C5 - The Theory of Consumer Choice
C5 - The Theory of Consumer Choice
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Introduction
Recall from Lecture 1:
People face tradeoffs.
Buying more of one good leaves
less income to buy other goods.
Working more hours means more income and
more consumption, but less leisure time.
Reducing saving allows more consumption
today but reduces future consumption.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
1
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Budget Constraint:
What the Consumer Can Afford
Example:
Vicky divides his income between two goods:
breads and mangos.
A “consumption bundle” is a particular combination
of the goods, e.g., 40 breads & 300 mangos.
Budget constraint: the limit on the consumption
bundles that a consumer can afford
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
2
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The budget constraint
Vicky’s income: $1200
Prices: PB = $4 per loaf, PM = $1 per mango
A. If Vicky spends all his income on breads,
how many breads does he buy?
B. If Vicky spends all his income on mangos,
how many mangos does he buy?
C. If Vicky buys 100 breads, how many mangos
can he buy?
D. Plot each of the bundles from parts A – C on a
graph that measures breads on the horizontal
axis and mangos on the vertical, connect the
dots.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Answers
D. Vicky’s budget
Quantity constraint shows
of Mangos the bundles he can
B
A. $1200/$4 afford.
= 300
breads
C
B. $1200/$1
= 1200
mangos
C. 100 breads
cost $400,
$800 left
A
buys 800
mangos Quantity
of breads
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Slope of the Budget Constraint
From C to D, Quantity The slope of the
of Mangos budget constraint
“rise” =
equals the relative
–200 mangos
price of the good
“run” = on the X axis.
+50 breads C
Slope = – 4 D
Vicky must
give up
4 mangos
to get one bread.
Quantity
of
Breads
Budget constraint, continued
Show what happens to Vicky’s budget constraint if:
A. His income falls to $800.
B. The price of mangos rises to
PM = $2 per mango
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Answers, part A
Quantity A fall in income
Now, of Mangos shifts the budget
Vicky constraint down.
can buy
$800/$4
= 200 breads
or
$800/$1
= 800 mangos
or any
combination in
between. Quantity
of
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. Breads
Answers, part B
Vicky Quantity An increase in the
of Mangos price of one good
can still buy
300 breads. pivots the budget
constraint inward.
But now he
can only buy
$1200/$2 =
600 mangos.
Notice:
slope is smaller,
relative price of
breads is now
only 2 mangos. Quantity
of
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. Breads
Utility Function
A utility function is…
A function that measures the level of satisfaction a
consumer receives from any basket of goods and
services.
Written as U = u(y)
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
9
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Marginal Utility
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
11
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Marginal Utility Example
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
12
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Preferences: What the Consumer Wants
Indifference curve: Quantity One of Hurley’s
shows consumption of Mangos indifference curves
bundles that give the
consumer the same
level of satisfaction
B
A, B, and all other
bundles on I1 make A
Hurley equally happy:
I1
he is indifferent
between them.
Quantity
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
13
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Four Properties of Indifference Curves
If the quantity of
fish is reduced, B
the quantity of
A
mangos must be
I1
increased to keep
Hurley equally
happy. Quantity
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
14
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Four Properties of Indifference Curves
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
15
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Four Properties of Indifference Curves
Quantity Hurley’s
3. Indifference curves of Mangos indifference curves
cannot cross.
Suppose they did.
Hurley should prefer
B to C, since B has B
more of both goods.
Yet, Hurley is indifferent C A
between B and C: I1 I4
He likes C as much as A
(both are on I4).
He likes A as much as B Quantity
of Fish
(both are on I1).
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
16
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Four Properties of Indifference Curves
Quantity
4. Indifference curves of Mangos
are bowed inward.
A
Hurley is willing to give
up more mangos for a 6
fish if he has few fish
1
(A) than if he has
B
many (B). 2
1 I1
Quantity
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
17
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Marginal Rate of Substitution
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
18
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
One Extreme Case: Perfect Substitutes
Perfect substitutes: two goods with
straight-line indifference curves,
constant MRS
Example: nickels and dimes
Consumer is always willing to trade
two nickels for one dime.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
19
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Another Extreme Case: Perfect Complements
Perfect complements: two goods with
right-angle indifference curves
Example: Left shoes, right shoes
{7 left shoes, 5 right shoes}
is just as good as
{5 left shoes, 5 right shoes}
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
20
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Less Extreme Cases:
Close Substitutes and Close Complements
Quantity Quantity
of Coke of hot dogs21
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Optimization: What the Consumer Chooses
A is the optimum: Quantity
The optimum
the point on the of Mangos
is the bundle
budget constraint
Hurley most
that touches the
1200 prefers out of
highest possible
all the bundles
indifference curve.
he can afford.
Hurley prefers B to A, B
but he cannot afford B. 600
A
marginal
price of fish
value of fish
(in terms of
(in terms of
mangos)
mangos) 150 300 Quantity
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
23
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Lets consider Julie’s preferences for clothing C
and food F. Her utility function was U(C,F) = CF.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
24
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Effects of an Increase in Income
Quantity
of Mangos
An increase in
income shifts the
budget constraint
outward.
B
If both goods are
A
“normal,” Hurley
buys more of each.
Quantity
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
25
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Inferior vs. normal goods
An increase in income increases the quantity
demanded of normal goods and reduces the
quantity demanded of inferior goods.
Suppose fish is a normal good
but mangos are an inferior good.
Use a diagram to show the effects of
an increase in income on Hurley’s optimal
bundle of fish and mangos.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Answers
Quantity
of Mangos
If mangos are
inferior, the new
optimum will
contain fewer
mangos.
A
B
Quantity
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Effects of a Price Change
Initially, Quantity
of Mangos
PF = $4
1200
PM = $1 initial
optimum
PF falls to $2 new
optimum
budget constraint 600
rotates outward, 500
Hurley buys
more fish and
fewer mangos.
150 300 600 Quantity
350 of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
28
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Income and Substitution Effects
A fall in the price of fish has two effects on
Hurley’s optimal consumption of both goods.
Income effect
A fall in PF boosts the purchasing power of Hurley’s
income, allows him to buy more mangos and more
fish.
Substitution effect
A fall in PF makes mangos more expensive relative
to fish, causes Hurley to buy fewer mangos and
more fish.
Notice: The net effect on mangos is ambiguous.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
29
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The Income and Substitution Effects
Initial Quantity In this example,
optimum at A. of Mangos
the net effect
PF falls. on mangos is
negative.
Substitution effect:
from A to B,
buy more fish and A
fewer mangos. C
Income effect: B
from B to C,
buy more of both
Quantity
goods.
of Fish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
30
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
The substitution effect in two cases
Do you think the substitution effect would be
bigger for substitutes or complements?
Draw an indifference curve for Coke and Pepsi,
and, on a separate graph, one for hot dogs and
hot dog buns.
On each graph, show the effects of a relative
price change (keeping the consumer on the initial
indifference curve).
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Answers
ButInthe substitution
both graphs, theeffect is bigger
relative pricefor substitutes
changes
bythan
the complements.
same amount.
Quantity
of Pepsi Quantity of
hot dog buns
A
B B
Quantity Quantity
of Coke of hot dogs
Deriving Hurley’s Demand Curve for Fish
A: When
B: WhenPPFF== $2,
$4, Hurley
Hurley demands
demands 350
150 fish.
fish.
Quantity Price of
of Mangos Fish
A
$4
A
B
B
$2
DFish
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Summary
• A consumer’s indifference curves represent her
preferences. An indifference curve shows all the
bundles that give the consumer a certain level of
happiness. The consumer prefers points on
higher indifference curves to points on lower
ones.
• The slope of an indifference curve at any point is
the marginal rate of substitution—the rate at
which the consumer is willing to trade one good
for the other.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Summary
• The consumer optimizes by choosing the point
on her budget constraint that lies on the highest
indifference curve. At this point, the marginal
rate of substitution equals the relative price of
the two goods.
• When the price of a good falls, the impact on the
consumer’s choices can be broken down into
two effects, an income effect and a substitution
effect.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Summary
• The income effect is the change in consumption
that arises because a lower price makes the
consumer better off. It is represented by a
movement from a lower indifference curve to a
higher one.
• The substitution effect is the change that arises
because a price change encourages greater
consumption of the good that has become
relatively cheaper. It is represented by a
movement along an indifference curve.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.
Summary
• The theory of consumer choice can be applied in
many situations. It can explain why demand
curves can potentially slope upward, why higher
wages could either increase or decrease labor
supply, and why higher interest rates could
either increase or decrease saving.
© 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as
permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.