0% found this document useful (0 votes)
330 views32 pages

Financial Accounting Theory: Sixth William R. Scott

Uploaded by

anon_757820301
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
330 views32 pages

Financial Accounting Theory: Sixth William R. Scott

Uploaded by

anon_757820301
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 32

Financial Accounting Theory

Sixth Edition
William R. Scott

Chapter 9
An Analysis of Conflict

9-1
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Chapter 9
An Analysis of Conflict

9-2
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.2 Game Theory

• Models a conflict situation between rational


players
• Number of players
– More than 1
– Few enough that each player takes the actions of other
players into account
• Types of games
– Cooperative
• Binding agreement
– Non-cooperative
• No binding agreement

9-3
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.3.1 A Single-Period Non-
Cooperative Game
Table 9.1 UTILITY PAYOFFS IN A NON-COOPERATIVE GAME
Manager
HONEST (H) DISTORT (D)
BUY (B) 60, 40 20, 80
Investor
REFUSE
TO BUY (R) 35, 20 35, 30

» Continued

9-4
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
A Single-Period Non-Cooperative
Game (continued)
• Nash equilibrium solution
– RD: payoffs 35,30
• Cooperative solution
– BH: payoffs 60, 40
• Single play of the game
– Why is BH unlikely?
• Multiple plays: BH more likely
– Manager reputation and ethical behaviour
– Folk theorem

9-5
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.3.2 A Multi-Period Game (optional section)

• Example 9.2
– A 5-period game
– If parties do not trust each other, game unravels to
single-period
– If parties trust each other, game continues with
probabilities shown.
• Note: trust is not complete but depends on difference
between a player’s expected payoff from continuing and
payoff from ending the game
– How is trust maintained?
• Ethics
• Legal liability
• GAAP

9-6
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.4 Agency Theory
• A principal wants to hire an agent for some
specialized task
– Assume single-period, for simplicity
– Agency models separation of ownership and control
• Principal and agent are rational. Agent is risk-
averse. Principal may be risk-averse, but assume
risk-neutral for simplicity
• Principal wants agent to work hard, but
– Agent is effort-averse

>> Continued

9-7
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Moral hazard problem of information asymmetry


– Principal cannot observe manager effort - call it a
– Call manager’s disutility of effort V(a)
• More effort ---> greater disutility
– Implies manager may shirk on effort
• E.g., if paid a fixed salary, how hard will the manager work?
• Analogy: if no final exam, how hard will students work?

>> Continued

9-8
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Examples of agency contracts


– What gives the following agents an incentive to “work hard” for
the principal?
• Doctor, dentist
• Lawyer
• Auditor
• Hockey player
• Construction worker
• Manager

9-9
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.3


– Owner: rational, risk-neutral
• Wants manager to work hard, to max. expected firm payoff
• Think of payoff as the total cash flow to be realized from
manager’s current-period effort
– Manager: rational, risk-averse and effort-averse
• Wants to max. expected utility of compensation , net of
disutility of effort V(a)
• More effort, less utility
– If manager works hard, V(a) = -2
– If manager shirks, V(a) = -1.71

» Continued

9 - 10
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.3 (continued)


– Motivating the manager to work hard
• Salary: manager will shirk
• Direct monitoring of manager effort: unlikely in
owner/manager context. Manager will shirk
• Indirect monitoring: Unlikely in owner/manager context
unless moving support. Manager will shirk
• Owner rents firm to manager: Manager will work hard, but
manager bears all the risk, requires low rent for manager
to attain reservation utility, reducing contract efficiency
• Give manager a share of the payoff

» Continued

9 - 11
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.3 (continued)

– A problem arises if manager paid a share of payoff


• Firm payoff not known until after contract expires (single
period contract).
• Some manager effort does not pay of in current period
– e.g., R&D, contingencies
• Manager has to be paid at contract expiry
– A solution
• Base manager compensation on a performance measure
which is available at period end
– Performance measure must be jointly observable

» Continued

9 - 12
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.3 (continued)


– Net income as a performance measure
• To motivate manager effort, an efficient contract may offer the
manager compensation based on a share of firm net income
– Will manager be willing to accept contract?
• Concept of reservation utility, call it R
– If manager is to work for owner, must receive expected utility of
at least R
» Level of R depends on manager reputation
» R treated as fixed in a single-period contract

» Continued

9 - 13
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.4


– Assumptions
• Manager has 2 effort choices:
– Work hard (a1 )
– Shirk (a2 )
• If manager works hard
payoff = 100 with prob. 0.6
payoff = 55 with prob. 0.4
• If manager shirks
payoff = 100 with prob. 0.4
payoff = 55 with prob. 0.6

Note fixed support

» Continued

9 - 14
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.4 (continued)


• Assumptions, cont’d
– Manager’s contract : compensation = k × net income, 0 ≤ k ≤ 1
– Manager’s reservation utility: R = 3
– Quality of net income (noisy, but unbiased, e.g., fair value
accounting)
• If payoff is going to be $100
– Net income = $115 with prob. 0.8
– Net income = $40 with prob. 0.2

• If payoff is going to be $55


– Net income = $115 with prob. 0.2
– Net income = $40 with prob. 0.8

» Continued

9 - 15
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.4 (continued)


– Manager’s utility
EUm(a1) = 0.6[0.8(k × 115)1/2 + 0.2(k × 40)1/2]
+ 0.4[0.2(k × 115)1/2 + 0.8(k × 40)1/2] - 2
EUm(a2) = 0.4[0.8(k × 115)1/2 + 0.2(k × 40)1/2]
+ 0.6[0.2(k × 115)1/2 + 0.8(k × 40)1/2] – 1.71
– Owner’s utility (risk neutral)
EUO(a1) = 0.6[0.8(100 - (1 – k) × 115) + 0.2(100 - (1 – k) × 40)]
+ 0.4[0.2(55 - (1 – k) × 115) + 0.8(55 - (1 – k) × 40)]

» Continued

9 - 16
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.4 (continued0

– Formal Statement of the Owner’s Problem


• Find k to maximize EUO(a)
Subject to:
Manager wants to take a1 (incentive compatibility: i.e.,
manager utility higher for a1 than a2)
Manager receives reservation utility of R = 3
– The result:
K = .3237

» Continued

9 - 17
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.4 (continued0


– Check
• Manager’s utility:

EUm(a1) = 0.6[0.8(.3237 × 115)1/2 + 0.2(.3237 × 40)1/2]


+ 0.4[0.2(.3237 × 115)1/2 + 0.8(.3237 × 40)1/2] – 2 = 3

EUm(a2) = 0.4[0.8(.3237 × 115)1/2 + 0.2(.3237 × 40)1/2]


+ 0.6[0.2(.3237 × 115)1/2 + 0.8(.3237 × 40)1/2] – 1.71 = 2.9896

• Manager wants to “work hard” since his/her utility is higher

» Continued

9 - 18
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• Agency contract example 9.4 (continued0


– Owner’s utility
EUO(a1) = 0.6[0.8(100 - .3237 × 115) + 0.2(100 - .3237 × 40)]
+ 0.4[0.2(55 - .3237 × 115) + 0.8(55 - .3237 × 40)]
= 55.4566

Compare with owner’s utility of rental contract (Example


9.3) = 51

9 - 19
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)

• A more efficient contract, Example 9.5


– Retain example 9.4 assumptions, except
• Higher quality of net income (less noisy, still unbiased)
– If payoff is going to be 100
» Net income = $110 with prob. 0.8462
» Net income = $45 with prob. 0.1538

– If payoff is going to be 55
» Net income = $110 with prob. 0.1538
» Net income = $45 with prob. 0.8462

• What share of net income does manager now require to


attain reservation utility?

» Continued

9 - 20
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Agency Theory (continued)
• A more efficient contract, Example 9.5 (continued)
– k = .3185 (compared with .3237 in previous contract)

EUm(a1) = 0.6[0.8462(.3185 × 110)1/2 + 0.1538(.3185 × 45)1/2]


+ 0.4[0.1538(.3185 × 110)1/2 + 0.8462(.3185 × 45)1/2] – 2 = 3
EUO(a1) = 0.6[.8462(100 – (.3185 × 110) + 0.1538(100 - .3185 × 45)]
+ 0.4[.1538(55 – (.3185 × 110) + 0.8462(55 - .3185 × 45)]
= 55.8829
Compare with owner’s utility of 55.4566 in Example 9.4
Less noisy net income increases contract efficiency
How can accountant decrease noise in net income?

9 - 21
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.5 Manager’s Information
Advantage
• Post-decision information
– Manager can observe unmanaged net income, but
owner can’t
– In a single-period contract, rational manager will shirk
and report highest possible net income
– Example 9.6: owner utility falls to 50.8165

» Continued

9 - 22
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Manager’s Information Advantage
(continued)

• The revelation principle


– If high net income is realized, manager will report high
net income
– Raise manager’s compensation if low net income is
realized to the point where same compensation is
received whether net income is high or low
– Then, if low net income is realized, manager is
indifferent between reporting high or low net income
– Assume if indifferent, manager will report low net
income if low net income is realized
– Result: manager reports truthfully
» Continued

9 - 23
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Manager’s Information Advantage
(continued)

• Example 9.7
– Manager continues to shirk
– Owner’s utility remains at 50.8165 as per Example 9.6
– But, manager reports truthfully
• No adverse selection problem

» Continued

9 - 24
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Manager’s Information Advantage
(continued)

• Problems in applying revelation principle in a


financial reporting context
– Manager may be punished for reporting the truth
• May be fired if low net income reported
– Contract restrictions
• If compensation is capped, manager is effectively
punished for reporting net income higher than cap
– Restrictions on ability to communicate
• Reporting the truth may impose legal liability and
reputation loss on manager and owner, effectively
blocking honest communication

» Continued

9 - 25
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Manager’s Information Advantage
(continued)

• Result of these problems is that it may be more


efficient to allow some upwards earnings
management
• But manager will then overdose on earnings
management
– i.e., back to example 9.6
• A solution: restrict earnings management
through GAAP: Example 9.8

» Continued

9 - 26
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Manager’s Information Advantage
(continued)

• Example 9.8 (optional)


– Illustrates how GAAP can restrict earnings management
to point where manager must work hard to attain
reservation utility
– Some earnings management remains, but under control
– Owner’s utility now 55.4981, up from Examples 9.6 and
9.7 (50.8165)
– Some earnings management can be “good” if controlled
by GAAP

9 - 27
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.8 Implications of Agency Theory
for Accounting
• Holmström’s agency model
– Basing manager’s compensation on 2 variables is better
than on 1 variable, unless the 2 variables are perfectly
correlated
• Example 9.10
– Holmström’s model implies that net income is in
competition with share price performance for “market
share” in compensation contracts

» Continued

9 - 28
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Implications of Agency Theory for
Accounting (continued)
• Holmström’s agency model (continued)
– To maintain market share in compensation contracts,
net income must be informative about manager effort
– To be informative, net income must have
• Sensitivity
• Precision
– These two desirable qualities usually have to be traded
off
• E.g., fair value accounting may be more sensitive than
historical cost, but less precise. Why?

9 - 29
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
Implications of Agency Theory for
Accounting (continued)
• Contract incompleteness & rigidity
– These are basic reasons why accounting policies can have
economic consequences
• Incompleteness
– Contracts cannot anticipate all possible state realizations
– E.g., new accounting standards may arise during contract term
» Manager’s net-income-based compensation may be affected
» Debt covenant ration may be affected

• Rigidity
– Once signed, contracts hard to change
– Result: economic consequences
• I.e., accounting policies matter since they can affect contracts

9 - 30
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.9 Reconciliation of Economic
Consequences and Securities
Market Efficiency
• Contract incompleteness and rigidity mean that
accounting policies matter
• This argument does not conflict with efficient
securities market theory

9 - 31
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc
9.10 Conclusions

• Accounting policies (even without cash flow


effects) can have economic consequences but
securities markets can still be efficient
• Role of net income in monitoring and motivating
manager performance equally important as
informing investors
• Net income competes with share price as a
performance measure
• Role of GAAP in controlling earnings
management

9 - 32
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Canada Inc

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy