Econ 2020A: Section 8: Sarah Wolfolds and Cuicui Chen
Econ 2020A: Section 8: Sarah Wolfolds and Cuicui Chen
Agenda
(1) Exchange Equilibrium and the Second Welfare Theorem
(2) Two Sector Equilibrium with Production
1. Exchange Equilibrium and the Second Welfare Theorem
Consider an exchange economy with two identical consumers. Their common utility
function is ui (x1i , x2i ) = x1i x1
for 0 < < 1. Society has 10 units of x1 and 10 units
2i
of x2 in all. Find endowments 1 and 2 , where 1 6= 2 , and prices that will support an
equilibrium allocation of (5,5) for both consumers.
First well start as usual by normalizing prices so that our price vector p* = (1, p).
Also note that we can write each consumers endowment as 1 = (11 , 21 ) and 2 =
(10 11 , 10 21 ) since there are a total of 10 units of each good in the economy.
Next find each consumers Walrasian demands. We know consumer 1s wealth is 11 +p21 ,
so consumer 1s Walrasian demands are:
(1)
(11 + p21 )
).
p
(3)
which simplifies to
(4)
10 + 10p = 10,
To find all endowments that will support as a Walrasian equilibrium allocation the equaldivision allocation giving both consumers the bundle (5,5) at these prices, we consider
conumer 1s Walrasian demands, and find all allocations such that x11 = 5. In other
words:
1
21 ) = 5.
(6)
x11 = (11 + p21 ) = (11 +
which means that the set of all endowments supporting the Walrasian equilibrium allocation
(5,5) is:
(5)
p=
(8)
5 (1 )21
, 11 + 12 = 10, 21 + 22 = 10, and 11 6= 5}
Notice that we only had to look at one consumers Walrasian demand (in this case we
chose x11 ) to find the conditions defining the set of endowments that support (5,5) as a
Walrasian equilibrium. If its not clear why that was sufficient, check that setting each of
x21 , x12 , and x22 equal to 5 all yield the same condition as we saw in (7).
(1 , 2 ) = {(11 , 21 ) : 11 =
Now, assuming that the consumers endowments are 1 = (2, 4) and 2 = (8, 6). What
transfers would need to be made in order to reach an endowment that supports the Walrasian equilibrium (5,5)?
From before, we know that consumer 1s wealth is 11 + p21 and consumer 2s wealth is
10 11 + p(10 21 ), and that p = 1
. Moreover, we know that after the transfer, each
consumer must be able to afford the bundle x = (5, 5), which means each will have wealth
equal to 5 + 5p = 5 + 5 1
. The transfers then are the difference between the wealth
needed to consume x and each consumers initial wealth:
(9)
T1 = p x p 1 = 1 5 +
1
1
1
5 (1 2 +
4) = 3 +
1
1
1
5 (1 8 +
6) = 3
T2 = p x p 2 = 1 5 +
Question 2c) Suppose that the economy consists of just these two consumers. What
price p is necessary to clear the market for bread (and simultaneously for rice)?
Question 2d) What bundles do these consumers choose at that equilibrium price p?
Describe this equilibrium outcome in practical terms - who produces what and what do
they trade?
Question 2e) How does farmer 2s greater relative preference for leisure affect the
nature of the equilibrium results? Depending on the equilibrium price that you identified
in part (c), why is this price greater than / equal to / less than 1?
Solutions. Question a1) As is standard, we want our budget constraint to reflect the
fact that the consumer cannot spend more than her wealth. Here, the wealth is given by
her production of rice:
(11)
1/2
1 xR + p xB 1 LR
Question a2) If w is fixed, and we dont need to consider the consumers choice of
xL , then the remaining preferences are simply Cobb-Douglas over the other two goods.
1/2 1/2
And since we have Cobb-Douglas with xR xB , we know that the consumer will split her
wealth evenly between the two goods (each will have a budget share = 1/2). This means
xR = 21 w and xB = 21 wp .
Note here that preferences are quasilinear, with leisure as the numeraire. This means
that, for sufficient levels of rice and bread, the marginal utility of additional leisure will
be larger than the marginal utility of bread or rice. If we use the Lagrangian, we see that
u
1
the marginal utility of leisure is the inverse of our wage ( x
= wage
). We can think of
L
the wages as the price of leisure or what we pay in foregone income when we choose
to work less.
Note that we usually normalize the price of the numeraire to 1, and therefore the value
of the Lagrange multiplier is usually equal to 1. In the standard quasilinear model, we
usually think about the numeraire as money, which means that the Lagrange multiplier
or the shadow price of wealth is denominated in dollars. However, in this model, weve
chosen to normalize the price of emphrice to 1, and so the shadow price of wealth is instead
directly related to our wage.
Question a3)
To evaluate the farmers optimal behavior, we can solve her constrained optimization
problem:
(12)
1/2 1/2
1/2 1/2
L = xL + xR xB (1 xR + p xB 1 (H xL )1/2 )
Taking the first-order conditions with respect to the choice variable and Lagrangian we
get:
(14)
L
1/2 1/2
= 1/2xR xB = 0
xR
(15)
L
1/2 1/2
= 1/2xR xB p = 0
xB
(16)
L
= 1 + [.5(H xL )1/2 ] = 0
xL
L
= (H xL )1/2 xR p xB = 0
If we use the first two equations to solve for , we can set them equal:
(17)
1/2 1/2
(18)
1/2 1/2
1/2xR xB
(19)
1/2xR xB
=
p
xB =
xR
p
If we plug this into our expression for from the first first-order condition, we get:
(20)
1/2
= 1/2xR
xR 1/2
) = 1/2p1/2
p
Next, we can use the third first-order condition to get another expression for :
(21)
1 = .5(H xL )1/2
(22)
= 2(H xL )1/2
We use this expression and set it equal to the expression for that we wrote above:
(23)
(25)
1/p = 16(H xL )
xL = H
1
16p
As defined above, Lr
= (H xL )1/2 , so
LR =
(26)
1
16p
Question a4) Now we simply want to plug in this optimal value into the fourth first
order condition, which we can rewrite as:
(27)
(H xL )1/2 = xR p xB = xR + p
xR
= 2xR
p
We can then solve for xR and plug in for the value of xL we found in the previous section:
(28)
xR
(H (H
(H xL )1/2
=
=
2
2
1
1/2
16p ))
1
8p1/2
Now, we use the relationship we found between xR and xB to find our last variable:
(29)
xB =
xR
1
1
1
= 1/2 = 3/2
p
p
8p
8p
Question b1) Again, we just want to find an expression to ensure the farmer does not
spend more than he makes by producing bread:
(30)
1/2
1 yR + p yB p LB
Question b2) If w is fixed, the consumer will split her wealth evenly between the two
= 1 w and
goods bread and rice (each will have a budget share = 12 ). This means yR
2
= 1w
yB
2 p
Question b3)
We will use the same steps as we did in part a.
(31)
1/2 1/2
1/2 1/2
L = 2yL + yR yB (1 yR + p yB p (H yL )1/2 )
Taking the first-order conditions with respect to the choice variable and Lagrangian we
get:
(33)
L
1/2 1/2
= 1/2yR yB = 0
yR
(34)
L
1/2 1/2
= 1/2yR yB p = 0
yB
(35)
L
= 2 + [.5p(H yL )1/2 ] = 0
yL
L
= p(H yL )1/2 yR p yB = 0
If we use the first two equations to solve for , we can set them equal:
(36)
1/2 1/2
1/2 1/2
yB
(37)
1/2yR
(38)
yB =
1/2yR yB
p
yR
p
If we plug this into our expression for from the first first-order condition, we get:
1/2
(39)
= 1/2yR
yR 1/2
) = 1/2p1/2
p
Next, we can use the third first-order condition to get another expression for :
2 = .5p(H yL )1/2
(40)
(41)
4(H yL )1/2
p
We use this expression and set it equal to the expression for that we wrote above:
1/2p1/2 =
(42)
4(H yL )1/2
p
(43)
yL = H
(44)
1/2
1
p
64
1
p
64
Question b4) Now we want to plug in this optimal value into the fourth first order
condition, which we can rewrite as:
LB =
(45)
yR
= 2yR
p
We can then solve for yR and plug in for the value of yL we found in the previous section:
(46)
p(H yL )1/2 = yR + p yB = yR + p
1
p))1/2
p(H (H 64
p(H yL )1/2
p3/2
=
=
2
2
16
Now, we use the relationship we found between yR and yB to find our last variable:
(47)
yR
=
(48)
yB
=
yR
p3/2 1
p1/2
=
=
p
16
p
16
1/2
yB + xB = LB
Plugging in for the optimal values of these variables we found in previous sections, we
get:
(50)
p1/2
1
p1/2
+ 3/2 =
16
8
8p
Simplifying, we get:
(51)
p1/2
p2 + 2
=
8
16p3/2
(52)
8p2 + 16 = 16p2
(53)
8p2 = 16
(54)
p = 21/2
Note that we could also check the market-clearing price for rice, but it will give us the
same price by construction (although its always good to check ones algebra!)