Lecture 7
Lecture 7
Monetary Policy
Lecture Outline
1 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Define monetary policy and describe the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy
goals.
The Fed has four main monetary policy goals that are intended to promote a
well-functioning economy:
1. Price stability
2. High employment
4. Economic growth
Price stability and high employment are both sometimes said to be goals that
the Fed has a dual mandate to attain and are explicitly mentioned in the
Employment Act of 1946 that Congress passed at the end of World War II.
Congress and the president may be better able to promote economic growth in
particular than is the Fed, such as through changes in tax laws that increase
the return to saving and investing.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 6 of 57
The Money Market and the Fed’s Choice of Monetary Policy
Targets
2 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Describe the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy targets and explain how
expansionary and contractionary monetary policies affect the interest rate.
The Fed tries to keep both the unemployment and inflation rates low, but it can’t
affect either of these economic variables directly.
Instead, it uses monetary policy targets, which are variables that it can affect
directly and that, in turn, affect variables, such as real GDP, employment, and the
price level, that are closely related to its policy goals.
The two main monetary policy targets are the money supply and the interest rate,
although the Fed was forced to develop new policy tools during the recession of
2007–2009.
During normal times, the Fed typically uses the interest rate as its policy target.
The money demand curve slopes downward because lower interest rates cause households
and firms to switch from financial assets, such as U.S. Treasury bills, to money.
All other things being equal, a fall in the interest rate from 4 percent to 3 percent will increase
the quantity of money demanded from $900 billion to $950 billion.
An increase in the interest rate will decrease the quantity of money demanded.
The interest rate is the opportunity cost, or what you forgo, to hold money.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 9 of 57
Figure 26.3 Shifts in the Money Demand Curve
Changes in real GDP or the price level cause the money demand curve to shift.
An increase in real GDP or an increase in the price level will cause the money demand
curve to shift from MD1 to MD2.
A decrease in real GDP or a decrease in the price level will cause the money demand
curve to shift from MD1 to MD3.
The sellers of these Treasury securities deposit the funds they receive from the
Fed in banks, which increases the banks’ reserves.
Typically, the banks loan out most of these reserves, which creates new
checking account deposits and expands the money supply.
If the FOMC decides to decrease the money supply, it orders the trading desk
to sell Treasury securities, which decreases banks’ reserves and contracts the
money supply.
When the Fed increases the money supply, the short-term interest rate must fall
until it reaches a level at which households and firms are willing to hold the
additional money.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 11 of 57
Figure 26.4
The loanable funds model is concerned with the long-term real rate of interest,
and the money market model is concerned with the short-term nominal rate of
interest, but there is often a close connection between their movements.
The long-term real rate of interest is the interest rate that is most relevant when:
When conducting monetary policy, however, the short-term nominal interest rate
is most relevant because it is the interest rate most affected by increases and
decreases in the money supply.
There are many different interest rates in the economy, but for purposes of
monetary policy, the Fed has targeted the interest rate known as the federal
funds rate.
In normal times, banks keep few excess reserves, and when they need
additional reserves, they borrow in the federal funds market from banks that
have reserves available.
Federal funds rate The interest rate banks charge each other for overnight
loans.
The Fed can set a target for the federal funds rate, which is determined by the
supply of reserves relative to the demand for them.
Changes in the federal funds rate have greater and quicker effects on short-
term interest rates than they do on long-term interest rates.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 15 of 57
Figure 26.6 Federal Funds Rate Targeting, January 1998–September 2011
The Fed does not set the federal funds rate, but its ability to increase or decrease bank
reserves quickly through open market operations keeps the actual federal funds rate close
to the Fed’s target rate.
The orange line is the Fed’s target for the federal funds rate, and the jagged green line
represents the actual value for the federal funds rate on a weekly basis.
Note: The federal funds target for the period after December 2008 was 0 to 0.25 percent.
3 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Use aggregate demand and aggregate supply graphs to show the effects of
monetary policy on real GDP and the price level.
With the exception of government purchases, changes in interest rates will affect
the components of aggregate demand in the following ways:
• Consumption. Lower interest rates lower the cost of durable goods and
reduce the return to saving, leading households to save less and spend more.
Higher interest rates raise the cost of consumer durables and increase the return
to saving, leading households to save more and spend less.
• Investment. Higher interest rates make it more expensive for firms and
households to borrow, thereby decreasing investment.
Lower interest rates increase the demand for stocks and make it less expensive
for firms and households to borrow, thereby increasing investment.
If interest rates in the United States decline relative to interest rates in other
countries, the value of the dollar will fall and net exports will rise.
The Effects of Monetary Policy on Real GDP and the Price Level
The Fed can use monetary policy to affect the price level and, in the short run,
the level of real GDP, allowing it to attain its policy goals of high employment
and price stability.
In the basic version of the aggregate demand and aggregate supply model,
we assume that there is no economic growth, so the long-run aggregate supply
curve doesn’t shift.
To stimulate the economy in late 2008, the Fed pushed the target for the federal funds rate to
nearly zero and kept it there through 2011, but faced a liquidity trap when many banks began
piling up excess reserves rather than lending the funds out to those whose financial positions
had been damaged by the recession.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 22 of 57
Making Too Low for Zero: The Fed Tries “Quantitative
the Easing” and “Operation Twist”
Connection
Because the federal funds rate
cannot be negative, the Fed embarked on a
policy of quantitative easing by purchasing
securities—including certain mortgage-backed
securities—beyond the short-term Treasury
securities that are usually involved in open
market operations.
So in September 2011, the Fed announced a new program, which some people in
financial markets called “Operation Twist,” under which it would purchase $400 billion
in long-term Treasury securities while it would sell an equal amount of shorter-term
Treasury securities.
Both quantitative easing and Operation Twist had the same objective: to reduce
interest rates on long-term Treasury securities, which typically move closely with
those on home mortgage loans, in order to increase aggregate demand.
MyEconLab Your Turn: Test your understanding by doing related problems 3.11 and 3.12 at the end of this chapter.
A lag, or delay, can occur before the Fed recognizes that a recession has begun
because it takes months for economic statistics to be gathered by the Commerce
Department, the Census Bureau, the Bureau of Labor Statistics, and the Fed
itself.
By the time the FOMC analyzes the data and concludes that the economy is in
recession, it may begin an expansionary monetary policy when it is not needed if
the recession has already ended and an expansion has begun.
In that case, the increase in aggregate demand caused by the Fed’s lowering
interest rates is likely to push the economy beyond potential real GDP and cause
a significant acceleration in inflation.
In sum, the Fed has inadvertently engaged in a procyclical policy, which increases
the severity of the business cycle, as opposed to a countercyclical policy, which is
meant to reduce its severity and is what the Fed intended to use.
Making this mistake is less likely in a long and severe recession such as that of
2007–2009.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 24 of 57
Figure 26.8 The Effect of a Poorly Timed Monetary Policy on the Economy
The upward-sloping straight line represents the long-run growth trend in real GDP.
The curved red line represents the path real GDP takes because of the business cycle.
If the Fed is too late in implementing a change in monetary policy,
real GDP will follow the curved blue line.
The Fed’s expansionary monetary policy results in too great an increase in aggregate
demand during the next expansion, which causes an increase in the inflation rate.
In addition to the other problems the Federal Reserve encounters in successfully conducting
monetary policy, it must make decisions using data that may be subject to substantial
revisions.
MyEconLab Your Turn: Test your understanding by doing related problems 3.13 and 3.14 at the end of this chapter.
The arrows point to the steps involved in the policy that occur relative to what
would have happened without the policy.
This point is important because a contractionary monetary policy does not cause
the price level to fall; rather, it causes the price level to rise by less than it would
have risen without the policy.
4 LEARNING OBJECTIVE
Use the dynamic aggregate demand and aggregate supply model to analyze
monetary policy.
The dynamic aggregate demand and aggregate supply model can provide us
with a more complete understanding of monetary policy.
The hypothetical information in the table above shows what the values for real GDP and the
price level will be in 2015 if the Fed does not use monetary policy.
a. If the Fed wants to keep real GDP at its potential level in 2015, should it use an
expansionary policy or a contractionary policy?
Should the trading desk buy Treasury bills or sell them?
Solving the Problem
Step 1: Review the chapter material.
Step 2: Answer the questions in part a. by explaining how the Fed can keep real
GDP at its potential level.
Because the economy will be below potential real GDP in 2015 without monetary policy,
the Fed must undertake an expansionary policy to keep real GDP at its potential level
by buying Treasury bills, which will increase reserves in the banking system.
Banks will increase their loans, which will increase the money supply and lower the
interest rate.
The hypothetical information in the table above shows what the values for real GDP and the
price level will be in 2015 if the Fed does not use monetary policy.
b. Suppose the Fed’s policy is successful in keeping real GDP at its potential level in 2015.
State whether each of the following will be higher or lower than if the Fed had taken
no action:
i Real GDP
ii Potential real GDP
iii The inflation rate
iv The unemployment rate
Step 3: Answer part b. by explaining the effect of the Fed’s policy.
If the Fed’s policy is successful, real GDP in 2015 will increase from $15.4 trillion to its
potential level of $15.6 trillion.
Potential real GDP is not affected by monetary policy, so its value will not change.
The expansionary monetary policy shifts the AD curve to the right, so short-run equilibrium
will move up the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve, and the price level will be higher.
Because the level of real GDP will be higher, the unemployment rate will be lower than it
would have been without policy.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall 34 of 57
Solved Problem 26.4
The Effects of Monetary Policy
Year Potential GDP Real GDP Price Level
2014 $15.2 trillion $15.2 trillion 114
2015 15.6 trillion 15.4 trillion 116
The hypothetical information in the table above shows what the values for real GDP and the
price level will be in 2015 if the Fed does not use monetary policy.
c. Draw an aggregate demand and aggregate supply graph to illustrate your answer.
Be sure that your graph contains LRAS and SRAS curves for 2014 and 2015; AD curves
for both years, with and without monetary policy action; and equilibrium real GDP and the
price level in 2015, with and without policy.
Step 4: Answer part c. by drawing the graph.
Your graph should look similar to Figure 26.9.
MyEconLab Your Turn: For more practice, do related problems 4.4 and 4.5 at the end of this chapter.