units. Once the operating volume crosses the breakeven threshold, each additional unit contribution margin results in additional profit. We get an interesting insight into the nature of a business by comparing the unit contribution margin with the price. In the case of the ice cream business, the unit contribution margin is 80% of the price. When the price and unit contribution margins are close, most of the revenue generated from additional sales turns into profit once you get above the breakeven level. However, if you fall below the breakeven level, the loss will grow equally dramatically as the volume level drops. Businesses like software providers, which tend have mostly fixed costs, see a close correlation between revenue and profit. Businesses of this type tend to be high risk and high reward. On the other hand, businesses that have predominantly variable costs, such as a retail grocery outlet, tend to have relatively modest changes in profit relative to changes in revenue. If business level falls off, they can scale down their variable costs and profit will not decline so much. At the same time, large increases in volume levels beyond the breakeven level can achieve only modest profit gains because most of the additional revenue is offset by additional variable costs. 2.6 The Impact of Price Changes eo © vailable under Creative Commons NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License ¢itp//c reativecommons.orgcenses/by.nc-sa/A0n In the preceding analyses of the ice cream venture, we assumed ice cream bars would be priced at $1.50 per unit based on the price that was charged in the previous summer. The students can change the price and should evaluate whether there is a better price for them to charge. However, ifthe price is lowered, the breakeven level will increase and if the price is raised, the breakeven level will drop, but then so may the customer demand. To examine the impact of price and determine a best price, we need to estimate the relationship between the price charged and the maximum unit ‘quantity that could be sold. This relationship is called a demand curve. Demand curves generally follow a pattern called the law of demand, whereby increases in price 2 result in decreases in the maximum quantity that can be sold. We will consider a simple demand curve for the ice cream venture. We will assume that since the operator of the business last year sold 36,000 units at a price of $1.50 that we could sell up to 36,000 units at the same price this coming summer. Next, suppose the students had asked the prior operator how many ice cream bars he believes he would have sold at a price of $2.00 and the prior operator responds that he probably would have sold 10,000 fewer ice cream bars. In other words, he estimates his sales would have been 26,000 at a price of $2.00 per ice cream bar. To develop a demand curve from the prior operator's estimates, the students assume that the relationship between price and quantity is linear, meaning that the change in quantity will be proportional to the change in price. Graphically, you can infer this relationship by plotting the two price-quantity pairs on a graph and connecting them with a straight ine. Using intermediate algebra, you can derive an equation for the linear demand curve P = 3.3 - 0.00005 Q, where P is price in dollars and Q is the maximum number of ice cream bars that will sell at this price. Figure 2.3 Linear Demand Curve for Ice Cream Bar Venture presents a graph of the demand curve. Price $3.50 $3.00 $150 $1.00 0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 60,000 70,000 Ice Cream Bars sar Demand Curve for Ice Cream Bar Venture it may seem awkward to express the demand curve in a manner that you use the quantity Q to solve for the price P. After all, in a fixed price market, the seller decides a price and the buyers respond with the volume of demand. Mathematically, the relationship for ice cream bars could be written B Q = 66,008 - 20,000 P. However, in economics, the common practice is to describe the demand curve as the highest price that could be charged and still sell a quantity Q. The linear demand curve in Figure 2.3 Linear Demand Curve for Ice Cream Bar Venture probably stretches credibility as you move to points where either the price is zero or demand is zero. In actuality, demand curves are usually curved such that demand will get very high as the price approaches zero and small amounts would still sell at very high prices, similar to the pattern inFigure 2.4 Common Pattern for Demand Curves . However, linear demand curves can be reasonably good estimates of behavior if they are used within limited zone of possible prices. Price $6.00 $5.00 $4.00 $3.00 0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 Figure 2.4 Common Pattern for Demand Curves We can use the stated relationship in the demand curve to examine the impact of price changes on the revenue and profit functions. (The cost function is unaffected by the demand curve.) Again, with a single type of product or service, revenue is equal to price times quantity. By using the expression for price in terms of quantity rather than a fixed price, we can find the resulting revenue function R= P Q= (3.3- 0.00005 Q)0= 3.3 Q- 0.00005 Q”. By subtracting the expression for the cost function from the revenue function, we get the revised profit function 14 m= (3.3 Q — 0.00005 Q*) - (40,000 + $2.3 Q) = -0.00005 Q? + 3.0 - 40,000. Graphs for the revised revenue, cost, and profit functions appear inFigure 2.5 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Venture for Linear Demand C urve . Note that the revenue and profit functions are curved since they are quadratic functions. From the graph of the profit function, it can be seen that itis possible to eam an economic profit with a quantity as low as 20,000 units; however, the price would need to be increased according to the demand curve for this profit to materialize. Additionally, it appears a higher profit is possible than at the previously planned operation of 36,000 units ata price of $1.50. The highest profitability appears to be at a volume of about 30,000 units. The presumed price at this volume based on the demand curve would be around $1.80. Revenue 10,000 . ~ 70,000 30,000 40,000 ~~ $0,000 60,000 70,000 Ice Cream Bars $40,000 $60,000 ~$80,000 Figure 2.5 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Venture for Linear Demand curve 2.7 Marginal Analysis Under Creative Commons-NonCammercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:lfc reativecommons.org/lcenses/by-nc-sa/4.00, Economists analyze relationships like revenue functions from the perspective of how the function changes in response to a small change in the quantity. These marginal measurements not only provide a numerical value to the responsiveness of the function to changes in the quantity but also can indicate whether the business would benefit from increasing or decreasing the planned production volume and in some cases can even help determine the optimal level of planned production. The marginal 16 revenue measures the change in revenue in response to a unit increase in production level or quantity. The marginal cost measures the change in cost corresponding to a Unit increase in the production level. The marginal profit measures the change in profit resulting from a unit increase in the quantity. Marginal measures for economic functions are related to the operating volume and may change if assessed at a different operating volume level. There are multiple computational techniques for actually calculating these marginal measures. Ifthe relationships have been expressed in the form of algebraic equations, one approach is to evaluate the function at the quantity level of interest, evaluate the function if the quantity level is increased by one, and determine the change from the first value to the second. Suppose we want to evaluate the marginal revenue for the revenue function derived in the previous section at last summer's operating level of 36,000 ice cream bars. For a value of Q= 36,000, the revenue function retums a value of $54,000. For a value of Q = 36,001, the revenue function returns a value of $53,999.70. So, with this approach, the marginal revenue would be $53,999.70 ~ $54,000, or -$0.30. What does this tell us? First, it tells. Us that for a modest increase in production volume, if we adjust the price downward to compensate for the increase in quantity, the net change in revenue is a decrease of $0.30 for each additional unit of planned production. Marginal measures often can be sed to assess the change if quantity is decreased by changing sign on the marginal measure. Thus, if the marginal revenue is -$0.30 at Q = 36,000, we can estimate that for modest decreases in planned quantity level (and adjustment of the price upward based on the demand function), revenue will rise $0.30 per unit of decrease in Q. At first glance, the fact that a higher production volume can result in lower revenue seems counterintuitive, if not flawed. After all, if you sell more and are still getting a positive price, how can more volume result in less revenue? What is happening in this illustrated instance is that the price drop, as a percentage of the price, exceeds the increase in quantity as a percentage of quantity. A glance back at Figure 2.1 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Cream Bar Business at Price of $1.50 confirms that Q = 36,000 is in the portion of the revenue function where the revenue function declines as quantity gets larger. If you follow the same computational approach to calculate the marginal cost and marginal profit when Q = 36,000, you would find that the marginal cost is $0.30 and the marginal profit is ~$0.60. Note that marginal profit is equal to marginal revenue minus marginal cost, which will always be the case. The marginal cost of $0.30 is the same as the variable cost of acquiring and stocking an ice cream bar. This is not just a coincidence. If you have a cost function that takes the form of a linear equation, marginal cost will always equal the variable cost per unit. The fact that marginal profit is negative at Q = 36,000 indicates we can expect to find a more profitable value by decreasing the quantity and increasing the price, but not by increasing the quantity and decreasing the price. The marginal profit, value does not provide enough information to tell us how much to lower the planned quantity, but like a compass, it points us in the right direction. Since marginal measures are the rate of change in the function value corresponding to a modest change in Q, differential calculus provides another computational technique for deriving marginal measures. Differential calculus finds instantaneous rates of change, so the values computed are based on infinitesimal changes in Q rather than whole units of Q and thus can yield slightly different values. However, a great strength of using differential calculus is that whenever you have an economic function in the form 16 of an algebraic equation, you can use differential calculus to derive an entire function that can be used to calculate the marginal value at any value of Q. How to apply differential calculus is beyond the scope of this text; however, here are the functions that can be derived from the revenue, cost, and profit functions of the previous section (i.e., those that assume a variable price related to quantity): marginal revenue at a volume Q = $3.3 ~ $0.0001 Q,marginal cost at a volume Q = $ @.3,marginal profit at a volume Q = $3 - $0.0001 Q. Substituting Q = 36,000 into these equations will produce the same values we found earlier. However, these marginal functions are capable of more. Since the marginal change in the function is the rate of change in the function at a particular point, you can visualize this by looking at the graphs of the functions and drawing a tangent line on the graph at the quantity level of interest. A tangent line is a straight line that goes through the point on the graph, but does not cross the graph as it goes through the point. The slope of the tangent line is the marginal value of the function at that point. When the slope is upward (the tangent line rises as it goes to the right), the marginal measure will be positive, When the slope is downward, the marginal measure will be negative. If the line has a steep slope, the magnitude of the marginal measure will be large. When the line is fairly flat, the magnitude will be small. Suppose we want to find where the profit function is at its highest value. If you look at that point (in the vicinity of Q = 30,000) on Figure 2.1 Graphs of Revenue, Cost, and Profit Functions for Ice Crea m Bar Business at Price of $1.50, you see itis like being on the top of a hill. if you draw the tangent line, it will not be sloped upward or downward; it will be a flat line with a zero slope. This means the marginal profit at the quantity with the highest profit has a value of zero. So if you set the marginal profit function equal to zero and solve for Q you find © = $3.00 - $2.0001 Q implies Q = $3.00/$0.0001 = 30,000. This confirms our visual location of the optimum level and provides a precise value. This example illustrates a general economic principle: Unless there is a constraint preventing a change to a more profitable production level, the most profitable production level will be at a level where marginal profit equals zero. Equivalently, in the absence of production level constraints, the most profitable production level is, where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. if marginal revenue is greater than marginal cost at some production level and the level can be increased, profit will increase by doing so. If marginal cost is greater than marginal revenue and the production level can be decreased, again the profit can be increased. 2.8 The Conclusion for Our Students e233 Available under Creative Cammons-NonCommercial-Sharedlike 4.0 international License (http://¢ reativecommons.orgilcenses/by-nc-sa/4.00, Our students will look at this analysis and decide not only to go forward with the ice cream business on the beach but to charge $1.80, since that is the price on the 7 demand curve corresponding to a sales volume of 30,000 ice cream bars. Their expected revenue will be $54,000, which coincidently is the same as in the original plan, but the economic costs will be only $49,000, which is lower than in the original analysis, and their economic profit will be slightly higher, at $5000. At first glance, a $5000 profit does not seem like much. However, bear in mind that we already assigned an opportunity cost to the students’ time based on the income foregone by not accepting the corporate internships. So the students can expect to complete the ‘summer with $10,000 each to compensate for the lost internship income and still have an additional $5000 to split between them. 2.9 The Shutdown Rule reativecommons.org/lcenses/by-ne-sa/A0N, lable under Creative Commons-NonCommerclal-ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:tic You may recall earlier in this chapter that, before deciding to disregard the $6000 nonrefundable down payment (to hold the option to operate the ice cream business) as a relevant economic cost, the total cost of operating the business under a plan to sell 36,000 ice cream bars at a price of $1.50 per item would have exceeded the expected revenue. Even after further analysis indicated that the students could improve profit by planning to sell 30,000 ice cream bars at a price of $1.80 each, if the $6000 deposit had not been a sunk cost, there would have been no planned production level and associated price on the demand curve that would have resulted in positive economic profit. So the students would have determined the ice cream venture to be not quite viable if they had known prior to making the deposit that they could instead each have a summer corporate internship. However, having committed the $6000 deposit already, they will gain going forward by proceeding to run the ice cream bar business. A similar situation can occur in ongoing business concerns. A struggling business may appear to generate insufficient revenue to cover costs yet continue to operate, at least for a while. Such a practice may be rational when a sizeable portion of the fixed costs in the near term are effectively sunk, and the revenue generated is enough to offset the remaining fixed costs and variable costs that are still not firmly committed. Earlier in the chapter, we cited one condition for reaching a breakeven production level where revenue would equal or exceed costs as the point where average cost per unit is equal to the price. However. if some of the costs are already sunk, these should be disregarded in determining the relevant average cost. In a circumstance where a business regards all fixed costs as effectively sunk for the next production period, this condition becomes a statement of a principle known as the shutdown rule: Ifthe selling price per unit is at least as large as the average variable cost per unit, the firm should continue to operate for at least a while; otherwise, the firm would be better to shut down operations immediately. Two observations about the shutdown rule are in order: In a circumstance where a firm's revenue is sufficient to meet variable costs but not total costs (including the sunk costs), although the firm may operate for a period of time because the additional revenue generated will cover the additional costs, eventually the fixed costs will need to be refreshed and those will be relevant economic costs prior to commitment to continue operating beyond the near term. If a business does not see circumstances changing whereby revenue will be getting better or costs will be going down, although 18 it may be a net gain to operate for some additional time, such a firm should eventually decide to close down its business. Sometimes, it is appropriate to shut down a business for a period of time, but not to close the business permanently. This may happen if temporary unfavorable circumstances mean even uncommitted costs cannot be covered by revenue in the near term, but the business expects favorable conditions to resume later. An example of this would be the owner of an oil drilling operation. If crude oil prices drop very low, the operator may be unable to cover variable costs and it would be best to shut down until petroleum prices climb back and operations will be profitable again. in other cases, the opportunity cost of resources may be temporarily high, so the economic profit is negative even if the accounting profit would be positive. An example would be a farmer selling his water rights for the upcoming season because he is offered more for the water rights than he could net using the water and farming, 2.10 A Final Word on Business Objectives Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (http:Jfe reativecommons.org/licenses/ay-nc-sa/4.0/, In the example used in this chapter, we assumed the students’ goal in how to operate the ice cream business was to maximize their profit—more specifically, to maximize their economic profit. Is this an appropriate overall objective for most businesses? Generally speaking, the answer Is yes. If a business is not able to generate enough revenue to at least cover their economic costs, the business is losing in the net. In addition to the business owners having to cover the loss out of their wealth (or out of society's largesse for a bankruptcy), there is an inefficiency from a societal perspective in that the resources used by the business could be more productive elsewhere, The ice cream business analyzed here was simple in many respects, including that it was intended to operate for only a short period of time. Most businesses are intended to operate for long periods of time. Some businesses, especially newly formed businesses, will intentionally operate businesses at a loss or operate at volumes higher than would generate the maximum profit in the next production period. This decision is rational if the business expects to realize larger profits in future periods in exchange for enduring a loss in the near future. There are quantitative techniques, such as discounting, * that allow a business decision maker to make these trade-offs between profit now and profit later. These techniques will not be covered in this text. Economists refer to a measure called the value of the firm, which is the collective value of all economic profits into the future and approximately the amount the ‘owners should expect to receive if they sold the business to a different set of owners. For a corporation, in theory this would roughly equate to the value of the equity on a company’s balance sheet, although due to several factors like sunk costs, is probably not really that value. Economists would say that a business should make decisions that maximize the value of the firm, meaning the best decisions will result in larger economic profits either now or later. One response to the principle that the overall goal of a firm is to maximize its value is that, although that goal may be best for those who own the business, it is not the optimal objective for the overall society in which {3 Many accounting and economics texts dlscuss the concept of discounting of profs over time. One good discussion can be found in an appendix in Hischey and Pappas (1896). 19 the business operates. One specific objection is that those who work for the business may not be the same as those who own the business and maximizing the value for the ‘owners can mean exploiting the nonowner employees. The common response to this objection is that it will be in the owners’ best interest in the long run (several periods of operation) to treat their employees fairly. Businesses that exploit their employees will lose their good employees and fail to motivate those employees who remain. The collective result will be lower profits and a lower value of the firm. A second objection to the appropriateness of operating a business to maximize the value for the owners is that this invites businesses to exploit their customers, suppliers, and the society in which they operate to make more money. Firms may be able to take advantage of outside parties for a while, but eventually the customers and suppliers will wise up and stop interacting with the business. With a high level of distrust, there will be a decline in profits in future periods that will more than offset any immediate gain. If a business tries to exploit the overall society by ruining the environment or causing an increase in costs to the public, the business can expect governmental authorities to take actions to punish the firm or limit its operations, again resulting in a net loss over time. So maximizing the value of the firm for the owners does not imply more profit for the owners at the expense of everyone else. Rather, a rational pursuit of maximal value will respect the other stakeholders of a business. In the case of nonprofit organizations, maximizing the value of the organization will be different than with for- profit businesses like our ice cream example. A nonprofit organization may be given a budget that sets an upper limit on its costs and is expected to provide the most value to the people it serves. Since most nonprofit organizations do not charge their “customers” in the same way as for-profit businesses, the determination of value will be different than estimating sales revenue. Techniques such as cost-benefit analysis. “have been developed for this purpose. 4.A dass text in cost benefit analysis was written by E, |. Mishan (1976). 20 Chapter 3 Demand and Pricing Under Creative Commons-NonCammercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:lfc reativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/A.0), Decisions related to demand and pricing are usually called marketing decisions. Marketing is an established profession and an applied academic discipline with a large body of literature. However, economic reasoning and concepts provide much of the theoretical foundation for marketing practice. In this chapter, we will address these elements from the perspective of economics. 3.1 Theory of the Consumer Oz reativecommons.org/lcenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/, Available under Creative Cammons-NonCommercial-Sharedlike 4.0 international License (http://¢ Back in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", we used a demand curve to represent the relationship between the price charged for ice cream bars and the maximum number of ice cream bars that customers would purchase. We will address how to create a demand curve later in this chapter, but we will begin our discussion with a brief review of microeconomic theory that endeavors to explain how consumers behave. A consumer is someone who makes consumption decisions for herself or for her household unit. Ina modern society, consumption is largely facilitated by purchases for goods and services. Some of these goods and services are essential to a consumer's livelihood, but others are discretionary, perhaps even a luxury. Consumers are limited in how much they can consume by their wealth. A consumer's wealth will change over time due to income and expenditures. She might be able to borrow against future income so as to increase her capacity to purchase now in exchange for diminished weaith and consumption later. Similarly, she may retain some of her current wealth as savings toward increased future consumption. Consumption decisions may be planned into the future, taking account of the expected changes in wealth over time. The theory of the consumer posits that a consumer plans her purchases, the timing of those purchases, and borrowing and saving so as maximize the satisfaction she and her household unit will experience from consumption of goods and services. In this theory, consumers are able to compare any two patterns of consumption, borrowing, and saving and deem that either one is preferred to the second or they are indifferent between the two patterns. Based on the ability to do these comparisons, consumers look at the prices charged for various services now, and what they expect prices to be for goods and services in the future, and select the pattern of consumption, borrowing, and saving that, generates the greatest satisfaction over their lifetime within the constraint of their wealth and expected future income. Although the consumers may anticipate changes in prices over time, they may find that their guesses about future prices are incorrect. When this happens, the theory states that they will adjust their consumption, borrowing, and saving to restore the optimality under the newly revealed prices. In fact, the theory identifies two effects of price changes: the substitution effect and the income effect. The substitution effect is based on an argument employing marginal 24 reasoning like the marginal analysis discussed in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships". Economists often use the term utility as a hypothetical quantitative value for satisfaction that a consumer receives from a pattern of consumption. If a consumer were to receive one more unit of some good or service, the resulting increase in their utility is called the marginal utility of the good. As a consequence of maximizing their overall satisfaction from consumption, or equivalently maximizing their utility, it will be the case that if you take the marginal utility of one good or service and divide it by its price, you should get the same ratio for any other good or service. If they were not roughly equal, the consumer would be able to swap consumption of one good or service for another, keep within their wealth constraint, and have higher utility. The substitution effect is the consumer's response to a changing price to restore balance in the ratios of marginal utility to price. Just as a simple illustration, suppose a consumer likes bananas and peaches as a treat. For the sake of the illustration, let’s suppose an additional banana has a marginal utility of 2 and a peach has a marginal utilty of 3, If a banana costs $0.20 and a peach costs $0.30, bananas and peaches have a ratio of the marginal utility to its price equal to 10. If the peach price increases to $0.40, the ratio will become lower for peaches and the consumer may substitute some purchases of peaches with purchases of more bananas. As the result of price changes and substitution, the consumers overall utility may increase or decrease. Consequently, the consumer may experience the equivalent of an increase or decrease in wealth, in the sense that it would have required a different level of wealth to just barely afford the new consumption pattern under the previous set of prices. This equivalent change in purchasing power is called the income effect. Economists have precise techniques for separating the response to a price change into a substitution effect and an income effect. 'This is beyond the scope of this text. For our purposes, itis sufficient to appreciate that price changes will affect the mix of goods and services that is best and change the consumer's overall level of satisfaction, In most cases, the primary response to a price change is a substitution effect, with a relatively modest income effect. However, for goods and services that a consumer cannot substitute easily, a sizeable price change may have a significant income effect. For example, when gasoline prices jumped dramatically in the United States, consumers may have reduced their driving somewhat but were unable to find a substitute for the essential needs served by driving their cars. As a result, consumers experienced a dramatic drop in wealth available for other goods and services and consumed generally less of all of those to compensate for the greater expenditure on gasoline. Normally, price increases result in less consumption of the associated good or service, whereas price decreases results in more consumption. This typical pattern is usually supported by both the substitution effect and the income effect. An interesting exception is the case of Giffen goods, which is a situation where consumption of a good or service may increase in response to a price increase or decrease in response to a price decrease. This anomaly is explained by a ‘strong income effect. An economist named Robert Giffen discovered that Irish consumers increased the use of potatoes in their diet during the Irish Potato Famine of the 1840s, even though the price of potatoes rose dramatically. Basically, because potatoes were a staple of the Irish diet, when the potato price increased, the wealth available to purchase other food items diminished and Irish consumers wanted to 1. Se Varian (1999) fora discussion ofthe substitution effet, income effect, and Gifen goods. 2 purchase more potatoes to compensate for the diminished purchases of other food items, 3.2 Is the Theory of the Consumer Rea 2 eag reativecommons.orgilcenses/by-nc-sa/4.00, Available under Creative Cammons-NonCommercial-Sharedlike 4.0 international License (http://¢ Strictly speaking, it would be difficult to make a case that the theory of the consumer conforms to our own experience of consumption decisions or what we observe of other consumers. We don’t consciously weigh the relative marginal utilities of tens of thousands of possible goods and services we might consume. We don't know all the current prices and don't even know of the existence of many goods and services. Even if we did, the computational complexity to solve for optimal consumption would overwhelm our faculties, and probably even the fastest computers available. Many times we and others don't think of our consumption in terms of what gives us the greatest satisfaction but in terms of what it takes to get by. Consumers who are impoverished or suffer a major ailment are probably unable to do even a modest attempt at optimizing consumption. Others may simply consume as a matter of habit rather than conscious choice. Although our consumption decisions may not fully conform to the theory of the consumer, there have been some attempts to argue that we do approximate it. Herbert Simon proposed a theory of bounded rationality * that states that humans do behave rationally with a limited range of options. So if consumers focus on a modest set of important goods and services, they may be able to achieve something close to the theoretical optimum in terms of overall utility. Simon also observed that human beings may not optimize so much as they “satisfice.” meaning that they work to meet a certain level of consumption satisfaction rather than the very best pattern of consumption. if the level of acceptability is reasonably close to the optimum level, again the results of consumption decisions may approximate what would occur if the consumers operated according to this theory. Another argument suggesting that differences between the theory and actual behavior may not result in starkly different consumption is that we observe how others behave. If someone else, either by active choice or by accidental discovery, is experiencing greater satisfaction under similar circumstances of wealth and income, their friends and neighbors will detect it and start to emulate their consumption patterns. So our consumption may evolve in the direction of the optimal pattern. Perhaps most importantly, the lack of face validity of the theory of the consumer does mean the theory is not useful in modeling consumer behavior. We do expect consumers to respond to price changes and we do expect consumers to respond to changes in their wealth, whether due to changes in their actual discretionary income or indirect impacts on wealth resulting from price changes. 2 Bounded rationality and satisficng are dlscussed in Simon (1997) 23 3.3 Determinants of Demand eo reativecommons org/lcenses/hy-ne-sal0/) vailable under Creative Commons NonCommercial'ShareAlike 4. International License (http://c We can approach the challenge of modeling consumer behavior in a more practical manner that is informed by the theory of the consumer. To estimate demand and study the nature of consumer demand, we start by identifying a set of key factors that have a strong influence on consumer demand. Probably the most important influencing factor is one we considered for the ice cream business in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships'—the price of the item itself. Price is also the key determinant of demand in the theory of the consumer. In the simplest cases, there is a single price that applies to any item or unit of service being sold. However, as we will discuss later in the section on price discrimination, prices may vary depending on who is buying it and how much they are buying. Businesses incur promotional costs to boost the consumption of their products. Promotion can be in the form of advertising, free samples, appearance in business directories, and so on. The theory of the consumer provides a supporting rationale for expenditure on promotion: If a consumer is regarded as deciding how to allocate his wealth across available goods and services, in order for your product to be included as a candidate in that choice, the consumer has to be aware that your product or service exists. However, as we will discuss in Chapter 7 "Firm Competition and Market Structure", large firms often ‘engage in promotion at expenditure levels well beyond what is needed to make your firm and product known to the consumer, as.a tactic of competition. ‘Consumer demand may vary depending on where and when the consumption is ‘occurring. Being able to quantitatively assess how consumption changes by location or time is a powerful tool in deciding where and when to sell your product. Some businesses decide to serve broad geographical regions; others target specific locations. Some businesses sell most or all times of the day and days of the year; others limit their operations to a restricted number of hours or periods within a year. What strategy will work best will depend on the product and the company's overall marketing strategy. Businesses have a choice of channels for selling. They can operate their own commercial establishments or sell wholesale to other retailers. Goods can be sold directly at a retail site or via the internet, telephone, or mail order. Understanding how the channels used will affect demand is important. The selection of price, promotional activities, location, and channel are generally in the control of the business concern. In texts on marketing strategy, “the composition of these decisions is called a marketing mix. For a marketing mix to be effective, the different elements need to be consistent. However, there are other important determinants of consumption for a good or service that are largely out of the control of the providing, firm, We will next consider some of these determinants. As suggested by the substitution effect in the theory of the consumer, the consumer is able to alter his pattern of consumption to meet his needs as prices and wealth levels change. The most significant swaps are likely to be between goods and services that come close to meeting the same consumer need. For example, a banana can serve as a substitute for a peach in meeting the need for a piece of fruit. Usually the items that act as 2. Kotler and Armstrong (2010) is 2 popular text on marketing principles 24 substitutes to the product of one firm will be sold by a different firm. Consequently, how that other firm elects to price, promote, locate, and channel its goods or services will have an impact on the consumption of substitutable goods or services sold by the first firm. Different goods and services can be strongly related in another way called a complementary relationship. Consumption of some goods and services can necessitate greater consumption of other goods and services. For example, if more automobiles are sold, there will be increased demand for tires, oil, repair services, automobile financing, automobile insurance, and so on. Correctly monitoring and forecasting the demand of key complements can improve the ability of a firm to forecast its own consumer demand. Most firms sell multiple products and services that are related. Within this collection, there are probably important substitute and complementary relationships. A car dealer that sells several models of vehicles has substitutable products that compete with each other. The car dealer may be offering services like repair service and financing that are complementary to vehicle sales. In situations with strong substitute and complementary product relationships, the firm needs to consider these in its demand forecasting and market strategy. Earlier, we discussed the income effect caused by price changes and indicated that this is caused by the consumer realizing an increase or decrease in overall purchasing wealth. Probably a more significant cause of changes in wealth occurs from fluctuations in the economic activity, which will affect the demand for most goods and services. The relationship between demand quantities and economic indicators of economic activity or disposable income can improve business forecasting considerably. Demand is also affected by the demographics of the population of eligible customers. How many people live in a region, their ethnic and socioeconomic composition, and age distribution can explain variations in demand across regions and the ability to forecast in the future as these demographics change. 3.4 Modeling Consumer Demand Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (htp:/fc reativecommons.org/licenses/ay-nc-sa/4.0/, To develop a formal model of consumer demand, the first step is to identify the most important determinants of demand and define variables that measure those determinants. Ideally, we should use variables for which data exist so that statistical estimation techniques can be applied to develop an algebraic relationship between the units of a good consumed and the values of the key determinants. Techniques to derive these algebraic relationships from historical data are outside the scope of this text, but an interested reader may want to consult a text on econometrics. “We will examine a simple example of a model of consumer demand. Suppose @ business is selling broadband services in a community. The managers of the business have identified four key determinants of demand: (a) the price they charge for the service, (b) their advertising expenditure, (c) the price charged by the competition, and (d) the disposable income of their potential customers. They define four variables to measure these determinants: 4, Stockand Watson (2007) san established econometrics text 25 P = the price per month of their service, in dollars, = advertising expenditure per month, in dollars,cP = the price per month of the competitor’s service, in dollars,DIPC = the disposable income per capita, in dollars, as measured by the U.S. Department of Commerce for that month. Using past data, they estimate the following equation to relate these variables to number of broadband subscribers to their service during a month, symbolized by Q 25,800-800P + 4A+ 200 CP + 0.4DIPC. This relationship is called a demand function. One application of the demand function is to estimate the consumption quantity Q for specific values of P, CP, and DIPC. Suppose P = $30, A = $5000, CP = $25, and DIPC = $33,000: Q = 25,800 - 800(30) + 4(5000) + 200(25) + 0.4(33,000) = 40,000 subscribers In Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", we introduced a demand curve to describe the relationship between the quantity of items sold and the price of the item. When there are multiple determinants of demand, the demand curve can be interpreted as a reduced view of the demand function where only the price of the product is allowed to vary. Any other variables are assumed to remain at a fixed level. For the previous demand function for broadband service, suppose we assume Ais fixed at $5000, CP is fixed at $25, and DIPC is fixed at $33,000. If you substitute these values into the demand function and aggregate constant terms, the demand function becomes 64,000 - 800 P. Recall that demand curves are usually expressed with price as a function of quantity With some basic algebra the equation of the demand curve can be written as P = $80 - $0.00125 Q. What happens to the demand curve if one of the other variables is a different value? Well, in short, the demand curve would shift. Suppose the competitor decides to increase its price to $35. Repeating the preceding steps, the demand function simplifies to 66,002 - 800 P or, expressed with P as a function of Q, 26 P = $82.50 - 2.00125 Q Figure 3.1 Shift in Demand Curve for Broadband Service Caused by Increase of Compe titor Price From $25/month to $35/month shows a graph of the demand curve before and after the shift. Effectively, the result is that the broadband firm would see its demand increase by 2000 customers per month, or alternatively, the firm could raise its price to $32.50 and still maintain 40,000 customers per month, 3.5 Forecasting Demand ox FEE i tiounter creative Commons Noncommercial ShareAlike 40 ternational License tpt reativacommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.07, Identifying the key determinants of demand and developing demand functions gives a business manager a better understanding of his customers. A benefit of that understanding is an improved accuracy in forecasting the demand levels for their products and services in an upcoming period. Most businesses need to plan production activities well in advance of when the goods and services are actually provided to the consumer. Businesses need to have an adequately sized operation, have a sufficient staff in terms of size and training, and obtain any necessary resources for production. These capabilities are usually not possible to achieve overnight. For some goods, production is a process that takes significant time from initiation to completion, such as constructing apartments or office space that will be leased to customers. Even businesses that provide products or services “made to order," where most of the direct organization or production activities occur after a purchase is made, usually need to have supplies, trained labor, and management structures in place in advance of the order to be in a position to negotiate a sale. 27 10,000 Figure 3.1 Shift in Demand Curve for Broadband Service Caused by Increase of Competitor Price From $25/month to $35/month Without some concrete estimate of what level of demand will result after these planning, designing, and production activities, a business may find itself with an ‘excess of unused capacity or unable to serve the demand that follows. Excess capability is costly because idle resources have an opportunity cost but do not contribute to sales or revenue, especially when the unused resources spoil and cannot be used at a later time. When businesses set production targets too low, they discover missed opportunities for profit and unmet demand that is likely to discourage those consumers from being customers in the future. To a limited extent, a business may be able to alter future demand to be more in line with its capacity because it has control ‘over some determinants of demand, like pricing, promotion, and location. If the business is surprised by demand levels that are higher or lower than expected, these market strategy elements can be adjusted to either stimulate or diminish demand to conform to its production capabilities. Still the financial performance of an enterprise is improved when the demand is consistent with the levels anticipated in the initial planning stages. Further, most businesses are not in control of all the key determinants of demand. The business cannot control the direction of the overall ‘economy and consumer incomes. The business may be able to guess at, but not control, actions by other companies that sell substitute and complementary goods and services. Anticipating the impact of these outside forces is critical. Businesses can improve demand forecasting with their demand functions using the future values of determinant variables in those demand functions. Forecasts for widely followed economic indicators like disposable income are available from public releases or private forecasting services. If the business has a record of data for these 28 uncontrollable variables, they can apply quantitative forecasting techniques like time series analysis or develop casual models that relate these factors to other variables that can be forecast. Readers are encouraged to look at a text in business forecasting for assistance in doing quantitative forecasts. “For variables where past patterns may not continue into the future, like competitor actions on pricing and promotion or unexpected climate events, a business can construct scenarios in which management postulates settings for these factors and then develops a demand forecast for each scenario. Although the future will almost certainly not conform exactly to any single scenario, the exercise prepares them to monitor for changes in these factors and be ready to make a prompt response whenever a similar scenario emerges. 3.6 Elasticity of Demand ox Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (htp:/fe reativecommons.org/lcenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/, Another use of a mathematical demand function is measuring how sensitive demand is to changes in the level of one of the determinants. Suppose we would like to assess whether the demand for broadband service will change much in response to a change in its price. One indicator of the level of response to a price change is the coefficient of the price term in the demand function equation, -800 P. The interpretation of the coefficient -800 is that for each increase of $1 in the monthly subscriber price, the number of monthly subscribers will decrease by 800 subscribers. This observation provides some insight, particularly if the broadband firm is considering a price change and would like to know the impact on the number of subscribers. However, for someone who measures price in terms of a different currency, say Japanese yen, a conversion to U.S. dollars would be needed to appreciate whether the demand change implied by the coefficient value is large or modest. Another limitation of this approach to measuring the responsiveness of demand to a determinant of demand is that the observation may not apply readily to other communities that may have a larger or smaller population of potential customers. An alternative approach to measuring the sensitivity of demand to its determinant factors is to assess the ratio of percentage change in demand to the percentage change in its determinant factor. This type of measurement is called an elasticity of demand. Assessing the elasticity of, demand relative to changes in the price of the good or service being consumed is called the own-price elasticity or usually just the price elasticity. As an illustration of this, suppose we want to measure the sensitivity of demand for broadband services corresponding to a modest change in its price. First, to determine the price elasticity, you need to clearly understand the settings for all the determinant factors because elasticity changes if you look at a different configuration of factor levels. Suppose we decide to find the price elasticity when P = $30, A = $5000, CP = $25, and DIPC = $33,000. Earlier we determined that the demand quantity at this setting was Q = 40,000 monthly subscribers. If we let the price increase by 10% from $30 to $33 and repeat the calculation of Q in the demand function, the value of Q will decline to 37,600 subscribers, which is a decline of 2400 customers. As a percentage of 40,000 monthly customers, this would be a 6% decrease. So the price elasticity here would be 5. One business forecasting text isa book authored by Hanke and Wichern (2009) 29 Price elasticity = ~6%/10% = -0.6. Since the law of demand states that quantity demanded will drop when its price increases and quantity demanded will increase when its price decreases, price elasticities are usually negative numbers (other than special cases like Giffen goods, described earlier in this chapter). Goods and services are categorized as being price elastic whenever the price elasticity is more negative than -1. in this category, the percentage change in quantity will be greater than the percentage change in price if you ignore the negative sign. When the computed price elasticity is between 0 and -1, the good or service is considered to be price inelastic. This does not mean that demand does not respond to changes in price, but only that the response on a percentage basis is lower than the percentage change in price when the negative sign is ignored. In those rare instances where price elasticities are positive, the product violates the law of demand. Again, these are similar to the Giffen goods discussed earlier. By assessing sensitivity to changes on a percentage basis, it does not matter, what units are used in the variable measurements. We could have constructed our demand function with a price measurement in cents or euros, and the price elasticity would have been the same. Also, if we wanted to compare the price elasticity of broadband service in this community with the price elasticity of broadband service in a larger community, we could compare the price elasticities directly without any need for further adjustment. Another important class of elasticities is the response of demand to changes in income, or the income elasticity. For our broadband example, if we were to calculate the income elasticity at the same point where we calculated the price elasticity, we would have found an elasticity of 0.33. The interpretation of this value is as follows: For an increase of 1% in income levels, demand for broadband will increase by 0.33%. When income elasticity of a product is greater than one, we call the product acyclic good. The adjective “cyclic” suggests that this demand is sensitive to ‘changes in the business cycle and will generally change more on a percentage basis than income levels. Luxury goods that customers can do without in hard economic times often fall in this category. When income elasticity is between zero and one, we call the product anoncyclic good. Our broadband service falls in this category. The demand for noncyclic goods tends to move up and down with income levels, but not as strongly on a percentage basis. Most of the staple goods and services we need are noncyclic. Normally we would expect demand for a good or service to increase when incomes increase and decrease when incomes decrease, other things being equal. However, there are arguably some exceptions that do not behave this way, Low-cost liquor, which might see increased use in hard economic times, is one of these possible ‘exceptions. When income elasticity is negative, we call the product acountercyclic good. When elasticities are calculated to measure the response of demand to price changes for a different good or service, say either a substitute product or complementary product, we call the calculated value a cross-price elasticity. Cross- price elasticities tend to be positive for substitute goods and negative for complementary goods. In our example, the competitor's service is a substitute good. If we calculate the cross-price elasticity for changes in the competitor's price on demand for broadband service at the point examined earlier, the result is 0.125. Elasticities can be calculated for any factor on demand that can be expressed quantitatively. In our 30 example, we could also calculate an advertising elasticity, which has a value of 0.5 at the given settings for the four factors in our demand function. This value indicates that an increase of 1% in our monthly advertising will result in a 0.5% increase in subscribers. In interpreting and comparing elasticities, it is important to be clear whether the elasticity applies to a single business in a market or to all sellers ina market. Some elasticities, like price elasticities and advertising elasticities, tend to reflect greater sensitivity to changes in the factor when an elasticity is calculated for a single business than when assessed for the total demand for all sellers in a market. For example, we noted earlier that consumers will be unable to decrease gasoline consumption much, at least immediately, even if gasoline prices climb dramatically This implies that gasoline is very price inelastic. However, this observation really applies to the gasoline industry as a whole. Suppose there was a street intersection in a city that has a gasoline station on every corner selling effectively the same product at about the same price, until one station increases its price dramatically (believing gasoline was highly inelastic to changes in price, so why not), but the other three stations leave their price where it was. If prices were clearly displayed, most customers would avoid the station that tried to increase the price and that station would see nearly all of its business disappear. In this situation where the competitors’ goods are highly substitutable, the price elasticity for a single gasoline station would be very price elastic. 3.7 Consumption Decisions in the Short Run and the Long Run eax Available under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (htp:/fc reativecommons.org/lcenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/, The main reason most consumers are unable to respond very quickly to an increase in gasoline prices is because there is not an effective substitute for automobile travel. However, if consumers were convinced that gasoline prices were going to continue to rise into the foreseeable future, they would gradually make changes to the lifestyles so that they are able to reduce gasoline consumption significantly. They could purchase more fuel-efficient cars or cars that use an alternative fuel, or they could change jobs or change residences so that they are closer to their places of employment, shopping, and such. Economists distinguish short-run decisions from long-run decisions. A consumer decision is considered short run when her consumption will occur soon enough to be constrained by existing household assets, personal commitments, and know-how. Given sufficient time to remove these constraints, the consumer can change her consumption patterns and make additional improvements in the utility of consumption. Decisions affecting consumption far enough into the future so that any such adjustments can be made are called long-run decisions. Demand functions and demand curves can be developed for short-run or long-run time horizons. Short-run demand curves are easier to develop because they estimate demand in the near future and generally do not require a long history of data on consumption and its determinant factors. Because long-run demand must account for changes in consumption styles, it requires longer histories of data and greater sophistication. Elasticities of demand in the short run can differ substantially 34 from elasticities in the long run. Long-run price elasticities for a product are generally of higher magnitude than their short-run counterparts because the consumer has sufficient time to change consumption styles. There is so much uncertainty about long-run consumption that these analyses are usually limited to academic and government research. Short-run analyses, on the other hand, are feasible for many analysts working for the businesses that must estimate demand in order to make production decisions. 3.8 Price Discrimination ea © lable under Creative Commons-NonCommercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (itp//c reativecommons.orgficenses/by.nc-sa/A0/} In the ice cream bar summer business in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", we presumed that the student operators would decide on a price to charge. All ice cream bars would be sold at that price. We reasoned that more ice cream bars could be sold as the price is decreased. If the students decide to charge $1.50 per ice cream bar, a potential customer will decide if the utility of the ice cream bar is sufficiently high for them to be willing to give up $1.50 of their wealth. If not, they will walk away without making a purchase. If the students instead decide to charge $1.80 per ice cream bar, the demand curve indicated that 6000 fewer unit purchases would occur, meaning 6000 of those purchases were not worth $1.80 to the purchasers. However, some of the customers would have been willing to pay over $2.00, and fewer even more than $2.50 or $3.00. When all consumers pay the same price, some of them get a kind of surplus because they would have been willing to pay more for the ice cream bar. Sellers may wish they were able to charge customers the maximum amount they are willing to pay, which would result in more revenue and no added cost. In ‘economics, the term for charging different prices to different customers is called price discrimination. Economists have actually defined multiple types of price discrimination, called first-degree price discrimination, second-degree price discrimination, and third-degree price discrimination. First-degree price discrimination is an attempt by the seller to leave the price unannounced in advance and charge each customer the highest price they would be willing to pay for the purchase. IF perfectly executed, this would meet the ideal of getting the greatest revenue possible from sales. Unfortunately, anything close to perfect execution of first-degree price discrimination is unrealistic because customers have an incentive to not reveal how much they would be willing to pay and instead try to pay as little as possible. Attempts to sell using first-degree price discrimination may be illegal as well, as it may be deemed discriminatory in the legal sense of the word. Some commercial dealings resemble attempts at first-degree price discrimination. Sometimes there is no set price, and the buyer and seller negotiate a price. This is the ‘customary way that automobiles have been sold in the United States. The process may start with a preannounced price, but one that is usually higher than the seller actually expects to receive. This falls short of pure first-degree discrimination because the buyer is probably able to negotiate down from the most he would pay, possibly quite a bit ifthe buyer is a good negotiator. In addition, there is time and effort expended in the negotiating, which is a kind of cost to the transaction that the buyer 2 may see as part of the purchase cost and the seller may see as an added cost of business. Goods and services are sometimes sold or purchased via an auction. This is usually an effective means when the seller has a limited number of items to sell. Run properly, an auction will distinguish those willing to pay more, although it probably will not manage to get a bid as high as the maximum the buyer would have paid. Again, the cost of operating an auction is expensive in comparison to selling using a set, preannounced price. Businesses that sell a product that is in demand with no good substitute available will sometimes employ a sliding price, where they begin selling at a very high price that is attractive to relatively few consumers. After a time when presumably those high-value customers make their purchases, the business will drop the price somewhat and attract purchases from another group that was willing pay slightly less than the first group. Successive price drops can continue until it would be unprofitable for the seller to drop the price any lower. Sliding prices are sometimes used with products that employ new technologies, when the initial seller has the market to itself, at least for a while, and offers a got-to-have item for some customers. Of course, although these eager customers may be willing to pay more, they may be aware of this pricing strategy and delay their purchase, so this approach will not extract the full value customers would have been willing to pay. When goods and services are sold according to a preannounced price, the customary arrangement is that the charge for multiple items is the price times the number of items. This is called linear pricing. However, customers differ in the volume they are interested in purchasing. A business may benefit by offering different prices to those who purchase in larger volumes because either they can increase their profit with the increased volume sales or their costs per unit decrease when items are purchased in volume. Businesses can create alternative pricing methods that distinguish high-volume buyers from low-volume buyers. This is second-degree price discrimination. A donut shop might offer a free donut to anyone who purchases a whole dozen because the purchase requires less clerk time per donut sold and increases how many donuts get purchased. However, since only those who buy at least a dozen donuts get a free donut, the discount is limited to those people and not the customer who purchases just a donut or two, This would be second-degree price discrimination. Another nonlinear pricing scheme to employ second-degree discrimination is a two-part price. Acustomer pays a flat charge to be a customer and then pays a per unit charge based ‘on how much they consume. Some services like telephone service are primarily fixed cost and have a very small per unit variable cost. By charging telephone customers a flat monthly fee and low per unit charge, they encourage more use of the service than if they simply charged a linear price per unit and see more revenue in relation to costs. Membership stores that require customers to pay an entry fee before being allowed to shop, but offer lower prices than regular stores for purchased items, is another example of a two-part pricing. Third-degree price discrimination is differential pricing to different groups of customers. One justification for this practice is that producing goods and services for sale to one identifiable group of customers is less than the cost of sales to another group of customers. For example, a publisher of music or books may be able to sell a music album or a book in electronic form for less cost than a physical form like a compact disc or printed text. A second justification for charging different prices to different groups of customers is that one group may be more sensitive to price than the other group. Earlier we discussed elasticity of 3 demand. If we separated the demand for the two groups into separate demand curves, at any given price the more price sensitive group will have stronger negative price elasticity. Sellers are able to increase economic profit by charging a lower price to the price-elastic group and a higher price to the more price-inelastic group. As an ‘example, 25 years ago music was sold in two formats: cassette tapes and compact discs. The production cost of a cassette tape was roughly equivalent to a compact disc, but music on compact discs often retailed at a higher price because it was perceived that customers of compact discs were more demanding of quality and more price inelastic. To apply third-degree price discrimination, the seller must be able to clearly identify and sort the customer by a salient characteristic. For example, a cable provider may be aware that existing subscribers are price inelastic relative to other households that are not existing customers. The cable provider will typically charge reduced rates to attract new customers and is able to execute the price discrimination because it knows whether a customer is an existing customer or not. A sports clothing retailer may know that fans of a team are more price inelastic in the purchase of apparel displaying the name or mascot of that team than customers who are not fans. However, if the clothing retailer were to attempt to charge differential prices, the customers who are fans would have the incentive to disguise that characteristic, so third-degree price discrimination would not work well in this case. 34 Chapter 4 Cost and Production Under Creative Commons-NonCammercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:lfc reativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/A.0), in the previous two chapters we examined the economics underlying decisions related to which goods and services a business concern will sell, where it will sell them, how it will sell them, and in what quantities. Another challenge for management is to determine how to acquire and organize its production resources to best support those commitments. In this chapter and in the following chapter we will be discussing key concepts and principles from microeconomics that guide its organization and production activities to improve profitability and be able to compete effectively. A number of highly useful methodologies have been developed based on the concepts and principles discussed. This text will not address specific techniques for tracking costs and planning production activities. Readers seeking guidance on these tasks might consult a text on cost accounting or operations management.[***Two classic texts on cost accounting and operations management are by Horngren (1972) and Stevenson (1986), respectively.***] 4.1 Average Cost Curves Under Creative Commons-NonCammercial ShareAlike 4.0 International License (hetp:lfc reativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/A.0), In Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", we cited average cost as a key performance measure in producing a good or service. Average cost reflects the cost ona per unit basis. A portion of the average cost is the amount of variable costs that can be assigned to the production unit. The other portion is the allocation of fixed costs (specifically those fixed costs that are not sunk), apportioned to each production unit, The average cost generally varies as a function of the production volume per period. Since fixed costs do not increase with quantity produced, at least in the short run where production capabilities are relatively set, the portion of the average cost attributable to fixed cost is very high for small production volume but declines rapidly and then levels off as the volume increases. The portion of average cost related to the variable cost usually changes less dramatically in response to production volume than the average fixed cost. In fact. in the example of the ice cream bar business in Chapter 2 "Key Measures and Relationships", we assumed the average variable cost of an ice cream bar would remain $0.30 per unit whether the operation sold a small volume or large volume of ice cream bars. However, in actual production environments, average variable cost may fluctuate with volume. At very low production volumes, resources may not be used efficiently, so the variable cost per unit is higher. For example, suppose the ice cream bar venture operators purchase those bars wholesale from a vendor who delivers them in a truck with a freezer. Since the vendor's charge for ice cream bars must cover the cost of the truck driver and truck operation, a large delivery that fills the truck is likely to cost less per ice cream bar than a very small delivery. At the same

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy