Microeconomics Solution: /general Equilibrium
Microeconomics Solution: /general Equilibrium
Solution/General Equilibrium
Exercise 1
Consider a two-individual, two-good economy. The preferences of individual A and individual B over
good 1 and good 2 are represented by the utility function:
u (x1 ; x2 ) = x1 x2 ; x1 0; x2 0;
where xi denotes the quantity of good i consumed by the individual. There are 3 units of each good in the
economy.
A x2A x2B
MRS12 x1A ; x2A = MRS12
B
x1B ; x2B , = : (1)
x1A x1B
Using the binding material constraints,
x1B = 3 x1A ;
x2B = 3 x2A ;
(1) is equivalent to
x2A 3 x2A
A
= , x2A 3 x1A = x1A 3 x2A , x1A = x2A ;
x1 3 x1A
which corresponds to the 45 -line inside the Edgeworth box. We have to add (0; 0) and (3; 3) to
this segment to get the whole Pareto set:
n o
x1A ; x2A ; x1B ; x2B 2 [0; 3]4 : x1A = x2A and x1B = x2B = 3 x1A :
The 3 units of each good are initially shared as follows between the two individuals: A has one unit
of good 1 and 2 units of good 2; B has 2 units of good 1 and 1 unit of good 2:
2. Determine the Walrasian equilibria.
A Walrasian equibrium is (x ; p ) such that: (1) each individual maximizes his utility s.t. his budget
constraint; (2) the market clearing condition holds.
Individual i0 s UMP leads to the Marshallian demand functions:
1 p1 + 2p2 1 p1 + 2p2
x1i (p; w) = and x2i (p; w) = ; i = fA; Bg :: (2)
2 p1 2 p2
1
By Walras’ law, each markets clears iff:
p1 + 2p2 p1
2x1i (p; w) = 3 , =3, = 1: (3)
p1 p2
Exercise 2
Consider a two-person, two-good pure exchange economy. A’s preferences over consumption bundles
(x1 ; x2 ) are represented by the utility function
U A (x1 ; x2 ) = x1 x2
where x1 0 denotes the quantity of good 1 and x2 0 the quantity of good 2: B’s preferences over
consumption bundles are represented by the utility function
U B (x1 ; x2 ) = x1 + x2 :
subject to
The optimization programme is concave. The material balance constraint are binding at the optimum. So,
the Lagragian can be written as:
2
The necessary and sufficient first-order conditions are:
x2A
= 1 , x2A = x1A : (11)
x1A
Therefore,
Case 2: Corner solution with x1A = 0: Since A has Cobb-Douglas preferences which do not intersect
the x1A = 0 axe for x2A > 0, it must be x2A = 0: A’s origin belongs to the Pareto set. (Have a look at the
figure drawn in Question 1)
Case 3: Corner solution with x1A = 1. For x2A < 1; there is no maximum with x1A = 0: For x2A 1;
and U B = uB given, U A is maximum along the right-hand side of the Edgeworth rectangle. (Have a look
at the figure drawn in Question 1)
In summary, the Pareto set is given by 0 x1A 1; 0 x2A 2 such that:
Exercise 3
Consider a two-person two-good pure exchange economy. Person A’s and person B’s preferences over
consumption bundles (x1 ; x2 ) 2 R2+ are represented by the following utility functions:
U A (x1 ; x2 ) = x1 + ln x2 ;
U B (x1 ; x2 ) = x1 + 2 ln x2 :
There are initially 5 units of good 1 and 3 units of good 2 in the economy.
1. Determine the set of Pareto optimum allocations. Represent it in the Edgeworth box.
Interior Pareto optimum allocations are characterized by
A x2B
MRS12 x1A ; x2A = MRS12
B
x1B ; x2B , x2A = : (16)
2
Using the material constraint x2A + x2B 3; which must be binding at any Pareto optimum since U A
and U B are strictly increasing in x1 and x2 ; (16) is equivalent to
3 x2A
x2A = , x2A = 1:
2
Hence, interior Pareto optimum allocations are such that
3
The Pareto set is therefore
n o
x1A ; x1B ; x2A ; x2B 2 (0; 5)2 (0; 3)2 : x2A = 1 and x2B = 2 [ ff0g [0; 1]g [ ff5g [1; 2]g :
2. Consider any Pareto optimum allocation x1A ; x2A ; x1B ; x2B >> 0; where xij stands for the quantity of
good i available to person j:
(a) Establish that it is a general equilibrium associated with a price vector and a distribu-
tion of person A’s and person B’s exogenous incomes, denoted ω A and ω B respectively.
Without loss of generality, the price of good 1 will be normalized to 1:
It must be established that there is a price vector and a distribution of wealth for which any
given interior Pareto optimum is obtained as a general equilibrium. To this aim, let us first
derive each consumer’s Marshallian demand functions.
(i) Since we are focusing on interior Pareto optimum allocations, we are only interested in the
demand functions for interior solutions. A necessary condition for A’s utility maximization
programme is:
A 1
MRS12 x1A ; x2A = x2A = ;
q
where p = 1 is the normalized price of good 1 and q the price of good 2: Using A’s budget
constraint, which must be binding, one gets:
x1A = ω A qx2A = ω A 1;
B x2B 1 2
MRS12 x1A ; x2A = = , x2B = ;
2 q q
from which
x1B = ω B qx2B = ω B 2:
(ii) Any interior Pareto optimum allocation must satisfy
Therefore, using (i), the utility maximization programmes of the consumers lead to an interior
Pareto optimum allocation provided 1=q = 1 and 2=q = 2; i.e.
q = 1;
in which case
ωA = x1A + 1;
ωB = x1B + 2:
(b) Determine the Pareto optimum allocation for which the distribution of incomes is egali-
tarian in the sense that ω A = ω B :
Using Question 2b, it must be
ω A + ω B = x1A + x1B + 3 , 2ω A = 8 , ω A = 4:
4
So, ω A = ω B = 4 with q = 1; from which
x1A = ωA 1 = 3;
x2A = 1;
x1B = ωB 2 = 2;
x2B = 2:
(c) Person A has 4 units of good 1 and 2 units of good 2: Person B has 1 unit of each good.
What are the income transfers from A to B which lead to the egalitarian equilibrium?
Given prices p = q = 1; A’s initial wealth amounts to
ω A = 6:
ωA T =6 T:
6 T = 2 + T , T = 2:
Exercise 4
Consider a two-good (1 and 2), two-individual (A and B) economy. Let x = (x1 ; x2 ) 2 R+ R++ be a
consumption bundle. A’s preferences are represented by the utility function defined over consumption
bundles, uA : R+ R++ ! R with
uA (x) = x1 + ln x2 ;
B0 s preferences are represented by uB : R+ R+ ! R with
from which p1
if wA p1 ;
x2A = p2 (19)
wA =p2 otherwise.
5
Here, wA = 3p1 > p1 ; so the solution is always interior.
(iii) Market clearing requires:
p1 3p2 p1
+ = 3 , 0 = p (2 p) , p = 2; with p = : (20)
p2 p1 + p2 p2
The unique equilibrium is thus:
2. A productive sector is now added to the pure exchange economy considered above. The productive
sector consists of one firm which transforms a quantity y1 of good 1 in a quantity y2 of good 2
according to the technology
y2 = f (y1 ) = ay1 ; where a > 0:
π = p2 y2 p1 y1 = (p2 a p1 ) y1 :
(i) Let us suppose there is a strictly positive quantity solution to the firm’s maximisation
programme. Then, it must be
p1
ap2 p1 = 0 , = a: (22)
p2
Without loss of generality, let p1 = 1: Then
3
x2A = a and x2B = : (23)
a+1
By Walras’ law, the production plan ( y1 ; ay1 ) is chosen so as to clear the market for good 2:
3 a 2
a+ = 3 + ay1 , y1 = : (24)
a+1 1+a
In conclusion,
a 2 a (a 2)
a > 2 : y1 = and y2 = , etc. (25)
1+a 1+a
0 < a 2 : y1 = y2 = 0 and E 2 = E 1 : (26)
If the technology used to transform good 1 into good 2 is not effective enough, the firm won’t
produce at the general equilibrium.
6
Exercise 5
Let us consider a two-good, one-consumer (A) economy. x is the sole consumption good and leisure is
denoted L: A’s preference relation is represented by the utility function U (x; L) = xα L1 α ; with 0 < α < 1:
His initial endowment is 0; L : So, labour is defined as ` := L L: A firm uses labour ` to produce the
consumption good x:
1. Examine the Walrasian equilibria of this economy when the technology is x = `1=2 :
Without loss of generality, p
the price of the consumption good is normalized to 1:
(i) The firm’s profit is π = ` ω`: The FOC is:
1 1=2 1
` ω = 0 , `d (ω) = : (27)
2 (2ω)2
So, the firm’s supply is
1
xs = : (28)
2ω
The firm’s profit amounts to:
1 1 1
π (ω) = ω 2
= : (29)
2ω (2ω) 4ω
Hence,
Lω + π (ω) 1 1 α
L ` = (1 α) = (1 α) L + , `s (ω) = Lα : (30)
ω 4ω 2 4ω 2
By Walras’ law, the wage equilibrium is obtained for `s (ω) = `d (ω) ; i.e.
r
12 α
ω = > 0: (31)
L 4α
2. Examine the Walrasian equilibria of this economy when the technology is x = a`; a > 0:
We know that each factor is paid at its marginal productivity. Hence,
ω = a:
In addition,
π = 0:
So, A’s budget constraint reads:
x+ω L ` = Lω: (32)
Since the considered individual has Cobb-Douglas preferences, his Marshallian demand functions
are
Lω
L ` = (1 α) ;
ω
x = αLω.
7
(Recall that the consumption price has been normalized to 1): Consequently, at the equilibrium,
L ` (ω ) = (1 α) L , ` (ω ) = Lα; (33)
x (ω ) = ω ` = Laα: (34)
With constant returns to scale, there is a dichotomy when solving for the equilibrium: the production
side of the economy yields the price equilibrium, while the consumption side of the economy
provides the quantities which are produced and traded at the equilibrium.
3. The technology is x = `2 :
(a) Represent the production possibility set and draw some indifference curves in the (`; x)-
space.
For α = 1=2; for instance, the equation of the indifference curve of level k is:
e2k
x= ; (35)
L `
e2k e2k
with x0 = 2 > and x00 = 2 3 > 0:
(L `) (L `)
(b) Determine the Pareto optimal allocation of this economy. Represent it in the same graph.
The Pareto optimal allocation is solution to:
(` ; x ) is Pareto optimal.
(c) Show that the Pareto optimal allocation cannot be decentralized as a Walrasian equilib-
rium. Comment.
Let us try to decentralize this allocation. The consumer owns all initial endowments (i.e. a
quantity of labour). His budget constraint reads:
x+ω L ` = Lω + π; (40)
where π is the firm’s profit. Hence, the consumer’s labour supply amounts to
(1 α) π
` = Lα : (41)
ω
8
If ` is equalized to ` ; the Pareto optimum labour supply found in (b),
Lα
π= ω < 0: (42)
1+α
The equilibrium can be decentralized only if π < 0:
As a consequence, this Pareto optimal allocation cannot be decentralized with a wage earner,
on the one hand, and an entrepreneur, on the other hand (provided the entrepreneur’s prefer-
ence relation is monotonic and thus his utility function increasing in π; which is the case for a
rational agent). The second fundamental theorem of welfare economics cannot apply because
of the non-convexities of the production side of the economy.