Financial Options - Part2
Financial Options - Part2
How volatility can be either estimated from historical data or implied from options
prices using the model?
How the Black-Scholes-Merton model can be extended to deal with European call
and put options on dividend-paying stocks?
The Brownian Motion increments from date t 1 to t2 are normally distributed with
mean 0 and variance t2-t1
3. Zt2 – Zt1 and Zt4 – Zt3 are independently distributed ∀t4 > t3 ≥ t2 > t1
There are no jumps: if we observe the Brownian Motion at very short time
intervals we can’t see any gaps in its process;
o even though prices go up and down all the time, over the long run they
follow an upward trend, whereas the Brownian Motion has no trend (the
mean value of dZt is zero);
The Geometric Brownian Motion (defined below) satisfies all the above requirements
We will use to model the price process for the underlying asset:
In order to price options, we need to know what the distribution of the underlying asset
prices at expiration (ST) is.
If the stock price process is described by a Geometric Brownian Motion what is the
distribution of the future date t prices, ST?
Because our price process incorporates uncertainty, we will never know, before
date t, what St will be;
We will only be able to obtain the distribution of possible ST values;
FINAL ANSWER:
The price in the future date t is given by:
Expression for St :
This happened because we jumped straight to the end of the story (missing the derivations
has this drawback)
We missed the part of the story where we switched to the risk neutral world:
the reason why we need to be in the risk neutral world is the same as in the
binomial model;
If we were not in the risk-neutral world we would need to discount at the expected rate of
return of the call, not r:
but we don’t know the rate of return;
and that’s why we price the option in the risk-neutral world where:
The expectation of the indicator function (the second expectation) is the probability of the
event (ST > K) happening:
if we have trouble seeing this, consider that S T has equal probability of assuming n
different values {ST,1, ST,2, … , ST, m, ST, m+1, …, ST, n} and that the first m of those values
are such that ST > K
m
In that case the probability of ST >K is clearly and:
n
N the
cumulative distribution
The third equality follows from writing the expectation in its integral form, where
2
−ε
2
e is the standard normal pdf;
∅ (ε )=
√ 2 π
The last equality follows from the fact that S T > K when ε >−d 2, as we determined
previously.
Substituting for ∅ (ε ):
where:
Plugging everything together, we obtain the Black-Scholes formula for a call option:
where:
Of course, that we can arrive at the formula for the put price using formula for the call
price and the put-call parity (remember, we are pricing European options).
COMPUTING N( . )
Just by inspecting the Black-Scholes formula, we can determine the replicating portfolio of
a call:
So:
Obviously, the probability of a put option expiring ITM (i.e. a call expiring OTM) is:
When we used the binomial model, the answer to these questions were:
p0=0.502 € x 100=50.02 €
Next, we look up on the tables the values closest to N(-d1 ) and N (-d2) and interpolate them:
Now, suppose the stock price 0.125 years from today is 5.025€:
this corresponds to the price after one up move when we used the binomial model on Day 07
If we compute the price of the put in this scenario using the Black-Scholes formula using these
parameters:
we obtain:
The Black-Scholes model assumes that the replicating portfolio is continuously adjusted, that is,
after a very short time interval and after a very change in the price of the underlying asset:
in practice, even daily adjustments on the replicating portfolio might not be frequent enough;
To work around this problem, we will have to hedge not only the delta (as we are doing here), but
other greeks.
VOLATILITY ESTIMATION: HISTORICAL VS. IMPLIED
All parameters needed to use the Black-Scholes formula are readily observable, except for
the annualized volatility of the underlying asset’s rate of return σ :
K and the expiration date, from which we compute T, are written on the option
contract;
S0 can be observed in the market;
r can also be observed in the market, being the risk-free rate of return with a
maturity T (or close to it);
Recall that assuming a GBM as the stock price process (and working with real-world
probabilities) we have: