Consumer Choice: ECON1005 Principles of Economics I (Microeconomics)
Consumer Choice: ECON1005 Principles of Economics I (Microeconomics)
Page 2
2. PREFERENCES
Basic assumptions of consumers’ rational preferences:
Page 3
3. UTILITY FUNCTIONS
Utility: a set of numbers that is arbitrarily assigned to reflect the preference ordering of
consumption baskets.
If a consumer prefers A to B, we would say the utility obtained from A is higher than the utility obtained
from B.
Hence, it is also commonly interpreted as the measure of overall satisfaction obtained from consumption.
It is not possible to compare utilities between different consumers.
Utility function: shows the relationship between utility measures and quantity of goods
consumed.
𝑈=𝑈 ( 𝑞1 , 𝑞2 , ⋯ , 𝑞𝑛 )
q1
1 2
PAGE 5
APPLICATION:
FLAT
EXPECTATIONS
In 2009, it seemed that 3D movie could rescue a film
business battered by falling DVD sales.
Fully 71% of the box office spending on “Avatar” on its
opening weekend, in December 2009, went on the 3D
version.
PAGE 6
The total utility curve: the graphical
U The total utility of
representation of the utility function of a single
consuming two units
of the good. Total Utility good.
56
Marginal utility: the additional utility that can
50 Note that the MU is be obtained by consuming one more unit of a
the slope of the total
42 good.
∆U utility curve.
30
∆q
U U (q , q )
1 2
q1
q2
8
Keep q2 6
8 Keep q1
constant at 6
certain level 2 2 constant at
0 certain level
PAGE 8
3. UTILITY FUNCTIONS
If we were to cut the utility hill vertically at a particular level of good 2, we can study
how utility level varies with the change in consumption of good 1, keeping q2 constant.
For example, if q2 is kept constant at 4 units, the total utility curve of good 1 can be
derived:
6 Total Utility
(when q2 = 4)
q1
4 9
PAGE 9
4. INDIFFERENCE CURVES
If we cut the utility hill horizontally at a particular level of utility, and project the outside
edge of the hill on the floor. We derive an indifference curve that shows all the
combinations of good 1 and good 2 that yield the same level of utility.
U
U=6
c
U=4
a b
q1
q2
8
8 6
6
2 2
0
CONTOUR LINES
PAGE 11
4. INDIFFERENCE CURVES
Indifference map: a graphical representation of a set of indifference curves.
q2
8 a
b
4
I (U 6)
2
I (U 4)
1
I (U 2)
3
q1
2 4
4. INDIFFERENCE CURVES q2
Given the assumptions about preferences, indifference
Region I (upper right):
curves have four important properties:
Consumption baskets that
yield a higher level of
Indifference curves slope downward and indifference utility
curves farther from the origin represent higher level of
utility. q21
q2 A> B
A
but B ~ C and A ~ D
(inconsistent!)
B C>D
B
C
A I2
D I1
q1 PAGE 13 q1
4. INDIFFERENCE CURVES
The downward sloping indifference curve q2
implies that a consumer is willing to give up
one good to consume more of another, to
keep his utility constant.
a
q1
5. BUDGET CONSTRAINT
Budget constraint identifies all the combinations of goods that a consumer can buy with his
available income, at given prices.
p1q1 p2 q2 Y
Budget Line: a graphical representation of the budget constraint, showing all the combinations of
goods that a consumer can buy spending all his available income, at given prices.
Suppose the price of good 1 (p1) is $1, price of good 2 (p2) is $2 and the income available for the
consumer (Y) is $50, then the budget line can be drawn:
q2
The slope of a budget line (magnitude) is
called the relative price of good 1: the
amount of one good (good 2) that a
consumer is required to give up for an Y
25
extra unit of another good (good 1) from p2
Slope = 0.5
the market. That is (Relative price of good 1 = p /p )
1 2
p1
Relative price of good 1
p2
L
Y q
50 1
PAGE 16 p1
5. BUDGET CONSTRAINT
Example 1 (Change in income): q2
Suppose the consumer’s income
rises from $50 to $100, with
prices remain unchanged at p1 = 100
50
$1 and p2 = $2. How would the 2
budget line change?
Y 50 p1/p2 = 1
25
p2 2
p1/p2 = 0.5
L2
Example 2 (Change in price): L1
q1
Suppose the price of good 1 Y 50
25
Y 50
50 100
100
increases from $1 to $2, with the p1 2
'
p1 1 1
price of good 2 and the
consumer’s income remain
unchanged at p2 = $2 and Y =
$50. How would the budget line
change?
6. CONSUMER’S OPTIMAL
CHOICE
How an individual make his consumption choice?
Among all the affordable choices, he chooses the one that he prefers most.
The consumer’s optimal choice is the consumption basket that maximizes his
utility subject to his budget constraint.
It can be identified by putting the budget line and indifference curves together.
PAGE 18
Which point is 𝑝1
the consumer’s q2 |𝑀𝑅𝑆|>
optimal choice? 𝑝2
The point
where the a
budget line is e I3 𝑝1
tangent to the |𝑀𝑅𝑆|<
highest 𝑝2
attainable I2
indifference
curve. d
b
I1
L
q1
6. CONSUMER’S OPTIMAL
CHOICE
The tangency condition implies:
𝑝1
|𝑀𝑅𝑆|=
𝑝2
It means the amount of good 2 that the consumer is willing to give up for an additional
unit of good 1 is equal to the amount he is required to give up for it from the market, at
the optimal choice. (What is the intuition behind?)
PAGE 20
Which point is the 𝑀𝑈 1 𝑀 𝑝 𝑈12
consumer’s q2 |𝑀𝑅𝑆> |>
optimal choice? 𝑝1 𝑝𝑝2 2
The point
where the a
budget line is
tangent to the
e I3 𝑀𝑈 1 𝑀𝑝𝑈1 2
|𝑀𝑅𝑆<|<
highest 𝑝1 𝑝𝑝22
attainable
indifference I2
curve. d
b
I1
L
q1
6. CONSUMER’S OPTIMAL
CHOICE
The tangency condition implies:
𝑝1
|𝑀𝑅𝑆|=
𝑝2
It means the amount of good 2 that the consumer is willing to give up for an additional unit of good 1 is
equal to the amount he is required to give up for it from the market, at the optimal choice. (What is the
intuition behind?)
Recall that MRS = MU1/MU2. Rearranging the terms, the tangency condition also implies:
𝑀𝑈 1 𝑀 𝑈 2
=
𝑝1 𝑝2
where MUi / pi is the marginal utility the consumer can obtain by spending an extra dollar on good i, which
is called marginal utility per dollar. Thus, the tangency condition means the marginal utility the consumer
can obtain by spending an extra dollar on each good is the same, at the optimal choice. (What is the
intuition behind?)
At this point, there is no further gain from reallocating the spending on two goods.
PAGE 22
6. CONSUMER’S OPTIMAL
CHOICE
The first interpretation is based on the indifference curve approach (in the appendix of
chapter 6) and the second interpretation is based on the marginal utility approach (in
the main content of chapter 6). Here we demonstrate that the two approaches
essentially yield the same conclusion.
Suppose a consumer consumes n goods, the condition for the optimal input choice can
be generalized
𝑀𝑈 1 𝑀 𝑈 2 𝑀 𝑈𝑛
= =⋯=
𝑝1 𝑝2 𝑝𝑛
PAGE 23
6. CONSUMER’S OPTIMAL
CHOICE
Example 3: Mark consumes only cookies and books. At his current consumption bundle, his
marginal utility from books is 10 and from cookies is 5. Each book costs $10, and each cookie
costs $2.
Is he maximizing his utility? Explain.
If he is not, how can he increase his utility while keeping his total expenditure constant?
In order for him to be maximizing his utility, he must set his consumption such that the marginal
utility per dollar (MUi/pi) of the last unit consumed is equal across commodities. In this case:
MU b 10 MU c 5
1 2.5
pb 10 pc 2
MU b MU c
pb pc
Specifically, the marginal utility per dollar is greater for cookies. Therefore, he should decrease
his consumption of books and increase his consumption of cookies. By consuming fewer books
and more cookies, MUb will rise and MUc will drop (why?). Mark should reallocate his spending
until MUb/pb = MUc/pc, at which he is maximizing his utility.
PAGE 24
7. COMPARATIVE STATICS
ANALYSIS
Applying the consumer theory, we can examine the changes in the consumer
choices whenever there is a change in an exogenous variable. We attempt to
provide answers to two main questions:
PAGE 25
7. COMPARATIVE STATICS ANALYSIS:
CHANGES IN INCOME
q2
Suppose Income increases from Y1 to Y2
Will the consumer be better off?
I2
e1
q 12
I1
L2
L1
q1
1
q
1 Page 26
APPLICATION: CHINA’S
SEAFOOD DEMAND
Long the world’s top producer and exporter of
seafood, China is set to also be the world’s
biggest market for seafood in 2016, according
to the FAO.
e1
q 12 e2
I1
I2
L1 L2
q1 (Luxury fish)
1
q1
Page 28
8. COMPARATIVE STATICS
ANALYSIS: CHANGES IN PRICE
q2 1
Suppose price of good 1 decreases from p1 to p1
2
I1
L1 L2
q1
1
q1 q1
2
Y p11 Y p 2
1 Page 29
8. COMPARATIVE STATICS
ANALYSIS: CHANGES IN PRICE
q2
In analyzing the price effect, our main focus is the impact of a change
in price of good 1 on the quantity of good 1 consumed. How about the
impact on good 2?
What if good 1 and good 2 are substitutes?
e3 What if good 1 and good 2 are complements?
e1 If the consumer view good 1 and 2 as substitutes
e2 (complements), a decrease in price of good 1 will
I2
reduce (increase) the her consumption in good 2.
I2
I1
L1 L2
q1
q1
1
q1 Y p
2 1
1 Y p 2
1
Page 30
APPLICATION:
SANDWICHED
Fast-food chains continued to be a rare bright spot for
Japan during its two-decade-long economic slump. Since
2008 the size of the market has increased from $35 billion
to $45 billion (those figured include convenience stores, or
konbini); that of restaurants has declined every year in that
period.
Page 31
APPLICATION: SANDWICHED
e2
e1
I1
I2
L2 L1
q1 (Fast food)
PAGE 32
q2
Suppose price of good 1
8. COMPARATIVE STATICS ANALYSIS: 1 2
decreases from p1 to p1 to p13
Y p2 CHANGES IN PRICE
e3
e1 e2 In this case, the amount of good 1
I 3
consumed increases
I2
I1
L1 L2 L3 Individual demand curve: shows
q1 the relationship between the
Y p11 Y p12 Y p13
p1 quantity demanded for a single
good and its price, keeping
income constant.
p11 E1
p12
E2 How about market demand
E3
curve?
p13
Individual
demand curve
q1
q11 q12 q13
Page 33