Mathematical Analysis - Busines - Weber, Jean E PDF
Mathematical Analysis - Busines - Weber, Jean E PDF
https://archive.org/details/mathematicalanalOOOOwebe
MATHEMATICAL
ANALYSIS
MATHEMATICAL
ANALYSIS
Business and
Economic Applications
THIRD EDITION
JEAN E. WEBER
University of Arizona
All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this
book may be used or reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission
except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical articles and reviews.
For information address Harper & Row, Publishers, Inc., 10 East 53rd Street,
New York, N.Y. 10022.
Weber, Jean E.
Mathematical analysis.
Bibliography: p.
Includes index.
1. Business mathematics. 2. Mathematical
analysis. 3. Economics, Mathematical.
I. Title.
HF5691.W38 1976 510'.2'433 76-2078
ISBN 0-06-041762-5
Contents
INTRODUCTION, 1
Sets, 2
Variables, 6
Relations and Functions, 8
Inverse Functions, 13
1. GRAPHICAL REPRESENTATION, 16
1.1 Introduction, 16
1.2 Rectangular Coordinates, 16
Fundamental Principle, 17
1.3 Straight Lines, 17
Slope of a Straight Line, 19
Equations for Straight Lines, 21
Two-Point Form, 21 Intercept Form, 22 Point-Slope Form, 23
Slope-Intercept Form, 24 Vertical Lines, 24 Horizontal Lines, 25
Parallel, Perpendicular, and Intersecting Lines, 26
Intersection of Two Straight Lines, 27
Independent Equations, 27 Consistent Equations, 27
Families of Lines, 33
1.4 Applications of Straight Lines in Business and Economics, 37
Linear Demand and Supply Curves, 37
Linear Demand Curves, 38 Linear Supply Curves, 40
Market Equilibrium, 43
Break-Even Analysis, 44
The Consumption Function, 46
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves, 50
Intercepts, 51
Symmetry, 51
Extent, 56
Asymptotes, 57
Factorization, 60
Real Curve, Point Locus, or Imaginary Locus, 61
Summary: General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves, 62
1.6 Quadratic Curves, 70
Identification of a Quadratic Equation, 72
vi / Contents
The Circle, 72
The Ellipse, 74
The Parabola, 77
The Hyperbola, 81
Special Cases of the Equilateral Hyperbola, 86
Families of Quadratic Curves, 90
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and
Economics, 92
Demand and Supply Curves, 92
Market Equilibrium, 93
Product Transformation Curves, 98
Pareto's Law of Distribution of Income, 107
1.8 Exponential and Logarithmic Curves, 111
Exponential Functions, 111
Logarithmic Functions, 114
1.9 Applications of Exponential and Logarithmic Curves in
Business and Economics, 117
Compound Interest, 118
Growth Functions, 119
Biological Growth Curves, 119 Gompertz Curves, 120 Learning Curves, 121
1.10 Trigonometric Curves, 123
Degree and Radian Measure, 124
Trigonometric Functions, 125
Trigonometric Identities, 129
Polar Coordinates, 129
1.11 Applications of Trigonometric Curves in Business and
Economics, 133
Technical Notes I, II, III, IV, and V 133,133,134,137, and 137
The general outline of the previous editions is retained in the third edition. Within
this general framework, there has been considerable revision. Throughout the book
the exposition has, hopefully, been clarified; verbal explanation has been added to
many of the examples.
Some new material has been added. Specifically, additional material concerning
trigonometric functions is included. Capital formation and continuous compounding
are discussed as applications of integration. Several statistical concepts are consid¬
ered; probability is obtained by integration as the area under a curve, and joint
probabilities are obtained by double integration under a surface. The least squares
estimates for bivariate linear regression are derived as an application of maximiza¬
tion and minimization using partial differentiation. Vector derivatives of linear
functions, quadratic forms, and bilinear forms are considered; the application of
vector differentiation in obtaining maxima and minima of functions of several
variables is illustrated by the derivation of the least squares estimates for multi¬
variate linear regression. Problems have also been added. A revised solutions
manual, including complete solutions to all problems, is available to instructors
adopting the text.
Most of the changes, particularly with respect to additional material, were made
in response to suggestions by users and reviewers. These suggestions were very
helpful and are greatly appreciated; even more of them would have been followed
if excessive length were not a consideration.
Every effort has been made, by author and publisher, to avoid errors in the text
and solutions manual. The author accepts responsibility for any errors which have
gone unnoticed.
j. e. w.
Preface
This text offers the student an understanding of quantitative techniques both in their
mathematical contexts and as they are applied to business and economic problems.
The material has been used in various stages of development in graduate and
undergraduate quantitative analysis classes at The University of Wisconsin. It
assumes reasonable facility with algebra; there is, however, an algebra review
section at the end of the book for students whose skills in this area need
sharpening. The text is designed for a one-year course, allowing perhaps for some
omissions at the option of the instructor.
There are eight chapters: Graphical Representation, Differential Calculus: Func¬
tions of One Variable, Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One
Variable, Integral Calculus, Differential Equations, Difference Equations, Vectors
and Matrices, and Applications of Matrix Algebra. Each chapter includes mathe¬
matical presentation of its subject and applications to business and economics.
Each also includes many problems, for we believe that substantial practice in prob¬
lem solving is essential in the study of mathematics. An extensive solutions
manual providing complete calculations for all problems is available on request to
instructors who adopt the text.
We wish to express our gratitude to the students who have used this material
through its many drafts and whose comments and suggestions have been incor¬
porated in the revisions. We would also like particularly to thank Myrna Edmonds
for her patient and painstaking typing of the manuscript. Finally, we accept full
responsibility for any errors that may remain.
j. E. D.
j. s. K.
Introduction
From the beginning of recorded history, cultural and scientific advances have
depended on the use of symbols. The history of civilization can be viewed as the
history of man’s increasingly sophisticated use of symbols. As thinking in any area
develops, the symbols used become increasingly abstract.
When the concepts to which symbols refer are essentially nonquantitative in
nature, the symbols and their relationships can be studied in the general framework
of logic and there is no need for mathematics as such. It is when symbols represent
essentially quantitative concepts that mathematics is useful and, in fact, essential for
analyzing their relationships. Mathematics is a branch of logic, the branch of logic
that provides a systematic framework within which quantitative relationships can be
studied. In pure mathematics definitions or axioms and assumptions are precisely
stated symbolically, and the analysis proceeds by deduction to obtain conclusions.
Applied mathematics differs from pure mathematics in a very important respect—in
pure mathematics symbols represent abstract concepts whose properties are assigned
by definition, while in applied mathematics many symbols represent variables ob¬
served in the real world; the properties of these variables must be determined by
observation, not by abstract definition, and then stated mathematically. In addition,
the empirical accuracy of the deductions of applied mathematics can be determined.
Applied mathematical analysis thus is based on empirically determined definitions
and assumptions from which empirically verifiable conclusions are obtained by
deduction. Pure and applied mathematical analysis differ only with respect to the
empirical aspect of the definitions and assumptions and conclusions, not with respect
to the methods of deduction.
Because economics is concerned with concepts that are essentially quantitative in
nature—for example, price, cost, wage rates, investment, income, and profit—much
of economic analysis is inescapably mathematical in nature. Mathematics provides a
logical, systematic framework within which quantitative relations can be studied.
When economic variables are represented by symbols and their properties stated
mathematically, mathematics provides the techniques for analyzing relations among
the symbols and thus among the variables they represent. Much of economic analysis
is therefore applied mathematical analysis.
In economic analysis, as in applied mathematics in general, deductions obtained
by mathematical analysis are interpreted and evaluated empirically. It should be
1
2 / Introduction
noted in this regard that if the deductions following from a set of definitions and
assumptions are not correct with respect to empirical observation, mathematical
analysis (if correctly performed) is not responsible and the difficulty is to be found in
the definitions or assumptions. Mathematics enables the economist to be precise in
defining relevant variables, to state clearly the assumptions made, to be logical
in developing the analysis, and to consider a larger number of variables than might
be feasible verbally. However, it does not and cannot prevent the omission or the
empirically incorrect definition of relevant variables nor can it prevent empirically
inaccurate or incomplete statements of assumptions. Mathematical analysis takes
definitions and assumptions as given and obtains the conclusions that follow log¬
ically from them. Mathematical analysis is thus by nature logical, not empirical, and
can be held responsible for conclusions only with respect to their logical validity
given the definitions and assumptions on which they are based and not with respect
to their empirical accuracy.
Thus if mathematical analysis is correctly performed, but its conclusions are
empirically incorrect, the definitions and assumptions must be examined for accur¬
acy and completeness. By providing a systematic framework for the deduction of
empirically verifiable conclusions, mathematical analysis helps the economist deter¬
mine the accuracy of his definitions and assumptions—if the conclusions are unten¬
able, the definitions and assumptions must be examined and revised.
The purpose of this book is to help the student understand, appreciate, and
perform applied mathematical analysis. Mathematical proofs are minimized except
when they can be made heuristic. The book is organized so that a type of analysis is
discussed first with respect to its mathematical (logical) procedure and then with
respect to its applications in economics and business. The assumptions required for
each type of analysis are emphasized and its applications are discussed in terms of
these assumptions.
The subsequent sections of this chapter review some of the basic mathematical
concepts and definitions used in later chapters.
Sets
EXAMPLE
The notation x e S means that the entity or object x is an element of the set S. The
notation x 4. S means that x is not an element of the set S.
A defining relation that is satisfied by no element is said to define the empty set,
denoted by 0.
EXAMPLE
a e A
b B
4 £ B
4 e C
4 E D
1$C
7 e B
7 e D
d <£ A
d£D
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
A cfi B
B a I)
BjzC
CcD
The union of two sets S and T is the set consisting of the elements of S and the
elements of T. The union of S and T, denoted by S u T, is described by
S u T = {x : x e S and/or x e T}
4 / Introduction
Note that an element common to both sets is not counted twice in the union.
The intersection of two sets S and T is the set consisting of the elements that are
common to S and T. The intersection of S and T is denoted by S n T and is
described by
S n T = {x: x e S and x e T}
The set difference of two sets S and T is the set consisting of the elements of S that
are not elements of T. The set difference of S and T is denoted by S — T and is
described by
S — T = {x : x e S and x $ T}
A universal set or universe is a specified set that contains all the elements of interest
for a particular discussion. If two sets have the property that their union is the
universal set and their intersection is the null set, one set is said to be the complement
of the other with respect to the universe. If U denotes the universal set, the comple¬
ment of a given set S is denoted by S' and is described by
S' = u -s
A statement of complementation must be qualified unless the universal set is clearly
understood. For example, if the complement of S is taken with respect to U and also
with respect to V, the notation S'v and S'v is used.
EXAMPLE
B u D = D
A u C = {a, b, c, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6}
A n D = 0
B n D = B
B n C = jl, 3, 5}
C n D = C
C-D = 0
C-B = {2, 4, 6}
D - A = D
D — B = {x : x is an even integer}
If U = {x : x is an integer}, then
Cy = {7, 8, 9, 10}
Sets formed by unions, intersections, and complements are shown here diagram-
matically; the shaded area is the set indicated below each diagram. This type of
representation of sets is called a Venn diagram.
Sets / 5
A U B
PROBLEMS
1. If A, B, and C are sets such that A c B c= C, what is the relationship between C — B and
C - A?
2. Show that, in general, (A n B)' = A' u B'.
3. Show that, in general, A n (B vj C) = (A n B) yj (A n C).
4. Show that (S n 7') u (5 n 7) = S n (S u 7) = S u (S n 7) = S.
5. Show that K u (L n M) = (K u L) n (K u M).
6. If/4 n B = 0 and /4 n C = 0, is it necessarily true that B n C = 0?
7. If /4 ^ B and B ^ C, is it necessarily true that /4 ^ C?
8. If /4 B and B cfz C, is it necessarily true that /4 ^ C?
9. If /4 c: C and B c D, is it necessarily true that /luBcCuD?
10. If d c C and B <= D, is it necessarily true that /4 n B c C n D?
11. If S u T = {1, 2, 3, 4}, S n 7 = {1, 3}, and S — T = {2}, find S and T.
12. If d n B / 0, d n C # 0, and B n C # 0, is it necessarily true that Bn C#0?
13. If U is a universal set, determine which of the following statements are incorrect and
correct them by changing the right-hand side of the equation.
a. B u 0 = B h. C u C = C
b. C n U = C i. (D') = U
c. A u A' = U j. (4 — C)uC = 4 — C
d. B u U = U k. Bn (B — D) = ByjD
e. D n 0 = 0 l. If A = B\ then B — A'
f. 4 n 4' = 4 m. (C - D) = C' - D
g. B n B = 0 n. (4 u D) — D = 4 — D
14. If /4 = {c, / and B = {e, /i}, find
a. /4 — B c. A n B
b. B — A d. 4 u B
15. If 7 = {w, x, y}, S = {u, v, w} and 7 = {w, v, w, x}, and the universal set is
U = {m, v, w, x, y, z}, find
a. R' n T' n S' e. (5 u 7) - T
b. (R — S) n T f. (7 - 7) - (S - 7)
c. (7' - 7') u 5 g. (S - 7) - [(7 - 7) u (7 S)]
d. (7' u S')' h. (7 - 7) u S
16. If/4 n B = 0 and /!' = C, is it necessarily true that B c?
6 / Introduction
0
II
g- B n B = B k. B n (B - D) = B - D
i. (D')' = D m. (c- D) = C' u D
15. a. {z} c. S e. T g- 0
b. M d- {w} f. M h. S
Variables
In mathematics there are two types of quantities, constants and variables. A constant
is a quantity whose value remains unchanged throughout a particular problem. An
absolute or numerical constant has the same value in all problems; an arbitrary or
parametric constant (or a parameter) has the same value throughout any particular
problem but may assume different values in different problems. The absolute or
numerical value of a constant a is denoted by \a\ a and means the magnitude of a
regardless of its algebraic sign. Thus | + a | = — a a\ = a.
A variable is a quantity that assumes various values in a particular problem; the
set of values which a variable assumes is its range. A variable may be either contin¬
uous or discrete. A continuous variable is one that may assume any value within a
specified interval of real numbers (possibly all real numbers); successive values of a
continuous variable thus may differ by infinitesimal amounts. A discrete variable is
one that may assume only values specified in a countable range. Note that the
number of points or values in any specified real interval, say between 5 and 10, is
uncountable and no rule can be given for obtaining all possible such values.
However, the number of integers or integer values in any specified interval is count¬
able. The number of points on the real line (or on any part of the real line) is said to
be a noncountable or nondenumerable infinity. The number of integers on the real
line is a countable or denumerable infinity and any set obtained from the integers by
a specified rule is also countable or denumerable.
Thus in any problem there may be
1. Absolute constants that always have the same value; such quantities are either
numbers or symbols denoting numbers.
2. Parametric constants that have the same value throughout any given problem but
may have different values for different problems; such quantities depend on the
particular situation represented in the problem.
3. Variables that assume all values meaningful for the problem; such quantities may
vary discretely or continuously and may be restricted, for example, to positive
values.
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
A = nr2
In pure mathematics, usually the letters at the beginning of the alphabet are used
to represent parameters and the letters at the end of the alphabet are used to repre¬
sent variables. However, in applied mathematics there are many exceptions to this
convention, and a variable is frequently represented by the first letter of its name—
for example, p for price, q for quantity, c for cost, s for savings, and so forth.
The only values of either constants or variables considered subsequently are real
numbers. The real number system includes all the familiar types of numbers—rational
numbers (positive and negative integers, fractions and decimal fractions) and irra¬
tional numbers that are roots of rational numbers and other numbers that cannot be
expressed as fractions; it does not include even roots of negative numbers (which are
called imaginary numbers) or numbers that have both real and imaginary parts
(which are called complex numbers). The set of all real numbers is denoted by
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
The equation x5 + 32 = 0 has the real solution x = —2 (it also has four complex solutions not
of interest for the present discussion).
The quotient a/b of two numbers a and b is a number x such that a = bx. Division
by zero is not permissible as a result of this definition. Note that if b = 0, a = 0 * x,
which is true only if a = 0, in which case x can be any number. Thus the expressions
a 0
x and -
0 0
are meaningless. To distinguish between a/0 and 0/0, a/0 is sometimes said to be
“undefined” and 0/0 is sometimes said to be “indeterminate.” Note that 0/b = 0
for M 0, since 0/b is the value of x for which b ■ x — 0 and must be zero for
b^0.
Relationships involving inequalities are expressed as follows:
Many problems in mathematics involve sets of ordered pairs of numbers. For exam¬
ple, representation of an object moving in a straight line involves pairs of numbers
specifying distance of the object from the origin and the corresponding time in
motion. Representation of demand for a given commodity involves pairs of numbers
specifying quantity demanded and the corresponding price.
A set of ordered pairs of real numbers is referred to as a binary relation. The set of
first elements of a binary relation is called the domain of the relation; the set of second
elements is called the range of the relation. For a given set {(x, j/)}, x and y are
referred to as variables. The set of values variable x takes on is the domain and x is
usually called the independent variable; the set of values variable y takes on is the
range and y is usually called the dependent variable. When the number of variables is
clear from the context, a binary relation may be referred to simply as a relation.
EXAMPLE
Sx = {(1, 2), (2, 8), (2, 3)} is a binary relation whose domain is {1, 2} and whose range is
{2, 3, 8}.
52 — {(x, y): x, y real numbers, x < y} is a binary relation some of whose members are
(2, 2), (3, 4), (5, 5), and (8, 20). Note that (2, 1), (3, 2), and (25, 20), for example, are
not members of S2 ■
53 = {(x, y): y = x2, x e $} is a binary relation. The domain of S3 is & and the range is the
set of all nonnegative real numbers.
If a relation is such that to each element of the domain there corresponds one and
only one element of the range, the relation is said to be a function. Functions consti¬
tute a subset of relations—all functions are relations, but not all relations are func¬
tions. Note that the relations S3 and S4 of the above example are functions, but the
relations Sx and S2 are not functions. A special notation is used for functions to
denote the element of the range corresponding to an element of the domain. If /
denotes a function {(x, y)}, then the number y associated with a given x is denoted by
/(x), read “/ of x.” With this notation, the set of pairs defining/may be written as
{(*>/(*))} where y=f(x).
EXAMPLE
Other letters, for example, g, F, G, 0, and T, are also frequently used to indicate a
function. An equation such as g(x) = x2 + (1/x) provides a rule for finding the
second member of a pair whose first member is x. Such an equation or formula is said
to define the function, although the function is not the formula but is the set of
ordered pairs {(x, #(x))} or {(x, y)}. When a value of x is substituted in the formula for
a function, the result is said to be the function value or the value of the function for that
value of x.
In the case of a function involving two variables, whenever the value of the
independent variable is specified the value of the dependent variable is determined. It
is the independent variable whose value is thought of as being assigned arbitrarily
(except for nonpermissible values), thus determining also the value of the dependent
variable. It is conventional in applied mathematics to represent the independent
variable by x and the dependent variable by y.
For most problems in analytic geometry and other branches of pure mathematics,
the choice of independent and dependent variables is a matter of convenience and the
conventional designation of x and y is concerned only with graphical representation,
as discussed below. For example, in considering the equation
x — 4 v2 + 2y + 6 = 0
it is clearly more convenient to find pairs of points by regarding y as the independent
variable and x as the dependent variable as follows:
x = 4 y2 — 2y — 6
When the variables are purely mathematical and do not represent quantities in a
particular context, there is no basis other than convenience for making the choice of
independent and dependent variables. However, when the variables do represent
quantities in the context of a particular subject matter, the logic of the situation
usually determines the choice of independent and dependent variables. For example,
quantity produced is thought of as a primary determinant of total cost rather than
vice versa. There are exceptions even in these types of problems; for example, price
may be thought of as determining quantity demanded, or quantity demanded may be
thought of as determining price.
EXAMPLE
If/(x) = x2 - x + 2, then
f(z) = z2 - z + 2
/(2) = 4 - 2 + 2 = 4
/(_3) = 9 + 3 + 2= 14
/(0) = 0 — 0 + 2 = 2
f(a) — a2 — a + 2
f(x + 2) = (x + 2)2 — (x + 2) + 2
= (x2 + 4x + 4) — (x + 2) + 2
= x2 + 3x + 4
EXAMPLE
/(!)= 1 +i = 2
/(-i)= =o
/(0) = 0 (undefined)
a h \ ci 1
f{a + h) — f(a) =
a + h a
a2 + ah + a — a2 — ah — a — h
a(a + h)
h
a(a + h)
A functional form can be obtained by the substitution of one form into another. If
y = f(x) and u = g(y) and if u = g[f(x)] = h(x), then h is called the g composite of f.
EXAMPLE
f[g{x)] = (x - l)2 - (x - 1) - 1 = x2 - 3x + 1
and
g[f(x)] = (x2 - x - 1) - 1 = x2 - x - 2
EXAMPLE
If g(x) = x2 + 2, then
EXAMPLE
PROBLEMS
1. For each of the following relations, state the domain and range and indicate whether the
relation is a function.
a. S = {(1, 3), (2, 3), (2, 4), (3, 2), (4, 1), (5, 5)}
b. A = {(1, 3), (2, 3), (3, 3), (4, 3)}
c. T = {(x, v): y = 4x 4- 1 if 0 < x < 2, y = 10 — x2 if 2 < x < 3}
d. B = {(x, y): y2 = x, y is an integer and |y | <8}
2. For each of the following, determine if the set {(x, y)} of pairs of real numbers formed
according to the given rule is a function.
a. yz = x x2 + 4
i- y =
x — 2
b. y3 = x
1
c. y4 = x j- y =
x2 — 6
d. x2 + y = 1
k. x =
e. x + y2 = 1 y -y + 2
f. x2 + y2 = 1
1. = X
g. y = x2 + 4 y2 + 2
h. xy = 1
3x2 - 8
4. If/(x) = , find a./(3); b./(- 1); c./(x - 2); and d./(a - h).
x — 1
and d. -7 4- [h(a)]2.
h(a)
10. Give the domain and range of each of the following relations; determine whether each
relation is a function and, if not, explain why.
a. y = x2 + 6 25
s- y = ~2
x
b. y = lOx — 5
x2 + 16
h. y =
c. y = + yj'4 — 2x2 x + 4
d. y = —y/4 — 2x2 1. y = x
j. 2x + y = 3
e. y = v/4 — 2x2
k. 3x2 + 2y = 4
9
f. y =
lOx — 5 l. 4x2 4- 6y2 = 10
t2 + 4
11. If/(x) = y - x and g(t) = , find
31
x2 - 1 7
12. If q(x) = p{x) + g(x) and p(x) = —-—, g(x) = , find q(2).
J X
5. a. T5 [ x2 -I- 4x
b. ^3
d- V TTT
c.
a
7. a. 2 3h - 1
b. -10
c. 3a — a2
9. a. 4 1 + (4a — a2)3
b. 7 4a — a2
c. 4(a + 6 — c) — a2 — 62 + c2 — 2ab
11. a. b. 0
15.
19. e«b2
Relations and Functions / 13
INVERSE FUNCTIONS
The domain and range of any relation may be interchanged to form a new relation.
Each pair in the new relation is obtained by interchanging the elements of a
corresponding pair in the original relation. Two such sets of pairs are said to be
inverse relations; each relation is said to be the inverse of the other. If both relations
are functions, they are called inverse functions. The inverse relation is a function if and
only if the original function is such that to each element of its range there corre¬
sponds one and only one element of its domain. The inverse of a function/is denoted
by the symbol f~l. In this notation — 1 is not an exponent; it means only that/ -1 is
the inverse of/ If/-1 is the inverse function of/ then
and
Providing the algebra can be done, the relation /-1(x) can be found by solving
f[f l(x)\ — x as though /- *(x) were a variable in the equation. When a domain is
not specified, it is assumed to be the set of all real numbers.
EXAMPLE
Let g = {(x, y): y = 2x — 1}. Find the inverse relation and determine whether it is a function.
y = 2x — 1
x = i(y+ 1)
Since the letters used to indicate the values of the domain and the range are arbitrary, x and y
are used in their customary order.
EXAMPLE
Find the inverse of/= {(x, y): y = x2, x > 0} and determine whether it is a function.
y = x2
* = Vy
which is a function; thus the inverse function is
Note that if / had as its domain the set of all real numbers in the above example,
f~1 would not be a function since its domain would be the set of all nonnegative real
numbers and its range would be the set of all real numbers.
14 / Introduction
EXAMPLE
1 — x
y = r+x
y(l + x) = 1 — x
y + xy = 1 — x
y + xy + x — 1=0
x -I- xy = 1 — y
x( 1 + y) = I - y
x = \~j = 9(y)
PROBLEMS
1. Determine for each of the following whether the inverse relation is a function; if it is not,
alter the range of the given function so that its inverse is a function.
a. {(x, y): y = x2 + 1} c. {(w, z): z = y/l - w2}
b. {(x, y): y = 4 - x2} d. {(«, v): v = \ u |}
2. For each of the following functions, find the inverse function f~1(x) and show that
/[/~1(x)]=/-1[/(x)] = x.
a. /(x) = 3x + 2 c. /(x) = (x - 2)/(x + 2)
b. /(x) = x/(x - 4) d. /(x) = (x + 3)/x
3. Find f[g{x)] and g[f(x)] for each of the following.
a- /(x) = l/(x - 1) and ^(x) = x2/(x2 - 1)
b. /(x) = x/(4 - x) and g(x) = x/(x - 4)
c- /(x) = ^(x) = (x + l)/(x - 1)
d. f(x) = y/x- 1 and g(x) = l/(x -f 1)
4. If/(x) = (ax + 1 )/(bx — 1), find values of a and b such that/is its own inverse—that is,
/[/(x)] = x.
h
11. If P(x) = ^/x, show that P(x + /?) — P(x) =
x + h -k/x
x
13. Iff(x) , show that/(x) +/( —x) = 2/( — x2).
1 + x
.2
14. If g(y) = y2 L/.A _
and h(y) = >' „u~„,
, show L/..2X _
that h(y2) = 9(y) .
i - y i - g(y)
15. If g(x) = 2 In x and/(x) = x3/2, show that Q[f(x)] = jQ(x).
1.1 Introduction
The French philosopher, Rene Descartes (1596-1650), developed a form of graphic
analysis in which algebraic equations are plotted in terms of geometric curves. Thus
it is possible to see relationships among such variables as price and quantity; direct,
indirect, and total cost; savings, investment, and consumption. In addition, much of
the theory of calculus can be presented in geometrical terms.
In order to relate algebra and geometry, and thus make possible this dual
representation, use is made of a coordinate system which provides a means for
locating specific points in a plane or in space. This correspondence may be estab¬
lished in many ways, but the system most commonly used is rectangular coordinates.
In this chapter, graphical representation using rectangular coordinates is dis¬
cussed for straight lines and for quadratic, exponential, trigonometric, and logarith¬
mic curves. General methods of graphing and special methods of graphing particular
types of curves are considered. Applications of each type of curve in business and
economics are also discussed.
y
II(-,+) I(+,+)
•(-3,2) • 0,2)
(-1,1) • •(3,1)
x
(-4,-2)
• • (3,-2).
(-2,-2)
• (2,-3)
III ( —» “) IV(+, -)
Fundamental Principle
There is a one-to-one correspondence between number pairs and points in the plane
in which they are represented—that is, to each pair of numbers (coordinates) there
corresponds one and only one point in the plane and, conversely, to each point in the
plane there corresponds one and only one pair of numbers. The terms point and
coordinates of a point are generally used interchangeably.
Ax + By + C = 0 (1)
where A, B, and C are constants and at least one of A and B is nonzero, is said to be
linear in x and y and such an equation has a straight line as its geometrical represen¬
tation. Equation (1) is also referred to as the general equation of the first degree in two
variables.
The degree of a variable is the value of the positive integral power to which the
variable is raised. The degree of a term of an equation in x and y is the sum of its
degrees in x and y; that is, the sum of the powers to which x and y appear in the term.
The degree of an equation is the degree of its term of greatest degree. For example,
x3 + y4 + 6 4- y — 12 = 0 is a fourth-degree equation; 4x2 + y4 + 2x3y3 — 21 = 0 is
a sixth-degree equation.
There are two aspects of the problem of correspondence between a straight line
and a linear equation: (1) given a linear equation, to graph the corresponding line,
and (2) given (conditions determining) the line, to find the corresponding linear
equation.
The coordinates x and y of every point (x, y) on a given line satisfy the equation
corresponding to the line; conversely, the straight line that passes through all the
points, and only through those points, whose coordinates satisfy the equation is
called the graph or locus of the equation. However, since there are an infinite number
of points on any given line or curve, establishing correspondence between algebraic
equations and their geometrical representations point by point is clearly not feasible;
it is the purpose of analytic geometry to develop methods using a minimum number
of points for establishing this correspondence. In general, the more simple the alge¬
braic equation (and thus its corresponding graph), the fewer points necessary for
establishing meaningful correspondence.
One easy way to graph a straight line is to compute its intercepts. The intercepts of
a line are the points where the line crosses the axes. Thus the y-intercept is the point
determined by setting x = 0 in the equation of the line; similarly, the x-intercept is
the point determined by setting y = 0 in the equation of the line.
EXAMPLE
y-intercept x-intercept
if x = 0 if y = 0,
5y -20 = 0 4x - 20 = 0
5 y = 20 4x = 20
y=4
Intercept (0, 4) Intercept (5, 0)
1.3 Straight Lines / 19
Figure 1.2
The intercepts may then be plotted and the line drawn through them, as shown in
Figure 1.2. As a check for accuracy, a third point is sometimes plotted as well. For
example, let y — 2 in the example above. Then
4x + 5(2) - 20 = 0
4x - 10 = 0
Y _ 10 __ 5
X — 4 — 2
yi ~ yi Ay
m = tan 9
X2 - Xj Ax
It is customary, especially in calculus, to use the notation Ay, read delta y, to repre¬
sent the difference y2 — yx. This symbol Ay denotes the change in y or the difference
between two values of y. Do not think of Ay as delta times y. Similarly, Ax denotes
x2 - Xj.
20 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.3
y y
y2 - yi = yi - y2
x2 - Xi xx - x2
the slope of a line may be interpreted as the ratio of the directed change in vertical
distance to the corresponding directed change in horizontal distance as a point
moves along the line in either direction. In some problems (particularly in physics
and engineering), Ay = y2 — y1 is called the rise and Ax = x2 — Xi is called the run;
then the slope is defined as the rise per unit of run, that is, slope = rise/run = Ay/Ax.
If y\ — y2 and xx x2, the line through (xls yt) and (x2, y2) is parallel to the
x-axis, its angle of inclination 0 is zero, and tan 6 — Ay/Ax = 0.
If xx = x2 and yl y2, the line through (x1? yj and (x2, y2) is parallel to the
y-axis, its angle of inclination 6 is 90°, and tan 6 = Ay/Ax is undefined (see Figure
1.4). (Remember that an expression which involves division by zero is said to be
undefined or indeterminate and no numerical value can meaningfully be assigned to
it.)
summary: slope
The slope of the x-axis is zero.
The slope of the y-axis is undefined.
If a line slopes upward to the right, Ax and Ay have the same sign and tan 6 =
Ay/Ax > 0; in this case 0 < 6 < 90°.
If a line slopes downward to the right, Ax and Ay have opposite signs and tan 6 =
Ay/Ax < 0; in this case 90° < 6 < 180°.
Figure 1.4
y y
o
o
lies on it and its slope. These formulas are all equivalent to the general equation
for a straight line,
Ax By 4- C — 0
and are generally easily transformed into it and into each other.
Two-Point Form
One of the fundamental properties of a straight line is its constant slope; the slope
can be determined using any two distinct points on a straight line. These two facts
can be used to develop a formula for obtaining the equation of a nonvertical straight
line when the coordinates of two points on the line are known.
If (xl5 yx) and (x2, y2) are two distinct points on a nonvertical straight line, then
the slope m of the line is given by
*2 “ *1
If (x, y) is any other point (that is, a general point) on the straight line, then it and the
point (xj, >q) can also be used to determine the slope m of the line
X — Xj
y - yi = y2 -yi
X — Xi X2 - Xj
22 / Graphical Representation
or
See Figure 1.5, noting that the labeling of the points is arbitrary and may be chosen
for convenience.
Equation (la), referred to as the two-point form for a straight line, is generally most
convenient for determining the equation of a straight line when two of its points are
given.
EXAMPLE
Find the equation of the line passing through the points (3, 4) and ( — 5, 2).
y - 4 = i(x - 3)
x — 4y + 13 = 0
3 - 4(4) +13 = 0
0 = 0
Insert (- 5, 2) in x - 4y + 13=0:
-5 -4(2)+ 13 =0
0 = 0
Intercept Form
For the special case when the point (x1? y.t) is the y-intercept, denoted by (0, b),
where b =/= 0, and the point (x2, y2) is the x-intercept, denoted by (a, 0), where a f 0,
1.3 Straight Lines / 23
y (x-0)
a
y x
- 1 =
b a
x
= 1
a
Equation (lb), referred to as the intercept form for a straight line, is generally most
convenient for determining the equation of a straight line when its two intercepts are
given.
EXAMPLE
Find the equation of the line having intercepts (0, —6) and (4, 0).
b = —6 a = 4
3x — 2 y = 12
3.x — 2y — 12 = 0
3(0) — 2( — 6) — 12 = 0
0 = 0
Insert (4, 0) in 3x — 2y — 12 = 0:
3(4) - 2(0) - 12 = 0
0 = 0
Point-Slope Form
Since the slope of a nonvertical line is m = (y2 — yi)/(x2 — xi), Equation (la) can be
written
Equation (lc), referred to as the point-slope form for a straight line, is generally
most convenient for determining the equation of a straight line when one of the
points on a line and its slope are given.
24 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE _======^^
Find the equation of the line passing through the point ( — 1, 2) and having slope —4.
(*i, yi) = (— 1, 2) m = -4
y - yx = m(x - xx)
y — 2 = — 4(x + 1)
4x 4- y + 2 = 0
Check: m = — 4 in 4x + y + 2 = 0. Insert ( — 1, 2) in 4x +- y + 2 = 0:
4( — l) + 2 + 2 = 0
0=0
Slope-Intercept Form
For the special case when the point (x1? yt) is the ^-intercept, denoted by (0, b),
equation (la) can be written
y = mx + b (Id)
Equation (Id), referred to as the slope-intercept form for a straight line, is generally
most convenient for determining the equation of a straight line when its y-intercept
and slope are given.
EXAMPLE
Find the equation of the line having y-intercept (0, 5) and slope 3.
b — 5 m — 3
y = mx + b
— 3x + 5
3x — y + 5 = 0
3(0) -5 + 5 = 0
0 = 0
Vertical Lines
Since the slope of a vertical line is undefined, the above formulas are not appropriate
for obtaining the equations of vertical lines. A vertical line passing through the point
(xx, yx) has the equation x = xv
EXAMPLE
Find the equation of the vertical line passing through the point (5, —4).
x = xl = 5
x = 5
1.3 Straight Lines / 25
Horizontal Lines
Since a horizontal line has zero slope, its equation may be obtained from the two-
point, point-slope, or slope-intercept forms. A horizontal line passing through the
point (xl5 yx) has the equation y = yx.
EXAMPLE
Find the equation of the horizontal line passing through the point ( — 3, —2).
y = yi = -2
y = -2
General form: Ax + By + C = 0
X V
Intercept form: - + 7=1
a b
Slope-intercept form: y = mx + b
Vertical lines: x = x{
Horizontal lines: y = yx
PROBLEMS
1. a. Which of the following points lie on the line 3x + 4y — 10 = 0?
i. (1,2) iv. (-25,21)
ii. (-2, 4) v. (0,0)
iii. (10, -5) vi. (4r, \)
b. Graph the line indicating points above which lie on it.
2. For each of the following equations,
i. Graph using intercepts.
ii. Put into slope-intercept form.
iii. Put into intercept form—this form is inappropriate for one of the equations; which one
and why?
a. 4y — 3x = 12 c. 2y + 3x + 2 = 0
b. 5x — y = 10 d. x — 3y = 0
3. a. Which of the following points lie on the line x — 5y + 4 = 0?
i. (0, 0) iv. (3, 2)
ii. (4, 0) v. (0, 4)
iii. (1, 1) vi. (— 1, 5)
b. Graph the line, indicating the points above which lie on it.
4. For each of the following pairs of points,
i. Find the slope of the line through the two points.
ii. Find the equation of the line using the slope.
iii. Find the equation of the line without using the slope.
iv. Graph the line.
a. (0, 0) and (6, 3) d. (3, -2) and (3, 5)
b. (-X, 0) and (0, |) e. (- 1, -2) and (4, 1)
c. (-7, 4) and (8, 4) f. (-2, -3) and (-5, -6)
26 / Graphical Representation
5. Find the equation of the line through the point (3, —2) and perpendicular to the line
through the points ( — 1, —3) and (3, 7).
6. Find the equation of the line through the point (4, 3) and parallel to the line through the
points (0, —3) and (6, 1).
7. Find the equation of the line through the point (5, 15) and parallel to the line y = x + 25.
What relation (parallel, perpendicular, coincident, or intersecting) does this line have to
the line through the two points (6, 0) and ( — 2, 8)?
8. Find the equation of the line which has intercept (0, —3) and is perpendicular to the line
through the points ( — 2, —1) and (2, 5).
9. Find the equation of the line which is parallel to the line through the points (5, 6) and
(7, 8) and also passes through the intersection of the line having slope —2 through the
point (-4, -6) and the line having slope 3 through the point (2, 2).
10. Find the equation of the line passing through the point (-1, 1) and perpendicular to the
line having slope -J and passing through the point (5, 2).
PARALLEL PERPENDICULAR,
AND INTERSECTING LINES
Any two lines in a plane are either parallel or intersecting; lines that intersect at right
angles are perpendicular. Two lines that are parallel have equal angles of inclination
and therefore have equal slopes, and conversely. Two lines that are perpendicular
have slopes which are the negative reciprocals of each other, and conversely.
EXAMPLE
The line 2x + 6y — 4 = 0 has the indicated relationship to each of the following lines (note
that 2x + 6y — 4 = 0 can be written in the form y = — ix + §):
(a) 4x + 12y — 8 = 0
12>’ = — 4x + 8
y = +i coincident with y = — ix + 3
(b) — 3x + y — 4 = 0
y = 3x + 4 perpendicular to y = — 3X + |
(c) x + 3y — 9 = 0
3y = — x + 9
(d) 2x + y — 4 = 0
y = - 2x + 4 intersecting y = —3X -1- 3
1.3 Straight Lines / 27
where Al9 A2, Blf B2, Cl9 and C2 are positive or negative constants.
Independent Equations
These equations are independent if one cannot be obtained from the other by multi¬
plication by a nonzero constant—that is, they are independent if the equality
a1/a2 = bjb2 = Cj tc2 does not hold. If the equality does hold, the equations are
dependent.
note: Twoequations that are dependent are equivalent—that is, they represent
the same line and have the same graph, since any point that lies on one of the
equations lies on the other also.
EXAMPLE
The equations
3x + 5y + 10 = 0 6x + lOy + 20 = 0
are dependent or equivalent, since the second equation is obtained by multiplying the first
equation by 2; they have the same straight line as their graph.
Consistent Equations
Two equations are said to be consistent if they can hold simultaneously—that is, they
are consistent if
A\ _ ^1 _ ^1 or if — ± —
A2 B2 c2 °r 1 A2 B2
If Ax jA2 = Bl /B2 = Cx /C2, the lines coincide and the equations are both consistent
and dependent. If A1 /A2 ^ Bv /B2, the lines have different slopes and thus intersect
at just one point; such lines are consistent and independent. Two linear equations
that are inconsistent—that is, not consistent—have parallel lines as their graphs.
EXAMPLE
The equations
3x + 5y + 10 = 0 6x 4- lOy +15=0
are inconsistent (since | ^ ^ {3) and cannot both hold simultaneously; they have parallel
lines as their graphs.
28 / Graphical Representation
A, Ct
B,
and
C2
y=
B2
Thus if Ax /A2 = By /B2, the lines have the same slope. If By /B2 = Cy jC2, the lines
have the same intercept. If Ay/A2 = By /B2 = Cy /C2, the lines have the same slope
and the same intercept and are identical.
A point is said to be a simultaneous solution of two equations if its coordinates
satisfy both equations; geometrically, two lines intersect (or coincide) at a point
which is their simultaneous solution. Two straight lines have a unique simultaneous
solution if they are intersecting (consistent and independent), no simultaneous solu¬
tion if they are parallel (inconsistent), and infinitely many simultaneous solutions if
they are coincident (consistent and dependent). These cases are illustrated in
Figure 1.6.
Figure 1.6
Usually two linear equations can quite easily be solved simultaneously by elimina¬
tion or substitution; in some cases the method of determinants (to be discussed in
detail later) provides the solution more readily. To solve the equations
A^x-\-B^y-H Ui = 0 T 2 x T B2y T C2 — 0
A^A2x-\~A2Biy-\-A2Ci=0 A ^ A2 x T A j B2 y A^C 2 = 0
subtract to eliminate x,
solve for y,
V — ^2^1 ~ A1 Cl
A\ B2 A2 Bi
' A2 Ci ~ axc2\
Ax x + Bx + cx =0
,AlB2 — A2bx )
A2Ci — AxC2\ c±
x =
A, A]_ B2 A2 Bi J
—
Bi C2 — B2 C i
AxB2 — A2 Bi
In many cases it is easier to obtain the simultaneous solution for a particular pair of
linear equations directly by elimination or substitution rather than by these
formulas.
30 / Graphical Representation
FXAMPLE
3x — 4y + 6 = 0 x - 2y - 3 = 0
3x — Ay + 6 = 0
— 3x + 6y + 9 = 0
2y + 15=0
2y = -15
y - —t
Substituting y = in the first equation,
3x - 4(-^) + 6 = 0
3x + 30 + 6 = 0
3x = —36
x = —12
-36 + 30 + 6 = 0
0 = 0
Equation 2: — 12 — 2( —V) — 3 = 0
-12 + 15 - 3 = 0
0 = 0
Figure 1.7
y
1.3 Straight Lines / 31
Alternatively, substituting for x obtained from the second equation in the first equation:
x = 2y + 3
3(2y + 3) - 4y + 6 = 0
6y + 9 — 4y + 6 = 0
2y + 15 = 0
2y = -15
y - —r
Substituting for y obtained from the second equation in the first equation:
3x — 2x+ 6 + 6 = 0
x + 12 = 0
x = —12
_ C2 — B2 Ci — A2 C1 — A i C2
A1B2 — A2B1 A1B2 — A2B1
12 + 12 _ 24
-6 + 4~^2
(1X6) - (3X-3)
(3X-2 )-( l)(-4)
6 + 9 15
-6 + 4~^2
These equations are consistent and independent and have a unique simultaneous solution,
the point (- 12, —x)-
EXAMPLE
2x — 3y + 3 = 0 4x — 6y + 12 = 0
32 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.8
y
4x — 6y -f 6 = 0 4x — 6y + 12 = 0
(see Figure 1.8). These equations are inconsistent and do not have a simultaneous solution;
they are represented by parallel lines.
EXAMPLE
2x — 3y + 1 = 0 4x — 6y + 2 = 0
4x - 6y + 2 = 0 4x - 6y + 2 = 0
(see Figure 1.9). These equations are dependent and therefore equivalent and have infinitely
many simultaneous solutions; they are represented by the same straight line, every point of
which is a simultaneous solution of the equations.
Figure 1.9
y
1.3 Straight Lines / 33
FAMILIES OF LINES
An important concept in both theoretical and applied mathematics is that of a family
of straight lines or curves. The members of a family possess some geometric property
(such as passing through a given point) in common, but differ in at least one other
geometric property (such as having different slopes). Algebraically, this corresponds
to the fact that some of the parameters in a general equation are specified and at least
one is not. Remember that an arbitrary (that is, unspecified) constant is called a
parameter.
The general equation for a straight line
Ax + By + C = 0
has two parameters, since if any one of the parameters A, B, or C is not zero, it may
be used as a divisor to reduce the equation to a form involving only two parameters.
The slope-intercept and intercept are two such forms.
The two essential parameters in the equation of a straight line correspond to the
two geometric conditions that may be imposed on the line. For each of these geome¬
tric conditions there is an algebraic equation showing the corresponding relation
between the parameters. Since any given number of variables is determined by that
same number of independent linear equations involving the variables, it follows that
the number of independent geometric conditions that can be put on a line is the same
as the number of essential parameters in the equation of a line, that is, two.
The general equation Ax + By 4- C = 0 with two essential parameters represents
all lines in the plane. When one of the two constants is specified and the other is
unspecified (that is, remains a parameter) a family of lines—such as all lines of a
given slope, or all lines passing through a particular point—is represented by the
equation. When both constants are specified, one particular line is represented by the
equation.
EXAMPLE
y - yt = m(x - xx)
The two essential parameters are expressed in this form of the equation as the slope m and
the point (x1? yx). Suppose the condition that the line is to have slope 2 is imposed. This
geometric condition corresponds to the algebraic equation
y - yi = 2(x - xx)
The family of lines represented by this equation consists of an infinite number of lines parallel
to each other and all having slope 2. (See Figure 1.10.)
One further condition can be imposed on the line. Geometrically, a point through which
the line is to pass can be specified (as a special case, this point could be either the x-intercept or
the y-intercept); algebraically, a pair of constant values can be assigned to the coordinates
(x1? }q). Suppose it is specified that the line is to pass through the point (4, 5), that is,
(xi, yi) = (4, 5). (See Figure 1.11.) Now a particular line is determined by the equation
y — 5 = 2(x — 4) or 2x — y — 3 = 0
Figure 1.10
Figure 1.11
EXAMPLE
x
- +
a
The two essential constants are expressed in this form of the equation as the x-intercept
(a, 0) and the y-intercept (0, b). Suppose the condition that the line is to have the x-intercept
(3, 0) is imposed. This geometric condition corresponds to the algebraic equation
The family of lines represented by this equation consists of an infinite number of members,
each having a different y-intercept (and thus a different slope) but all passing through the point
(3, 0). (See Figure 1.12.)
One further condition can be imposed on the line. Geometrically, the y-intercept can be
specified; algebraically, a constant value can be assigned to b.
1.3 Straight Lines / 35
Figure 1.12
Suppose that it is specified that the ^-intercept of the line is to be (0, — 1), that is, b = — 1.
(See Figure 1.13.) Now a particular line is specified by the equation
Figure 1.13
or
x — 3y = 3
x — 3y — 3=0
a = 3 b = -1
corresponding to the imposed geometric conditions; this line has the x-intercept 3 and the
y-intercept — 1.
PROBLEMS
1. What relation (parallel, perpendicular, coincident, or intersecting) does the line
y — 2x — 4 = 0 have to the following lines?
a. y — x — 2 = 0 d. y — 3x — 4 = 0
b. 4y — 8x — 16 = 0 e. 2y + x — 6 = 0
c. 5y — lOx — 4 = 0
2. What relation (parallel, perpendicular, coincident, or intersecting) does the line
2x — 5y + 6 = 0 have to each of the following lines?
a. 15x + 6y + 9 = 0 d. 4x — 8y + 3 = 0
b. lOx + 4y — 5=0 e. 6x — 15y + 8 = 0
c. 4x — 10y +12 = 0 f. lx — 5y + 2 = 0
3. What relation (parallel, perpendicular, coincident, or intersecting) does the line
3x + 4y — 2 = 0 have to each of the following lines?
a. 15x + 20y - 10 = 0 d. 3x + y - 4 = 0
b. 8x — 6y + 5 = 0 e. 12x — 9y + 2 = 0
c. 9x + 12y + 7 = 0 f. 2x 4- y — 6 = 0
4. Determine whether each of the following pairs of equations are a. independent or depen¬
dent and b. consistent or inconsistent.
i. 2x — 6y + 5 = 0 and 3x — 8y + 3 = 1 * 3 * 5
ii. x + 5y — 2 = 0 and x + 5y — 5 = 0
iii. 3x — 9y + 12 = 0 and x — 3y + 4 = 0
iv. 5x — 4y — 6 = 0 and 4x — 5y + 6 = i
5. Referring to the pairs of equations in Problem 4, a. determine which pairs of equations
have simultaneous solutions and obtain those solutions and b. graph the pairs of
equations.
6. If a pair of equations are consistent and independent, do they necessarily have a unique
simultaneous solution?
7. If a pair of equations are consistent and dependent, do they necessarily have a simultan¬
eous solution? If so, is it unique?
8. Can a pair of equations be inconsistent and dependent?
9. If a pair of equations represent perpendicular lines, are the equations consistent? Are they
independent?
10. Graph the family of straight lines parallel to the x-axis and give the equation correspond¬
ing to this specification. Graph the member of this family that passes through the point
(10, -6).
11. Graph the family of straight lines passing through the point (— 1, 6) and give the equation
corresponding to this specification. Graph the member of this family which is parallel to
the line y + 6x — 5 = 0 and write the equation for this line.
12. Graph the family of straight lines perpendicular to the line 2x — 5y — 10 = 0 and give the
equation corresponding to this specification. Graph the member of this family which
passes through the point (4, — 1) and write the equation for this line.
7. yes; no
9. yes; yes
11. y = mx + 6 + m; y = —6x
In this section several applications of straight lines in business and economics are
discussed. These applications include linear supply and demand curves and the
corresponding market equilibria, break-even analysis, and the consumption function.
Figure 1.14
y y
Jt
(a) (b)
38 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.15
y y
D
Price
O
a-
-x
Quantity Quantity
demanded demandec
general; the formulas for a straight line do not indicate the range of values of x and y
which are to be considered. When it is specified, as it is for the present purpose, that
only zero or positive values of x and y are of interest—and conversely, that negative
prices or quantities are not meaningful—the range of values for x and y is restricted.
These restrictions are based on the interpretation and meaning of the equation for a
particular application; they are not based on its inherent mathematical properties.
This must be kept in mind to avoid misinterpretations, particularly when more
complicated equations are considered.
EXAMPLE
Ten watches are sold when the price is $80; 20 watches are sold when the price is $60. What is
the demand equation?
y 2 - yi
y-y i =
(x - Xi)
X2 — *1
*i = 10 yj = 80
*2 = 20 y2 = 60
/ 60 - 80^
V - 80 =
20 ^To)(x-10)
= — 2(x — 10)
2x + y - 100 = 0
Figure 1.16
EXAMPLE
When the price is $100, no watches are sold; when watches are free, 50 are demanded. What is
the demand equation?
-+H
a b
a = 50 b = 100
*+j^ = i
50 100
2x 4- y = 100
2 x + y — 100 = 0
Figure 1.17
y
40 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE
Because they are considered necessary for national security, 50 heavy-duty generators are
bought every year, regardless of price. What is the demand equation?
x = x i = 50
Figure 1.18
y
<u
_o
U-
Ou 50
(50, 0)
►-x
Quantity
demanded
Figure 1.19
y y y
<L>
O
'c
Cl
- X -x
Quantity Quantity
supplied supplied
EXAMPLE
When the price is $50, 50 cameras of a fixed type are available for market; when the price is
$75, 100 of the cameras are available for market. What is the supply equation?
y-yi = t
X2
—
~
~(x-xt)
A!
Xj = 50 yi = 50
x2 = 100 y2 = 75
sn = 1 75 - 50 )(x — 50)
y — 50
100 - 50
= i(x - 50)
x — 2y + 50 = 0
Figure 1.20
EXAMPLE
When the price is $25, no cameras of a fixed type are available for market; for every $10
increase in price, 20 more cameras are available for market. What is the supply equation?
y = mx + b m —\ b = 25
y = \x + 25
x — 2y + 50 = 0
Figure 1.21
X
42 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE
According to the terms of the contract between Company A and the telephone company,
Company A pays the telephone company $500 per month for long-distance calls of unlimited
length of time. What is the supply equation?
>’ = = 500
Figure 1.22
y
Price
(0, 500)
L k
\
o
o
II
Quantity
supplied
Figure 1.23
y y
y
1.4 Applications of Straight Lines in Business and Economics / 43
Market Equilibrium
Market equilibrium is said to occur at that point (price) at which the quantity of a
commodity demanded is equal to the quantity supplied, as shown in Figure 1.23.
Thus, provided the same units for x and y are used in both equations, the equilibrium
amount and the equilibrium price correspond to the coordinates of the point of
intersection of the demand and supply curves. Algebraically, the equilibrium quan¬
tity and price are found by solving the supply and demand equations simultaneously
(again, provided the same units for x and y are used in both equations).
In general, for an equilibrium to be meaningful, the values of both x and y must be
positive or zero—that is, the demand and supply curves must intersect in the first
quadrant. This occurs if and only if the y-coordinate of the y-intercept of the demand
curve is greater than or equal to the y-coordinate of the y-intercept of the supply
curve and the x-coordinate of the x-intercept of the demand curve is greater than or
equal to the x-coordinate of the x-intercept of the supply curve. This can be seen
geometrically in Figure 1.23; the proof is given in Technical Note I.
EXAMPLE
Find the point of equilibrium for the following demand and supply equations.
y = 10 — 2x
y = fx + 1
10 — 2x = fx + 1
tx = 9
y = 10 - 2(^)
_
—
34
~T
Figure 1.24
y
44 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE
Find the point of equilibrium for the following demand and supply equations.
y = 5 — 3x
y = 4x + 12
Solving the equations simultaneously by substitution,
5 — 3x = 4x + 12
lx = — 7
x — —1
y = 5-3(—1)
8
Answer: (-1, 8) is not a meaningful equilibrium—note that bD = 5 < bs = 12.
(See Figure 1.25.)
Figure 1.25 y
BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS
Break-even graphs are frequently used in business and economics to analyze the
implications of various pricing and production decisions. A break-even graph, in
simplified form, is shown in Figure 1.26.
Figure 1.26
y
1.4 Applications of Straight Lines in Business and Economics / 45
In this particular case, costs have been divided into two general categories: fixed
and variable. Fixed costs remain constant at all levels of output and commonly
include such items as rent, depreciation, interest, plant, and equipment; variable
costs are those which vary with output and include such items as labor, materials,
and promotional expense. Total cost at any level of output is the sum of fixed cost
and the variable cost at that level of output.
In Figure 1.26 the straight line FC represents fixed cost. It is the straight line with
the y-intercept equal to the constant fixed cost (that is, cost when output is zero) and
slope zero.
The line TC represents total cost; its y-intercept is equal to fixed cost and its slope
is equal to the increase in variable cost per unit increase in output. Note the assump¬
tion that variable cost is proportional to output over the relevant range.
The line TR represents total revenue to the firm for different quantities sold; its
intercept is at the origin and its slope is equal to the price per unit, assuming that this
price is constant for all quantities sold.
The break-even point E is that point at which the lines TR and TC intersect. It
represents the quantity at which the producer just breaks even—that is, the quantity
for which there is just sufficient revenue to cover costs. Break-even analysis is used
more frequently in practice to demonstrate probable effects of changes than to deter¬
mine what those changes should be.
EXAMPLE
In Figure 1.27, suppose the firm decides that it could sell the same quantity of product,
denoted by point Q, if the price per unit were increased so that total revenue would be raised
from TR to TR'. TC remains the same, and the break-even point changes from E to E.
At the original price, profit to the firm is represented by the area of triangle EAB, at the
higher price, it is represented by the area of triangle EAC.
If, on the other hand, the firm assumes that the increase in price resulting in TR' would
reduce the quantity sold to that denoted by point Q', the following would be indicated:
Figure 1.27
46 / Graphical Representation
Since the profit area E'A'C' is greater than the profit area EAB resulting from the larger
quantity sold at the original price, the company might decide to increase the price even though
sales would be expected to drop.
Break-even analysis may be used to study possible results of many combinations of factors
involved in a particular problem.
EXAMPLE
Suppose the fixed cost of production for a commodity is $5000; the variable cost is $7.50 per
unit and the commodity sells for $10 per unit. What is the break-even quantity?
5000 = 2.5x
x = 2000
National income analysis provides an interesting example of the use of linear func¬
tions, since the consumption function is frequently assumed to be linear over rela¬
tively short ranges or “ in the short run.” The analysis, in one of its simplest forms, is
based on the following assumptions:
Ac Ac
-t— will be positive but less than one, that is, 0 <-< 1
Ay,
4. The proportion of an increment in disposable income which will be consumed is
constant. This proportion is referred to as the “marginal propensity to consume.”
These assumptions can be translated into the point-slope form of the equation for
a straight line
c = a + byd
EXAMPLE
When national disposable income is 0, national consumption is 5 (in billions of dollars). For
the economy as a whole consumption is linearly related to national disposable income as
follows: At each level of disposable income, consumption equals 5 (in billions of dollars) plus
80 percent of disposable income.
What is the equation that expresses this relationship?
c = 5 + 0.8yd
c = 5 + 0.8(40) = 37
Figure 1.28
EXAMPLE
c = 10 + 0.55yd
where c is aggregate consumption and yd is disposable income (in billions of dollars). What is
aggregate consumption when disposable income is 10 billion dollars? When disposable
income is 5 billion dollars, what proportion of it is consumed? When disposable income is 5
billion dollars, what proportion of aggregate consumption is consumption of disposable
income?
if yd = 10,
c = 10 + (0.55)(10)
= 15.5
Thus aggregate consumption is 15.5 billion dollars when disposable income is 10 billion
dollars.
48 / Graphical Representation
The proportion of disposable income that is consumed is 0.55 for any level of disposable
income.
If yd = 5,
c = 10 + (0.55)(5)
= 12.75
PROBLEMS
1. Which of the following equations represent demand curves, which represent supply curves,
and which represent neither demand nor supply curves? (Assume y represents price and x
represents quantity.)
a. x — 2y = 0 f. 2x T 5y + 4 = 0
b. 3x + 4y — 10 = 0 g. 3x + 4y — 12 = 0
c. y- 4 = 0 h. 5x — y — 10 = 0
d. x — 3 = 0 i. 2y T 3x -t- 2 = 0
e. 2x — 3y +1=0 j. x - 3y = 0
2. The demand curve for a commodity is x = 10 - y/4. (Assume y represents price and x
represents quantity demanded.)
a. Find the quantity demanded if the price is i. 4, ii. 16, iii. 25.
b. Find the price if the quantity demanded is i. 9, ii. 7, iii. 2.
c. What is the highest price that would be paid for this commodity?
d. What quantity would be demanded if the commodity were free?
e. Graph the curve.
3. The supply curve of a commodity is x = l.ly — 0.1. (Assume y represents price and x
represents quantity supplied.)
a. Find the price if the quantity supplied is i. 1, ii. 0.8, iii. 0.5.
b. Find the quantity supplied if the price is i. 8, ii. 6, iii. 4.1.
c. What is the lowest price at which this commodity would be supplied?
d. Graph the curve.
4. The demand equation of a commodity is x = A — By, where A and B are positive con¬
stants, y represents price, and x represents quantity demanded.
a. Find the price if the quantity demanded is A/3.
b. Find the quantity demanded if the price is A/2B.
c. Find the quantity demanded if the commodity is free.
d. What is the highest price that would be paid for this commodity?
5. The supply equation of a commodity is x = ay — b, where a and b are positive constants, y
represents price, and x represents quantity supplied.
a. Find the price if the quantity supplied is i. 5a — b, ii. a + 2b.
b. Find the quantity supplied if the price is i. 3b/a, ii. 5b/a.
c. What is the lowest price at which this commodity would be supplied?
6. For each of the following pairs of straight lines,
i. Determine which is the demand and which is the supply curve.
ii. Graph the curves and estimate the market equilibrium price and quantity.
iii. Solve the equations algebraically and verify the estimates for market equilibrium price
and quantity.
1.4 Applications of Straight Lines in Business and Economics / 49
a. y = 10 — 2x and y = fx + 1 c. x = 15 - 3y and x = 2y — 3
b. y = 6 and x = 3y - 3 d. 2y + 3x = 10 and x = 4y - 6
7. A manufacturer sells his product at $5 per unit.
a. What is the total revenue for sales of 5000 units of product? What is the equation for
this revenue function? Graph the function.
b. Fixed costs are constant at $3000 regardless of the number of units of product involved.
Superimpose the graph of this function on graph a. above.
c. Total cost is equal to the sum of fixed costs and variable costs. In this company,
variable costs are estimated at 40 percent of total revenue. What is the total cost when
5000 units of product are sold? Graph the function superimposed on graph a.
d. What is the break-even point? Indicate this point on the graph, and solve for the
corresponding amount sold. Indicate on the graph the quantity at which the manufac¬
turer will cover his fixed costs.
8. At a price of $5 per unit, a firm will supply 5000 plastic battery lanterns every month; at
$3.50 per unit it will supply 2000 units. Determine the equation of the supply function for
this product. Graph the equation.
9. For the economy as a whole, consumption is linearly related to national disposable
income as follows: at each level of disposable income, consumption equals 3.5 (in billions
of dollars) plus 75 percent of disposable income, a. What is the equation that expresses this
relationship? b. What is aggregate consumption when disposable income is 50 (in billions
of dollars)?
10. A firm has analyzed its sales and found that its customers will buy 20 percent more units of
its products with each $2 reduction in the unit price. When the price is $12, the firm sells
500 units. What is the equation of the demand function for this product? Graph the
equation.
11. a. Assume that water is in unlimited supply in a municipality. The consumer pays $5.00
per month for water regardless of the amount used. Graph the demand and supply
equations.
b. There is only one genuine painting by Rembrandt titled “The Night Watch.” Assign
arbitrary values to the painting and graph the demand and supply equations.
12. A bus company has learned that when the price of a short excursion trip is $5.00, 30 people
will buy tickets; when the price is $8.00, only 10 tickets will be sold. Obtain the point-slope
form of the equation for the demand function and graph the equation.
13. Identify which of the following equations represents a demand curve and which represents
a supply curve; determine the equilibrium point and graph the curves.
a. x + y = 5
b. 2x — y = 5.5
14. Change equation b. in Problem 13 to 2x — y = 6. Graph the equation and identify it as
supply or demand. Has the equilibrium quantity involved increased or decreased relative
to that in Problem 13?
15. Suppose the fixed cost of production for a commodity is $45,000. The variable cost is 60
percent of the selling price of $15 per unit. What is the break-even quantity?
16. If profit is $100 per unit and the fixed cost of production is $225,000, what is the break¬
even quantity?
17. Aggregate national consumption is given (in billions of dollars) by the equation
c = 4.5 + 0.9 yd
a + 3b
5. a. i. 5, ii. c. b/a (cannot be attained)
a
b. i. 2b, ii. 4b
7. a. $25,000 d. break-even point at x = 1000;
TR = 5x recovery of fixed costs at
c. $13,000 x — 600
9. a. c = 3.5 + 0.15yd b. 41 billion dollars
13. equation a. is demand,
equation b. is supply
(3.5, 1.5)
15. 5000
17. a. 18 billion dollars b. 0.75
Any equation whose graph is not a straight line is referred to as nonlinear. There are
several types of nonlinear curves, all of which can be classified as either algebraic or
transcendental.
A polynomial in x and y is the sum of a finite number of terms of the type kxrys,
where k is a constant and each of the exponents r and s is either a positive integer or
zero. The degree of a term is r + s and the degree of the polynomial is the degree of the
term or terms of highest degree. Equations of the form f(x, y) = 0, where/(x, y) is a
polynomial in x and y, are referred to as algebraic; the graphical representation of an
algebraic equation is an algebraic curve. Note that a straight line is an algebraic
curve.
Any equation in x and y which is not algebraic is referred to as transcendental; the
graphical representation of a transcendental equation is a transcendental curve.
Included among the transcendental curves are the graphs of trigonometric, logarith¬
mic, and exponential functions. Curves represented by algebraic equations of degree
greater than two in x and y or by transcendental equations are referred to as higher
plane curves.
The general methods of graphing discussed below can be used for graphing any
type of algebraic or transcendental curve. However, for graphing many types of
curves, special methods of graphing, which are more efficient than the general
methods, are available. The general methods are discussed first. Then methods of
identifying and graphing specific types of quadratic curves (circles, ellipses, parab¬
olas, and hyperbolas) and trigonometric, exponential, and logarithmic curves are
discussed.
Graphing a straight line from its equation is a relatively simple problem, since any
two distinct points uniquely determine a straight line. However, graphing more
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves / 51
INTERCEPTS
The intercepts of a curve are the points at which it crosses the axes. The x-intercepts
are obtained by setting y = 0 in the equation of the curve and solving for x; the
y-intercepts are obtained by setting x = 0 in the equation of the curve and solving
for y.
SYMMETRY
Two points are symmetric with respect to a line if that line is the perpendicular
bisector of the line segment joining the two points. Two points are symmetric with
respect to a third point if that third point is the midpoint of the line segment joining
the first two points. From these definitions it follows that the point (x, y) is a
symmetric to the point
Figure 1.29 Symmetry with respect to (a) the x-axis, (b) the .y-axis, and (c) the origin.
52 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.30 Symmetry with respect to (a) the x-axis, (b) the .y-axis, and (c) the origin.
Note that symmetry with respect to both the x- and y-axes implies symmetry
about the origin, but symmetry about the origin does not imply symmetry about
either axis. More generally, symmetry with respect to any two of the three (x-axis,
y-axis, and origin) implies symmetry with respect to the third. Thus symmetry can
occur with respect to none, one, or three of the x-axis, y-axis, and origin but never
with respect to just two of them. This can be seen from the definitions above:
Substitution of —y for y
leaves the equation unchanged
(x-axis symmetry) Substitution of — x for x and
and — y for y leaves the equation
substitution of — x for x ^ unchanged (symmetry to origin)
leaves the equation unchanged
(y-axis symmetry)
and similarly for the other two cases. (The symbol => means “ implies,” the symbol
=/> means “does not imply,” the symbol <= means “is implied by,” the symbol
means “ is not implied by.”)
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves 53
EXAMPLE
3 x2y + y + x3 = 0
is symmetric to the origin but not to either axis (see Figure 1.31).
Figure 1.31
f(x, —y)= —3x2y — y + x3, so f(x, — y) = 0 is not the same equation as f(x, y) = 0 and
f(x, y) = 0 is not symmetric to the x-axis.
/( — x, y) = 3x2y + y — x3, so /( — x, y) = 0 is not the same equation as/(x, y) = 0 and
/(x, y) = 0 is not symmetric to the y-axis.
/(— x, — y) = — 3x2y — y — x3, so /(— x, — y) = 0 is the same equation as/(x, y) = 0 and
/(x, y) = 0 is symmetric to the origin.
EXAMPLE
2x4 + x2y + y + 6 = 0
is symmetric to the y-axis but not to either the x-axis or the origin (see Figure 1.32).
/(x, — y) = 2x4 — x2y — y + 6, so/(x, — y) = 0 is not the same equation as/(x, y) = 0 and
/(x, y) = 0 is not symmetric to the x-axis.
Figure 1.32
54 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE __=
Figure 1.33 y
f(x, — y) = 5x2 + xy + 6x3, so /(x, — y) = 0 is not the same equation as/(x, y) = 0 and
/(x, y) = 0 is not symmetric to the x-axis.
/( —x, y) = 5x2 + xy - 6x3, so /( —x, y) = 0 is not the same equation as/(x, y) = 0 and
/(x, y) = 0 is not symmetric to the y-axis.
/( — x, — y) = 5x2 — xy — 6x3, so /( —x, — y) = 0 is not the same equation as/(x, y) = 0
and/(x, y) = 0 is not symmetric to the origin.
EXAMPLE
x3y + 3xy = 0
is symmetric to the x-axis, the y-axis, and the origin (see Figure 1.34).
Figure 1.34 y
= 0
x3y + 3xy = 0
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves / 55
Figure 1.35 Symmetry with respect to (a) the line x = h, (b) the line y = k, and (c) the point (h, k).
(c> 0)
fa) (b) (c)
EXTENT
The rectangular coordinate system denned represents only those points (x, y) whose
coordinates are real numbers; thus values of x for which y is imaginary and values of
y for which x is imaginary must be excluded. When even powers of a variable appear
in an equation, the solution for that variable may involve square roots (or other even
roots) and the extent of the curve may then be limited, since negative numbers do not
have real square roots (or other even roots). When possible, an equation should be
solved explicitly for each variable to see whether the range of any variable is limited
and the curve is correspondingly limited in extent. Note that any limitation on the
extent of one variable may implicitly limit the extent of the other variable.
EXAMPLE
Determine whether there is any limitation on the extent of the curve represented by the
equation
x2 + y2 = 9
Solving for x,
x = ± y/9~— y2
the quantity under the radical sign 9 — y2 is negative if | y | > 3; the extent of the curve in the
y-direction is therefore limited to the interval — 3 < y < 3.
Solving for y,
y= ± — x2
and the extent of the curve in the x-direction is therefore similarly limited to the interval
— 3 < x < 3.
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves / 57
EXAMPLE
Determine whether there is any limitation on the extent of the curve represented by the
equation
x2 - y2 = 4
Solving for x,
x = ± y/4 + y2
the quantity under the radical sign 4 + y2 is always positive and the extent of the curve in the
y-direction is therefore not limited.
Solving for y,
y = ± v/x2 - 4
the quantity under the radical sign x2 — 4 is negative if | x | <2; the extent of the curve in the
x-direction is therefore limited to the values — 2 < x < 2.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following equations, determine a. the intercepts; b. whether the curve repre¬
sented is symmetric to the x-axis, the y-axis, or the origin; and c. whether there is any
limitation on extent.
1. x3 — y2 — 9 = 0 4. xy + 5x — 15 = 0
2. x2 + y2 - 18 = 0 5. x2 + y4 - 6 = 0
3. y2 — 2x + 5 = 0 6. x2y2 — 25 = 0
ASYMPTOTES
A curve may have the property that a point can move along it so that the distance
from the origin to the point increases without limit. If, as the distance (in some
direction) of a point from the origin increases without limit, the distance between the
point and a fixed straight line approaches zero through values of the same sign, the
line is called an asymptote of the curve.
To show that a particular line is an asymptote of a particular curve it is necessary
to show that the curve approaches arbitrarily close to the line as the distance from
the origin increases without bound. This property involves the concept of limits,
which will be discussed in succeeding sections.
In general, then, the line y = mx -F b is an asymptote of the curve y = f(x) iff(x)
becomes arbitrarily close to mx + b as x and y increase without bound. This may be
written f(x) -> mx + b as x, y -> oo. (See Figure 1.37.)
58 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.37 /(x) -> mx + b as x, y -> oo; (a) from above, (b) from below.
y y
Asymptotes that are parallel to or coincident with one of the coordinate axes are
frequently of particular interest. These vertical and horizontal asymptotes are defined
as follows (see Figure 1.38).
Figure 1.38
EXAMPLE
Determine whether the curve represented by the following equation has vertical or horizontal
asymptotes:
xy + x — 3y — 2 = 0
3y + 2
* “ y + i
Figure 1.39
3;
as y -*■ + oo, x -► 3, and x < 3; as y -* — oo, x -► 3, and x > 3; thus x = 3 is an asymptote of the
curve and is approached from left and right.
Solving for y,
x —2
y - ,—
3 —x
as x -» + oo, y -*■ — 1, and y < —1; as x -► — oo, y -> — 1, and y > — 1; thus y = — 1 is an
asymptote of the curve and is approached from above and below.
EXAMPLE
Determine whether the curve represented by the following equation has vertical or horizontal
asymptotes:
x2 - y - 1 = 0
^ = ±V//)M- 1
asy->+oo, x->±oo;y> — 1, so y cannot approach — oo; thus the curve does not have a
vertical asymptote.
Solving for y,
y = x2 — 1
as x-++oo, y->+oo; as x—► — oo, y-++oo (as above); thus the curve does not have a
horizontal asymptote.
60 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.40
FACTORIZATION
If the left member of the equation / (x, y) = 0 can be written as the product of two or
more factors, for example, if /(x, y) = g(x, y) • h(x, y) = 0, then only those points
(x, y) whose coordinates satisfy either g(x, y) = 0 or h(x, y) = 0 lie on the graph of
f(x, y) = 0. Thus the graph of/(x, y) = 0 consists of the graphs of g(x, y) = 0 and
h(x, y) = 0. It is important to check for factorization, since a factorable equation may
be difficult to graph correctly if it is not factored.
EXAMPLE
x2y — xy2 — x + y = 0
Figure 1.41
Factoring,
xy(x — y) - x + y = 0
*>’(* - y) - (x - y) = 0
(xy - l)(x - y) = 0
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves / 61
Thus the graph of x2y — xy2 — x + y = 0 consists of the graphs of the curve xy — 1 = 0 and
the straight line x — y = 0.
EXAMPLE
Figure 1.42
Factoring,
Thus the graph of 2x2 — 3xy — 2y2 = 0 consists of the graphs of the straight lines 2x + y — 0
and x — 2y = 0.
EXAMPLE
The equation x2 + y2 — 0 is satisfied only by the point (0, 0), and its graph is thus a point
locus.
62 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE
The equation (x* 1 2 3 * 5 — 4)2 + (y2 — 4)2 = 0 is satisfied only by the points (2, 2), (2, —2), ( — 2, 2),
and ( — 2, —2), and its graph is thus a point locus.
EXAMPLE
The equation x2 4- y2 — — 5 is satisfied by no pair of real numbers x and y and its locus is thus
imaginary.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following equations, determine a. the asymptotes; b. whether the equation can
be factored; and c. whether the equation represents a real curve, point locus, or imaginary
curve.
1. Intercepts 4. Asymptotes
2. Symmetry 5. Factorization
3. Extent 6. Real curve, point locus, or imaginary locus
The following examples illustrate the use of these six properties in graphing a
given equation. Although factorization occurs near the end of the list (because in
practice factorable equations occur relatively infrequently), it should be checked first,
as it may make investigation of some of the other properties unnecessary. The
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves / 63
EXAMPLE
y = (x + 2)(x — 3)2
Figure 1.43
Intercepts: If y = 0, x = — 2, 3; if x = 0, y = 18.
Symmetry: Not symmetric with respect to either axis or the origin.
Extent: No apparent limits.
Asymptotes: None (as x -> + oo, y -*■ + oo and as x -► — oo, y -* — oo).
Factorization: Not factorable. [Note that factorability refers to the equation /(x, y) =
(x + 2)(x — 3)2 — y = 0, which is not factorable, although y = /(x) = (x + 2)(x — 3)2 is, in
fact, factored.]
Real, point, or imaginary locus: Real curve.
EXAMPLE
x2 — 4x -I- y — 12 = 0
Figure 1.44
EXAMPLE
xy — y — x — 2 = 0
x + 2
Figure 1.45
EXAMPLE
xy + x2 = 0
Figure 1.46
EXAMPLE
y3 + xy2 — xy — x2 = 0
Figure 1.47
EXAMPLE
x4 + x2 — y2 — y = 0
= (x2 - y)(x2 + y + 1) = 0
Figure 1.48
EXAMPLE
x2y — x2 — 4y = 0
y/(y — 1) is negative if 0 < y < 1 and is undefined if y = 1, so y is limited to the intervals y < 0
and y > 1. Solving for y, y = x2/(x2 — 4), so there is no limitation on the extent of x except y is
not defined for x = ± 2.
Asymptotes: x = ± 2 yjy/(y — 1). As y + oo, x-*■ ±2 and x> 121; as y —► — oo, x->±2
68 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.49
and x < 121; so x = ±2 are asymptotes, y = x2/(x2 — 4). As x -► + oo, y -*■ 1 and y > 1; as
x —> — oo, y -> 1 and y > 1, so y = 1 is an asymptote.
Factorization: Not factorable.
Real, point, or imaginary locus: Real curve.
EXAMPLE
x2y — x2 + 4y = 0
Figure 1.50
V = 1
1.5 General Methods of Graphing Nonlinear Curves / 69
Asymptotes: x = ± 2y/y/(l - y). y is limited in extent and cannot become large or small
without bound, y = x2/(x2 + 4). As x -> + oo, y -*■ 1 and y < 1; as x -> — oo, y -► 1 and y < 1,
so y = 1 is an asymptote.
Factorization: Not factorable.
Real, point, or imaginary locus: Real curve.
EXAMPLE
y2 — 4xy2 — 1=0
so there is no limitation on the extent of y, except that x is not defined for y = 0. Solving for y.
so x is limited to x <
Asymptotes: x = (y2 — l)/4y2. As y -> ± oo, x J, so x = J is an asymptote.
Figure 1.51
y
70 / Graphical Representation
x is limited in extent and cannot become large without bound. As x -► — oo, y -*■ 0, so y = 0 is an
asymptote.
Factorization: Not factorable.
Real, point, or imaginary locus: Real curve.
PROBLEMS
Sketch the curves represented by the following equations; give intercepts, extent, symmetry,
and asymptotes, as relevant.
Ax2 + Cy2 + Dx + Ey + F = 0
The removal of the xy-term is accomplished by changing from one set of axes to a
new set, which can be obtained by rotating the original axes about the origin. This
procedure will not be discussed in detail, because it is seldom necessary to use it in
practice.
Essentially, absence of the xy-term in a second-degree equation indicates that the
corresponding curve is symmetric to a line or lines (axes of the curve) parallel to one
or both of the coordinate axes. A circle, by definition, always has this type of sym¬
metry and B is always zero for a circle.
The curves represented by Equation (2) can be obtained by cutting a (double)
cone with a plane and thus are known as conic sections. The four special forms of a
conic section are the circle, the ellipse, the parabola, and the hyperbola (see Figure
1.52). In addition to these curves, Equation (2) may represent various types of degen¬
erate conics (actually special cases of conic sections). Degenerate conics may be
represented by two intersecting straight lines, two parallel straight lines, two coinci¬
dent straight lines (that is, one straight line), a point, or no points at all.
Any conic section can be defined as the locus of a point that moves in such a way
that the ratio of its distance from a fixed point (called its focus) to its distance from a
fixed line (called its directrix) is a constant e (called its eccentricity). Conic sections
can be classified into the four basic types according to the value of their eccentricity.
(For a circle, e = 0; for an ellipse, 0 < e < 1; for a parabola, e = 1; for a hyperbola,
e > 1.)
There are many interesting scientific applications of conic sections. For example,
the planets move in elliptic orbits about the sun with the sun at a focus; whispering
galleries usually have elliptical ceilings arranged so that a person standing at one
focus can hear a slight noise made at the other focus while someone standing between
the two foci hears nothing; elliptic arches are frequently used in architecture. The
cable of a suspension bridge hangs in the form of an arc of a parabola; a reflecting
surface made by rotating a parabola about its axis will send the light out in parallel
rays if the source of light is at the focus; the larger reflector in a reflecting telescope is
usually parabolic; the path of a projectile, neglecting air resistance, is a parabola. The
small reflector of a reflecting telescope is often a hyperbolic mirror (used to reflect the
image to the eyepiece); the hyperbola can be used to locate an invisible source of
72 / Graphical Representation
sound, such as an enemy’s guns, by considering two listening posts as the foci of a
hyperbola and performing certain computations on the difference in time of arrival of
the sound of the gun at the listening posts.
In economics and business, certain types of parabolic and hyperbolic curves are
appropriate for representing demand and supply functions, production functions,
and many other relationships. Applications of circular and elliptic curves are less
common but occur, for example, in representing product transformation functions.
The type of conic section represented by a second-degree equation can be
identified from an examination of its coefficients, whether or not the equation in¬
cludes an xy-term. However, only if the equation has no xy-term can it readily be put
into an appropriate standard form from which properties useful for graphing and for
other purposes can be obtained and from which degenerate cases can be identified.
with at least one of A and C nonzero can be identified as a circle, ellipse, parabola, or
hyperbola as follows:
The standard forms for each of the four types of conic sections and their geometri¬
cal representations and properties are discussed in the following sections. The alge¬
braic procedure known as “ completing the square,” which is used to put equations
into these standard forms, is discussed in detail in Technical Note III.
THE CIRCLE
Geometrically, a circle is the locus of points in a plane which are a fixed distance
from a given point called the center. The distance of the points from the center is the
radius of the circle. The general equation of a circle can be written
Ax2 -F Ay2 + Dx + Ey + F = 0
where (h, k) is the center of the circle and r is its radius, as shown in Figure 1.53.
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 73
Figure 1.53
When an attempt is made to put an equation in the standard form for a circle,
degenerate or imaginary loci can be detected from the indicated value of r2:
If r2 < 0, there is no real locus (imaginary radius)
If r2 = 0, the locus is a point (zero radius)
If r2 > 0, the locus is a circle
EXAMPLE
Put the following equations into the appropriate standard form for a circle, check for degener¬
ate or imaginary loci, and graph.
(x — 2)2 + (y — 3)2 = -6
r2 < 0, so no real locus.
Figure 1.54
Figure 1.55
(5, -2)
(x - 5)2 + (y + 2)2 = 0
THE ELLIPSE
Geometrically, an ellipse is the locus of points in a plane the sum of whose distances
from two fixed points (called foci) is constant. An ellipse has two (perpendicular) axes
of symmetry; the longer of these is the major axis, the shorter is the minor axis; the
point at which the axes intersect is the center of the ellipse (see Figure 1.56).
The general equation of an ellipse can be written
Ax2 + Cy2 + Dx + Ey + F = 0
(where A f C and A and C are of the same sign). As shown in Technical Note III,
any equation that represents an ellipse can be written in the standard form
x-h)2 (y-k)
7 b2
where (h, k) is the center of the ellipse and the major axis is parallel to the x-axis if
a> b and to the y-axis if a < b. (See Figure 1.57.)
The length of the axis parallel to the x-axis is 2a and the length of the axis parallel
Figure 1.56
y
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 75
Figure 1.57
y y
(a) ellipse with major axis (b) ellipse with major axis
parallel to x-axis (a > b) parallel to r-axis(a < b)
to the y-axis is 2b. a and b are referred to as semiaxes. When a = b, the ellipse
becomes a circle with radius r = a = b.
When an equation is in the standard form for an ellipse, the locus is an ellipse.
However,
If (x-^ + (r-fe£
= 0, the locus is the point (h, k)
a
EXAMPLE
Put the following equations into the appropriate standard form for an ellipse, check for
degenerate or imaginary loci, and graph.
(x - hf (y - kf
= 1
a2 + b2
(x-3)2 (y + 2)2
"2T'“ + W
Figure 1.58
y
---x
(3, -2)
6x2 H- 4y2 — 36x -j-16+ 4- 70 = 0
(x + 2)2 (y + l)2
= 1
2 + 9
(x + 2)2 + (j, + l)2
1
(y /2 r 3 '
Major axis 6.
Minor axis 2+2.
Major axis parallel to y-axis.
See Figure 1.59.
(x - 4)2 (y - 6)2
+ = -1
12
(x — h)2 (y-k)2
a1 bz
Figure 1.59
V
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 77
PROBLEMS
Determine whether each of the following equations represents a circle or an ellipse, put the
equation into the appropriate standard form, check for degenerate or imaginary loci, and
graph.
1. x2 + y2 + 2x - 4y + 1 = 0 4. x2 + y2 - 8x - 4y + 18 = 0
2. 9x2 + 4y2 - 24y = 0 5. x2 + y2 - lOx + 25 = 0
3. x2 -I- 4y2 — 6x + 16y + 45 = 0 6. x2 + y2 — 2x + 4y -f 11 = 0
3. ellipse:
(* - 3)2 . (y + 2f -5
4 1
so there is no real locus
THE PARABOLA
Geometrically, a parabola is the locus of points in a plane which are equidistant from
a fixed point (called the focus) and a fixed straight line (called the directrix). A
parabola is symmetric about a line, called its axis; the point of intersection of the
parabola and its axis is the vertex of the parabola (see Figure 1.60).
The general equation of a parabola can be written
Ax2 + Dx + Ey + F = 0
Cy2 + Dx + Ey + F = 0
if the axis is parallel to the x-axis. As shown in Technical Note III, any equation that
represents a parabola can be written in the standard form
(x - h f = 4p(y - k)
78 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.61
y y
where (h, k) is the vertex of the parabola and the axis is parallel to the y-axis, or in the
standard form
where (h, k) is the vertex of the parabola and the axis is parallel to the x-axis. The
orientation and curvature of a parabola are determined by the sign and magnitude of
p as follows:
For a parabola with axis parallel to the y-axis:
(see Figure 1.61). The distance between the point (focus) and the line (directrix)
defining a parabola is 2p (distance from a point to a line is measured along the
perpendicular); as shown in Figure 1.62, the larger the value of p, the faster the
parabola opens.
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 79
Figure 1.62
y y
When an equation is in either standard form for a parabola, the locus is a para¬
bola. However,
EXAMPLE
Put the following equations into the appropriate standard form for a parabola, check for
degenerate or imaginary loci, and graph.
(a) y2 - 8y + 17 = 0.
(b) x2 — 4x + y + 14 = 0.
(c) x2 - lx + 12 = 0.
(d) y2 - lOy + 25 = 0.
(e) y2 — 2y — 6x + 19 = 0.
(a) y2 - Sy + 17 = 0
(y — 4)2 = -1
(y — k)2 < 0, so there is no real locus. Note that the x-term is missing in this example.
(b) x2 — 4x + y + 14 = 0
x2 — 4x + 4 = —y —14 + 4
Parabola: Vertex (2, —10), axis parallel to the y-axis, parabola opens downward.
Figure 1.63
not possible for a real number. In (b), the square of a number is said to be the negative of a
quantity involving a variable, which implies that the quantity (y + 10) must be negative or
zero; y + 10 is negative or zero if y is limited in extent to the interval y < —10, as shown in
Figure 1.63.
(c) x2 - lx + 12 = 0
x2-7x + 4? = —12 + 4?
(x-j)2=i
x—
V- 7
1
_ IA
— ± a/3
x — ? ~ ±1
x=j or x — 4 = 0
and
x = -§ or x — 3 = 0
The locus is two parallel straight lines, parallel to the y-axis (see Figure 1.64). Note that the
y-term is missing in this example and the equation could have been factored (x — 4) x
(x - 3) = 0 without completing the square.
(d) y2 - lOy + 25 = 0
(y - 5)2 = o
Figure 1.64
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 81
Figure 1.65
o
II
1
The locus is two coincident straight lines (see Figure 1.65). Note again that the x-term is
missing.
(e) y2 - 2y - 6x + 19 = 0
(y2 - 2y + 1) = 6x - 19 + 1
(y - l)2 = 6x - 18
(y - l)2 = 6(x - 3)
Figure 1.66
Parabola: Vertex (3, 1), axis parallel to the x-axis, parabola opens to the right (see Figure 1.66).
THE HYPERBOLA
Geometrically, a hyperbola is the locus of points in a plane the difference of whose
distances from two fixed points (called foci) is a constant. A hyperbola has two
(perpendicular) axes of symmetry; the axis that intersects the hyperbola is its trans¬
verse axis; the point at which the axes intersect is the center of the hyperbola. A
hyperbola always has two branches.
82 / Graphical Representation
Ax2 + Cy2 -f Dx + Ey + F = 0
(where A and C are opposite in sign.) As shown in Technical Note III, any equation
that represents a hyperbola can be written in the standard form
{x-hf (y-kf
a2 b2
where (h, k) is the center of the hyperbola and the transverse axis is parallel to the
x-axis, or in the standard form
where (h, k) is the center of the hyperbola and the transverse axis is parallel to the
y-axis. (See Figure 1.67.)
Every hyperbola has a pair of intersecting straight lines as asymptotes; these
asymptotes are given by the equations
Note that the equations for these asymptotes can be obtained from the standard form
by replacing 1 by 0, transposing the negative term, and taking square roots.
If a = h, the asymptotes of the hyperbola are perpendicular and the hyperbola is a
rectangular or equilateral hyperbola. Equilateral hyperbolas are discussed in more
detail below.
When an equation is in the standard form for a hyperbola, the locus is a hyper¬
bola. However,
Figure 1.67
y y
(x — h* 2) (y - kf
If = 0, the locus is two intersecting straight lines,
a' b2
x — h y-k
= +
a b
Note that these are also the equations for the asymptotes of the hyperbola.
There is no possibility of an imaginary locus in the case of a hyperbola. If, for
example,
x — h)2 (y — k)2
-j-— = C where C < 0
a bz
then
(V - kf (x — h)2
^2
=c where C > 0
b2~
EXAMPLE
Put the following equations into the appropriate standard form for a hyperbola, check for
degenerate loci, and graph.
6(x2 — 2x + 1) — A(y2 + Ay + 4) = 34 + 6 — 16
(x - l)2 (y + 2):
= 1
22 (V6);
Hyperbola: Center (1, — 2), a = 2, b = ^/6, transverse axis parallel to the x-axis.
. x — 1 y + 2
Asymptotes: —-— = ± —j=-
2 v/6
y + 2=±^6(x-1)
y « 1.23(x — 1) — 2 y « — 1.23(x — 1) — 2
If x = 0, y « —3.23 If x = 0, y « —0.77
If y = 0, x « 2.63 If y = 0, x « —0.63
Figure 1.68
note: The symbol « means “approximately equal to” and is used because of the approxi¬
mation Of y/6.
(y - 3)2 (x - 3):
= 1
1 2
(y - 3)2 (X - 3)2
= 1
l2 (7+
Hyperbola: Center (3, 3); a = b = 1, transverse axis parallel to the y-axis.
1
Asymptotes: y — 3 = ± —t= (x - 3)
v^
Plotting the asymptotes:
y » 0.7l(x - 3) + 3 y * —0.71(x - 3) + 3
If x = 0, y % 0.87 If x = 0, y * 5.13
If y = 0, x * - 1.23 If y = 0, x % 7.23
(x + 2)2 _ (y + 4)2 =
5
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 85
Figure 1.69
y= ±v/|(x + 2)-4
y « 1.29(x + 2) — 4 y « — 1.29(x + 2) — 4
If x = 0, y * - 1.42 If x = 0, y « -6.58
If y = 0, x « 1.10 If y = 0, x « —5.10
Figure 1.70
y
86 / Graphical Representation
(x — h)(y — k) = c
where (h, k) is the center of the hyperbola, about which it is symmetric, and x = h
and y = k are the asymptotes. (Note that this is the special case A = C = 0, B =/= 0, of
the general second-degree equation Ax2 + Bxy -I- Cy2 + Dx + Ey -l- F = 0.) If the
asymptotes are considered as coordinate axes, the hyperbola has its two branches in
the first and third quadrants if c > 0 and in the second and fourth quadrants if c < 0,
as shown in Figure 1.71. The intercepts of the hyperbola are the points (h — (c/k), 0)
and (0, k — (c/h)), where h — (c/k) and k — (c/h) may be positive or negative accord¬
ing to the values of h, k, and c. Note that this type of hyperbola has no more than one
x-intercept and one y-intercept; for a hyperbola to have two x-intercepts, its equa¬
tion must include an x2-term, and for a hyperbola to have two y-intercepts, its
equation must include a y2-term. Similarly, for a hyperbola to have one y-intercept,
its equation must include an x-term and for a hyperbola to have one y-intercept, its
equation must include a y-term.
The equation of an equilateral hyperbola whose asymptotes are the coordinate
axes can be written in the standard form
xy = c
[Note that this is the special case h = k = 0 of the equation (x — h)(y — k) = c.]
Figure 1.71
y y
Figure 1.72
y y
This type of hyperbola has its center at the origin, about which it is symmetric; its
branches occur in the first and third quadrants if c > 0 and in the second and fourth
quadrants if c < 0. Since it is asymptotic to both coordinate axes, the hyperbola has
no intercepts (see Figure 1.72).
The equation xy — c expresses an inversely proportional relationship between x
and y—that is, as one variable increases, the other variable decreases proportionally.
The variable y is said to be inversely proportional to the variable x, if there is a
constant c such that
c
y=— or xy = c
x
or xny = c
EXAMPLE
(x - 4)(y + 12) = 2
Figure 1.73
EXAMPLE
(x - 2)y = -4
Figure 1.74
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 89
EXAMPLE
x3y = 16
Points to aid graphing: (2, 2), (1, 16), (*/l6, 1), (-2), (-1, -16),
(— y/l6, — 1) (note that ^/l6 « |).
Figure 1.75
y
EXAMPLE
Figure 1.76
90 / Graphical Representation
Points to aid graphing: (1, 5), (25, 1), (i 10), (1, -5), (25, -1), (i -10).
PROBLEMS
Determine whether each of the following equations represents a parabola or a hyperbola, put
the equation into the appropriate standard form, check for degenerate or imaginary loci, and
graph.
1. y1 2 3 - 2y - 2x + 9 = 0 4. y2 - 8y + 24 = 0
2. x2 - 3y2 - 4x + 12y - 11 = 0 5. xy - 4x - 5y + 5 = 0
3. 3x2 — 2y2 — 6x — 4y + 1 = 0 6. xy + 5x — y — 5 = 0
has five arbitrary constants, since if any of the constants A, B, C, D, £, and F is not
zero, it may be used as a divisor to reduce the equation to a form involving only five
arbitrary constants; after the values of five constants are set arbitrarily, the value of
the other constant must be set so that the sum of the terms is zero. These five
arbitrary constants in the equation of a second-degree curve permit five geometric
conditions to be imposed on the curve.
As discussed above, various conditions on the constants A, B, and C determine the
general form of the second-degree curve; complete specification of the constants
determines a particular curve. Families of various types of curves are represented by
an equation in which one (or more) of the constants is specified and the others are
unspecified (that is, remain parameters). For example, a family of circles may have
the same center (that is, be concentric) but have different radii, or a family of parab¬
olas may have the same vertex but have different degrees of curvature. Such families
of curves will be discussed in more detail in later sections.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following equations, identify the curve represented, put the equation into the
appropriate standard form and identify the parameters and properties thus obtained, and
sketch the curve.
1. x2 + y2 - 6x - 2y - 6 = 0 4. y2 - lOy = 0
2. y2 — 6y + 9 = 0 5. xy — 4y = — 4
3. 3x2 + 3y2 - 6x + 4y = 1 6. x2 - y2 + 4x - 2y + 1 = 0
1.6 Quadratic Curves / 91
(X - o)2
7. ellipse: + (y - Q)2
52 (5s/2)2
center (0, 0)
semiaxes 5^2,5
major axis parallel to y-axis
>-2)2 , (y-1)
9. ellipse with no real locus: + = -3
(y + 3)2
11. hyperbola: —
(73)2
center (2, —3)
asymptotes y = J3 x - 2^3 - 3 and y = -y/3 x + 2^/3 - 3
transverse axis parallel to x-axis
i c ir (x ~ 4)2 (y - 0)2
15. ellipse:~ = 1
center (4, 0)
semiaxes 3, 1
major axis parallel to x-axis
17. hyperbola:
. (y - o); (X - o)2
(3+3): 32
center (0, 0)
asymptotes y = ^/3x and y = — y/3x
transverse axis parallel to y-axis
92 / Graphical Representation
y y
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 93
y y
(b)
positive y-axis, provided the parabola has positive x- and ^-intercepts. The cond¬
itions on the coefficients of the equation which specify the family of curves appro¬
priate for representing a particular type of economic function can be determined
using the corresponding standard form of the equation (see the problems).
Market Equilibrium
Market equilibrium price and quantity are the price and quantity represented by the
coordinates of the point of intersection of the demand and supply curves. An approx¬
imate solution for these coordinates can be obtained geometrically for any supply
and demand curves. However, algebraic simultaneous solution, even for second-
degree demand and supply functions, may involve solution of a third- or fourth-
degree equation.
Since general methods for solution of equations of degree greater than two are not
discussed here, the examples and problems are limited to cases involving solution of
94 / Graphical Representation
a quadratic equation. For example, if one equation is linear and the other equation is
parabolic or hyperbolic, their simultaneous solution involves solution of a quadratic
equation; similarly, simultaneous solution of two parabolic equations which are
quadratic with respect to the same variable involves solution of a quadratic equation.
Unless a quadratic equation can be factored, its solution is most readily obtained
by using the quadratic formula: The root(s) of a quadratic equation
ax2 + bx + c = 0 are given by
— b± yjb2 — 4ac
x =
2a
This formula is obtained by the process of completing the square, as shown in
Technical Note IV. Note that the number of real roots an equation has is determined
by the value of b2 — 4ac:
EXAMPLE
Find the equilibrium price and quantity for the following demand and supply equations
(where x represents quantity and y represents price):
2x + y — 10 = 0
y2 — 8x — 4 = 0
so
y2 - 4 = —4y 4- 40
y2 + 4y — 44 = 0
-4±yi6^4)F44)
y 2
_ —4± 8^3
“ 2
= ~2± V3
x=i(-y+ 10)
= 6 ± 273
73 as 1.732, so the approximate solutions are (2.5, 4.9) and (9.5, —8.9) and the approximate
equilibrium point is (2.5, 4.9).
Plotting the curves to verify the result geometrically (see Figure 1.80),
2x 4- y — 10 = 0 y2 — 8x — 4 = 0
If x = 0, y = 10 y2 = 8x + 4
If y = 0, x = 5 y2 = 8(x + i)
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 95
Figure 1.80
EXAMPLE
Find the equilibrium price and quantity for the following demand and supply equations
(where x represents quantity and y represents price):
x2 + 5x — y + 1 = 0
2x2 + y — 9 = 0
y = x2 + 5x + 1
y = — lx2 -f 9
so
x2 + 5x + 1 = — 2x2 4- 9
3x2 + 5x — 8 = 0
(3x + 8)(x — 1) = 0
x = -f, 1
y = — 2x2 + 9
The solutions are (— -§, —V) and (1, 7) and the equilibrium point is (i. n
Plotting the curves to verify the result geometrically (see Figure 1.81),
(x2 + 5x + ^) = y — 1 + tt 2x2 = — (y — 9)
(x + i)2=y + ^ x2=~Uy~ 9)
96 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.81
EXAMPLE
Find the equilibrium price and quantity for the following demand and supply equations
(where x represents quantity and y represents price):
y* 2 3 + y + x-20 = 0
2 y2 — x — 3y — 4 = 0
x = — y2 — y + 20
x = 2 y2 — 3y — 4
so
— y2 — y + 20 = 2 y2 — 3y — 4
3y2 - 2y - 24 = 0
2±V4-4(3)( —24)
y 6
_ 2 ± 2v/73
6
= 1 ±/73
3
x = -y2 - y + 20
1 ± 2n/73 + 73 1 ± v/73
+ 20
77 ± 5^73
+ 20
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 97
Figure 1.82
y/Ti « 8.544, so the approximate solutions are (6.7, 3.2) and (16.2, —2.5), and the approxi¬
mate equilibrium point is (6.7, 3.2).
Plotting the curves to verify the result geometrically (see Figure 1.82),
y2 + y + x-20 = 0 2y2 — x — 3y — 4 = 0
y2 + y + i — — x + 20 + i 2 (y2 — iy + te) = x + 4 + |
EXAMPLE
Find the market equilibrium price and quantity for the following demand and supply equa¬
tions (where x represents quantity and y represents price):
(x + 12)(y + 6) = 169
x — y 4- 6 = 0
x + 12 = ±13
x = 1, -25
y=x + 6
y = 7,-19
The solutions are (1, 7) and ( — 25, —19) and the equilibrium point is (i. n
Plotting the curves to verify the result geometrically (see Figure 1.83),
If x = 0, y = 6 asymptotes x = —12, y = —6
If y = 0, x = — 6 If x = 0, y = fi
lfy = 0, x=^
98 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.83
y y
(a) (b)
100 / Graphical Representation
and 1.87. Note that for circular, elliptic, and parabolic product transformation curves,
the entire first-quadrant part of the curve is appropriate. However, for hyperbolic pro¬
duct transformation curves, the range is limited to the lower branch of the hyperbola;
this limitation is usually stated as a restriction on the range of x:
c
0 < x < h —-
k
EXAMPLE
A company produces amounts x and y of two different grades of steel using the same produc¬
tion process. The product transformation curve for the input used is given by
y2 + x + 4y — 20 = 0
(a) What are the largest amounts x and y that can be produced?
(b) What amounts x and y should be produced in order to have x = 4y?
Figure 1.88
y
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 101
— 4±yi6~-(4)( —20)
y 2
_ -4 ± 4v//6
~ 2
= -2 ± 2^6
x/6 ^ 2.449, so y « 2.9, —6.9 and the largest amount y is (approximately) 2.9.
(b) Substituting x = Ay in y2 -f x + 4y — 20 = 0,
y2 + 4y + 4y — 20 = 0
y2 + 8y — 20 = 0
(y + 10)(j, - 2) = 0
y= -10,2
EXAMPLE
A company produces amounts x and y of two different kinds of candy using the same produc¬
tion process. The product transformation curve for the input used is given by
(a) What are the largest amounts x and y that can be produced?
(b) What amounts x and y should be produced in order to have y = |x?
(a) If y = 0,
5x2 = 98
■ X2 = IT
x = = = i^x/lO
Figure 1.89
y
102 / Graphical Representation
2 y2 = 98
y2 = 49
y = ±7
5x2 + 2(-^)x2 = 98
^x2 = 98
x2 = 16
x — ±4, y = ±3
EXAMPLE
A company produces amounts x and y of two petrochemicals using the same production
process. The product transformation curve for the input used is given by
(a) What are the largest amounts x and y that can be produced?
(b) What amounts x and y should be produced to have x = iv?
(a) If y = 0,
x = — ^ + 24 = ^
Figure 1.90
y
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 103
^ — 24)0--36) = 240
y -36= ±^360
y = 36 ± 6v//l0
y « 36 ± 19.0
55, 17
So the amounts produced are (approximately) x = y = 17. (Note that the solution x =
y = 55 violates the restriction x < Af and is on the upper branch of the hyperbola.)
EXAMPLE
A company produces amounts x and y of two different textiles using the same production
process. The product transformation curve for the input used is given by
(a) If y = 0,
x2 = 100
x = ± 10
So the largest amount x is 10. If x = 0, y = 20, so the largest amount y is 20.
Figure 1.91
y
104 / Graphical Representation
-5 ± 5/17
2
-5 ± 5(4.123)
y « 7.8, -12.8
PROBLEMS
For each of the following pairs of equations, i. determine which equation represents a demand
curve and which equation represents a supply curve, ii. determine the market equilibrium
quantity and price algebraically, and iii. check geometrically the algebraically determined
equilibrium points.
1. a. x = 16 - 2y 10. a. x = 84 - y2
b. 4x = 4y + y2 b. x = y + 4y2
b. x = 96 — 8y — 2y2
b. y = 2x + 4
4. a. y = 16 — x 14. a. x = 2y2 — 2y — 6
b. y = 4 + x b. x = —y2 — y + 18
5. a. x = 32 — 4y — y 15. a. y = 10 - 3x2
b. y = 4 4- x2 + 2x
16. a. xy = 30
6. a. y = 9x + 12
b. 3y - x = 9
b. y = 39 — 3x2
17. a. xy = 15
x2
7. a. y = 6 + — b. y = x + 2
4
18. a. (x + 10)(y + 20) = 300
b. x = ^36 — y
b. x = 2y — 8
8. a. y = (x + 2)2
19. a. (x + 6)(y + 12) = 144
b. y = 39 - 3x2
i ^ x
9. a. y = 48 — 3x2
b- y =2 + 2
b. y = x2 + 4x 4- 16
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 105
b. x — y + 6 = 0 , . x
b.y=l+-
21. a. (x + 5)(j; + 6) = 80
26. a. y = x2 -I- 5x + 1
, x
b. y = - + 3
b. y + 2x2 — 9 = 0
b. x = 10 — y2 — y
24. a. y(x 4- 3) = 18
b. y — 3x + 6 = 0
Each of the following equations represents a product transformation curve for the amounts
x and y, respectively, of two related commodities; find the largest amounts x and y that can be
produced.
29. x = 36 — 6y2
30. y = 65 — 12x — 5x2
31. y = 45 — 9x2
32. x = 16 - 4y- 2y2
33. The production manager has decided that the marketing department can sell 126 units of
product daily, and he wants to produce that much. If he assumes that all factors other than
the number of employees and the resultant output remain constant within the range of this
total production, the production function can be expressed by the equation
2x2 + 4x — y = 0
with x representing the number of employees and y representing the units of production.
The production manager claims that he will need 7 men to produce the 126 units, a.
Assuming that the equation is appropriate, is the production manager correct in his
statement concerning the number of men needed? b. What type of curve does the equation
represent? Graph the curve, c. Draw up a schedule of units of production output per man
employed in the range 1 through 7 employees. Indicate the change in the number of units
produced through this range as each employee is added.
34. A company’s operations research director believes that the short-run average cost of
production can be expressed by the equation
x2 — 16x — y + 68 = 0
with x representing the number of units produced and y representing the average cost per
unit. He says that the average cost will be lowest when eight units are produced, a. Is his
statement correct? b. What type of curve is represented? Graph the curve, c. Draw up a
schedule of values of y for the range x = 4 through x = 12 and indicate the amount of
change in y for each change in x.
35. In national income analysis, the demand for a stock of money to be held, or the “ liquidity
preference,” as Keynes calls it, is often considered to be dependent on three motives: the
transactions motive, the precautionary motive, and the speculative motive. Assume that, at
a given level of national income, the effects of the transactions and precautionary motives
are constant. The speculative motive is considered to be a function of the interest rate as
expressed by the equation (x — l)y = 4, where x is the rate of interest (%) and y is the
demand for money to hold expressed in billions of dollars, a. What type of curve does the
equation express? Graph the curve, b. Draw up a schedule of values for y, the amount of
money demanded to be held (in billions of dollars) for the values of x from 2% through
106 / Graphical Representation
7%. What is the value of y when x = 100 (in billions of dollars)? c. Note and describe the
segment of the curve which represents the “ liquidity trap ”—that segment in which the
interest rate seems to lose its force as an effective factor in influencing the demand for
money to hold.
36. According to convention, in the economic analysis discussed in Problem 35, the dependent
variable (the demand for money to be held) is often assigned to the x-axis rather than the
y-axis. An equation used to express Keynesian ideas concerning the relationship between
the rate of interest and the money demanded to be hid is then x(y — 1) = 4. a. What type of
curve does this equation represent? Graph the curve, b. Draw up a schedule of values for
the interest rate y for the values of x from 1 through 7 (in billions of dollars). What is the
value of y when x = 100 (in billions of dollars)? c. Note and describe the segment of the
curve that represents the “ liquidity trap.”
37. Consider the parabola y = ix2 — x + 4 and the equilateral hyperbola (x + 2)(y - 2) = 4.
a. Show that for x = 0 and x — 2 both equations have the same value of y, but for x = 4
and x — —2 they have different values of y. b. Show that the two equations have the same
value of y only for x = 0 and x = 2. c. Sketch the two curves on the same set of axes.
38. A company produces x and y amounts of steel of two different grades, using the same
resources; the product transformation curve is
^20-3<^ <*<3°>
a. Sketch the curve, b. Determine the largest amounts of x and y that can be produced, c. If
the demand for grade x steel is twice that for grade y steel, determine the amounts the
company should produce.
39. A company manufactures two grades of candy from the same resources. If x and y
represent the quantities produced, the product transformation curve is
a. Sketch the curve, b. Determine the largest amounts of x and y that can be produced, c. If
the demand for grade x candy is two-thirds that for grade y, determine the amounts the
company should produce.
40. A company manufactures two grades of paper from the same resources; if x and y repre¬
sent the quantities produced, the product transformation curve is
(x - 30)(y - 15) = 150 (x < 30)
a. Sketch the curve, b. If the demand for grade x paper is three times that for grade y paper,
determine the amounts of paper the company should produce, c. If the demand for grade y
paper exceeds that for grade x paper by four units, determine the amounts the company
should produce.
b. supply
(2, 2)
33. a. yes ,
b. parabola, vertex (— 1, — 2), axis parallel to y-axis
Number of Total
employees units produced
X y Ay
1 6
2 16 10
3 30 14
4 48 18
5 70 22
6 96 26
7 126 30
The economist Vilfredo Pareto proposed the following law of distribution of income:
The number of individuals N from a given population of size a whose income exceeds
x is
108 / Graphical Representation
Figure 1.92
EXAMPLE
216 x 1010
N= .3/2
216 x 1010
= 2160 millionaires
(106)3/2
_ 216 x 1010
= 216 x 104
(104)3/2
1.7 Applications of Quadratic Curves in Business and Economics / 109
so the number with incomes between $3600 and $10,000 is 107 — 216 x 104 = (1000 — 216) x
104 = 784 x 104 or 7,840,000.
216 x 1010
(c) 80 = -3/2
216 x 1010
x-3/2
1 =--= 27 x 109
80
x = (27 x 109)2/3 = 9 x 106
or $9,000,000 is the lowest income of the 80 people with the highest incomes.
EXAMPLE
16 x 1012
N= .5/3
, , 16 x 1012 16 x 1012 c
(a) N"(8x 103)5'3 “ 25 x 105 “ 5 x 10
so 5 x 106 people have incomes above $8000 and 16 x 1012 — (5 x 106) = (16 x 106 — 5)
x 106 or 15,999,995,000,000 have incomes below $8000.
(b) The number with incomes over $125,000 is
16 x 1012
N= = 16 x 102 or 1600
(106)5/3
So the number with incomes over $125,000 but less than $1,000,000 is 51,200 - 1600 = 49,600.
16 x 1012
(c) 50 =
x5/3
=
16 x 101"
x5/3
= 32 x 10 10
50
or $8,000,000 is the lowest income of the 50 people with the highest incomes.
PROBLEMS
1. Pareto’s law for the distribution of incomes for a particular group is
„ 8 x 108
„ 1.9 x 1012
XT 100,000
N =-2—
x
„ 32 x 1010
xr 625 x 109
N ~ X3'2
17.6
12.03
b. 8796
To,
a(tb - sb)
c. $10,000 d.
sbtb
3. a. 444
e. a(lb ~ 1)
b. 22 (15 x 105)b
c. $141 9. a. $27,455
5. a. 4,375,000 b. $473.21
b. $250,000 c. 4.574
a d. 4.975
7. a. —r
kb
a
b.
10 5b
EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS
A function having a variable base and a constant exponent is a power function. For
example, y = xa is a power function, where x is the base and a is the exponent. Many
examples of power functions have been discussed in previous sections. A function
having a constant base and a variable exponent is an exponential function. For
example, y = ax is an exponential function, where a is the base and x is the exponent.
The following rules of exponents are applicable to both power functions and
exponential functions.
If x, y, and z are positive real numbers,
Rule Example
5. x~m = m
x
m 1
x Ym-n _
6.
X' x"“m
Figure 1.93
y y
(c) a > 0, k > 0, c < 0, |c| < a (d) a > 0, k < 0, c < 0, \c\ < a
(if \c\ > a, intercepts negative) (if \c\ > a, intercepts negative)
y y
y = aekx + c
LOGARITHMIC FUNCTIONS
In 1614, John Napier wrote the first treatise on logarithms. He based his discus¬
sion on the comparison of two sets of numbers—one in arithmetic progression and
one in geometric progression. For example, consider the following two progressions:
Arithmetic: 0 1 2 3 4 5 6...
Geometric: 1 3 9 27 81 243 729...
32 = 9
33 = 27
and so forth. Furthermore, the two progressions indicate that in order to multiply, it
is necessary only to add exponents: 32 x 33 = 32 + 3 = 35. And to divide, it is neces¬
sary only to subtract exponents: 35 -f- 32 = 35-2 = 33. This idea is the basis for the
computational short cuts possible using logarithms.
By definition, the logarithm of a positive number y to a positive base b, other than
1, is the exponent x to which the base must be raised to obtain the number. Thus, if
b > 0, b ± 1, and b, x, and y are related by the equation
y = bx (3)
then x, the exponent of b, is the logarithm of y to the base b. This relationship may
also be expressed by the equation
* = loSb y (4)
Equations (3) and (4) express the same relationship between b, x, and y in expon¬
ential and logarithmic forms, respectively, and are inverse functions—that is, if y is an
exponential function of x, then x is a logarithmic function of y.
Although the base of a logarithm can be any positive number other than 1, in
practice the base is almost always either 10 (common or Briggsian logarithms) or
e ~ 2.718 (natural or Naperian logarithms). The base e is defined in terms of limits as
follows:
n
e = lim
n-> oo
The concept of limits is discussed in detail later; for present purposes it is sufficient to
1.8 Exponential and Logarithmic Curves / 115
Rule Example
The curve representing the function y — log* x lies entirely in the first and fourth
quadrants; it is monotonically decreasing if 0 < b < 1 and monotonically increasing
if b > 1; in both cases the curve is asymptotic to the y-axis and has x-intercept (1, 0).
The parameter b determines the curvature of the function (see Figure 1.95).
Figure 1.95
Figure 1.96
y
Figure 1.97
y y
Since y = bx and y = logb x are inverse functions, the graph of either one of these
families of curves (or of one particular curve for some specified value of b) can be
obtained from the graph of the other geometrically by reflection about the line y — x.
(Recall that reflection of a curve about a line consists of obtaining the curve that is
symmetric to the given curve with respect to the line; see Figure 1.96.)
A more general form for logarithmic functions is
y = ,4 1n(l + x) + # x> —1
The curve representing the function y = A In (1 + x) -I- B lies to the right of and is
asymptotic to the line x = — 1; the curve is monotonically increasing if A > 0 and
monotonically decreasing if A < 0. It has x-intercept (e~B/A — 1, 0) and y-intercept
(0, B); see Figure 1.97. (The x-intercept is obtained in Technical Note V.)
PROBLEMS
1. For what ranges of x are the following curves defined?
a. y = In (x + 1) c. y = In (x3 + 27)
b. y — In (x — 4) d. y — In (x4 — 16)
2. Sketch on the same set of axes the curves represented by the equations
a. y = 2X c. y = 2x/1
b. y = 2~x d. y = 2lx
3. Sketch on the same set of axes the curves represented by y = ax for a = 2, e, 3, and 10.
4. Sketch on the same set of axes the curves represented by y = logaX for a — 2, e, 3, and 10.
5. Sketch on the same set of axes the curves represented by the equations
a. y = 3* b. y = log3x
6. For what ranges of x are the following curves defined?
a. v = i In (1 — x2) d. y = —3 — 6 In (x — 2)
b. y = In (36 — x2) e. y = In (x — 27)
c. y — In (x2 — 36)
As can be noted in Figures 1.94 and 1.97, several types of exponential and logarith¬
mic functions are appropriate for representing demand or supply curves. Exponential
cost functions, representing total cost as an exponential function of number of units
produced, are also frequently used. Many examples of these uses of exponential and
logarithmic curves appear in later sections. The applications discussed in this section
are compound interest and various types of growth functions, problems for which
exponential and logarithmic functions are uniquely appropriate. A table of exponen¬
tial functions and a table of logarithms are provided at the end of the book.
118 / Graphical Representation
COMPOUND INTEREST
If the interest rate is 100* percent per year payable (that is, compounded) k times per
year, an amount of money x (the principal) becomes after n years
y = x(l + i)
(when k is large, y « xein, where e « 2.718 is the base of the natural logarithms).
This formula can be developed as follows: If the interest at rate 100* percent is
payable yearly, then the amount (principal plus interest) at the end of the first year
is
yt = x + ix — x(l + *)
y„ = x(\ + if
If interest is payable k times per year, then the rate of interest in any one period is
100(i/k) percent and the number of periods is nk. Thus the amount after n years is
EXAMPLE
A man deposits $5000 at 4% interest. How much has he (principal plus interest) after 10 years
(a) if interest is payable yearly, and (b) if interest is payable quarterly?
= 5000(1 + 0.04)10
= 3.6990 + (10)(0.0170)
= 3.8690
y = $7396.67
nk
y = x 1 +
40
0.04
= 5000 1 +
= 3.6990 + 40(0.0043)
= 3.8710
y = $7430.00
1.9 Applications of Exponential and Logarithmic Curves / 119
GROWTH FUNCTIONS
There are many relationships in business and economics which are appropriately
represented by curves referred to as growth functions, for example, number of em¬
ployees as a function of annual sales of a company, amount of finished stock as a
function of days after beginning a production run, sales as a function of advertising
expenditure, maintenance cost as a function of number of hours a machine is run,
and sales as a function of length of time a product has been on the market can be
represented by growth functions.
The basic property of the various curves referred to as growth functions is that
they are monotonically increasing. Growth functions may or may not have an upper
asymptote (although usually for business and economic applications absence of an
upper asymptote is reasonable only when relatively short periods of time are con¬
sidered) and they may be of various shapes. Three particular types of growth func¬
tions are discussed below: (1) very simple functions originally developed to describe
certain types of biological growth and appropriate only for growth that does not
have an upper asymptote, (2) Gompertz functions used to describe growth that starts
rather slowly and approaches an upper asymptote, and (3) learning functions orig¬
inally used by psychologists to describe human learning and appropriate for growth
that begins rapidly, levels off, and approaches an asymptote.
N = N0Rt
Figure 1.98
N
120 / Graphical Representation
EXAMPLE
The National Aerospace Research Organization is beginning its operations with a staff of 5
men. At the end of each year of its operation, each employee will hire 3 assistants. How many
employees will National Aerospace Research Organization have after 10 years of operation?
N = N0R{
= (5)(410)
= 5,242,880 employees after 10 years
Gompertz Curves
Gompertz curves, named for their originator, are represented by the equation
N = caR'
where N is the number of individuals in the population at time t,R(0<R < 1) is the
rate of growth, a is the proportion of initial growth, and c is the growth at maturity
(that is, the upper asymptote). Note that when t = 0, N = ca, which corresponds to
N0 of the biological growth function.
The two basic types of Gompertz curves are characterized as follows and il¬
lustrated in Figure 1.99:
Curves of Type I are positively accelerated for small positive t and negatively ac¬
celerated for large positive t; curves of type II are negatively accelerated for all
positive t. The mathematical definitions of positive and negative acceleration are
discussed later; essentially, a positively accelerated curve is increasing at an increas¬
ing rate and a negatively accelerated curve is increasing at a decreasing rate.
Gompertz curves have been used extensively by psychologists to describe various
aspects of human growth and development, including some types of learning. Organ¬
ization theorists have found Gompertz curves appropriate for describing the growth
1.9 Applications of Exponential and Logarithmic Curves / 121
Figure 1.99
of many types of organizations. These curves are also appropriate for many other
functions in business and economics, for example, total revenue and production
functions.
EXAMPLE
On the basis of expected sales and data for similar companies, the Personnel Director of
National Industries predicts that the number of employees can be described by the equation
N = 200(0.04f5'
where N is the number of employees after t years. Assuming he is correct, how many em¬
ployees will National Industries have after 3 years? How many employees did the company
employ initially? How many will it employ when it reaches its maximum size?
The company employs (200)(0.04) = 8 people initially and 200 at maximum size. After 3
years it employs
N = (200)(0.04)°53
= 2.3010 + (0.125)(-1.3979)
= 2.1263
Learning Curves
Because of their extensive use by psychologists to describe learning, exponential
curves of the form
y = c — ae~kx
where c, a, and k are positive, are frequently referred to as learning curves. [Note that
this is case (f) of the general form y = aekx + c discussed previously.] In his reinforce¬
ment theory of learning, Clark Hull used the special case c — a of this function as one
of the basic equations for describing the relationship between strength of learning y
and number of reinforcements x.
122 / Graphical Representation
The function y = c — ae~kx rises rapidly at first, flattens out, and then approaches
its asymptote y — c (see Figure 1.100). These curves have been found to be appro¬
priate for representing various cost and production functions.
EXAMPLE
If the number of items y manufactured per day x days after the beginning of a production run
is given by
y = 200(1 -e-°Ax)
how many items are manufactured per day 10 days after beginning the run and what per cent
of the maximum is this?
y = 200(1 - e-1)
= 200(1 -0.368)
= 200(0.632)
EXAMPLE
If the yearly maintenance cost y of a computer is related to its average monthly use x (in
hundreds of hours) by the equation
y = 35,000 - 25,000e-oo2x
what is the yearly maintenance cost for 200 hours average monthly use?
y 35,000 - 25,000c-0'04
= 35,000 - 25,000(0.135)
35,000 - 3375
PROBLEMS
1. Chem Corporation has $10,000 to deposit and expects to leave the deposit for 20 years.
Two options are available: 5% interest payable semiannually and 4\% interest payable
quarterly. Which option should Chem Corporation choose?
2. In order to have $20,000 after 20 years at 6% interest payable yearly, how much must be
deposited?
3. The National Professional Society has been formed with 10 original members. The rules
state that each member may invite 2 people to join at the beginning of each year. If each
member always takes advantage of this rule, how many members will the society have after
15 years?
4. Monthly total revenue (in dollars) for a particular firm can be described by the equation
R = 1000(0.10)° 8p
where p is the amount spent for promotion and advertising. What is total revenue when
nothing is spent for promotion and advertising? What is the maximum attainable total
revenue? What is total revenue if $20 is spent for promotion and advertising?
5. Production costs (in hundreds of dollars) for a firm are described by the equation
where x is the number of units of output. What are the firm’s fixed costs? When output is
100 units, what proportion of the production costs are fixed?
6. One job on a production line consists of screwing a small screw into a metal plate. For a
typical employee, the number of plates completed per hour is described by the equation
y = 50 — 40c~°‘30jc
where x is number of hours the employee has worked on the production line. a. How many
plates can an employee complete the first hour? b. How many the sixth hour?
7. The number of firms in a particular industry is described by the equation
N = 6(0.5)°75'
where t is the number of years since the industry began. How many firms were there in the
industry after 5 years? How many firms were in the industry originally? How many firms
will there be when the industry reaches maximum size?
8. In order to have $10,000 after $6,000 has been deposited for 25 years with interest payable
yearly, what interest rate must be paid?
9. For a 10-year deposit, what interest rate payable annually is equivalent to 5% interest
payable quarterly?
10. For a 25-year deposit, what interest payable semiannually is equivalent to 4% payable
quarterly?
Figure 1.101
x
r
n radians = 180°
Thus
1 radian
Figure 1.102
6 = 1 radian
1.10 Trigonometric Curves / 125
EXAMPLE
200tt 1071
200 ° —— radians = — radians
3571 In
-35° — ~~~ radians = — — radians
180 36
3007c 571
300° -radians = radians
180 3
TRIGONOMETRIC FUNCTIONS
The trigonometric functions of an angle 9 are the sine of 9 (sin 9), the cosine of 9
(cos 9), the tangent of 9 (tan 6), the cosecant of 6 (esc 0), the secant of 6 (sec 9\ and
the cotangent of 6 (cot 0). When the angle 6 is at the center of a circle of radius r and
is measured counterclockwise, as in Figure 1.103, the trigonometric functions of 6 are
defined by the equations
a b a
sin 9 = cos 9 = tan 9 =
r r b
r b
esc 9 = — sec 9 = cot 9 =
a b a
Note that
+ + —
+ —
+
— — —
+ + —
Figure 1.103
y
126 / Graphical Representation
The values of the trigonometric functions can be obtained geometrically for some
commonly used angles. For example, if 9 = 45° = n/4 radians, b = a and, using the
Pythagorean theorem, r2 — a2 + b2 and r — a-sjl, as shown below.
Thus
sin 6 =
a = sft
cos 0 =
a
A2 tan 8 = - = 1
a^fl 2 aj2 a
Thus
a u a
sin 0 = - = 1 cos 6 = - = 0 tan 9 = - not defined
a a 0
Values of the sine, cosine and tangent are given for some commonly used angles in
the table below. These values can all be obtained geometrically.
71 n n n 3n
Radians 0 n 2n
6 4 3 2 T
Sine 0
1 V~2 75 1 0 -l 0
2 2 2
73 ■J~2 1
Cosine 1 0 -1 0 1
2 2 2
V3 not not
Tangent 0 1 73 0 0
3 defined defined
The graphs of the sine, cosine, and tangent functions are given in Figure 1.104.
Note that the function sin x is defined and continuous for all values of x. Sin x is a
periodic function with the period 2n, since sin (x + 2n) = sin x for any x, that is,
when the value of x is increased by 2n, the value of y is unchanged. The function cos x
1.10 Trigonometric Curves / 127
Figure 1.104
is also defined and continuous for all values of x and is periodic with period In. The
graph of y — cos x can be obtained from the graph of y = sin x by taking the line
x = n/2 as the y-axis; that is, the graph of y = cos x is the same as the graph of
y — sin x when that graph is shifted to the right by n/l radians. The function tan x is
discontinuous for all values of x such that x = (n + j)n, where n is any positive or
negative integer; tan x is periodic with period n.
128 / Graphical Representation
The symmetry and periodicity of the sine, cosine, and tangent functions make it
possible to obtain a trigonometric function of any angle, 0 < 6 < 2n, from the trigon¬
ometric function of an angle 6 such that 0 < 6 < 7i/2. Thus trigonometric functions
are tabled only for angles between 0 and jc/2. The formulas for reducing angles are
given below. Note, for example, that sin ( — 6)= —sin 6, cos ( — 6) — cos 6,
tan ( — 9) = —tan 6, and so forth.
EXAMPLE
Find the value of each of the following trigonometric functions: cos 3n/4, tan 57i/6, sin 5n/3,
sec ln/6, esc 2n/3, cot ( — n/4).
2n In n\ n_ yj2
cos — = cos - + - = —sin
4 2 4
5n I n\ n V3
tan — = tan I n — -1 =
6~~ 3
5n . I n . n 0
sin — = sin I in — - - sin - = -
3 2
In / n' 71 1 _ 2/3
sec — = sec \ n + sec - =
6 \ 6 6 n
cos -
6
271 / n\ n _ 1 _ 2^3
CSC — = CSC I 71 — I = CSC „
3 3/ 3 n
sin
7T n
cot — cot 7 = -1
4 n
tan
1.10 Trigonometric Curves / 129
TRIGONOMETRIC IDENTITIES
There are a number of trigonometric identities which are useful in simplifying results
involving trigonometric functions. Some of the more commonly used identities are
given below without proof; additional identities and proofs can be found in any
trigonometry book.
2 tan x
sin 2x = 2 sin x cos x cos 2x = cos2 x — sin2 x tan 2x =
1 — tan2 x
1 — cos x x / 1 + cos x
sin — = + cos - = +
2 V1 2 2 ~
X 1 1 — COS X
tan - = 4-
2 yj 1 + cos x
POLAR COORDINATES
It is frequently more convenient to describe a point by its polar coordinates rather
than by its rectangular coordinates. If a point is described by the rectangular coor¬
dinates (x, y), then it can also be described by the polar coordinates (r, 6) as follows.
Consider a line drawn between the point and a given origin; the angle 6 which this
line makes with the horizontal axis and the distance r between the point and the
origin determine the point, as shown in Figure 1.105.
Note that the polar coordinates of a point are not unique. For example, the polar
coordinates (r, 6), (r, 6 + 2n), and (r, 6 — 2n) all represent the same point. In prac¬
tice, the polar coordinates of a point are usually written using the angle between 0
and 2n.
Figure 1.105
130 / Graphical Representation
The rectangular coordinates (x, y) and the polar coordinates (r, 6) of a point are
related as follows:
• a y wO
a
H —
x
-
/-s s- tan 6 — —
X
7x + y 7*2 + /
These relations are used to change from one system of coordinates to the other.
EXAMPLE
Find polar coordinates for the following points given in rectangular coordinates,
r = 7*2 + y1 = 70 + 2 = 72
so
n
9 =
K'
Polar coordinates (r, 0) = ,
r = Vx2 + y2 = V1 + 1 = sfi
_ j_ = 72
cos 9 = and sin 9 = J_ = v7
72 2 T2 2
so
n
9 =
n'
Polar coordinates (r, 9) = J2,
EXAMPLE
Find rectangular coordinates for the following points given in polar coordinates
1.10 Trigonometric Curves / 131
(a) M)
r cos 9 (3)(0) = o
r sin 9 (3)(1) = 3
(x, y) (0, 3)
(b) M)
r cos 9
4 4
^>( ) -
r sin 9
4 -
(*> y) (44 - )
EXAMPLE
Find the equation in rectangular coordinates of the curve whose equation in polar coordinates
is r = 4/(1 + 2 cos 9).
y** 1 2 + y
y'x2 + y2 + 2x 4
4 - 2x
EXAMPLE
Find the equation in polar coordinates of the curve whose equation in rectangular coordinates
is Ax + By + C = 0.
Ar cos 9 4- Br sin 9 + C = 0
PROBLEMS
1. Find the number of radians in each of the following angles given in degrees.
a. 9 = -240° d.9 = -40°
b. 9 = 70° e. 9 = -100°
c. 9 = 120° f.9 = 315°
In , 47T
a. sin — b. esc —
6 3
132 / Graphical Representation
5n 5n
c. tan d. cos
4 T
3. Obtain polar coordinates for the following points given in rectangular coordinates.
a. (1, 73) c. (3, 3,/3)
b. (-1, -1) d. (-1,0)
4. Obtain rectangular coordinates for the following points given in polar coordinates.
b. ( — 2, n)
Obtain the equation in rectangular coordinates that corresponds to each of the following
equations given in polar coordinates.
5. r = 5 12. r = a sec 9
6. r = sin 9 + cos 9 13. r2 = a2 cot 9
14. r — tan 9 sec 9
7. r = —-- —-
2 — cos 9 15. r3 = a3 esc 9
8. r = 1 + cos 9 16. r = a tan2 9
9. r = a cos 9 17. r2 = 9
10. r = a sin 0
18. 9 = ^
11. r = 9 2
Obtain the equation in polar coordinates that corresponds to each of the following equa¬
tions given in rectangular coordinates.
4tc
1. a. s = —
T
In
b. s =
18
2n d. (1, n)
c. s —
5. x2 + y2 = 25
2n 7. 3x2 + 4 y2 — 4x — 4 = 0
d. s =
9 9. x2 + y2 — ax = 0
11. y = x tan (^/x2 + y2)
5n
—
13. y3 4- x2}; — a2x = 0
9
15. x2y -I- y3 = a3
In 17. y = x tan (x2 -f y2)
f. s —
4 19. r = 4a cot 9 esc 9
21. r = cos 9 + sin 9
3. a. 2, *) 23. r — a cot2 9 esc 9
V 25. r2 = \a2 sec 9 esc 9
27. r3 = a sec 9 esc2 9
1.11 Applications of Trigonometric Curves in Business and Economics / 133
_ C2 — B2 C1 _ A2Ci Al C 2
A1B2 ~ A2Bl A±B2 ^2^1
provided At B2 — A2 Bl ^ 0.
Thus if the nonvertical demand and supply curves
y = mDx + bD y = msx + bs
(where the subscripts D and S distinguish demand and supply curves) are written
mDx — y + bD = 0 msx — y + bs = 0
bD ~ bs bDms - bsmD
x =- y —-
ms -mD ms mD —
bn b<? . , .
<— (since mD < 0)
mD ms
mD ms
which is the second condition stated for equilibrium in the first quadrant, since the
x-coordinate of the x-intercept of the line y = mx + b is —(b/m).
Table 1.1
In this table,
I= A + C
B2
C = AC-
4
E2 D2 B2
J = AC + CF + AF-
4 4 4
In many cases it can be assumed (owing to the nature of the application) that the
given equation represents a proper conic (that is, D ± 0) and a real locus (that is, /
and D opposite in sign if C > 0). In such cases it is necessary only to compute C and
note the coefficients A, C, and B in order to determine which type of conic section is
represented by the equation.
a \ x + - x I = — cy — d
a
a | x 2 -I- —
^x T
= — cy — d +
a 4a2 4a
b^2 cl d b4
x + - y H-—
2a > a\ c 4ac,
EXAMPLE
3x2 + 4x + 2y — 4 — 0
3(xz + I* + %) = — 2y + 4 + 3
(X + |)2 = -2(3; _ 8)
If ax2 + by2 + cx + dy + e = 0, then the terms to be included in the perfect squares are
ax2, cx, by2, and dy; thus
2 c c2 \
. / 2 ^ c2 d2
a x + -x + —c + -—f —
\ a 4? +T +by + 4p 4a 4b
dL
x + y+
2a, 2b; c2 d2
+ = 1/ +
a ab\4a + 4b 4 a2b 4 ab2 ab
EXAMPLE
3x2 + 4y2 - 6x + ly - 10 = 0
(* — l)2 ,
4-1-^- = TZ(ld +
{y + i)2 1 /17 I 49 \
TB) -
257
T9I
The essential aspect of the process of completing the square is the addition of the appro¬
priate constant terms so that groups of terms form perfect squares; the most convenient form
of writing the constant coefficients depends on the particular problem.
A second-degree equation can be put into the appropriate standard form for the type of
conic it represents by the process of completing the square.
136 / Graphical Representation
The circle:
Ax2 4- Ay2 4- Dx + Ey + F = 0
D D2 E2 r
a(x2 4- ^x +
4A 2j + ^( y +Ay + 4 A2 4A + 4 A
D Ex2 D2 E2 F
+
X + 2A +\y + 2A, 4 A4 4A2 ~ A
D D4 E2 F
h = - k = — r2 = +
2A " 2A 4 A2 4A2 A
D D2 \ J , E E2 D2 E2 ^
A\x +—X + — ]+C\y +~y + 2 — T — — f
4 A4 C 40 4A 4C
D2 E2
Denoting — + — - F by k,
D
x + y + 2C\
2A,
+ = 1
k k
A C
(x - h)2 , (y - k)2
+ = 1
a
where
D
h = - k = -
2A 2C
. Dx+
A4 x22 + —
4A 2) \y + E 4AEi
D D4 4 AF]
x +
2A. 4AE
D D2 - 4AF
h = - k = 4P = ~
2A 4AE A
., 2 D D2 \ / - E E2 D2 E2
— _(_ — —
Aix +AX + 4A2 + CV +Cy + 4C~2 4A 4C
^ D2 E2
Denoting — + — - F by k.
D
x + y + 2C,
2A
+ = 1
k k
A C
1.11 Applications of Trigonometric Curves in Business and Economics / 137
(x - h)2 (y - k)2
a2 b2
or
(y - k)2 (x - h)2
b2 a2
E
2C
ax2 + bx + c = 0
bx b2
a\x -K — ~C + ~T~
a 4 a2 4a
b'2 b2 — 4ac
x +
2a, 4a2
b b2 — 4ac
= +
X + Ta 4 a2
— b± ^/b2 — 4ac
2a
ae = —c
Note in Figure 1.94 that only cases (c), (d), (e), and (f) have x-intercepts and that
1
In — > 0 if a > 0, c < 0, k < 0, a > I c [case (d)]
a,
or
1
k
In j < 0 if a > 0, c<0, k > 0, a > | c [case (c)]
or
In (1 + x) = — —
A
e-WA)= 1 + x
x= e~{B,A) — 1
and
Thus
e~(BIA) _ j >Q
if
e~(B,A) - 1 <0
if
2.1 Introduction
Calculus is concerned with the mathematical analysis of change or movement. Be¬
cause everything in the world changes, calculus has applications in virtually all areas
of scientific inquiry. It is nearly impossible to exaggerate the importance of calculus,
particularly differential calculus, as a basis for mathematical analysis.
As a distinctly new mathematical method, calculus was developed in the seven¬
teenth century by Sir Isaac Newton and Gottfried Leibnitz, working independently.
For Newton, calculus originated in attempts to solve certain problems connected
with his work in physics and astronomy: finding the velocity of a moving body, the
work done by force, the center of mass of a body. For Leibnitz, calculus originated in
attempts to solve certain problems in geometry: finding the tangent to a curve, the
length of a portion of a curve, the area bounded by one or more curves, the volume of
a solid.
The basic operations of calculus are differentiation and integration; these opera¬
tions are the inverses of each other, as are addition and subtraction, and multiplica¬
tion and division. Differentiation is concerned essentially with determining the rate
of change of a given function. Integration is concerned essentially with the inverse
problem of finding a function when its rate of change is given.
The analogy of a moving-picture film is frequently used in discussing the processes
of differentiation and integration. A moving-picture film is a series of (static) pictures,
each at least slightly different from the others;each frame depicts the subjects in given
positions at a particular instant of time. When the film is run through a projector at
proper speed, the pictures are summed up and the illusion of motion is created.
Similarly, differentiation essentially breaks up a function into many infinitesimally
small (static) pieces and thus analyzes it at a particular point of time or for a
particular value of the independent variable; integration, on the other hand, sums up
the infinitesimally small pieces to obtain the function.
When relations among variables are stated in equations, calculus can be used to
analyze these relations. Calculus has been used by physicists, astronomers, chemists,
and engineers almost since its development; more recently, calculus has also been
used by biologists, sociologists, psychologists, and economists.
Since analysis in business and economics is frequently concerned with change,
139
140 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
calculus is an extremely valuable tool for these problems. Marginal analysis is per¬
haps the most direct application of calculus in business and economics; marginal rate
of change or variation on the margin is expressed analytically as the first derivative of
the relevant function. Differential calculus is also the method by which maxima or
minima of functions are obtained. Thus problems of maximizing profit or minimizing
cost under various assumptions can be solved using calculus. Mathematical
programming, which is concerned with maximizing or minimizing a function subject
to constraints, is applied increasingly in business and economics; the methods used
in mathematical programming are based on differential calculus.
The idea of the rate of change of a function, which is the basis of differential
calculus, is discussed in the following paragraphs. The applications of this concept to
marginal analysis and to various problems of maximization and minimization are
discussed in some detail in following chapters.
The simplest type of functional relationship between two variables is represented
by a straight line and corresponds to a constant, or uniform, rate of change in the
dependent variable with respect to change in the independent variable. A variable
rate of change in the dependent variable with respect to change in the independent
variable is represented by a curvilinear (or nonlinear) function. The average variable
rate of change is the average value over an interval of the variable rate of change.
For many analyses the most important concept is that of instantaneous rate of
change, that is, the variable rate of change at a particular instant of time or for a
particular value of the independent variable. Instantaneous rate of change is ob¬
tained by differentiation and is the first derivative of the function evaluated at the
point of interest. The concept of instantaneous change is the basis of marginal
analysis in economics; marginal analysis considers the effect on the dependent var¬
iable of small changes in the independent variable, that is, variation on the margin.
The mathematical definition and derivation of instantaneous or marginal rate of
change are discussed in detail later; the concept can perhaps best be understood
intuitively in terms of an example of physical movement. If a car is driven from city A
to city B at a constant speed, then the rate of change in its distance from city A is
constant with respect to change in time since leaving city A; the car is traveling at a
constant or uniform rate. However, if the car occasionally slows down for curves,
towns, traffic, and so forth, it travels at a variable rate. Suppose the trip from city A to
city B takes 5 hours; the number of miles traveled each hour could be averaged to
obtain the average variable rate of travel per hour. There is clearly another rate of
travel of interest to both drivers and traffic policemen—the rate of travel at a particu¬
lar instant of time. It is this instantaneous rate that is obtained by differential
calculus.
Although rate of change is perhaps most readily understood in terms of physical
motion, it can be generalized to any type of functional relationship. For example,
total cost is a function of the quantity produced and usually changes at a variable
rate as the quantity produced changes. The rate of change of total cost as quantity
produced changes is the marginal cost and is the first derivative of total cost; mar¬
ginal cost is a function of the quantity produced and can be evaluated for any
quantity of interest.
The first derivative, that is, the rate of change of a function, can be used to
determine its maximum and minimum points, if any. A function increases (positive
rate of change) until it reaches a maximum and then decreases (negative rate of
change); similarly, a function decreases until it reaches a minimum and then
increases. This basic method for determining the maxima and minima of a function
by differentiation has been developed and generalized for use in problems of
varying complexity; as noted above, it is the basis of the methods of mathematical
programming.
2.2 Limits / 141
2.2 Limits
DEFINITION OF A LIMIT
Consider a function f(x) and let the independent variable x assume values near a
given constant a; then the function f(x) assumes a corresponding set of values.
Suppose that when x is close to u, the corresponding values of/(x) are close to some
constant A. Moreover, suppose that the values of/(x) can be made to differ arbi¬
trarily little from A by taking values of x that are sufficiently close to a, but not equal
to a and that this is true for all such values of x. Then /(x) is said to approach the
limit A as x approaches a. More concisely, the definitions of the limit of a variable
and the limit of a function are as follows.
A variable x is said to approach a constant a as a limit when x varies in such a way
that the absolute difference | x — a | becomes and remains less than any preassigned
positive number, however small this number is chosen. This is indicated by the
notation
lim x = a or x —> a
142 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
1 3 7 15 2" - 1
2’ 4’ 8’ 16’ 2" ’
1 3 7 15 2" - 1
2’ 4’ 8’ 16’ ■’ 1 ' 2"
EXAMPLE
/(1) = 7 /(-1) = 3
fii) = 6 f(~i) = 4
/(i) = 5t /(—i) = 4i
49
/(tto) = 5yts /(—tot) = 4TU
1 1499
/(Wot) = 5-jot /( two) =
etc. etc.
The following two statements of the definition of the limit of a function are
equivalent to the definition given above.
It is implied in the above discussion of limits that both x and/(x) approach finite
constants (a and A, respectively) as limits. It is also possible, however, for either one
or both of x and f(x) to become arbitrarily large or arbitrarily small. These types of
limiting behavior are defined as follows:
EXAMPLE
/(i) = o
/(5)=l
/(20) = %
/(100) = -nni
/(1000) = «
/(10,000) = «
etc.
Similarly, the limit off(x) may be defined when x becomes negatively infinite, that
is, decreases without limit. This is indicated by the notation
EXAMPLE
lim /(x) = 1
X~+ 00
If a function f(x) is greater than an arbitrarily large positive number for all values
of x that are sufficiently near a constant a and for which x a, then f(x) is said to
become positively infinite (that is, increases without limit) as x approaches a. This is
indicated by the notation
Similarly,/(x) becomes negatively infinite (that is, decreases without limit) when it
assumes numerically large negative values. This is indicated by the notation
EXAMPLE
lim f(x)— oo
x-2
144 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
If a function /(x) is greater than an arbitrarily large positive number for all
positive values of x that are sufficiently large, then f(x) is said to become positively
infinite (that is, increases without limit) as x becomes positively infinite (that is,
increases without limit). This is indicated by the notation
EXAMPLE
Iff(x) = x4 — 4, then
EXAMPLE
If/(x) = x3 — 8, then
In some cases a function may approach either of two different limits, depending on
whether the variable approaches its limit through values larger or smaller than that
limit; in such a case, the limit is not defined (does not exist) but the right-hand and
left-hand limits exist.
The right-hand limit of a function is the value the function approaches when the
variable approaches its limit through decreasing values (that is, from the right); this
type of limiting behavior is indicated by the notation
The left-hand limit of a function is the value the function approaches when the
variable approaches its limit through increasing values (that is, from the left); this is
indicated by the notation
Thus the limit of a function exists if and only if its right-hand and left-hand limits
exist and are identical; in that case
EXAMPLE
fit)
8
7
6
5
4 l
3
fit) = [t]
2
1
t
EXAMPLE_=============
m
146 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Thus limt_0 f(t) is not defined; as t approaches 0 from above,/(r) becomes positively
infinite; as t approaches 0 from below,/(f) becomes negatively infinite.
It is also possible that even right-hand and left-hand limits do not exist; this is the
case, for example, for the sine and cosine functions which are oscillatory in nature.
PROPERTIES OF LIMITS
The following properties of limits are useful in evaluating the limit of a function.
1. lim K = K.
x~*a
That is, the limit of a constant is equal to that constant. For purposes of interpreting
the following properties of limits, a constant may be thought of as a special type of
function—that is, a function that assumes only one value. Thus the following state¬
ments are valid (as special cases) if some or all of the functions are constants.
That is, the limit of the sum (or difference) of two functions is equal to the sum (or
difference) of their limits.
note: This rule applies to the sum or difference of any finite number of func¬
tions, that is, if limx^a f{(x) = a{ for i = 1, 2, ..., n, then
lim ( £ Mx)\
x -* a \ i = 1 /
= 2 lim j\(x) =
( = 1 x~* a
£ a,
i= 1
That is, the limit of the product of two functions is equal to the product of their
limits.
note: This rule applies to the product of any finite number of functions, that is,
=
if lim*^ f^x) = at for i 1, 2, ..., n, then
Um ( fl fi(x)\ = fl lim
x -* a \ i — 1 / i= 1 jc -► a
f\(x) = f] ^
i= 1
fix) lim/(x) b
4. lim ') { = ——- = if c ^ 0.
x-a g(x) lim g(x) c
x-+a
That is, the limit of the quotient of two functions is equal to the quotient of their
limits, provided the limit of the divisor is not zero.
That is, the limit of the nth power of any function is equal to the nth power of the
limit of the function. (This follows from rule 3 applied to the product of n equal
factors.)
That is, the limit of the principal nth root of a positive function is equal to the
principal nth root of the limit of that function. (This follows from rule 4.)
EXAMPLE
= 6 + 5 (rules 3, 1)
= 11
EXAMPLE
/ X2 | -i
lim I - (rule 4)
x-- 1 \x2 + a)1 lim |(x2 + a)
lim x
u->- 1
(rules 5, 2)
lim x) +1 lim a
\x~* — 1 / \x-+-l
1
(rule 1)
1 + (3
EXAMPLE
1/3
= 10(27)1/3 (rules 1, 2, 5)
= 30
EXAMPLE
lim (x2 + a)
'x2 + a] x->0
lim (rule 4)
x-»0 >x2 + b, lim (x2 + b)
x-+0
a
(rules 2, 1, 5)
b
EXAMPLE
lim a
X-> 00
lim (rules 4, 2, 4)
X-* 00 lim 1
X~> 00
lim 1 +
x-* 00 lim X
X~* 00
a
1 + 0 (rule 1)
= a
148 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
lim 2
lim lim b - _^.- ~c0_ (rules 2, 4)
X-* - 00 3x + 10J -*-» lim (3x + 10)
= b - 0 (rules 1, 2, 3)
= b
In applying rule 4 concerning the limit of a quotient, it may happen that the
quotient of the limits takes the form 0/0. This is one of the indeterminate forms
discussed in some detail in a later section; however, it is frequently possible to obtain
a determinate limit for the original quotient if a very simple procedure is used. This
procedure consists of dividing both the numerator and the denominator by an ex¬
pression which in the limit is equal to zero, thereby obtaining an expression having a
limit.
EXAMPLE
Iff(x) = (x2 — 4)/(x - 2), then limx^2 /(*) is the indeterminate form 0/0. But if x £ 2, both
numerator and denominator can be divided by x — 2. Then /(x) = (x2 — 4)/(x — 2) = x + 2
and limx_+2 f(x) = 4.
Recall that in evaluating limx^2 /(*), it is not the value of/(x) at x = 2 but only the values
of/(x) for x close to 2 which are of interest. It is assumed that x becomes arbitrarily close to 2,
but does not equal 2. For x =/= 2,/(x) = x + 2 and limx^2 /(x) = limx_>2 (x + 2) = 4. Thus,
even though/(x) is undefined at x = 2, it has the limit 4 as x -> 2.
EXAMPLE
If F(h) = [(2 + h)2 — 4\/h, then lim^o F(h) is the indeterminate form 0/0. However, for h =/=■ 0,
F(h) = (4 -I- 4h + h2 — 4)/h — (4h -F h2)/h = 4 + h and thus lim^_0 F(h) = 4.
A second type of indeterminate form that can arise as a result of applying rule 4 is
oo/oo. This is another of the indeterminate forms discussed in later sections; in this
case it is frequently possible to obtain a determinate limit for the original quotient if
both the numerator and denominator are divided by the highest power of the var¬
iable which appears in the denominator.
EXAMPLE
/(x) = (2x3 + x2 - 3)/(x3 + x + 2), then lim*^ /(x) is the indeterminate form oo/oo.
If
However, if both the numerator and denominator are divided by x3, then
2x3 -F x2 — 3
/M x3 + x + 2 i 1 2
1 + 2 -3
X X
EXAMPLE
If/(x) = [x + (l/x)]/(2x — (1/x)], then limX-+Xf(x) is the indeterminate form oo/oo. However, if
both the numerator and denominator are divided by x, then
1 1 1
x 4— 1 4—o
/(*) =
2x - 1 2 - *
X X
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following limits.
1. lim (t2 -f 6t 4- 5) 19. lim e r
t-> 2 f-> ao
/V 4- e
2. lim (x2 + 6x 4- 3) 20. lim L-
x->0 t->o \ 2
21. lim
3!'" (^) x-o \x + yj
4. lim (y — 3)2 '2X - 2 — x\
y--2 22. lim
x-*o \2JC 4- 2
5. lim (x3 — 3x 4- 5)
x-2 x-yy
23. lim
x\ x -I- 2' ro \* + ^
6. lim
x-+2 \ X + 1 x3 — 2x 4- 5'
24. lim
2 2x3 - 7
7. lim
x~>oo x2 + 1 ^x2 4- a2'
25. lim
x-ao \x3 4- a3
8. lim 1 +
x-0 X 1 x3 — 5x 4- 6\
26. lim
,2 x-o \*2 - 2x + 3/
9. lim
x-> - i \X +X+1 1
27. lim
X -> 00
1 + 21/xj
10. lim 4-
x 4- 1 1
X~+ OO \
28. lim
x~* — oo 1 + 21/A
31 - 5'
11. lim
t-»o \ f 4~ 2
29- (rrW
3r2 - 5t + 4^
12. lim
t~* oo \ t2 4- 2 /
3a(nW,
13. lim ax + h
/i-0
31. lim x3
x 2
14. lim 2~h
/i — o 32. limx-3
x-* 2
15. lim x-4
x->2
„ lax 4- 10'
33. lim
x~>a X
16. lim x4
x--2
(h + l)e~h
36. lim I 1 l7x 52. lim
1 + ellxl /i-0 h2 4- 1
42. lim
(el — e 2t — e3{2 n + <?1//r
58. lim -5-
r-0 10 h— - oo V ^ /
16
43. lim 59. lim
x—4 (x - 4)2 fc-2 \x 4- h
x2 — 16 ^2 - 6f 4- 8\
44. lim 60. lim
X- -4 (x^4p f-2 ^2 — 5r 4 6/
x2 - 16
45. lim 61. lim (£±*
x—4 (x 4 4)2 *-« \3/i + 2h6
-t
h~x + h;
46. lim I 62. lim , .,
x-0 ' *-o U + e 1 >
11. 5 a2 + 10
—7
33.
13. ax a
i
15. T5 35. 1
17. 0 37. 1
19. 0
21. -1 1
39.
23. 1 lOe
2.3 Continuity / 151
41. 6 57. 0
43. oo
45. 0 59. *
47. 1 X
49. 2 61. 0
51. 0 63. i
53. 1 65. 0
55. 0
2.3 Continuity
1. f(a) is defined.
2. lim f(x) exists.
note: When a limit is said to exist, this should be understood to mean that the
limit exists finitely. Possible confusion arises because, for example, the expression
limx^a A = oo is written; however, this does not mean that A approaches a number
designated by oo, but only that A becomes arbitrarily large as x approaches a. It
should be remembered that oo is not a number and should not be thought of as a
number, even though for convenience it is used as a number would be used in some
expressions.
A function f(x) is said to be continuous in (or on) an interval b < x < c (or
b < x < c) if it is continuous at every point of the interval.
A function that is not continuous at a point x = a is said to be discontinuous at
x = a.
From the definition of continuity, it follows that the graph of a function that is
continuous on an interval consists of an unbroken curve (that is, a curve that can be
drawn without raising the pen from the paper) over that interval. Continuity was
tacitly assumed for the curves discussed in the preceding sections concerning graphi¬
cal representation. In subsequent sections this assumption, which makes it possible
to sketch a curve by plotting relatively few points and drawing an unbroken curve
through them, will be justified for several (large) classes of curves.
TYPES OF DISCONTINUITIES
The three conditions that must be satisfied for a function to be continuous can be
violated in various ways, resulting in different types of discontinuities. In general,
three types of discontinuities occur.
152 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
It should be noted that a discrete function is defined only for a finite number of
values of x in any interval and is thus discontinuous at all other (infinitely many)
values of x in the interval. Since x assumes only discrete values, the concept of a limit
is not appropriate for discrete functions.
Geometrically, the curves representing functions having different types of discon¬
tinuities are quite different in appearance: The curve representing a function having
an infinite discontinuity at x = a approaches x = a as an asymptote; the curve re¬
presenting a function having a finite discontinuity at x = a has an abrupt jump or
step at x = a; the curve representing a function having a missing-point discontinuity
at x — a appears to be continuous, but the single point x = a is missing; the curve
representing a discrete function consists of discrete points and thus is not a curve in
the usual sense.
A missing-point discontinuity at x = a occurs because/(a) is not defined; this type
of discontinuity may be removed by defining
since all three conditions of the definition of a continuous function at x = a are then
satisfied. It is possible for a function to have more than one missing-point discontinu¬
ity; as long as the number of these discontinuities is finite, they may be removed by
the procedure described. Note that there is also the logical possibility (although a
practical example is difficult to find) that there is a discontinuity at x = a because
f(a), although defined, is not equal to limx^fl/(x). Such a discontinuity is not remov¬
able, since f(a) is already defined and cannot therefore be defined as equal to
lim*-.. /(4
Although missing-point discontinuities are removable, finite and infinite discon¬
tinuities are not removable. This is the case because the definition of a function is an
arbitrary set of rules; adding another rule to this set, provided it is compatible with
the others, is perfectly permissible, and this is all that is required to remove a
missing-point discontinuity. On the other hand, finite and infinite discontinuities
occur because the function in question does not approach a limit under the specified
conditions. A limit either exists or does not exist as a mathematical fact associated
with the nature of the function in question and cannot be defined into existence; thus
there is no way to remove a discontinuity resulting from the nonexistence of a limit.
EXAMPLE
The function f(x) = l/(x — 2)2 has an infinite discontinuity at x = 2, since f(x) oo as x -► 2
and/(2) is undefined. However, this function is continuous at all values of x other than x = 2
(see Figure 2.3).
2.3 Continuity / 153
Figure 2.3
fix)
EXAMPLE
The function f(x) = 4x/(4 — x2) has infinite discontinuities at x = ±2, since f(x)-> oo as
x -*• 2 /(x) -> — oo as x->2 + ,/(x)->oo as x —► — 2~, and /(x) -► — oo as x —► — 2 + , and
/(+ 2) and/(— 2) are undefined. However, this function is continuous for all values of x other
than x = ±2 (see Figure 2.4).
154 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
The function /(x) = 1/(1 + 21/x) has a finite discontinuity (that is, a “jump”) at x = 0, since
lim^o /(x) is undefined. However, this function is continuous at all values of x other than
x = 0 (see Figure 2.5).
Figure 2.5
fix)
EXAMPLE
The function /(x) = (x3 — 2x2 — 3x + 6)/(x — 2) is undefined and is thus discontinuous for
x = 2. However, for x ^ 2,
then f(x) is continuous for all x and its graph is the parabola
y = x2 - 3
Figure 2.6
2.3 Continuity / 155
EXAMPLE
The function /(x) = (x2 — 9)/(x + 3) is undefined and is thus discontinuous for x = — 3.
However, for x ^ — 3,
x2 — 9
■^> 7TT= = *-3
then/(x) is continuous for all x and its graph is the straight line
y= x —3
(see Figure 2.7).
Figure 2.7
Many functions in business and economics are discrete or have finite discontinui¬
ties of the step-function type. For example, price and cost functions are frequently
discrete because of the nature of the commodity involved or have discontinuities
because cost and price per unit decrease (or increase) abruptly for particular quanti¬
ties. Supply and demand functions and many other economic functions are also
frequently discrete because of the nature of the commodity involved. It should be
noted that functions which are, in fact, discrete are frequently represented as contin¬
uous for convenience; this applies, for example, to the supply and demand functions
for commodities sold in units—such as refrigerators, eggs, light bulbs, chairs, lawn
mowers, cars, and so forth. Representation as continuous of a function which is by
nature discrete makes possible the use of many tools of analysis not otherwise
applicable. However, in interpreting the results of such analyses, the inherent
discreteness should not be forgotten—for example, it is inappropriate to discuss the
price of 1.632 refrigerators or the wages of 29.2 workers.
156 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
A wholesale grocer sells number 2 size cans of a certain vegetable in case lots according to the
following price schedule:
If y is total price and x is quantity in cases, the price function can be represented algebraically
as follows.
Figure 2.8
Note that, for this price function, total price is not a monotonic function of
quantity ordered. This makes certain orders unlikely. For example, the price of 17
cases is $42.50, while the price of 21 cases is only $42.00; thus an order of 17 cases
would probably be unlikely.
EXAMPLE
A company sells printed business stationery only in boxes of 200 sheets at $2.25 per box. If y is
total price and x is number of boxes, the price function can be represented algebraically by the
equation
Figure 2.9
y
C/5
I—
—
20.25 -
o
"O
15.75-
u
o
a 11.25 f—
cd
o
h* 6.75 h
2.25 - •
J L
12 3 4 5 6 7 8
Quantity (in boxes)
and geometrically by the graph in Figure 2.9. This function is discrete, since it is defined only
for integer values of x.
EXAMPLE
An oil refinery has 5 distillation towers and operates as many of them as needed to process the
raw materials available. The overhead cost of operating each distillation tower (operator,
maintenance, and so forth) is $100 per week; in addition, the cost of raw materials is $0.40 per
Figure 2.10
y
158 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
gallon of refined oil. Each distillation tower can process raw materials yielding 10,000 gallons
of refined oil per week. If y is the total cost of operation and x is the quantity of refined oil (in
gallons), the cost function can be represented algebraically by the equation
x
f(x) = 10o( + 1 + 0.4x
10,000
where [x/10,000] denotes the largest integer part of x/10,000. Note that 1 is added to [x/10,000]
because [x/10,000] distillation towers produce a maximum of 10,000x gallons. Thus for any
additional production, another distillation tower must be operated. The graph of the function
is shown in Figure 2.10. This function has finite discontinuities at x = 10,000, 20,000, 30,000,
and 40,000.
EXAMPLE
United States first-class postage is 10 cents per ounce or fraction of an ounce. If y is postage
required and x is letter weight (in ounces), the cost function can be represented by the equation
y = 0.10([x] + 1)
where [x] denotes the largest integer part of x. The graph of the function is shown in
Figure 2.11. This function has finite discontinuities at all integer values of x.
Figure 2.11
EXAMPLE
A stationery store sells Christmas cards for 10 cents each or $1.00 for a dozen. If y is price and
x is number of cards sold, the price function for a customer can be represented by the equation
X
y= + 0.10 for x = 1, 2, 3, ...
12
where [x/12] denotes the largest integer part of x/12. This function is discrete since it is defined
only for integer values of x; it is also nonmonotonic, as a result of discounting for larger
quantities purchased. (See Figure 2.12.)
2.3 Continuity / 159
Figure 2.12
y
Price (in dollars)
3.10
3.00
i
2.10
2.00 +*
1.10
1.00 *;•*
0.20
0.10 L X
11 12 23 24 35 36
Number of cards
PROBLEMS
For each of the following functions, determine the values of x for which the function is
discontinuous, identify the types of discontinuities, and give appropriate definitions for remov¬
ing any removable discontinuities.
3x + 5 x —2
i- /M = 2. /(x) =
x2 + 4x + 4 x 4- 1
160 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
x2 - 1 x2 + 2x — 8
3- f(x) 26. /(x)
x — 1 x 4 4 ~
x2 + 4 1
27. /(x) =
4- f(x) 3e3x - 3
x2 — x — 2
8. f(x) 10
V x - 1 31. /(x) =
e6x - 1
9. fix)
_(x ~ l)2_ x2 -I- x — 2
(x — l)(x2 — 4x + 5) 32. /(x) =
x2 + 27x -f 50
x2 — 2x x2 — 5x 4- 6
13. fix) 36. /(x) =
x3 — x2 + X (x — 2)(x2 — 2x — 3)
x2 — 5x 4- 6 2x2 + 3x
14. fix) 37. /(x) =
x — 2 x3 — 9x
x2 4- 1 1
15. f(x) 38. /(x) =
x3 — 4x 3ex - 3
4x ex -f 4x
16. fix) 39. /(x) =
4 — x2 3e4x -1
_1_
17. fix) x2 + 5x + 4
4x2 — 16 40. /(x) =
(x + 4)(x2 — 6x + 10)
x — 2
18. fix) x2 - 1
(x — 2)(x2 4- 2x + 10) 41. f(x) = for x ^ — 1
x 4- 1
1
19. fix) = —2 for x = — 1
e4x - 1
x — 2 Is/(x) continuous at x = —1?
20. fix)
(x — 2)(x2 + 2x — 3)
x2 4 3x 10 - —
The slope m of a straight line is defined as the tangent of its angle of inclination or,
equivalently, as the ratio of the change in vertical distance (rise) to the change in
horizontal distance (run) as a point moves along the line in either direction (see
Figure 2.13).
y2 - yi Ay
m = tan 6
X2 — Xj Ax
The slope of any given straight line is a constant—that is, the rate of change of y as
x changes is constant over the length of the line. However, for other curves the slope
is not constant and must be determined for each particular point of interest.
Suppose that (xls yx) and (x2, y2) are any two points on the curve y = /(x). Then
the slope of the line (called a secant) joining (x1? yj and (x2, y2) is
y2 - yi Ay
m sec
x2 — Ax
Figure 2.13
y
162 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Suppose now that the point (x1? y^ is held fixed while the point (x2, y2) is moved
along the curve y = f(x) toward the point (xl5 yt); as the point (x2, y2) is moved
along the curve f(x), the slope of the line joining (x1? yx) and (x2, y2) will, in general,
vary. However, it may happen, and does happen for most curves encountered in
practice, that as the point (x2, y2) moves closer and closer to the point (x1? yx), the
slope of the secant line varies by smaller and smaller amounts and, in fact,
approaches a constant limiting value. When this happens, the limiting value is said to
be the slope of the tangent to the curve at (xl9 yj or the slope of the curve at (xls yx)
[see Figure 2.14].
More concisely, if, as the point (x2, y2) approaches the point (xl9 yj along the
curve y = f(x), the slope of the secant line approaches a constant limiting value, then
this limiting value is said to be the slope of the tangent to the curve at (x1? yx) or,
briefly, the slope of the curve at (xl9 yj, or the slope of/(x) at (xl9 yx). That is,
Ay
lim msec lim = slope of/(x) at (xx, yx)
Ax-» 0 Ax->0 Ax
The slope of a function at a given point is the first derivative of the function at the
given point.
It is customary in defining the first derivative to use the notation (x, y) for the
stationary point (xls yx) and the notation (x + Ax, y + Ay) for the moving point
(x2, y2). Then
is the first derivative with respect to x of the function y = /(x). This limit may exist
for some values of x and fail to exist for other values of x. At each point (x, y) where
this limit does exist, the function y =/(x) is said to have a derivative or to be
dy
differentiable and — is said to be the first derivative or the derivative of y =/(x). The
Various types of notation, in addition to are used to denote the first derivative of
dx
y =/(x) with respect to x. The most common of these are
Figure 2.14
x
2.4 Definition of the First Derivative / 163
It should be noted that the first derivative of a function with respect to x is, in
general, another function of x which must be evaluated for particular values of
interest. This corresponds to the fact stated above that, except for straight lines,
curves do not in general have the same slope at different points.
From the definition of a derivative and the properties of limits, rules for obtaining
the derivatives of various types of functions can be obtained. These are given in a
later section. For illustration, the derivatives of several relatively simple functions are
obtained directly rather than by using the formulas.
The steps for obtaining a derivative directly are as follows:
1. Consider the function y =f(x).
2. Give increments to x and y to obtain
k + Ay =/(x + Ax)
3. Subtract to obtain
d-f = !im^= li
dx a*-»o Ax ajc-*o Ax
EXAMPLE
4(x + Ax) + 1 — 4x — 1
= lim
Ax->0 Ax
4 Ax
= lim —
Ax->0 Ax
= lim 4 = 4
Ax-*0
dy
Note that y = 4x + 1 represents a straight line and thus — is a constant.
EXAMPLE
= 3x2 - 12
dy
Note that is a function of x and can be evaluated for any value of x.
dx
EXAMPLE
= 2x — for x ^ 0
dy
Note that again — is a function of x and can be evaluated for any value of x ^ 0.
dx
PROBLEMS
dy
For each of the following functions/(x), find the first derivative using the definition
dx
dy
lim f{x + AaX> ~f(x)
dx Ax-*o Ax
1
1. /(x) = x2 — X + 1 4. /(x) = x-
X
velocity at any instant. The term speed is used frequently to mean the magnitude—
that is, absolute value—of the velocity.
As
If, however, the motion is not uniform, the ratio — varies as At varies and is no
At
longer the velocity of the particle at any instant. It is instead the average velocity of
the particle during the particular time interval At:
limit. If so, this limit is said to be the instantaneous velocity at time tx:
i • • v As
instantaneous velocity at time f, = lim —
A!-»0 At
As
But, by definition, limA(^0 — is the first derivative of/(f) at the point t = tv Thus,
at an instant tu the velocity of a particle moving in a straight line according to the
Figure 2.15
s As
Distance
0
Time
0 t\ 11 -f- At
166 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
law of motion s = f(t), where s is the directed distance from a fixed origin and t is the
time, is given by the value of the derivative of 5 with respect to t for t = tl.
EXAMPLE
The distance of a train from its starting point when it is traveling along a straight track is given
by the equation
s = 16f2 -l- 2t
where s is distance in miles and t is time in hours. Find the distance traveled and the velocity
after 2 hours.
s = 16r2 + 21
= lim (32f + 2)
Af-0
ds
= 64 + 2 = 66 miles per hour
dt t=2
ds
(The notation means the function — evaluated for t — 2.)
dt t=2 dt ’
EXAMPLE
One of the attractions at a carnival is a “prove your strength ” bell, which rings if a lever is hit
with sufficient strength to propel an iron ball up a vertical shaft to hit the bell. When the lever
is hit with a force of 50 lb, the distance of the ball from the bottom of the shaft is given by
s — 401 — 3212
where s is distance in feet and t is time in minutes since the lever was hit.
(a) If the bell is at the top of a 15-ft shaft, is a force of 50 lb sufficient to ring it?
(b) How far from the bottom of the shaft is the ball after 30 seconds, 45 seconds, 1 minute, and
75 seconds, respectively?
ds si
(a) Velocity — is zero when the ball is at the top of the shaft, so solving the equation — = 0
dt dt
provides the time the ball travels up the shaft before coming back down.
2.4 Definition of the First Derivative / 167
= 40 - 64r
ds
If ~ = 0, t = = | minutes (or 37.5 seconds) and s = 40(f) — 32(ff) = 12.5 feet, so the force
is not sufficient to ring the bell 15 ft up the shaft. (See Figure 2.16.)
(b) If t = 30 seconds = \, s = 40(f) — 32(f) = 12 ft (on the way up)
If t = 45 seconds = f, s = 40(f) — 32(^) = 12 ft (on the way down)
If t = 1, s = 40 — 32 = 8 ft (on the way down)
If t — 75 seconds = f, s = 40(f) — 32(ff) = 0 (back down)
Figure 2.16
p—that is,q=f (p). If the ratio —^ of corresponding changes in the two quantities has
Ap
the same value for all values of Ap, it is called the rate of change of q with respect to p
and q is said to change uniformly with respect to p. But if the ratio ^ is not constant
Ap
as Ap changes, q does not change uniformly, and — is then called the average rate of
Ap
change of q with respect to p over the interval Ap.
If the ratio ^ approaches a limit when Ap approaches zero, then this limit is said
Ap
to be the instantaneous rate of change of q wi th respect to p.
From the definition of the derivative, it follows that the instantaneous rate of
change of a variable quantity q with respect to a related variable quantity p is given
dq
by the derivative of q with respect to p, that is,
dp
168 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
derivative — of q with respect to t gives the time rate of change of q. Thus the velocity
dt
of a particle is the time rate of change of its distance from the origin.
The interpretation of a derivative in terms of the rate of change of a function is
frequently applicable in economics, as discussed below.
COST
Suppose the total cost y of producing and marketing x units of a commodity is given
by the function
y=m
Then the average cost per unit is
y = Ax)
X X
That is, marginal cost is the derivative F(x) of the total cost function y =f(x) with
respect to x and is the rate of increase in total cost with increase in output.
2.5 Applications of the First Derivative in Business and Economics / 169
EXAMPLE
y = 20 + 2x + 0.5x2
where y denotes total cost and x denotes quantity produced. Average cost is
y = - = — + 2 + 0.5x
X X
dy
~r~ — 2 + x
dx
Thus total cost increases as output increases; average cost per unit decreases and then in¬
creases as output increases; and marginal cost (rate of increase in total cost) increases as
output increases (see Figure 2.17).
Figure 2.17
note: Derivatives are given in these examples without any explanation of how
they were obtained. The method of the preceding section or the rules given in the
next section can be used to verify the derivations.
170 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
REVENUE
For any given demand function
y =/(*)
where y is the price per unit and x is the number of units, total revenue R is the
product of x and y—that is,
R = xy = x • /(x)
Marginal revenue with respect to demand is the derivative with respect to x of total
revenue,
dR
R'(x)
dx
and is thus the rate of change in revenue with change in demand.
Note that average revenue, or revenue per unit, also represents the price per unit,
y—that is, the average revenue curve and the demand curve are identical.
Since x and y are always nonnegative within our previously stated analytical
dR
framework, R is also always nonnegative. However, — may be positive or negative—
dx
that is, although total revenue is always nonnegative, it may increase or decrease as
demand increases.
EXAMPLE
3x + 4y = 10
where y is the price per unit and x is the number of units. Then
5 3
y=2~4X
Total revenue is %
„ 5 3 .
R = - x - - x2
2 4
Figure 2.18
R
2.5 Applications of the First Derivative in Business and Economics / 171
clR y
Tx’y
dR _ 5 3
dx 2 2X
For the example above, note the following properties, which hold for all linear
demand functions. Total revenue increases and then decreases as quantity increases;
both average revenue and marginal revenue decrease (linearly) as quantity increases.
The average and marginal revenue curves have the same y-intercept and, apart from
this common point, the marginal revenue curve lies below the average revenue curve.
The marginal revenue curve intersects the x-axis at the output for which total
revenue is greatest and the average revenue curve intersects the x-axis at twice that
output. The slope of the average revenue curve is one-half the slope of the marginal
revenue curve.
ELASTICITY
The point elasticity of the function y = /(x) at the point x is the proportional rate of
change in y per unit change in x:
dy
Ey y x dy
Ex dx y dx
x
Note that the elasticity of a function is independent of the units in which the variables
are measured. This results from the definition of elasticity in terms of proportional
changes, which are necessarily independent of units of measurement.
The point elasticity of demand, supply, cost, productivity, and other functions is
an important concept in economic theory. Detailed examples of these and other
applications of derivatives are discussed in later sections, following the discussion of
the techniques of differentiation.
172 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
ds dc
dx dx
dc ds
dx dx
Note that if — = 0, then k = 1; that is, if none of the additional income is spent, the
dx
dc
total increase in income is equal to the initial expenditure; if-—► 1, k -> oo; that is, if
dx
all the additional income is spent, the total increase in income becomes infinitely
large.
EXAMPLE
c — 10 + 0.8x + 0.5v/x
2.5 Applications of the First Derivative in Business and Economics / 173
Figure 2.19
c, s
dc ds
dx, dx
where c is total consumption and x is total disposable income. Then the amount saved is
s = x — c
= — 10 + 0.2x — 0.5^/x
Note that c is positive for all positive values of x; s is negative for small positive values of x and
positive for larger values of x; for every value of x, c + s = x. Note also that c is an increasing
174 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
function of x; 5 is at first a decreasing and then an increasing function of x. (See Figure 2.19.)
The marginal propensity to consume is
and
dc ds
Note that — and k are decreasing functions of x and — is an increasing function of x. (See
dx dx
Figure 2.19.)
The procedure for obtaining derivatives directly was illustrated for several simple
functions in previous sections. Although straightforward, this procedure is tedious
and likely to result in errors, especially for more complicated functions. In practice,
derivatives are obtained using rules or formulas for differentiating particular types of
functions. These rules can be derived using the general procedure, as shown in
Technical Note I.
In this section, rules for differentiating polynomial, algebraic, logarithmic, expon¬
ential, trigonometric, inverse, and composite functions are stated and illustrated.
ALGEBRAIC FUNCTIONS
The formulas in this section apply to the products, quotients, powers, and roots of
differentiable functions.
EXAMPLE
10 = 6, d/
dx
= 0.
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 175
EXAMPLE
if y o.
Rule 2. The derivative of the nth power of a variable is the product of n and the
(n — l)st power of the variable: If y = x",
dx
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
_ vl/4 dy 3/4
If y = = ix
dx
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
5
if y 3^*
dy du
dx dx
EXAMPLE
If y - lOx, f = 10.
dx
176 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
Uy = 6x.
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
If y — — 3x 1, = — (— l)(3bc 2 = 3x 2 = -i .
dx x
dy du dv
dx dx dx
dy " dut
dx dx
EXAMPLE
dy
If y = 3x2 + 4x + 2, 6x + 4
dx
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
d'y
If y = 6x5 + x4 + 2x3/2 + 5, 30x4 + 4x3 + 3x1/2
dx
These four rules for differentiation can be summarized and generalized as the rule for
differentiation of polynomial functions. A single term of the form cx", where c is a
constant and n is zero or a positive integer, is called a monomial in x. A function that
is the sum of a finite number of such monomial terms is called a polynomial or a
polynomial function in x.
The derivative of a monomial in x is
— (cx") = cnxn~ 1
ax
and the derivative of the sum of a finite number of such terms (that is, the derivative
of a polynomial) is the sum of the derivatives of the terms:
d
( Zc.oc”') = Xc. HjX"1 1
dx \,
\ i -= 1 / i= 1
PROBLEMS
Find the first derivative with respect to x for each of the following functions y = f(x).
1. y = 6x + 2 7. y = 5x3/5 + 6x
2. y = x3 + x 8. y = lx2 + 8x~ 1/2 + 2
3. y — 4x2 + 2x 9. y = 9x3 + 5x" 1/4
4. y = x1/2 + 4 10. y = 10x4 + 2x5/4
5. y = 3x2 — x1/3 + 2 11. y = 12x3/2 + 6x1/2 + 2
6. y = 5x“1/3 + 5 12. y = x5 + 3x~7/3 + 5
fi(x) n uj
j= i
jfi
EXAMPLE
dy_ du
+ v
dx dx
and
du
3x2
dx
l(x‘-‘)= 1
dx
= x3 + 4 -f 3x3 + 9x2
= 4x3 + 9x2 + 4
EXAMPLE
dy . dv du
and
div
dx
dv
2x
dx
dy
(y/x 4- 3)(2x) + (x2 + 6)(^x_1/2)
dx
= fx3/2 + 6x + 3x~1/2
EXAMPLE
A,3x+1) = 3
and
^-(3x+7)(-2x 3) + (x 2 + 8)(3)
= —3x-2 - 14x“3 + 24
EXAMPLE
^ + 3> = ‘
^(2x + 3) = 2
4- {x2 + 1) = 2x
dx
and
du dv
dy dx dx
dx v2
EXAMPLE
x2 - 4x + 1
lfy= ■x—6-,
u = x2 — 4x + 1 v = x —6
du dv
2x — 4 1
dx dx
180 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
and
dy I(x — 6)(2x — 4)i-Cx2 -4x+ 1)(1)
dx (*: — 6 r
2x2 — 16x + 24 — x2 + 4x — 1
(x - 6)2
x2 — 12x -I- 23
(x - 6)2
EXAMPLE
Uy =
u = 4 v = x
dv
t- = o = 6x;
ax dx
and
dy _ (x6)(0) - 4(6x5)
dx (x6)2
— 24x5
-24
EXAMPLE
x3 + 16
\fy = ..2 ’
Tx{x2) = 2x
and
dy (x2)(3x2) — (x3 -I- 16)(2x)
dx x4
3x4 - 2x4 - 32x
x4 — 32x
x3 - 32
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 181
y = x 4 16x~ 2
-
dy
32x~3
dx
32
EXAMPLE
x3 + 3x 4- 15
Uy =
x2 4- 2x 4- 2
d_
(x3 4- 3x 4- 15) 3x2 4- 3
dx
d
(x2 + 2x 4- 2) 2x 4- 2
dx
and
dx (x2 + 2x 4 2)2
-
Rule 7. The derivative of the nth power of a differentiable function is the product
of n, the (n — l)st power of the function, and the derivative of the function: If y = un,
where u =f(x) is a differentiable function of x and n is any real number (positive or
negative, integer or noninteger),
dy du
nun
dx dx
i
nxn
which is Rule 2.
182 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
If y = (x2 + 3)3,
d du
nun
dx dx
u — (x2 + 3)
n = 3
'O
du
2x
dx
and
^ = 3(x2 + 3)2(2x)
dx
= 6x(x2 + 3)2
EXAMPLE
If ^ = (x + 3)~1/3,
d , . du
— {u ) = nu 1 —-
dx dx
u = (x + 3)
n = -i
du
= 1
dx
and
dy
= (_i)(x + 3)-4/3(l)
dx
-1
3(x + 3)4/3
EXAMPLE
but note that u = (x + l)/(x — 1) is a fraction and thus Rule 6 must be used to obtain dx.
du I(x i)l-( x + 1)
dx |(x - 1 )2
-2
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 183
and
dy -2i
fx+ 1\|I -2 \
dx !L-1/1 (*-i)i2/
— 4(x + 1)
(* - l)3
EXAMPLE
dy x dv du
Txiuv) = uTx + vTx
du
but note that u = (x + l)2 and v = (x2 + 1) 3 and thus Rule 7 must be used to obtain — and
dx
dv
dx
(x + l)2 — 2(x + 1)
dx
= — 6x(x2 + 1)~4
— 2(x + l)(2x2 + 3x — 1)
= (x2 + l)4
EXAMPLE
Ify = (x2-x)-2,
~ = ~2(x2 — x)~3(2x — 1)
dx
2(2x - 1)
(x2 - x)3
_ 2(1 - 2x)
” x3(x - l)3
EXAMPLE
If y = x2(x + l)"1,
184 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
= (x 4- l)~2[2x(x 4- 1) — x2]
= (x 4- l)~2(2x2 4- 2x — x2)
= (x 4- l)~2(x2 4- 2x)
x(x 4- 2)
“ (x + l)2
EXAMPLE
If y = (x 4- x~ *)2,
= 2(x — x“3)
= 2x~3(x4 - 1)
2(x4 - 1)
— v3
EXAMPLE
If y = 2x(3x2 4- 1)~ \
_ 2(1 - 3x2)
” (3x2 4- l)2
PROBLEMS
Find the first derivative with respect to x for each of the following functions y = f(x).
, 6 4 3 2x + 1
6. y = - 4- - -j 12.
X X X y = x^l
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 185
2x
13. y = 21. y
x2 4- 1 "(x5 4- 10)1/8
9. (x - 1 )2(x + 2)3(7x + 2)
LOGARITHMIC FUNCTIONS
The notation “ In” denotes natural logarithms; the base of the natural logarithms is
defined by e = lim„^00 (1 + (1 /n))n, and is approximately 2.718. The notation “log”
denotes common logarithms (base 10); if any other base is meant, it is specified.
dy loga e du
dx u dx
EXAMPLE
If y=log(^rr)’
d / \ = (x + 1) - x
(Rule 6)
dx \x + 1/ (x 4- l)2
186 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
and
= log e /_1 \
dx x \(x + l)2/
x 1
log e
x(x + 1)
EXAMPLE
If y = >g x,
dy 1 log e]
= ^ (log x)“1/2|
dx x
log e
2xv1og
EXAMPLE
If y = (log x2)3,
EXAMPLE
If y = In y/‘x2 - 1,
=-H*2 - 1 )-1,J(2x)
= x(x2-l)-'«
and
x2 - 1
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 187
EXAMPLE
If> =-,
x
d(\n x) = —
x
and
. |-)x — In x
dy \xj
(Rule 6)
dx x2
1 — In x
EXAMPLE
d
(x + ^/x2 + 4) = 1 + ^(x2 + 4) 1/2(2x)
dx
1/2
= 1 + x(x2 + 4)
and
dy =_
1
[l + x(x2 + 4)-1/2]
dx x + y x2 + 4
x
1 +
X2 + 4
x + ./x2 + 4
x 4- x/x2 + 4
x2 + 4
x + V*2 + 4
1
X2 + 4
EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS
Rule 9. If y = au, where u =f(x) is a differentiable function of x,
dy du
au In a
dx dx
EXAMPLE
Uy = 2~x,
2~x In 2
188 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
If y = 10x2-x,
= (2x — l)10x2-xln 10
EXAMPLE
If y = axxa,
= axx°~1(a + x In a)
dy
dx
EXAMPLE
dy _ xex — ex
dx x2
_ ex(x — 1)
EXAMPLE
If y = 10ex2 + \
% = 10eX’+4(2x)
= 20xe*2 + 4
EXAMPLE
e —e
X — X
lfy =
ex + e
(ex — e x) = ex + e x
dx
d
(ex -f e x) = ex — e~ X
dx
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 189
and
e2x 4- 2 + e 2x — e2x + 2 — e 2x _ 4
(ex + e“*)2 (<?* + e~x)2
Rule 10. If y = uv, where u =f(x) and v = g(x) are differentiable functions of x,
differentiate In y = v In u to obtain
dy du dv
vu v — — + uL In u —
dx dx dx
Note that Rule 9 is a special case of Rule 10, where u = a. Some algebraic functions
are also easier to differentiate if the logarithm of each side is differentiated and the
resulting equation is solved for the derivative of the function. (See the fourth example
below.)
EXAMPLE
If y = xx\
In y — x2 In x
1 dy 1
2x In x + x'
ydx ,x.
= x(2 In x + 1)
— = xx' + *(1 + 2 In x)
dx
EXAMPLE
If y =
In y — ex In x
1 dy IT
— = ex In x + ex -
ydx \X)
1
— ex\ In x +
dx \X ;
EXAMPLE
If y = (x4 4- 5y\
190 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
In y = x2 In (x4 + 5)
1 dy 4x3 '
2x In (x4 + 5) + x2|
y dx x4 + 5.
2x^
= 2x In (x4 + 5) +
x4'+ 5
dy
= 2x(x4 + 5)x2 ![(x4 + 5) In (x4 + 5) + 2x4]
dx
EXAMPLE
In y = -j In (x + 1) — -J In (x — 1)
1 dy__1_1_
y dx 3(x + l) 3(x — 1)
x — 1 — (x + 1)
3(x2 — 1)
-2
~ 3(x2 - 1)
-2 /x+n
31(X2 - 1) \X - 1/
r2_>c2 + 3
5. y — ex In x 17. y = 2x2ex
6. v =
jx
—
+ 1 18. y = log5 (x3 + x2)6
3 /x + 2 19. y = x2*4 + x
7. t = £>ln *
20. y log, (b - X3)2
8- y = axex /x + 3\2
21. y
9. y = log (x3 3x),1/3 F
TRIGONOMETRIC FUNCTIONS
Rule 11. If y = sin u, where u =f(x) is a differentiable function of x,
dy du
— = cos u —
dx dx
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
If y = sin2 3x,
= 6 sin 3x cos 3x
192 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
dy . du
— = —sin u —
dx dx
dy 9 du
— = sec u —
dx dx
Similarly,
1
y = esc u — —-
sin u
1
y = sec u =-
cos u
1
y = cot u = ——
tan u
can be differentiated to obtain the derivatives of the cosecant, secant, and cotangent
functions.
d y du
— (esc u) = — CSC u cot u —
dx dx
d , du
— (sec u) = sec u tan u —
dx dx
d ,
— (cot u) = — CSC u-j-
dx dx
EXAMPLE
If y = cos x + sec x,
dy
— = —sin x + sec x tan x
ax
= sin x(sec2 x — 1)
EXAMPLE
If y = (1 + cot x)2,
EXAMPLE
= 4 tan (x + 3) sec2 (x + 3)
EXAMPLE
= 2(cos2 x — sin2 x)
EXAMPLE
cot (x2 + 2)
If y
sec (x2 + 2) ’
dy — 2x esc2 1(x + 2)1 sec |(x2 + 2)1 — 2x cot 1(x2 + 2)1 sec 1(x2 -f 2) tan |(x2 + 2)
dx sec2 |(x2 + 2)1
— 2x[csc2 (x + 2) + 1]
sec (x2 + 2)
EXAMPLE
PROBLEMS
Find the first derivative of each of the following functions.
6. y = cot (x2 + 1)
^ sin x — cos x
7. y = x + cot x
2-^ =-X-
0 x -F sin x
3. y = x2 cot x 8 - y =---
4. y = tan x esc x
194 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
17. y tan 3x
9. —4 cos 2x sin 2x 1
23.
(sin x + cos x)'
11. 0
x cos x — sin x
13.
INVERSE FUNCTIONS
Rule 14. The derivative of the inverse of a function is equal to the reciprocal of the
derivative of the function. If y=f(x) and x ~ g(y) are inverse differentiable
functions,
dy 1
dx dx
dy
or
df(x) = 1
dx dg(y)
dy
EXAMPLE
dx
1 + y2 + >’4
dy
2.6 Rules for Differentiation / 195
dy 1 1
dx dx 1 + y* 1 2 + yA
dy
EXAMPLE
If x = In (y* + 3y2),
dx 4 y3 + 6 y
dy y4 + 3 y2
_ 4y2 + 6
y3 + 3y
dy _ 1 _ y3 + 3y
dx dx 4y2 + 6
dy
EXAMPLE
Ifx = e'y2+4y+2,
/j y
-f- — ( — 2y + 4r)e~y2+*yJr2
dy
dy _ 1 _^2-4>--2
dx dx 4 — 2y
dy
EXAMPLE
dx
6y2 tan (y3 + a) sec2 (y3 -I- a)
dy
dy 1
cot (y3 + a) cos2 (y3 + a)
dx d^
dy
PROBLEMS
Find the first derivative with respect to x of each of the following functions x = f(y).
1. x = y2 + 3y + 2 4. x = In (y5 — 6)
2. x = y3 — 2y3/2 + 6y 5. x = cos2 y + sin y
3. x = 5y4 — ey 6. x = y sec y
Find the first derivative with respect to y of each of the following functions y = /(x).
9. y = tan x sin x
8. y = In 10. y =
COS X
196 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
1 7. -e*
3.
20 y3 e*
CSC X
9. --2
1 + sec x
COMPOSITE FUNCTIONS
If y is a function of w and u is a function of x, then y is a function of a function or a
composite function; the derivative of y with respect to x is the product of the deriva¬
tive of y with respect to u and the derivative of u with respect to x.
dy dy du
dx du dx
EXAMPLE
dy
iu-1'3
du
3(x2 + 1)1/3
du
2x
dx
dy dy du 4x
dx du dx 3(x2 + 1)1/3
Alternatively,
g=j(x2 + l)-I'3(2x)
4x
“ 3(x2 4- 1)1/3
EXAMPLE
dy _ 2z(z2 4 1) — z2(2z)
dz (z2 4- l)2
2z
= (z2 + l)2
2^/2m 4 1
(2m 4- 2)2
\j2u + 1
2(m 4 l)2
g = i(2U+l)-(2)
1
y/2ll 4 1
dy _ dy dz 1
du dz du 2 (u 4- l)2
Alternatively,
z2 2m 4 1
^ z2 4 1 2m + 2
2
(2m 4 2)2
1
2(m + l)2
EXAMPLE
dw
Tz = 2z
dy dy dw 6z(z2 — l)2
dz dw dz (z2 — l)3 — 1
Alternatively,
dy 3(z2 — l)2(2z)
dz = (z2 — l)3 — 1
6z(z2 — l)2
= (z2 - l)3 -1
198 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
PROBLEMS
1. x = yn- 2y 12. x =
In y
2. x = </4 — 9y y
13. x = y2c_>1
3. x = (2 - 3y2)3
14. x = In (y2cy)
/ fr\2
4. x = a —
yj 15. x = In (ycos 2y)
5. x = yja2 + y2 4
16. x — ,
sec y
a -y
6. x =
a + y i /1 + sin y\1/2
17. x = In -;—— I
\ 1 — sin yf
7. x = + fry
18. x = (sin 2y)1/2
fr
8. x = - wa — y
a 19. y = a6; a = 1 + 2yx
EXAMPLE
y(x) — In x3
dy du dv
Thus (Rule 4).
dx dx dx
du , dv j
, = 2x and — = -
dx dx x
Thus
dy 3
2x +
dx x
EXAMPLE
v(x) = (x + l)2
dy dv du
Thus —— = u ——h v —— (Rule 5).
dx dx dx
du
= 2xcx2 + 2
dx
dv
- 2(x + 1)
dx
Thus
dy 2„x2 + 2
= 2ex +2(x + 1) -F 2x(x + \)2e
dx
= 2(x 4- l)e*2 + 2(l + x2 + x)
EXAMPLE
v(x) = tan x
dv , du ,, v „ dv
Thus — — vu 1 — + (In u)u — (Rule 10).
ax ax ax
du dv
and — = sec" x
dx dx
Thus
dy
= (tan x)x(tanx) 1 + (In x)xtanx(sec2 x)
dx
PROBLEMS
Obtain the first derivative of each of the following functions.
13. y = In3 x
1. y =
x + 1
14. y — log
e+4
2. s =
e
15. y = 10"*
3. y = In (x 4- y/\ + x2)
16. y = In (ax2 + b)
2
4- y = 17. 5 = e~‘ cos It
ex
18. y = i tan3 9 - tan 0 + 9
x3 + 1
5 .y = ir. a + bt + ct2
x
19. s = —
3
6. y =
x2 + 2 a + bx + cx2
20. z =
1
7. s =
1 - 21 21. z = a2y
22. y = exl
8. y =
4 — x2 23. y = x*
9. y = eax sin bx 24. y = xn(a + bx)‘
sin
7. 25. x sin x | + cos x In x I
(1 - 2r)2
9. - eax(a sin bx + b cos bx)
ad — be
11.
(cx + d)2
3 In2 x
13.
Rule 1. If y = c, , = 0.
dx
dy du
Rule 3. If y = cu, where u =f(x) = c
dx dx
dy du dv
dx dx dx
dy dv du
dx dx
du dv
dy dx dx
dx
dy du
nu n- 1
dx dx
Logarithmic Functions
Rule 8. If y = loga u, where u = /(x),
dy logae du
dx u dx
1 du
Special Case: If a = e, then y = In u and
u dx
Exponential Functions
Rule 9. If y = au, where u = f(x).
dy du
= au In a
dx dx
dy du
Special Case: If a = e, then y = eu and
dx dx
1
du dv
+ uv In u
V-
vu
dx dx
Trigonometric Functions
Rule 11. If y = sin u, where u = f(x),
dy du
= cos v —
dx dx
dy . du
— — —sin u —
dx dx
dy . du
— = sec u —
dx dx
Inverse Functions
Rule 14. If >’ = /(x) and x = g(y) are inverse functions,
dy 1
dx dx
dy
Composite Functions
Rule 15. If >’ = <h(w) and u = F(x),
dy dy du
dx du dx
Note that Rules 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, and 13 are special cases of Rule 15.
2.7 Differentials / 203
2.7 Differentials
I
dx — Ax
Therefore, dy is the increment (equal to QT) of the ordinate of the tangent corre¬
sponding to dx.
Figure 2.20
y
204 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
^ = /'(x) = tan 6
dx
Approximations
It can be seen in Figure 2.20 that Ay = QP' and dy = QT are approximately equal
when Ax = PQ is small. In fact, the differential of a function can be made arbitrarily
close to the increment of the function for sufficiently small changes in the indepen¬
dent variable. The value of the corresponding differential thus can be used as an
approximation for the change in a function when the independent variable changes
by a small amount.
EXAMPLE
dy = (4x3 — 6x2 + 9) Ax
= (32 — 24 + 9)(—0.003)
= -0.051
Since y = 25 when x = 2 and —0.051 is the approximate change in y when x changes from 2 to
1.997,
y + dy = 25 - 0.051
= 24.949
and y is approximately 24.949 when x = 1.997.
To obtain an estimate of the accuracy of this approximation, compute the error of the
approximation, which is given by Ay — dy.
Thus
And, for x = 2,
= 0.000107838081
EXAMPLE
-2
” 27100
= -0.1
EXAMPLE
Using differentials, find an approximate value for tan 46° given tan 45° = 1, sec 45° = yfl,
and 1° = 0.0175 radians.
If y = tan x, dy = sec2 x dx. When x changes to dx, y changes to y + dy, approximately.
71
x = 45° = - radians
4
Ax = 1° = 0.0175 radians
dy = sec2 x dx
= (V2)2(0.0175)
= 0.0350
EXAMPLE
Suppose C = 5 + 0.6x -I- 0.2v/x, where C is total consumption (billions of dollars) and x is
total disposable income (billions of dollars). If x = 25 with a maximum error of 0.3, find the
approximate maximum error in consumption.
dC — 0.6 + —^= dx
,
x
0
= 0.6 +
725
y<°.3)
= 10.6+ 531 (0.3)
= (0.62)(0.3)
= 0.186
du .
is the relative error in u
u
and
du .
100 is the percentage error in u
u
dC 0.186
_ = _ = 0.00744
EXAMPLE
16
where x is number of units demanded and y is price in dollars, assume y is 200 with a
maximum error of 10 and determine the approximate maximum relative error in x.
In x = In 16 + 4 In y
dx A dy
— = -4
x y
dx 40 1
~x ~ 200 ~~ ~ 5
and the percentage error is —20. The negative sign of the error indicates that the errors in
estimating x and y are opposite in sign.
2.8 Higher-Order Derivatives / 207
PROBLEMS
Use differentials to find the approximate value of each of the following.
1. 0010 3. 766
2. 05 4. 04
9. A container is made in the form of a 10-cm cube to hold 1 liter (1000 cm3). How accurately
must the inner edge be made so that the volume will be correct to within 3 cm3?
10. Using differentials, find the allowable percentage error in the diameter of a circle if the area
is to be correct to within 4 percent.
11. Show that the relative error in the nth power of a measurement is approximately n times
the relative error in the measurement.
12. Show that the relative error in the nth root of a measurement is approximately 1/n times
the relative error in the measurement.
EXAMPLE
If y = x3 — 3x2 + 2,
dy
— 3x2 — 6x
dx
d2y
= 6x — 6
dx2
d3y
= 6
dx3
d4y
= 0
dx4
and higher-order derivatives are also zero.
208 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
If x = Jt2 + 1,
^= l)-'/2(2f)
= r(r2 + 1)_1/2
= (t2 + 1 )_3/2
g=-^2 + l)-(2()
= — 3f(t2 + 1)"5/2
EXAMPLE
If y = sin x,
dy
~ = COS X
dx
d2y
= —sin x
dx
d3y
= —cos x
dx
dAy
d? = smx
and so forth for higher-order derivatives.
Just as the derivative of the function y =f{x) with respect to x represents the rate
of change in y as x changes, the second derivative of y =f (x) with respect to x
represents the rate of change in the first derivative y' = /'(x) as x changes.
In general, the nth derivative with respect to x of a function y — f(x) represents the
rate of change in the (n — l)st derivative of y = f(x) as x changes.
Higher-order derivatives are very important for certain theoretical problems in
mathematics and statistics; however, in most applied work, derivatives of order
higher than the second are not frequently encountered.
Second-order derivatives are useful in graphical representation of functions, as
discussed in later sections, and are also useful whenever the rate of change of the
quantity represented by the first derivative is of interest. For example, the rate of
change of velocity is acceleration and the rate of change of marginal cost indicates
2.8 Higher-Order Derivatives / 209
EXAMPLE
s = (2f + 3)2
v = j( = 2(2t + 3X2)
= 8t + 12
a = , =
dv e8
dt
EXAMPLE
An object projected vertically upward with a speed of 160 feet/second reaches an elevation of
s = 160f — 16f2
s = 160(5) - 16(52)
= 800 - 400
= 400 ft
(b) If s = 256,
t2 - lOf + 16 = 0
(t - 8)(f - 2) = 0
t = 8, 2
The object is thus at an elevation of 256 feet going up after 2 seconds and coming down after 8
seconds.
ds
If t = 2, v = — = 160 - 32t = 160 - 64 = 96 ft/sec
dt
(c) a = ~ = - 32 ft/sec2
210 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
y = 50 + 60x — 12x2 + x3
Figure 2.21
where y is total cost and x is output. Average cost is y/x = (50/x) -f 60 — 12x + x2 and
Figure 2.22
2.8 Higher-Order Derivatives / 211
— 24 + 6x
— 0 when x = 4
Thus marginal cost decreases for x < 4, increases for x > 4, and is constant for x = 4.
EXAMPLE
= 0 when x2 + 2x — 4 = 0
Figure 2.23
y
212 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.24
dy_ y
dx'y
d2y n , .at
- -2 = 0 when x = — 1+^/5
tf A
Thus marginal cost decreases for x < — 1 + yj 5, increases for x > — 1 + yj~5, and is constant
for x = — 1 + y/5.
PROBLEMS
Find the first and second derivatives of each of the following functions.
1. y = e3x 4. y = x2ex
2. y = x In x 5. y = e,n (xJ~3)
3' fx - 5'
3. y = log 6. y =
.X, x +1
Functions of the form y =f(x) express y explicitly in terms of x and can be differen¬
tiated according to the rules for the types of functions involved. However, as noted in
preceding sections, some equations involving x and y, of the form/(x, y) = 0, do not
give y explicitly in terms of x and cannot conveniently be written so that they do.
Such equations define y as a function of x in the sense that for each value of x there is
a corresponding value of y which satisfies the equation; the equation is said to
dy
determine y as an implicit function of x. It is possible to calculate — from such an
dx
equation by the method of implicit differentiation. In this method, y is treated as an
unknown but differentiable function of x and the rules for finding derivatives are
dy
applied. In general, this method gives an expression for — in terms of both x and y.
EXAMPLE
dy
Find — for the equation xy2 — x + y = 0. Differentiating with respect to x,
dx
2xydy
dx
+ y2-2x + dx
dy = 0
(2xy + 1)^ = 2x - y2
dy 2x — y2
dx 2xy -I- 1
note: In this example, xy2 is the product of two functions of x, x and y2, and is differen¬
tiated using the product rule
d . . dv du
Tx(uv) = uTx + vTx
, du dx t dv _ dy d , ^ dy , _ , .
where u = x, v = y , — = — =1, and — = 2y —ihus — (xy ) = 2xy — -f v . The deriva-
dx dx dx dx dx dx
tive of —x2 is — 2x, as in differentiation of explicit functions (note again that — = 11. The
dx
EXAMPLE
2 dy 0 dy
3x2 + 3y2 —-3ax -3ay = 0
dx dx
/(f-ax)Tx
2 , dy = ay-x 2
dy ay — x2
dx y2 — ax
EXAMPLE
dy
Find for the equation sin x cos y tan y = 0. Differentiating with respect to x,
dx
dy 7 dy
cos x cos y-sinxsiny--sec v — = 0
dx dx
dy cos x cos y
dx sin x sin y + sec2 y
EXAMPLE
dy
Find — for the equation x — y = 1. Differentiating with respect to x,
dx
2x-2y‘^ = 0
dx
dy x
dx y
dy
y X
dx
dy
Substituting
dx
2.9 Implicit Differentiation / 215
or, since y2 — x2 = — 1,
d2y 1
dx2 v3
EXAMPLE
dy
Find and for the equation ey xex = 0. Differentiating with respect to x,
dx
ey --ex — xex — 0
dx
dy ex(x + 1)
dx ey
or, since ey = xex,
dy x + 1
dx x
and
d2y x — (x + 1)
dx2 x2
1
EXAMPLE
+iy~ll2^ = 0
dy
dx x 1/2
dy . .
Differentiating — with respect to x,
dx
1/2 f?F\xi/2
d2y dxj
dx2 x
. dy y11
Substituting — = — -ji
dx x 1
^x-1 +ix~3l2y112
= 7X~3/2(x1/2 + yl/1)
PROBLEMS
d2y
Find a. dL and b. for each of the following functions by the method of implicit
dx dx2
differentiation.
1. x2 + y2 = 1 10. x2y2 + xy = 1
2. x3 + y3 = 1 11. x3y3 + x2y2 = a
3. x2/3 + y2/3 = j 12. x + y + xy + y2 =
4. xy + y2 = 1 13. x3y2 = a
5. y2 = x3 14. x2 + xy = a2
6. xy — a 15. xy2 + y2 = a
7. x2y2 = b 16. xy + y3 = b
8. x2y3 = c 17. (x + y)2 + (x + yf
9. x + y — xy = 2 18. x2 + y2 = ab
dy
Find — for each of the following functions by the method of implicit differentiation.
dx
x — 1 1 1
19. y2 27. + -= 1
X + 1 y X
. a. -x-'/y/3 b. y~4/y1/3
21. y
3
(x 4- yf
_ 3x2 3x
5. a. b. —
2y 4y 23. jx-1/2 +ix~2/3 + ix~3/4
2 sin x cos x
11. a. — - b. 2); 29.
X X sin y(l -F sec2 y)
3y 15y y(l+_x)
13. a. 31. -
2x 4x2 x(l - y)
-v 3y 5x4 + 4y3
15. a. b. 33.
2(x 4- 1) ■ 4(x + l)2 15/ - 12xy2
17. a. -1 b. 0
2.10 Differentiability and Continuity / 217
The relationships between differentiability and continuity are discussed in this sec¬
tion and smooth functions are defined and illustrated.
It can be shown that if the function y =f(x) has a finite derivative
Differentiability ^ Continuity
EXAMPLE
= —1 for x < 0
Figure 2.25
fix)
EXAMPLE
/(x) = x1/3 is continuous at x = 0, but does not have a derivative at x = 0, since/'(x) = \x 2/3
is not defined for x = 0 (see Figure 2.26).
218 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.26
fix)
Smooth Functions
A function f(x) is said to be a smooth function if both f(x) and its first derivative are
continuous. The graph of a smooth function is said to be a smooth curve; such a
curve is not only continuous and unbroken but also has a continuously turning
tangent. As shown in the following sections, a smooth function has some useful
properties not possessed by a continuous curve whose first derivative is discontinuous
at certain points.
EXAMPLE
dy
y = 1 — x2 is a smooth function, since y and its derivative — = — 2x are everywhere contin-
dx
uous (see Figure 2.27).
Figure 2.27
y
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 219
EXAMPLE
dy 2
dx 3^x- 1
is discontinuous (becomes infinite) at x = 1 (see Figure 2.28).
Figure 2.28
In this section the information concerning a function or curve which can be obtained
from its first and second derivatives is discussed. Such information is useful not only
for graphing but also for determining the appropriateness of equations for represent¬
ing various relationships in business, economics, and the behavioral sciences.
Figure 2.29
fix)
EXAMPLE
f(x) = 2x2 4- 10, f'(x) = 4x. Since f'(x) > 0 for x > 0 and f'(x) > 0 for x < 0,/(x) is an in¬
creasing function of x for positive x and a decreasing function of x for negative x. Note that
/'(x) = 0 for x = 0.
EXAMPLE
/(x) = 3x3, f'(x) = 9x2. Since f'(x) is nonnegative for all values of x, /(x) is an increasing
function of x for all values of x.
EXAMPLE
/(x) = x3 4- 6x2 + 15, /'(x) = 3x2 4- 12x = 3x(x 4- 4). Since /'(x) > 0 for x > 0 or x < —4
and f'(x) < 0 for — 4 < x < 0,/(x) is a decreasing function of x for the interval — 4 < x < 0
and an increasing function of x for all x < —4 and x > 0. Note that f'(x) = 0 for x = 0.
In the examples above, the values of x for which f'{x) = 0 are not discussed; such
values are of particular interest, as discussed below.
Figure 2.30
f(x)
that it is possible for a relative maximum value of a function to be less than a relative
minimum value of the function (see Figure 2.30).
If a function/(x) has a relative maximum or minimum at a value x = a for which
its first derivative is continuous, then f'{a) = 0. Values of x for which/'(x) is discon¬
tinuous must be considered separately, as discussed below.
CAUTIONS
1. A relative maximum or minimum at x = a impliesf\a) = 0 only if/(x) and/'(x)
are continuous at x = a.
2. f'(a) = 0 does not imply a relative maximum or minimum at x = a even if/(x) and
/'(x) are continuous at x = a; that is, if/(x) and/'(x) are continuous at x = a,
f'(a) = 0 is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for a relative maximum or
minimum at x = a.
EXAMPLE (CAUTION 1)
Figure 2.31
fix)
222 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
/ W = Y(x - i)1/3
and f'(x) is (infinitely) discontinuous at x = 1. Thus, although the function has a relative
minimum at x = !,/'(!) =/= 0 (see Figure 2.31).
EXAMPLE (CAUTION 2)
/'(*) = 3x2
and /'(x) = 0 for x = 0. However, the function/(x) = x3 does not have a relative maximum or
minimum at x = 0 (see Figure 2.32).
Figure 2.32
fix)
Consider a function f(x) at a value x — a for which f(x) and /'(x) are continuous.
It is evident geometrically that iff(a) is a relative maximum of/(x), then the slope
J'(x) off(x) changes from positive to negative as x passes through the point x = a;
similarly, if f(a) is a relative minimum of/(x), then the slope /'(x) of/(x) changes
from negative to positive as x passes through the point x = a (see Figure 2.33). The
corresponding algebraic argument is based on the fact that an increasing function
has a positive slope and a decreasing function has a negative slope.
Thus, in order to determine the relative maximum and minimum values, if any, of
a function y =/(x),
1. Solve the equation /'(x) = 0 to obtain its roots (sometimes called critical values).
2. For each root a, determine whetherf'(x) changes sign as x increases through a:
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 223
Figure 2.33
f(x)
note: The above procedure locates all relative maxima and minima that occur
at values of x for which f(x) and f'(x) are continuous. Relative maxima and minima
which occur at values of x for which/'(x) is discontinuous are discussed below.
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = 2x3 — 3x2 — I2x +13.
dy
= 6x2 — 6x — 12
dx
= 0 if x2 — x — 2 = 0
(x — 2)(x + 1) = 0
x = 2, - 1
Figure 2.34
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = 3x4 — 4x3.
~ = 12x3 - 12x2
ax
= 0 if x3 - x2 = 0
x2(x — 1) = 0
x = 0, 1 x
Figure 2.35
y
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 225
dy
If X <0, <0
dx
so no maximum or minimum at x = 0
dl
IfO < X < 1, <0
dx
dy
IfO < X < 1, <0
dx
so minimum at x = 1
dy
If X > 1, >0
dx
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = x/^/x2 + 1.
1
(x2 + 1)3/2
T4 0
Figure 2.36
In each of the examples above, the first derivative is continuous for all values of x.
Thus relative maxima and minima can occur only for values x = a for which
f'(a) = 0. As noted above, relative maxima or minima may also occur for values
x = a for which f'{a) is discontinuous. That is, if f(x) is continuous at x = a but its
226 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
_ v-2/3
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = x
dy _ 2 -1/3
dx~lX
dy A_ , dy +
-f- -> —oo asx-»0 and -—» oo as x -► 0
dx dx
dy
so — has an infinite discontinuity at x = 0.
dx
If x < 0, % < 0
dx
so minimum at x = 0
If X > 0, ~ > 0
dx
Figure 2.37
y
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 227
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = (1 — x)2/3(2 + x)1/3.
_ ~(x + 1)_
(1 - x)1/3(2 + x)2/3
= 0 if x = — 1
dy dy
— oo as x -> 1 and "f - oo as x -► 1+
dx dx
dy
so — has an infinite discontinuity at x = 1.
dx
Figure 2.38
y
228 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = — (4 — x)1/2 — 2.
1
“ 2(4 - x)1/2
dy dy dy
-► oo if x -► 4 , so — has an infinite discontinuity at x = 4. Note that y and —- are
dx dx dx
undefined if x > 4. Thus y = —(4 — x)1/2 — 2 has no relative maximum or minimum (see
Figure 2.39).
Figure 2.39
The least (or greatest) value of a function in an interval—that is, its absolute
minimum or maximum in an interval—may occur at an end point of the interval
rather than at a relative minimum or maximum value.
EXAMPLE
Find the maximum and minimum values of the function y = x2 — 2x in the interval 2 < x < 4.
dl — 2x — 2
dx
= 0 if x = 1
<0 if x < 1 . .
.. J so minimum at x = 1
>0 if x > lj
But x = 1 is outside the interval 2 < x < 4.
If x = 2, y = 0
If x = 4, y = 8
Thus in the interval 2 < x < 4, the least value of y occurs at the end point x = 2, and the
dy
greatest value occurs at the end point x = 4; at neither of these points is — equal to zero (see
dx
Figure 2.40).
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 229
Figure 2.40
EXAMPLE
The total cost curve of a commodity is y = 15x — 8x2 + 2x3, where y represents total cost and x
represents quantity. Suppose that market conditions indicate that between 3 and 10 units
should be produced (that is, 3 < x < 10). Determine the quantity in this interval for which
average cost is a minimum.
Figure 2.41
y
230 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
-f - = — 8 + 4x
ax
= 0 if x = 2
<0 if x < 2)
C so minimum at x = 2
>0 if x > 2)
Ifx = 3,5? = 9
If x = 10, y = 135
Thus in the interval 3 < x < 10, the least value of y occurs at x = 3 and the greatest value
dy
occurs at x = 10; at neither of these points is — equal to zero. Thus, for between 3 and 10
dx
units, average cost is minimum for 3 units (see Figure 2.41).
Note that the least or greatest value of a function in an interval, that is, its absolute
minimum or maximum in an interval, may occur at an end point of the interval
rather than at a relative minimum or maximum value.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following functions, determine maxima and minima; sketch the curve re¬
presenting each function.
1. y = 12 — 12x + x2 2x
6. y =
x2 - 1
2- y =
X + 1
7. y = x2 — 4x 4- 3
X3 X2
1 y = T-y-6x 8. y = Xy/l — x2
4. y = x4 — 32x + 48 9. y = x3 — 3x2 + 2
5. y = 10. y =
x2 + 7 x2 + 4
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 231
8x
11. y 16. v =
:2 - 8 x2 + 4
12. y x4 - 4x3 + 12
3x2
13. y
\/x2 + 3 18. y = x5 + 6
Concavity
Consider the function y = /(x) at the point x — a. The second derivative of y with
respect to x, y" = /"(x), is the slope at the point x of the curve representing the first
derivative y' = /'(x) of the function/(x); in particular,/"(a) is the slope of the curve
y' = f'(x) at the point x = a.
If the second derivative /"(a) of a function y =f(x) is positive, y' = f'(x) is an
increasing function of x at x = a; the curve representing y =f(x) is said to be concave
upward where/"(x) is positive. If the second derivative f"(a) of a function y =f(x) is
negative, y' = f'(x) is a decreasing function of x at x = a; the curve representing
y =f{x) is said to be concave downward where f"(x) is negative (see Figure 2.42).
Consider a function/(x) at a value x = a for which f(x) and f'(x) are continuous.
It is evident geometrically that iff'(a) = 0 and f(x) is concave downward at x = a,
then/(x) has a maximum at a; similarly, iff'(a) = 0 and/(x) is concave upward at
x = a, then/(x) has a minimum at a. The corresponding algebraic argument is based
on the fact that a positive second derivative indicates an increasing slope and a
negative second derivative indicates a decreasing slope.
caution : The second derivative test is only sufficient, not necessary, for a rela¬
tive maximum or minimum, since f(x) may be concave upward or downward at
x = a iff"(a) = 0. That is, iff'(a) = 0, then
232 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.42
From this follows a very convenient, although not always applicable, test for
relative maximum and minimum values:
f(x) and f'(x) are continuous > 0 => relative minimum
at x = a at x = a
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = 3X3 — lx1 + 3x + 1.
4x + 3
= 0 if x2 — 4x + 3 = 0
(x — 3)(x — 1) = 0
x = 3, 1
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 233
Figure 2.43
dy2
= 2x-4
dx“
d2y
If x = 1, -r-j < 0, so maximum at x = 1
dx
d2y
If x = 3, —2 > 0, so minimum at x = 3
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = x4.
= 0 if x = 0
Figure 2.44
y
234 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
d2y
= 12x:
dx2
d2y
If x = 0, —~ = 0, so there may or may not be a maximum or minimum at x = 0
dx
If x < 0, ^ < 0
dx
so minimum at x = 0
If x > 0, ~>0
dx
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = x3.
dy
— 3x"
dx
= 0 if x = 0
d2y
= 6x
dx2
d2y
If x = 0, = 0, so there may or may not be a maximum or minimum at x = 0
dxz
if x < o, 7 > o
dx
so no maximum or minimum at x = 0
If x > 0, ~>0
dx
Figure 2.45
y
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 235
In the examples above, when f"(a) — 0—that is, when the second derivative test
for a maximum or minimum does not apply—the first derivative is examined for
change of sign as x passes through a. There is, however, an alternative procedure,
involving derivatives of higher order, which is more convenient in some cases.
f\a) =f"(a) --y<"“1>(a) = 0 | f{n){a) < 0 => relative
maximum at x = a
for n even
f{n)(a) > 0 => relative
If i and then minimum at x = a
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima (if any) of the function y = 3x4 — x3 + 2.
^ = 12x3 - 3x2
dx
= 0 if 12x3 — 3x2 = 0
3x2(4x — 1) = 0
x = 0, ^
d2y
= 36x2 — 6x
dx2
= 6x(6x — 1)
d2 y
If x = i, —> > 0, so minimum at x = \
dx
d2y
If x = 0, —r = 0, so there may or may not be a maximum or minimum at x = 0
dxz
d3y
t = 72x — 6
dx
= 6(12x - 1)
d3y . .
If x = 0, T =/= 0, so no maximum or minimum at x = 0
dx
dy
If X <0, <0
dx
so no maximum or minimum at x = 0
dy
IfO < X < h <0
dx
dy
IfO < X < i> <0
dx
so minimum at x = \
dy
If X > i. >0
dx
Figure 2.46
y
Points of Inflection
A function y —f(x) is said to have a point of inflection at a point where the concavity
of the curve changes. Geometrically, at a point of inflection the tangent crosses the
curve. Since the sign of the second derivative indicates the concavity of a curve, it
follows that a change in the sign of the second derivative implies a change in concav¬
ity (and thus a point of inflection).
If a function f(x) has a point of inflection at a value x = a for which its second
derivative is continuous, then f"{a) = 0. Values of x for which f"(x) is discontinuous
must be considered separately, as discussed below.
CAUTIONS
1. A point of inflection at x = a implies f"{a) = 0 only if /(x) and f"(x) are
continuous at x = a.
2. f”(a) = 0 does not imply a point of inflection at x = a even if/(x) and /"(x) are
continuous at x = a; that is, iff(x) andf"{x) are continuous at x = a,f"(a) = 0
is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for a point of inflection at x = a.
note: If f(x) and /"(*) are continuous at x = a and f"(a) = 0, then /"'(a) 0
implies a point of inflection at x = a; this may be used as an alternative to checking
for change of sign of the second derivative at x = a.
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima and the points of inflection (if any) of the function
y = x1/3.
dy _ i _ 2/3
= ix
dx
^ 0 for all x
dy
discontinuous at 0
dx
If X < 0, ~ > 0
dx
> so no maximum or minimum at x = 0
If x > 0, % > 0
dx
d2y
2 yX~5/3
-£y
dx
d2y
discontinuous at 0
dx2
d2y
If x < 0, >0
dx2
> so point of inflection at x = 0
d2y
If x > 0, ~ < 0
dx
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima and the points of inflection (if any) of the function
y = *A/l ~ *2-
= (1 — x2)_3/2
— oo as x -+ ± 1, so infinite discontinuities at x = ±1
dx
g=-!( i-x2rs/2(-2x)
= 3x(l - x2)-5/2
= 0 if x =0
d2 y
If — 1 < x < 0, 2 <0
dx
so point of inflection at x = 0
d2y
IfO<x< 1, t4>0
i
dx '
Figure 2.48
EXAMPLE
Find the relative maxima and minima and the points of inflection (if any) of the function
y = x -h (1/x).
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 239
dy = t
dx x2
x2 - i
= 0 if x = + 1
dy discontinuous at x = 0
dx
dy
If x < — 1, — > 0
dx
so maximum at x = — 1
If -1 < x < 0, ^ < 0
dx
... ...
—r discontinuous at x = 0 but — also discontinuous at x = 0, so no point of inflection
dxz dx
at x = 0
See Figure 2.49.
Figure 2.49
y
240 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
/"(x) is discontinuous at x = a
dy
2. Determine the ranges of values of x for which — is positive and for which it is
dx
negative.
dyit y
3. Check points where — = 0 for possible maxima or minima.
dx
dy
4. Check points where — is discontinuous for possible maxima or minima.
dx
d2y .
5. Determine the ranges of values of x for which ^ 4 positive and for which it is
dx
negative.
d2y
6. Check points where , ? = 0 for possible points of inflection.
ax
d2y
7. Check points where —j is discontinuous for possible points of inflection.
dx
8. Determine the intercepts.
9. Note the nature of the curve for very small and very large values of x.
10. Sketch the curve as indicated by the signs of ~ (increasing or decreasing) and of
A-
d2y
(concave upward or downward), the intercepts, asymptotic properties, and
dx2
discontinuities
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 241
EXAMPLE_
dy
3 — 3x2
dx
if x = +1
if x = 0
so point of inflection at (0, 4). If x = 0, y = 4. As x -> oo, y -> - oo, and as x -> - oo, y -> oo.
See Figure 2.50.
Figure 2.50
y
242 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
dy = i _ 4
dx x2
d2y 8x 3
dx2 x4 x3
dy
= 0 if x = ±2
dx
dy
If x < -2, > 0 (increasing)
dx
di
If — 2 < x < 2 and x ^ 0 <0 (decreasing)
dx
If x > 2, (increasing)
d2y
<0 if x < 0 (concave downward)
dx2
Figure 2.51
2.11 Applications of Derivatives / 243
EXAMPLE
Find the points at which the curve represented by the function x — y4 + 2y2 —2 = 0 has
vertical tangents and sketch the curve.
3 dy A dy
i - 4.y + 4y -j- = 0
dx dx
dy 1
dx 4 y(y2 — 1)
dy dy
so — ^ 0 for all x. Vertical tangents occur when — is undefined, so there are vertical tangents
dx dx
at (2, 0), (1, — 1), and (1, 1). (Note that x = y4 — 2y2 + 2.)
d2y
= 0 if y = ±
dx'
d2y
Ify < -l, > 0 (concave upward)
dx2
Figure 2.52
244 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
r d2 y
if y/i < y < l > 0 (concave upward)
WA
d2 y
if y > i, -Hz <° (concave downward)
UA
If y = 0, x = 2. As y -* oo, x ->• oo, and as y -* — oo, x -*• oo. See Figure 2.52.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following functions, determine any maxima, minima, and points of inflection;
sketch the curve representing each function. (Refer to problems on pages 230-231 for maxima
and minima.)
1. y — 12 — 12x 4- x:
11. y =
y/x2 ~ 8
2- y =
X + 1 12. y = X4 - 4x3 + 12
X3 X2 3x2
3. y . —-— 6x 13. y =
3 2 Vx2 +"3
4. y = x4 — 32x + 48 1_
14. y =
16 — x2
5- y =
\/X2 + 7 15. y = |x3 — 4x2 -F 6x + 2
2x 8x
6- y = 16. y =
y/x2 ~ T x2 + 4
7. y = x2 - 4x + 3 x -I- 3
17. y = —j-
X
8- y = XV 1 - X2
18. y = x5 + 6
9. y = X3 - 3x2 + 2
19. y = (x — l)1/3(x + 1)2/3
1
10. y =
x2 + 4 20. y = i(x3 — 6x2 + 9x + 6)
21. Sketch a smooth curve y — f(x) having all the following properties:
a./(l) = 0 b./(l) = 0
f'(x) < 0 for x < 1 f'(x) < 0 for x < 1
f (x) > 0 for x > 1 f"(x) > 0 for x > 1
22. Sketch a smooth curve y =/(x) having all the following properties:
/(0) = 10 /'(6) = 0 f"(x) < 0 for x < 9
/(6) = 15 /'(10) = 0 /"(9) = 0
/(10) = 0 /"(x) > 0 for x > 9
23. Sketch a continuous curve y =f{x) having all of the following properties:
/(— 2) = 8 /'(x) > 0 for | x | >2 /"(x) < 0 for x < 0
/(0) = 4 /'(2) =/'(-2) = 0 /"(x) > 0 for x > 0
/(2) = 0
24. Sketch a continuous curve y =/(x) having the properties/'(x) > 0 for x < 2 and/'(x) < 0
for x > 2:
a. If/'(x) is continuous at x = 2
b. If/'(x) -> 1 as x -► 2~ and/'(x) -> - 1 as x -> 2 +
c. If/'(x) = 1 for x < 2 and /'(x) = - 1 for x > 2
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 245
y = ax3 + bx2 + cx + d a, b, c, d f 0
28. Sketch a continuous curve y =/(x) for x > 0 if/(l) = 0 and f'(x) = - for x > 0. Is such a
X
Functions of various types are used to represent total cost curves; in general, cost
curves have the following properties:
1. When no units are produced, total cost is zero or positive—that is,/(0) > 0. If
/(0) > 0, then /(0) is amount of overhead or fixed costs of production.
2. Total cost increases as x increases, so /'(x) is always positive.
3. The cost of producing an extremely large quantity of any commodity usually
reaches a point at which it increases at an increasing rate. Thus usually the total
cost curve eventually is concave upward, that is,/"(x) > 0; however, in a limited
range the total cost curve is frequently concave downward, corresponding to
decreasing marginal cost.
y=f(x)
then the average or per unit cost is
dy
dx
=/'(*)
dy = xf'jx) -f(x)
dx x2
® -m
Thus average cost is minimum at the value of x for which average cost equals
marginal cost; that is, the average and marginal cost curves intersect at the point of
minimum average cost. Note that the value of x (if any) for which ^ = 0 is assumed
UA
to be a minimum because of the third property of cost curves mentioned above; for a
particular total cost curve the existence of this minimum can be checked in the usual
way.
EXAMPLE
Marginal cost: ~ — a
dx
w • , dy b
Marginal average cost: — =-y
dx x
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 247
Figure 2.53
y*y
Total cost and marginal cost are represented by straight lines and average cost is repre¬
sented by the first quadrant branch of an equilateral hyperbola with horizontal asymptote
y = a. Average cost is thus a decreasing function of the number of units produced; it has no
minimum value but approaches a, the marginal cost, as the number of units increases (see
Figure 2.53).
EXAMPLE
Total cost is represented by the first quadrant part of a parabola, average cost is repre¬
sented by the first quadrant branch of a hyperbola, and marginal cost is represented by a
straight line (see Figure 2.54).
dy = 0 if ax2 = c
dx
Note that average and marginal cost are equal if x = yfcja, since
248 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.54
y
and
EXAMPLE
Total cost: y = ax3 + bx2 -f cx + d, where a > 0, b < 0, c > 0, d > 0, b2 < 3ac
dy
Marginal cost: 3ax2 T 2bx + c
dx
dy
Marginal average cost: 2 ax + b
dx
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 249
Figure 2.55
y
Total cost is represented by the first quadrant part of a cubic curve, average cost is
represented by the first quadrant branch of a hyperbola, and marginal cost is represented by
the first quadrant part of a parabola (see Figure 2.55).
Cubic cost functions are frequently appropriate when the concavity of the cost function
changes in a specified interval; however, such a function must have no relative maximum or
minimum in the first quadrant:
dy ,
— = 3 ax + 2 bx + c
dx
— 0 if 3ax2 + 2bx + c = 0
=a(^)+ m+c(^j+d
~2f>3 bc
3a +
= b(2b> - 9ac) ,
250 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
2b2 - 9ac < 0, since b2 — 3ac < 0 and thus, since a > 0 and b < 0, b(2b2 — 9ac)/21a2 > 0 and
{-b/3a, [b(2b2 - 9ac)/21a2] + d} lies in the first quadrant.
d2y
= 6 ax + 2b
dx2
d2y
=0
dx2 x = — b/2>a
= 6a^0
b(2b2 — 9 ac)
3 a’
Note that b2 — 3ac < 0 is a sufficient but not a necessary condition for y = ax3 +
bx2 + cx + d to have no relative maximum or minimum in the first quadrant. Other
cases are discussed in Technical Note II.
Frequently the tangent at the point of inflection provides a good linear approxi¬
mation of a cubic cost function for a limited range. The tangent at the point of
inflection x = —b/3a has slope
dv -
— = 3 ax2 + 2 bx + c
dx
dy b2 lb2
dx x=-b/3a 3a
b2
= c — —~ which is > 0, since b2 < 3ac
3a
If x = —b/3a,
b
y = a\- + b\ + c - •F d
21a' 9 a' 3a,
2b3 be
Tla1 ~ 3a +
The line through the point ( — b/3a, 2b3/21a2 — (bc/3a) + d) and having slope
c — (b2/3a) is given by
y - yl = m(x- Xj)
2b3 be \ 1 b2\ I b
y - I ■ - — + d i = I c - —-11 x + —
21 a2 3a 3a 3a,
b2\ be b3 2 b3 be ,
y-'C~Ta)X + Ja-9ai + T7^~Ta + d
b2\
= c - — X - + d
3a 21a:
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 251
EXAMPLE
y
Average cost: v = - = ax
h~ i c
-f -
x x
dy ,__
Marginal average cost: — = — l)x
U
Total cost is represented by the first quadrant part of an algebraic curve, average cost is
represented by the first quadrant branch of a hyperbola, and marginal cost is represented by
the first quadrant part of an algebraic curve (see Figure 2.56).
Figure 2.56
y
252 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
This type of simple polynomial curve is always concave upward for x > 0 and thus in
practice is usually appropriate only for limited ranges of x.
dy
= 0 if a(b — l)xb = c
dx
1 lb
x =
a(b — 1)
dy2 2c
= a(b - 1 )(b ~ 2)xb~3 +
dx" ' '' ' x'
>0
1 /b
so minimum at x =
a(b — 1)
Note that average cost and marginal cost are equal if x = (c/a(b — l))1/b, since
(b-l)/b / ^ \-l lb
y = a\ + c
a(b - 1), a(b — 1);
(■b~ 1 )/b
a + c
a(b — 1), ci(b — l)y
(b - l)/b
[a 4- a(b — 1)]
ya(b — l)y
(b~ 1 )lb
= ab I
a(b — l)y
and
(b- l)/b
d£ = ab[^T),
EXAMPLE
v aebx
Average cost: y — - = —-
x x
Figure 2.57
y
Total cost is represented by the first quadrant part of an exponential curve, average cost is
represented by the first quadrant branch of an exponential hyperbola, and marginal cost is
represented by the first quadrant part of an exponential curve (see Figure 2.57).
Exponential and logarithmic curves are either concave upward or concave downward for
all x > 0 and thus in practice are usually appropriate only for limited ranges of x.
^- = 0 if aeb*(bx - 1) = 0
dx
1
X~b
dy2 (abebx + ab2xebx — abebx)x2 — (abxebx — aebx)( 2x)
dx2 x4
axebx(b2x2 — 2 bx + 2)
If x = 1 /b, then
£*(1-2 + 2)
dy2
dx2 I
¥
= ab2e > 0
254 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
so minimum at x = l/b. Note that average cost and marginal cost are equal if x = 1 /b, since
y = abe
and
PROBLEMS
1. For each of the following average cost functions, find the minimum average cost and show
that at the minimum average cost, marginal cost and average cost are equal.
a. y = 25 — 8x + x2 e. y — 2x + 5 + -
b. y = 2 + x \n x f. y = 20 + 2x2 +-4x4
, c
d. y — 3x + 5 H—
6 , _ , _ 36
h. y — 6x + 7 + —
x
2. For each of the following total cost functions, find marginal cost and determine the nature
of marginal cost (increasing, decreasing).
a. y = lOOOx - 180x2 + 3x3 b. y = 220 + 55x - 2x3 + x4
3. Determine the nature of the marginal and average cost functions (increasing, decreasing)
for each of the following total cost functions.
a. y = yJx + 25, 0 < x < 10 b. y = 9x + 5xe~2x
4. For the following total cost function, find the equation of the tangent at the point of
inflection as an approximation of the function near that point.
y = x3 — 6x2 + 14x + 6
5. The Precision Machine Tool Manufacturing Company has a total cost function repre¬
sented by the equation yc = 2x3 — 3x2 — 12x, where y represents cost and x represents
quantity.
a. What equation represents the marginal cost function?
b. What is the equation for the average cost function? At what point is average cost at its
minimum?
c. Is this a set of equations one might realistically expect to find in practice? Why?
6. The Minute Man Colonial Furniture Company’s total revenue function is expressed by the
equation R = 24x — 3x2, where R represents revenue and x represents quantity.
a. What is the maximum revenue the company can expect, assuming this equation is
valid?
b. What equation represents the average revenue function?
c. What equation represents the marginal revenue function?
d. On one graph, plot the total, average, and marginal revenue functions.
7. Arto Company manufactures cabinets for TV sets; the total cost of producing a certain
model is given by y = 4x — x2 4- 2x3, where y represents total cost and x represents
quantity, in thousands of units. The sales department has indicated that between 2 and 6
units (in thousands) should be produced. At what quantity is marginal cost a minimum?
Explain your answer, and graph the marginal cost curve.
8. If the general formula for the total cost function is
9. An important generalization is often made about the relationships between the total
revenue (TR), average revenue (/!/?), and marginal revenue (MR) functions:
a. Illustrate this with an example from your reading or an example from the text.
b. Work out the analogous relationships for the total cost (TC), average cost (AC), and
marginal cost (MC) functions.
10. Henderson and Quandt in their book Microeconomic Theory state the following*:
“A monopolist is free to select any price-quantity combination which lies on his nega¬
tively sloped demand curve. Since an expansion of his output results in a reduction of his
price, his MR is less than his price. His first-order condition for profit maximization
requires the equality of MR and MC. His second-order condition requires that MC be
increasing more rapidly than MJR.” (Note that increasing more rapidly is logically equiva¬
lent to decreasing less rapidly.)
Which, if any, of the three diagrams in Figure 2.58 satisfies both conditions?
Figure 2.58
y y y
b- y’min 2
e
C. y • = 23/2
d. ymin = 5 + 6/2
e. J’min = 17
f- J’min = 20
§• 3’min ^
h- Jmin = 7 + 12/6
3. a. for 0 < x < 10, marginal and average cost always decreasing
b. marginal cost decreasing for x < 1 and increasing for x > 1; average cost always decreas¬
ing; yc -» 9 as x -> x
5. a. MC = 6x2 — 6x — 12
9. b. when MC = 0, TC is maximum
when MC > AC, AC is increasing
when MC < TC, TC is decreasing
when MC = TC, AC is unchanging
ELASTICITY
It is frequently of interest to consider the relative change in the dependent variable
which results from a small relative change in the independent variable. The ratio of
the relative change in the dependent variable, y, to the relative change in the indepen¬
dent variable, x, is referred to as the elasticity of y with respect to x. The elasticity of y
with respect to x measures the responsiveness of y to changes in x. Because relative
changes are used in the definition of elasticity, the elasticity of a function is dimen¬
sionless. That is, elasticity is independent of the units in which the variables are
measured. Elasticities are frequently used in measuring the responsiveness of demand
or supply to changes in price or income.
There are two types of measurement of elasticity, arc elasticity and point elasticity.
Arc elasticity measures the elasticity of a function between two points, that is, over an
arc. Unfortunately, the definition of arc elasticity is somewhat ambiguous, as dis¬
cussed below. However, for a continuous function of a continuous variable, point
elasticity, the elasticity of a function at a specific point, can be defined
unambiguously.
If y = /(x), the elasticity of y with respect to x is defined by
Ey _ Ay /Ax x Ay
Ex y y Ax
Ay dy
where, as Ax -* 0, . Elasticity is frequently denoted by t].
Ax dx
In general, the elasticity of a function varies over its range. For example, in Figure
2.59, note that elasticity of the function over the two arcs noted is not the same;
Ay Ay' x xr Ey Ey'
although — = ——, -7^— and thus —y- ^—7. Figure 2.59 also illustrates the
Ax Ax y y Ex Ex
ambiguity in defining arc elasticity since, for example, it is not clear whether
Xj/yq or x2/y2 should be used for x/y.
The following formulas are frequently used for measuring arc elasticity between
the points (xx, yt) and (x2, y2).
El = *1 . ZlTZ1 = . Ay
Ex yx x2 — xx yx Ax
Ry = *2 yi - y 1 _ *2
Ex y2 x2 — Xj y2 Ax
Ey = x! + x2 . y2 - yx _ xx -F x2 _ Ay
Ex yx + y2 x2 - xx yi + y2 Ax
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 257
Figure 2.59
y
The first formula is an approximation of the point elasticity at (x1} yj. The second
formula is an approximation of the point elasticity at (x2, y2). The third formula is
the average of the first two and is probably the most commonly used.
For point elasticity, this ambiguity does not arise. The point elasticity ofy = /(x)
at (xl9 yx) is
Ey = x± dy
Ex Vi
J 1
dx xi>
y yi
dy
= Ey = -L = x. dy
Ex dx y dx
x
The ratio of the derivative of a function to the function itself is called the logarith¬
mic derivative of the function; that is, if y =f (x), then
dy
f'(x) dx 1 dy d
In y
f(x) y ydx dx
is the logarithmic derivative of /(x). The elasticity of the function y —f{x) at the
point x is the ratio of the logarithmic derivative of y to the logarithmic derivative of
x:
1 dy
Ey y dx x dy
Ex 1 dx y dx
In x
dx x dx
Figure 2.60
y y y
y y
A ✓V
The classical and by far most frequent use of the concept of elasticity is in analyz¬
ing the responsiveness of demand for a commodity to changes in its price. Because
the slope of a demand curve is negative, its first derivative is negative, and thus rj < 0.
Since elasticity is dimensionless, the responsiveness of different commodity demands
to price changes can be compared. For this purpose, demand is frequently classified
in general categories as perfectly elastic (rj = — oo), relatively elastic (r/ < — 1), unit
elastic (r/ = — 1), relatively inelastic (— 1 < rj < 0), and perfectly inelastic (rj = 0).
The price elasticity of demand for a commodity is of interest to a firm; for
example, if demand is price elastic at a given price, a price decrease raises quantity
demanded proportionately more than the price decreases, so that total revenue,
which is the product of price and quantity, increases. When demand is unit elastic,
total revenue is unchanged by a decrease in price; when demand is inelastic, total
revenue is decreased by an increase in price. Demand curves having differing elastici¬
ties are shown in Figure 2.60. Note, however, that elasticity is not generally constant
over the range of a function; note also that slope is only one aspect of elasticity and
should not be equated with elasticity.
The concept of cross elasticity is useful as a measure of the relationship between
the demands for two or more commodities. Cross elasticity measures the respon¬
siveness of demand for one commodity to changes in the price of another commo¬
dity. The elasticity of demand for A with respect to price of B is defined as
dx*
Ex* = Xj_ = Ib . dxj
EyB dye xA dyB
yB
and arc cross elasticity as yB changes from ytt[ to yBl and xA changes from xAl to x l2
is given by
Exj = yBi + yB2 . xa2 ~
EyB xAl + xA2 y„2 - yBl
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 259
where the x^’s are the quantities of A, the yB’s are the prices of B, and the price of A is
assumed to be constant. The elasticity of demand for B with respect to price of A is
similarly defined.
When commodities are substitutes for each other, their cross elasticities are posi¬
tive. For example, when the price of butter increases, the consumption of margarine
also increases, assuming that the price of magarine and other relevant factors remain
constant. When commodities are complementary to each other, their cross elastici¬
ties are negative. For example, when the price of lettuce increases, the consumption
of salad dressing decreases, assuming that other relevant factors remain constant.
note: Demand functions are customarily written with price as the dependent
variable and quantity demanded as the independent variable and are graphed in a
corresponding manner. However, in analyses involving demand elasticities, demand
is logically considered to be the dependent variable and price the independent
variable. In the examples below, the demand function is given in one form in some
cases and in the other form in other cases and is represented graphically in both
forms. When a demand function is given in the form y = /(x) and it is not convenient
dx
to solve for x, — can be obtained by implicit differentiation.
dy
Because demand functions are conventionally written y = /(x), where y is price
dx
and x is quantity demanded, and the elasticity of demand involves the derivative —,
dy
equations and graphs must be read carefully to avoid misinterpretation.
EXAMPLE
The demand function for a particular commodity is given by y = yj{20 — x)/2 for 0 < x < 20,
where y is price per unit and x is number of units demanded. Consider the point y = 2, x = 12.
If the price decreases by 6%, determine the corresponding increase in demand and an approxi¬
mation to the elasticity of demand at the point y = 2, x = 12; compare this with the exact
elasticity of demand at the point y = 2, x = 12. Then compute an approximation to the
elasticity of demand and the exact elasticity of demand at the point representing the changed
price and quantity; also compute the arc elasticity based on average price and quantity (see
Figure 2.61).
Figure 2.61
y
260 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.62
X
y2 = i{20 - X)
x = 20 — 2 y2
See Figure 2.62.
y1=2 y2 = 2 - (0.06)(2) = 1.88 Ay = -0.12
xx = 12 x2 = 20 - 2(1.88)2 = 12.94 Ax - 0.94
Arc elasticity of demand at y — 2, x = 12, is
Ex yx Ax
Ey Xx Ay
_ 2 / 0.94\
“12\ Oil)
= -1.31
Point elasticity of demand at y = 2, x = 12, is
Ex y dx
Ey x dy
20 - 2y2 ^ 4y^
2 y2
y2 -10
Figure 2.63
Ex
Ey
Ex _ 2y2
Yy = y2 - 10
Ex
-1.09
Ey y= 1.88
Ex _ yi + y2 x2 — 3.88 / 0.94\
Ey Xi + x2 yi ~ yi 24.94\ 0.12/
= -1.22
EXAMPLE
q = 5 + l^fp
where q is the demand for margarine (hundreds of pounds) and p is the price of butter (dollars
per pound). Find the equation for cross elasticity of demand for margarine with respect to
price of butter. What is the demand for margarine when butter is $0.81 per pound ? What is the
demand for margarine when butter is $1.00 per pound ? What is the cross elasticity of demand
for margarine as butter goes from $0.81 to $1.00 per pound? (See Figure 2.64.)
Solving the demand equation for p,
q = 5 + 2 y/p
\/P=i(q - 5)
Figure 2.64
4
Eq dq p 1 p
EP dp q Jp 5 + 2 jp
=
5 + 2 Vp
See Figure 2.66.
Figure 2.66
Eq
Ep
P
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 263
Cross elasticity is
Eq _ \fp
Ep 5 + 2^/p
For p = 0.81,
Eq _ 0.9 09
= 0.13
Ep p = o.8i _ 5 + 2(0.9) 08
For p = 1.00,
Eq 1 _ 1
0.14
Ep p= i.oo 5 + 2 7
then
— = —amy 1
dy
Ex y dx
Ey x dy
= —m
EXAMPLE
Figure 2.67
Determine the elasticity of demand. Consider the point y — 2, x = -fj; if the price increases by
5 percent, determine arc elasticity at the point y = 2, x = f|, and at the point representing the
changed price and quantity (see Figure 2.67).
Solving the demand equation for y,
25
X = -4
y
nr
See Figure 2.68. *
Figure 2.68
v
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 265
Figure 2.69
Ex
Ey
dx —100
dy y5
Ex y dx
Ey x dy
-100\
- y f
25 1 V5 )
/
= -4
as could be obtained
2.69.
yi = 2 yi =
25
Xj = 1.56 X2 = = 1.29 Ax = -0.27
(2-1 Y
For the point yx = 2,
Ex _y i . Ax
Ey X! Ay
2 / -0.27
~ 1.56 \ 0.1
= -3.46
Ex _y 2 Ax
Ey x2 Ay
2.1 / -0.27
“ 1.29 ( 0.1 ,
= -4.40
PROBLEMS
1. For each of the following demand functions, i. determine arc elasticity at the point specified,
ii. determine arc elasticity at the point corresponding to the specified change in price or
266 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
demand, iii. determine point elasticity at the two points, iv. determine arc elasticity based
dy dx
on average quantities and prices, and v. show that — and — are reciprocals of each other.
dx dy
a. x =
60 - 2y2; x = 10, y = 5; price decrease 8%
b. x +
2y = 15; x = 7, y = 4; price increase 5%
c. x =
25 — 5y2; x = 5, y = 2; price increase 5%
d. x =
10 - 5y2; x = 5, y = 1; price increase 10%
e. y = (x — 10)2; 0 < x < 10; x = 8, y = 4; demand decrease 5%
f. x = 19 - 4y2; x = 3, y = 2; price decrease 5%
g. x = 36 - 4y2; x = 20, y = 2; price increase 5%
h. y = (x — 4)2; x = 1, y = 9; demand increase 30%
2. Find elasticity of demand, y, with respect to price, x, for each of the following functions.
3 d. y = 13c (5/4)*
a- y =
1 + 2x2
10
e- x - ^574
b. y = (x — 8)2, 0 < x < 8
Ex y dx
Ey x dy
, . dx 1
and, since — = —,
dy dy
dx
Ex _ y J_\
Ey x dy
dx I
<fy = _ y
dx Ex
x
Ey 1
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 267
Thus
dR
+ T
dx Ex
j_\
Ex
Ey,
Alternatively,
dR
dx
+y
x dy
y ~“7
ydx
+ 1
j_\
y 1+ Ex
Ey,
That is, marginal revenue is the product of the price per unit quantity demanded and
one plus the reciprocal of the elasticity of demand.
Since both x and y are either zero or positive, the total revenue, R = xy, is also
either zero or positive; however, the marginal revenue may be either positive or
negative.
R = xy = y ■ g(y) = G{y)
dR
+x
dy
This would perhaps be simpler for cases when the demand function is in the form
x = g(y) and it is not easy to solve for y in terms of x. However, to keep the
geometrical representation consistent (that is, to use x as the independent variable), it
dR d2R
is preferable to use implicit differentiation and the chain rule to obtain and
dx dx2
when the demand function is in the form x = g(y).
EXAMPLE
Figure 2.70
R
dR
dx
X
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 269
Thus R = x( 12 — x)1/2 is concave downward for 0 < x < 12. See Figure 2.70.
Ex y dx
Ey x dy
= -/-
xl dy
\dx
(12-x) 1/2 1
X —i (12 — x) “I/2
-2(12 - x)
dR /, 1 \
1+
\ Ey /
= (12 - x)1/2 1 -
2(12 - x)
3(8 — x)
(as above)
2(12-x)1/2
EXAMPLE
dR ■ x/3
= — Sxe x/3 + 15c
dx
= 5e */3(3 — x)
45
= 0 if x = 3, R = —
e
d2R
= -t<T*/3(3 - x) - 5e~xl3
dx2
= 5e Jc/3(^x — 2)
45
< 0 if x = 3, so maximum at x = 3, R — — « 16.6
e
= 0 if x = 6
270 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.71
0=-^x-2) + |,--
= 5e_x/3(l — ^x) >0 if x = 6
90
so point of inflection at x = 6, R = « 12.2. See Figure 2.71.
e
Ex y dx
Ey x dy
15 e~x/3{ 1 \
x \ — 5e~x/3)
_ 3
x
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 271
dR
dx
y 1 +
Ey
= 15e~x/3
PROBLEMS
1. When Mr. Smythe’s income was $300 per month he bought 20 qt of milk per month. When
his income increased to $350 per month he bought 24 qt of milk per month. Assuming no
change in the price of milk or other relevant factors, what was Mr. Smythe’s income
elasticity of demand for milk?
2. When the price of A was $5.00, 100 units of B were sold. When the price of A fell to $4.00,
120 units of B were sold. What is the cross elasticity of demand for A in terms of the price of
£? Are A and B substitutes or complements?
3. What is the relation between the slope (positive or negative) of the average cost curve and
the elasticity of total cost?
4. Demonstrate algebraically that the elasticity of total cost is equal to
„ MC
Etc~ac
dR
dx 1 + ~k
Ey
e. y = 100 — 6x2
c. y = 17 — 6x
6. Show that if demand is linear and negatively sloped, the elasticity of total revenue is always
less than 1, but to the left of its maximum value the elasticity of total revenue is positive and
to the right of the maximum value the elasticity of total revenue is negative.
Figure 2.72
y> yt
equilibrium under the following conditions: there is pure competition in which the
consumers’ demand depends only on price, the demand function does not change, the
producers adjust the supply curve to the new price which includes the tax, and a tax
of t monetary units is imposed on each unit of quantity produced.
The supply function can be represented by
y = g(x)
where x is the number of units of the commodity supplied and y is the price per unit.
If a tax of t per unit quantity is imposed, the supply function after taxation is
y, = g(x) +1
If the demand function is
y =/M
then the equilibrium point before taxation, E(x, y), is the solution of the equations
Demand: y =f(x)
Supply: y = g(x)
and the equilibrium point after taxation, E(xt, y,), is the solution of the equations
Demand: y = /(x)
Supply: yt = g(x) + t
See Figure 2.72.
note: If the supply function before taxation is in the form
x = G(y)
it may be possible to solve for y in a convenient form. If not, the supply function after
taxation,
y,-t = g(x)
The total tax revenue T received by the government from a tax of t per unit
quantity is
T — txt
where x, is the equilibrium quantity after taxation. This total may be represented by
the area of a rectangle of dimensions t and x,, which, if the supply function is linear, is
equivalent to the parallelogram in Figure 2.72. As this diagram indicates, the tax may
be large enough to reduce demand to the vanishing point. If the government is
interested in taxation for revenue purposes, the question is what amount of tax will
maximize revenue—if the tax t is considered as a variable, then there is no revenue if
t = 0 and there is also no revenue if t is large enough so that demand is zero; for some
intermediate value of t the tax revenue T = txt is maximum. Since T may be con¬
sidered a function of either t or x, maximum revenue possible from taxation can be
determined by considering marginal tax revenue with respect to either t or x. It is
usually more convenient to consider T as a function of x, since t occurs linearly in the
relation between t and x.
EXAMPLE
Demand: 2y + x = 14
3 x
Supply: y = - + -
Determine the maximum possible revenue from taxation which can be obtained from a tax of t
per unit quantity and the corresponding tax rate.
The supply function after taxation is y = | + (x/3) + t. Thus, after taxation, at equilibrium,
x 3 x
y= 7 — = —i-hr
2 4 3
t =
25
lx
T = tx = ^x — |x2
dT 25 5v
= '~ J*
dx
15
= 0 if x = ~4T
d2T Oc 15
— ~3 < 0, so maximum at x ~sr
dx2
25
If X :- 15 tt —
— ~r
25 — i«) — Ts , and T 375
= ~JT- So the maximum possible revenue from
taxation is Tmax = obtained from a tax of t = ^ per unit quantity. (See Figure 2.73.)
274 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.73
y> yt
Alternatively,
* = ¥ - jt
r = 1it- ft2
dT _ 15 12,
~dt~ 2 " 5t
=0 if t = f
d2T
-p- = — Ap < 0, so maximum at t = ^
EXAMPLE
Figure 2.74
y
Alternatively,
/21 -t
x =
3
27 - t\ 1/2
T=t\
3 )
/27t2 - t3'
( 3 )
(21 - t \ -11/2
(18 -0
=0 if t = 18
-m
t (21 - t\ ~3/2
= — — I—^—I <0 if t — 18, so maximum at t - 18
T — 11 Q°
27 - 18\1/2
1 max ) = 18^3
yc = xyc
(Note that in previous sections y has been used to denote price in some contexts and
cost in others; the subscript c is used here to differentiate cost from price.)
Presumably the monopolist will control the supply x and thus the price y
(determined by the demand function) so as to maximize his profit. The total revenue
he receives is
R = xy
where y =/(x); the total profit P is the difference between total revenue and total
cost
P = R- yc = xy - xyc
P has a relative maximum if and only if
dP dR dyc
= 0 that is
dx dx dx
and
d2P d2R d2yc
—y < 0 that is
dx dx2 dx2
In order to be meaningful this maximum must occur in the interval for which the cost
and demand functions have economic significance.
EXAMPLE
dP
—— = 18 — 6x — 12x2
dx
= 0 if 2x2 + x — 3 = 0
(2x + 3)(x — 1) = 0
x = 1
(x = — \ is not meaningful for this problem.)
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 277
d2P
— 6 — 24x
dx2
< 0 if x = 1, so maximum at x = 1
1P max =11
A A
Alternatively,
dR
= 26 — 4x — 12x2
dx
dye
2x + 8
dx
dR dyc
if 26 — 4x — 12x2 = 2x + 8
dx dx
2x2 + x - 3 = 0
(2x + 3)(x — 1) = 0
x = 1
d2R
-4 24x1
dx2 ' d2R d2yc
if x = 1, so maximum at x = 1
I dx2 < dx2
EXAMPLE
y = 28 — 5x
and the total cost to the monopolist of producing and marketing the commodity is
yc = x2 + 4x
= 24x — 6x2
dP
24 12x
dx
dP
0 if 2 — x = 0
dx
x = 2
d2P
-12 <0, so maximum at x = 2
dx2
P
1 max 24
278 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Alternatively,
^ = 28 - lOx
dx
l- = 2*
dx
+4
O' 1 X
if 28 — lOx = 2x + 4
II
'">3
x = 2
P =24
or alternatively,
x = ?(28 — y)
R = iy(28 - y)
= y?(28 - y)(48 - y)
dR 28 2,,
—
— s — ^y
dy
= ~t?(48 — y) — y?(28 — y)
dyc 2 76
25
dR dyc if 18 _ 2 _ _2_ _ 76
11 5 5/ — 254 25
dy dy
y = 18
d2R
dy2
d2R d2yc
< ——2“, so maximum at y = 18
d2yc dy2 dy“
25
dy2
Tmax = R - yc = 36 - 12 = 24
Figure 2.75
Hyc
If the marginal revenue and marginal cost curves are drawn on the same diagram,
they intersect at a point which gives the value of x corresponding to maximum profit.
If the demand curve y =f{x) and the average cost curve yc = g(x) are also drawn on
the diagram, the vertical distance between them is y — yc. For any given value of x,
the area of the rectangle of height y — yc and width x represents profit; this area is
greatest for the value of x where the marginal revenue and marginal cost curves
intersect (see Figure 2.76).
Figure 2.76
_ dy dR
y'y" a
280 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
yCt = yc + tx
P = R — yCt = R — yc — tx
dP dR dy^
-0 that is
dx dx dx
and
Since the marginal cost curve after taxation is the marginal cost curve before taxation
translated upward a distance t, the amount produced for maximum profit will be
decreased and the price increased after taxation. (See Figure 2.77).
The total revenue received by the government is
T — tx
where x is the amount produced after the tax is imposed. T is again a function of t
and is zero if t is either zero or large enough to tax the product out of the market.
Thus T has a maximum value obtainable in the usual way. As before, a subsidy may
be considered a negative tax and the general analysis is unchanged.
Figure 2.77
dyc dyc> dR
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 281
EXAMPLE
y = 20 - 4x
(a) If a tax of t per unit quantity is imposed on the monopolist, determine his maximum
possible profit and the value of t for which tax revenue is maximized.
(b) Determine the monopolist’s maximum possible profit if a 33^% sales tax is imposed.
Demand: y = 20 — 4x
Average cost: yc = 2
Total cost: yc = 2x
dP
= 18 — t — 8x
dx
dP „ .f 18 — f 22 + f
0 it x = —-—, y =
dx 8 ’ J 2
d2P 18 - t
= —8, so maximum if x =
dx2 8
(18-0:
16
r( 18 - t)
Tax revenue: T = tx =
_ 18 - 2r 9 — t
li ~ 8 "
=0 if r = 9
^2T
—i < 0, so maximum if t = 9
dt2
If t = 9,
p _ 81
■* max T5
rp _ 81
••max ”8”
(b) Demand function: y = 20 - 4x. So the price paid the monopolist after allowing for
33^% sales tax is
yt = |(20 — 4x)
282 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Figure 2.78
P
<-*—i
o
Ut
Oh
- X
Quantity
- 13x — 3x2
dP
= 13 — 6x
dx
-0 if x = -t?
d_2p 13
- —6, so maximum if x = “5“
dx2
P _ 169
' max 1 2
EXAMPLE
y = 14 — 3x
yc = x2 4- 5x
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 283
(a) If a tax of t per unit quantity is imposed on the monopolist, determine his maximum
possible profit, the change in price, and the tax revenue received by the government as a
function of t.
(b) Determine the maximum tax revenue obtainable by the government.
Demand: y = 14 — 3x
Total cost: yc = x2 + 5x
= (9 — t)x — 4x2
dP
= 9 — t — 8x
dx
n 9 -t 85 3
= o l{x- — ,y=.T +r
d2p q . 9-t
—2 = —8, so maximum n x =
dx' 8
P
1 max Jlzjl. 41 9-t)
g ^1
T
_ (9 ~ tf
16
Figure 2.79
o
u.
CL,
X
284 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
dT _9 _ i
_ 8 4
—so maximum if r = §
df2
1(9 - f) _ 72
81
T - —
8
PROBLEMS
1. Plot the demand curve y = 120 — x and the supply curve y = x — 10, where x is quantity
demanded and y is price per unit, and indicate the equilibrium price and quantity, a.
Assume that a tax of $15 per unit is imposed on the seller; draw the new supply curve and
indicate the new equilibrium, b. Assume that instead of a tax, a subsidy of $10 is paid to the
producers; draw the appropriate supply curve and indicate the corresponding equilibrium.
2. For each of the following pairs of demand and supply functions find the maximum revenue
that can be obtained by imposing a tax of t per unit and illustrate graphically (by sketching
the demand curve, the supply curves before and after taxation, and the revenue curve).
a. Demand: y = 14 — 3x d. Demand: y = 28 — x2
Supply: y = 4 + 2x Supply: y — 4 + x2
b. Demand: y — 25 — 2x2 e. Demand: y = 45 — x2
Supply: y = 5 + x Supply: y = 6 + 2x
c. Demand: y — 50 — 4x2 f, Demand: y = 30 — 2x2
Supply: y = 5 + x2 Supply: v = 3 + x2
3. For each of the following pairs of demand and (average or total) cost functions find the
maximum profit obtainable by a monopolist.
a. y = 24 — 7x d. y = 12 — 5x
yc = 6 — x yc = 4x 4- 6
b. y = 26 — 3x2 e. y = 26 — 2x 4x:
yc = 3x2 + 2x + 14 yc = x + 8
c. y = 12 — 4x
yc = 8x — x2
4. For each of the following pairs of demand and cost functions find i. change in price,
maximum profit, and maximum revenue from taxation as functions of t if an additive tax of
t per unit is imposed on a monopolist and determine the maximum revenue that can be
obtained by such taxation, and ii. find the maximum revenue that can be obtained by the
specified sales tax.
a. y = 50 — 6x d. y = 33 — 5x2
yc = x2 + 9x 4c = 3x2
Sales tax 20% Sales tax 10%
b. y = 25 — 2x2 e. y = 20 — 4x
yc = 3x 4c = 2
Sales tax 25% Sales tax 33^%
c. y = 12 - 4x f. y = 72 - lx2
yc = 2x 4c = *2
Sales tax 33^% Sales tax 40%
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 285
b p 50
1 max = ^9“
C P 4
= 3
v* 1 max
d P
1 max = 1
e 1P max = 11
INVENTORY MODELS
The objective of inventory control is to minimize total inventory cost. Inventory
costs are of three types: (1) cost of placing an order or starting a production run
(setup cost); (2) cost of holding inventory, including cost of capital or interest and
storage cost (carrying cost); and (3) cost of going short, including loss of goodwill
(shortage cost). Inventory control attempts to balance the economies of large orders
or large production runs against the cost of holding inventory and, in some models,
against the cost of going short.
In practice, various situations occur with respect to the nature of demand, the
procedures involved in ordering or production, the ease of storage, the seriousness of
shortages, and so forth. All the inventory models discussed in this book (including
two in this section and one in Chapter 3) assume that demand is known and uniform.
This assumption may be appropriate, at least as an approximation, in many situa¬
tions involving demand for an input of production; however, it is entirely unrealistic
in many situations involving retail demand. For these latter situations a model
assuming probabilistic demand is more appropriate.
The models in this book also assume that the setup cost, the per unit carrying cost,
and the per unit shortage cost do not depend on the number of items involved.
Neither of the two models discussed in this section permits shortages; each of them
can be derived as a special case of a model that does permit shortages by letting the
shortage cost become very large. The first model assumes that items enter inventory
in batches; the second model assumes that items enter inventory continuously during
the period of ordering or production.
Model A: uniform demand, no shortages, batch arrival
D = demand per period
cx = setup cost
c2 = carrying cost per item per period
q = number of items placed in inventory at one time
(See Figure 2.80.)
Figure 2.80
286 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
There are D/q batches per period for which the total setup cost is (cx D)/q. The
average inventory is q/2 and the carrying cost per period is (c2 q)/2. The total cost of
inventory per period is thus
Cj D
C=
<7
dC c2 cxD
dq 2 q2
dC
If
dq
d2C _ 2cxD
dq2 q3
>0
c2q
c2(q ~ Dti)
2 2
Figure 2.81
2.12 Applications of Derivatives in Business and Economics / 287
and the setup cost is c^D/q). So the total inventory cost per period is
d2C _ 2c1 D
>0
dq2 q3
EXAMPLE
Alicor needs 2500 widgets per quarter. It costs $3.00 a month to store a widget. The cost of
ordering a supply of widgets (any number of widgets not exceeding 2500) is $0.50. Alicor has
two alternatives: (1) purchase the widgets periodically in lots and allow no shortages to occur
and (2) purchase the widgets periodically from a supplier who sends them continuously at the
rate of 1500 per month until an order is filled and allow no shortages to occur. Determine the
quarterly cost of the optimal policy for each of these alternatives. In order to minimize total
quarterly cost of inventory, what policy should Alicor adopt?
Considering demand and costs on a quarterly basis,
D = 2500
Ci - 0.50
c2 = 9.00
k = 4500
2c i D (2)(0.50)(2500) _ 50
q =
c2 9 “ 3
2c i D (2)(0.50)(2500)
q rw i 2 5 00\
= 25
D
c2 1 -
Cj D i(2500)
C + “ =i(9)(25)(l-|)+ 25 - 100
For this problem, demand, supply and costs could be considered on a monthly basis. Since
demand and supply are assumed to be uniform, any convenient common time base can be used
for computation.
PROBLEMS
1. The Ace Manufacturing Company has a contract to supply 4000 refrigerators a year at a
uniform monthly rate. The annual storage cost per refrigerator is $50 and the setup cost for
a production run is $160. If production is instantaneous and shortages are not permitted,
determine the number of refrigerators which should be produced in each run in order to
minimize the total annual cost of inventory.
2. The Harvest Company has a contract to supply 500 tractors a month at a uniform daily
rate. The monthly storage cost per tractor is $10 and the setup cost for a production run is
$200. Production is at a constant rate of 1000 tractors per month. If shortages are not
permitted, determine the number of tractors which should be produced in each run to
minimize the total monthly inventory cost.
3. Profitco Electronics requires 25 transistors per month to make color TV sets. The monthly
storage cost is $2.00 per transistor and every time an order is placed it costs Profitco $4.00.
a. If orders are filled immediately and no shortages are permitted, how many orders of what
size should be placed every month? What is the monthly total cost of this inventory policy?
b. Suppose Profitco can order so that delivery is at the rate of 45 per month (in a uniform
flow, not a block) and that no shortages are permitted. How much inventory should be
accumulated before stopping the flow and how many times per month will the flow be
stopped? What is the total monthly cost of this inventory policy?
4. Fabric Corporation owns a machine which can produce 25 bolts of a particular type of
cloth per day and another machine which can make 10 bolts of this cloth into slipcovers per
day. It costs $1.50 to hold a bolt of cloth in inventory for a day and it costs $2.00 every time
the machine producing the cloth must be stopped, a. What amount of inventory should be
built up before the machine producing the cloth is stopped in order to minimize total
inventory cost ? b. How many times will the machine be shut down in a period of 90 days ? c.
What is the total amount of cloth that will be produced in a period of 90 days? d. If the
demand and cost conditions remain the same, except that the cost of stopping the machine
is interpreted as the cost of ordering, and the cloth must be ordered in batches from another
company, how many orders of what size will be placed in 90 days (assume no shortages)?
5. The yearly demand for a large cable bolt produced by Lanier Corporation is 9000. It costs
Lanier $1000 to put the production line for this cable into operation. The monthly cost of
carrying this item in inventory is $6000. Assuming that Lanier does not permit shortages to
occur, how many cable bolts should be produced per production run and how frequently
should production be stopped?
6. Bookworms Cooperative stocks a very popular gourmet cookbook for which there is a
demand of 1500 copies per month. The publisher pays postage, but the cooperative pays
$2.50 for each order in secretarial and administrative costs. Carrying cost is $0.50 per copy
per month. In order to minimize total inventory cost, how many books should be ordered
at one time? How frequently should orders be placed?
is discussed for certain particular types of functions f(x). In this section more general
procedures for evaluating these and other indeterminate forms are discussed. These
procedures are based on L'HospitaFs rule:
I /(«) = g(a) = o
or
If Jf{a) = g(a) = 00
U
then r
lim f(x) rhm —/
—= f'(x)(
x-*a g(X) x-+a d(x)
and
r f\x)
lim —T-r exists
>a g'(x)
(this rule holds for finite or infinite a). If lim — is itself an indeterminate form ^ or
x->a g(x) 0
oo f'(x) f"(x)
—, then L’Hospital’s rule is applied again and lim = lim v and so forth.
oo ■a g'(x) g"(x)
CAUTIONS
i 1- f'(x) d (f(x)\ . . .
1. hm —~~ # hm — ——- , that is, the quotient of the derivatives is not in general
x-ag(x) X^adx \g(x)l
equal to the derivative of the quotient.
EXAMPLE
Evaluate lim
y4Th-2
h-*0 h
0 4 + h- 2 r i(4 + h)~1/2 1
type -, so lim
h-> 0 h “ h-0 1 = 4
EXAMPLE
ex — (1 + x)
Evaluate lim
*-*•0
0 ex - (1 + x) O'
type - , so lim -5- lim ——— also type
U v —► o X x~* o 2x 0,
r ex 1
2 2
290 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
EXAMPLE
In x
Evaluate lim
X~> 00 X
oo .. In x
type —, so Inn lim !f* = 0
oo X y—► m A
EXAMPLE
x
Evaluate lim
X-* 00
1
00 X nx n-
, oo'
type —, so lim — = lim also type
oo x -* oo X-* oo 00;
n(n — l)x" 2 oo
= lim also type
X~* 00 00,
n
= • • • = lim ' = 0
X-00 ^
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following limits.
?y sin2 x
1. lim 12. lim
oo y x-0 X
X sin x — x
2. lim 13. lim
x-+ oo x->0 X
In x
3. lim (k > 0) 14. lim
x X-* 00 In x
px _ p x
4. lim —— 15. lim
x-o sin x X~* 00 x
ex — In (x 4- 1) — 1 ex — e x — 2 sin x
5. lim 16. lim
x-0 x x->0 3x3
sec x + 1 e2* - 1
6. lim 17. lim
x-*n/2 tan x x-o x — sin x
x2 + x — 1 2 — 3e~x + e~2x
7. lim 18. lim
x-oo er + e x-0 2x"
ex + e~x — 2
8. lim 19. lim
x-0 X-+O0
x4 — 4x3 + 16
9. lim (k > 0) 20. lim
X-* 00 x-2 x3 - 8
In x 4 — 3ex — e~3x
10. lim 21. lim
! X — 1
x-*0 4x2
x3 — 4x
11. lim ln(l~ v) 22. lim
x-+i cot nx x-2 x2 — 2x
2.13 Indeterminate Forms / 291
1 — cos t — \t
1 4.2
ex — 1
23. lim 33. lim ^2
t->o r x—0 X X
_3
r + 27
24. lim 34. lim -—
X-> 00 ex + x2 —2 x— — 3 x + 3
26. lim
X-* 00
4x2 + 3x — 6
8x + 2
36. lim COi
x_»o cot 2x
,V
4 y3 + 6y tan x — x
27. lim 37. lim-:-
o 3y3 + 2y x_o x — sin x
In sin x
28. lim 38. lim --
X-* 00 x-jt/2 (n ~ 2x)
sin z2 — sin2 z sin x — sin d>
29. lim 39. lim -—~
r-0 z x-<*> x ~ V
1 - sin 2x ey + sin y - 1
30. lim , t~a\- 40. lim —r—T.-r—
x-*/4 (n/4) - X y-o ln(l+y)
.1 1 + cos X ai v cot x
31. lim —-ry 41. lim —-
x-* (n - x) x-o In x
Type oo • 0:
Type 0°:
g(x) \ . 0
lim is of type -
x —a i
log/(x)
292 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
or
iiogf(x)\. co
lim ‘ is of type
x~>a 1 oo
9(x)
Type oo°:
If lim*^ f(x)g{x) = oo°, where limx^a f(x) = oo, limx_+a g(x) = 0, then
. g(x) \ . 0
lim /-— J is of type -
x-+a I t I O
log/(x)
or
. ,|og/(x)\. CO
lim I --—- I is of type —
x~+a 1 I oo
9(x)
EXAMPLE
= lim
X 00
EXAMPLE
In (1 - 2x)
type lx, so lim (1 — 2x)3/x = exp lim
x-*0 x-*0 x
3
In (1 — 2x)
lim = lim ————- = -6
x-*0 X x->0 1
3
lim (1 — 2x)3/x = e 6
x^O
EXAMPLE
cos x — sin x
ln (sin x + cos x) sin x + cos x 1
lim-- = lim ---= - = 1
x-0 x x-o 1 1
EXAMPLE
Evaluate limx^0+
ln x
type 0°, so lim xx = exp lim
x-*0 x-*0 +
In x
lim —— = lim = 0
x->0 + x-0
lim x* = e° = 1
x —0 +
EXAMPLE
-1
In (1 — x) 1 — x
lim — lim
cot nx esc nx
.. sin2 nx
— lim -—
x-1 X-l
= 0
lim (1 - x)tannx = e° = 1
X~>1
EXAMPLE
In x
type oo°, so lim x1/x = exp lim
*-► GO *“► 00
In x
lim lim 1/X = 0
X-» 00 X QQ X
lim x1,x = e° = 1
X-+ oo
EXAMPLE
1 +
In (x + ex) x + eJ
lim lim
X-+ 00 x *-►00 1
2 2
2(1 +
= lim
*-►00 x + ex
2ex
.1,8X
—
II
1 + ex
2ex
= lim - - 2
*-►00 e
lim (x + ex)2lx = e2
*-►00
2.13 Indeterminate Forms / 295
Type oo — oo:
If \imx^a [f(x) - g(x)] = oo - oo, where lim^ f(x) = oo, limx^a g(x) = oo,
then
Q(x) f(x) 0
lim / 1 1 ^1= lim is of type
x~>a 1 1 x->a 1 1 0
EXAMPLE
1 x — tan x
type oo — oo, so lim I cot x — lim
x-0 XI x— 0 x tan x
1 — sec2 x
lim
x-0 tan x + x sec2 x
— 2 sec2 x tan x
lim
x—0 sec2 x + sec2 x + 2x sec2 x tan x
— 2 tan x
lim
x-0 2(1 + x tan x)
EXAMPLE
QX — 1 — X
type oo - oo, so lim (- lim
x->0 x-> 0 x(ex - 1)
ex — 1
lim
x-* 0 ex + xex — 1
ex 1
lim
x-»0 ex + ex + xex 2
The types of indeterminate forms which can be evaluated using L’Hospital’s rule
are summarized in Table 2.1.
296 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
1. lim /(*) 0
lim /W
0
2. lim /(*) 00
g(x) 00
1 1
d(x) f(x)
7. lim [f(x) — g(x)] — oo — oo lim
1 1
g(x) f(x) I
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following limits.
1
6. lim (1 + x2)1,x2 17. lim ( 1
0
x-* 1 + \x - 1 ^x -
8. lim x In x
x-0
1
19. lim X \
x-l In x x — 1/
9. lim (1 + sin x)cotJC
x-0 20. lim (x — 1)<?
X-* 00
x-*-0 ^
47. lim esc xsin x
x->0 +
V* + 1
30. lim
x —0 X 48. lim x2 esc x
x-> 0
31. lim esc 7ix log x
x -* 1 ,.71 71(f)
49. lim — tan —
</>-0 0 2
32. lim (x — 2)e~*2
x —* 00
50. lim (1 + x2)1/x
x-» oo
33. limx2e_3x
x~* oo
51. lim x sin -
34. lim sin x log x X~* 00
x-*0 +
i™ (y - y.)
37. lim xcot nx 6~*( n/4-)
X- 1
3. 0 23. 0 41. 1
5. 0 25. 0 43. 1
9. e 29. -1 47. 1
11. 0 1 712
31. -- 49.
n 2
13. 1
33. 0 51. £7
15. e2
35. 0 53. 0
17. 00
37. e1/n 55. 11
19. ~11
298 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
S„ = ux + u2 + ■■■ + u„=
i= 1
and let S represent the limit of Sn as n -> 00,
00
S — lim Sn = Y, ui
n -* 00 i= 1
If the limit S exists finitely, the infinite series is convergent and is said to converge to
the value S; if the limit does not exist finitely, the infinite series is divergent. Diver¬
gence may occur because Sn becomes infinite as n -> 00 or because Sn oscillates
without approaching a limit as n ^ 00.
Infinite series are essential in calculating the values of many functions and can also
be used to define a number of useful functions. There are two problems generally
associated with infinite series: determining whether the limit of an infinite series
exists and determining the value of the limit, if it exists.
The problem of convergence is discussed before the use of infinite series in rep¬
resenting functions is considered. Establishing convergence or divergence of a series
is relatively straightforward if an expression for Sn can be obtained.
EXAMPLE
The first form is generally used if I r I < l; the second form is generally used if Irl > 1.
a
If | r | <1, lim rn = 0 and lim Sn - and the series is convergent.
n-+ oo n~* oo 1 -r
a — a + a — a + a — a + •••
and if n is odd, Sn = a; if n is even, Sn = 0. Such a series has no limit and is thus divergent; it is
referred to as an oscillating series.
note: It can be shown that the error involved in breaking a convergent alternat¬
ing series at any term does not exceed in absolute value the first of the terms
discarded. That is, if to — u2 + u3 — u4 -f • • • is a convergent alternating series, then
for any k,
00
< UL
n = k+ 1
3. Absolute convergence. A series of some positive and some negative terms is said to
be absolutely convergent if the series formed from it by making all its terms
positive is convergent. Other convergent series of some positive and some negative
terms are said to be conditionally convergent. If a series of some positive and some
negative terms is absolutely convergent, it is conditionally convergent, but the
converse is not necessarily true.
4. Cauchy's test-ratio test. Let
be an infinite series of positive terms. Using consecutive general terms un and un+1?
form the test ratio
Un+ 1
K
and let
un + 1
p = lim
n~* oo U„
300 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
Then
If p < 1, the series is convergent
If p > 1, the series is divergent
If p = 1, the test fails
5. Comparison tests. In many cases it is possible to determine whether a given series
is convergent or divergent by comparing it term by term with a series known to be
convergent or divergent. A series of positive terms is convergent if each of its terms
is equal to or less than the corresponding term of a known convergent series. A
series of positive terms is divergent if each of its terms is equal to or greater than
the corresponding term of a known divergent series. The geometric series dis¬
cussed above and the “p-series” are frequently useful in applying the comparison
test. The “p-series” is given by
1 1 1
1i + ^ + ^ + " * + ™ + ‘ * •
2p y nl
This series is convergent if p > 1 and divergent if p < 1. If p = 1, the p-series is the
harmonic series.
note: Since convergence or divergence of a series cannot be affected by the
omission of a finite number of terms, comparison tests may be applied to the terms
uk, uk+1, uk+2, ... rather than to the terms uuu2,u2,_
Assuming lim,,^ un = 0,
2. Apply the alternating-series test (if appropriate): An alternating series whose
terms decrease in numerical value and for which lim,,^ un = 0 is convergent.
P-series: 1 + Y” + y + '" + i +
Convergent if p > 1
Divergent if p < 1
2.14 Sequences and Series / 301
EXAMPLE
1 _ _3 5 _ 7
2 2? + 7? ~ 2* +
General term:
n+l2”-1
"n = (“I)
2"
lim un = 0
n -»> X
/ 2(n + 1) — 1 \
>n + 1
P = lim -= lim
n -► x n-» x 2rc — 1
2 "
2n + 1
= lim ) ~ lim (~i) — _i
X ” 2(2n - 1) / n -► x
EXAMPLE
n+l " + 1
K = (-1) 2n + 1
lim un — \
rt-+ x
EXAMPLE
1 1 1
V3 + ys yi + "'
General term:
i
un (-ir1
sj2n — 1
lim un — 0
rt X
302 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
and |m„+1 I < \un | for all n, so the alternating series is convergent.
I 1
+1 y/2(n+ 1) —T
p = lim lim
n oo Ur n~* ao 1
x/2n - 1 !
(2n — l)1/2\ _
= lim
n~* oo (2n + 1 )112) '
P |=1
EXAMPLE
1 2! 3] 4-!
^ I ^2 I I I
General term:
n\
Un = gn
lim un = oo
n-^oo
EXAMPLE
Un = n(if
lim un = 0
n-+ oo
3 + 1
un+ 1 (n+ 08)
= lim
p =
n~* oo Un n-* oo
%in + 1 3
= lim ! %
n~* oo \ "
I3 < 1
P =
so the series is convergent.
2.14 Sequences and Series / 303
EXAMPLE
52 53 54
5 + 2!+ 3!+4!+'"
General term:
5”
lim u„ = 0
n oo
/ 5”+1
(n + 1)!
p = lim lim -- = 0
n~* oo 5" n-+ oo ^ + 1
\ n! /
|p| = o < 1
so the series is convergent.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following series, write out the first few terms and determine whether the series
is divergent or convergent (conditionally or absolutely for alternating series).
yfy^vVi
00 ft2
12 Y _"_
' „ = ! 10(2n - 1)
00 00
n 1/n
2- I 13.
1=1 n +1 n= 1
oo oo
oo in
n
3- „=i
I n+2 14 n= 1
00 1 oo 3ft — 1
71 + 1
15. I(-l)
4- 71£
= 1 T1 + In n n=0 4”
oo 1 00
71 + 1 3n2/3 - 1
5 y (_ iy»+i- 16. I ( — 1)
nW L) (2n + 1)! n=0 4"
oo oo
10
y (n + 1 )(n + 2) \n+ 1
00 (n + 3)!
00
00 n + 2
8. I 19. Z(-1)"+1^T
«=o 3!«!3" 71= 1 ft -T 1
00 -"JTl
00 n3
20. £
„=1 «:
00 1Q71 00 O 2 71 — 1
10. I 21- I
n= 1 n1 71= ! n +1
oo MI 00
22. I(-l)n + i i
11. V -
,4-, 9" 71= 1 ft
304 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
POWER SERIES
An infinite series of the form
where the coefficients a0, au a2,... are independent of x, is called a power series in x.
More generally, an infinite series of the form
00
where the coefficients b0, bu b2, ... are independent of x, is called a power series in
x — a.
A power series in x (or in x — a) may converge for all values of x, or for no values
of x other than x = 0 (or x = a); or it may converge for some values of x and diverge
for others. If a power series converges for values of x in the interval — R<x<R,
then —R < x < R is the interval of convergence of the power series and R is the radius
of convergence. The interval of convergence is determined by the following procedure,
derived from the Cauchy test-ratio test.
Power series in x:
L = 0=> series converges for all x
L f 0 => series converges for the interval
If lim a"+1 = L, then \ — 1/1L | < x < 1/1L | and diverges outside this inter¬
n~* oo
val; the end points of the interval of convergence
must be examined separately.
Power series in x — a:
M = 0 => series converges for all x
EXAMPLE
General term:
un = nxn~ * 1
n + 1
LT = Vlim - = 1,
1
n-* ao n
so the interval of convergence is — 1 < x < 1 and the end points must be tested.
2.14 Sequences and Series / 305
u„ = (-\y-ln
lim u„ ^ 0
n -*■ oo
un = n
lim u„ =f= 0
n-> oo
EXAMPLE
4 x x x3 x4
1 - - + +
2 ' 3 • 22 5 • 23 ' 7 • 24
General term:
(-l)”+1x"_1
un 1
(2n - 3)2 n-
2n - _ i
L = lim I — 2,2n ~1 = lim I — - —i
[2(n + 1) - 3]2", n-> oo An — 21
so the interval of convergence is — 2 < x < 2 and the end points must be tested.
If x = — 2, the series is
2 22 23 24
1 + ~ + —-vy + -+ —-_-j + * * '
2 3-2 5•2 7-2
or
I + I+ 3 + 3 + 7 +
lim u„ = 0
n-+ oo
1
2n - 1
lim “^=lim — + U - 1 = lim = 1
n~* oo Mn n~* oo 1 n -*■ oo In + T
2n — 1
un = >— (p-series, p = 1)
2n — 1 2n
If x = 2, the series is
2 22 23 24
* — 2 + 3 . 22 _ 5"* 23 + 1 • 24
or
i-i+4
lim un = 0
n -*■ oo
| Un + 1 | ^ | Un |
so the alternating series is convergent.
Thus the original power series converges for — 2 < x < 2.
EXAMPLE
General term:
un = (n — 1)! x"_ 1
n\
L= lim = *lim n = oo
n~> oo 1) • n ■ oo
Thus the power series converges only for x = 0, that is, the series is divergent for all x =/= 0.
EXAMPLE
n+1 (X ~ 1)"
“n = (-!)'
n
n
M = lim = -1
n-* oo n + 1
so the interval of convergence is 0 < x < 2 and the end points must be tested.
If x = 0, the series is — 1— \ ^ \ — •••.
l
un
n
lim un = 0
n~* oo
u n+ 1
lim = 1
U,
n-* oo
2.14 Sequences and Series / 307
un = - (p-series, p = 1)
n
u„ =
n
lim un = 0
n-* oo
| +1 | \U„ |
so the alternating series is convergent.
Thus the original power series converges for 0 < x < 2.
EXAMPLE
General term:
■ +i (x - 0"
Un = (-1)
n
n
M = lim I — = -1
n-+ oo (n + 1)-
so the interval of convergence is 0 < x < 2 and the end points must be tested.
If x = 0, the series is — 1 — -J — i — rs — • • •.
1
Un j
n
lim un = 0
n~* oo
lim —- = 1
n~* oo Mn
| un | = 2 (p-series, p — 2)
K = (- 1)”+1 -2
n
EXAMPLE
General term:
(n + l)(x - 2)n
un =
n\
I n + 2
{n + 1)! r n + 2
M = lim = lim ^ = 0
n-> oo n + 1 n-> oo (»+ ir
\ n! /
Thus the power series converges for all x.
TAYLOR S THEOREM
For either theoretical or computational purposes, it is frequently convenient to
represent a function of x by a power series; Taylor’s theorem provides appropriate
power series for representing many functions.
* f(k){a) k x -
— a (x - a)2
I (x-af=f(a)+f’(a) — + f"(a) 2, ' + • • •
(x — a)n~ 1
+ Rn
(n - 1)!
converges and represents the function /(x) for those values of x for which all the
derivatives off(x) exist and for which Rn 0 as n -► oo. In this case/(x) is said to be
expanded in a Taylor s series about x = a. For the special case a = 0, the expansion is
a Maclaurins series.
Rn is called the remainder after n terms and it can be shown that
(x — a)n
K=f{n)(i) where a < £ < x
n\
This formula can be used to determine a bound for the error involved in using only the
first n terms of the series if maxa<^<x Rn is obtained.
note: There are some functions for which Taylor’s series converges for values of
x for which the remainder does not approach 0 as n -* oo; for such values of x, the
series does not represent the function. However, in most cases the interval of conver¬
gence of the series is the same as the interval for which Rn -+ 0 as n -> oo, as is the case
for the examples considered here.
A Taylor’s series about x = a is useful for calculating the function it represents for
values of x near a. Similarly, a Maclaurin series is useful for calculating the function it
represents for values of x near zero.
A rigorous proof of Taylor’s theorem is not simple and will not be given. However,
the result can be made plausible by the argument presented in Technical Note III.
2.14 Sequences and Series / 309
EXAMPLE
Expand the function/(x) = x 1/3 in powers of (x — 1) and determine the interval of conver¬
gence of the series.
f(x) = X"1'3
f'(x) = -ix^'3
/'(*)=■£*-7,3
1-4-7 10/3
/"'(*)
1-4-7-10 13/3
/(,v’(x) .-
34 '
1-4-7-10-13 16/3
/(V) (x) = -
/(x) =f{a) +
/»
v (x - a) +
/» (x - a)2 + • • • + Pn\a) (x — a)n +
2! n\
(3« + 1)(3n - 2) 1
bn+1 _ 3"+1(n + 1)! _ 3 n+\
(3n - 2)(3n - 5) ••• 1 ~ 3(n + 1)
~ 3 "n!
lim„_ qo bn+1 /bn = — 1, so the interval of convergence is 0 < x < 2 and the end points must be
tested.
If x = 0,
(3n - 2)(3n - 5) 1
Un ~ 3^!
note: For notational consistency, the general term is denoted un; actually it is the term
involving the nth derivative and is the (n + l)st term of the series.
If x = 2,
„ (3n — 2)(3n — 5) • • • 1
un = (-1)
3 Hn\
lim un = 1 =/= 0
EXAMPLE
Expand the function f(x) — 1/(1 + x)2 in powers of (x — 2) and determine the interval of
convergence of the series.
f(x) = (1 + x)~2
f(x) = 1! 2! nl
n + 2
bn+l = 3^ n + 2
bn n + 1 3(n + 1)
3n + 2
lim„_ bn + l jbn =
oo so the interval of convergence is — 1 < x < 5 and the end points must
be tested.
If x = — 1, un = (n + l)/32.
lim un ~ go 7^ 0,
n~* 00
If x = 5, un = (— l)”(n + l)/32.
lim un = 00 ^ 0,
EXAMPLE
Expand the function /(x) — (1 + xf, where m is any real number, in powers of x and deter¬
mine the interval of convergence of the series. This is known as the binomial expansion.
f(x) = (1 + xf
f'(x) = m( 1 + xf-1
ml
/"(x) = (1 + x)m-"
(m — n)\
m(m — l)(m — 2) • (m — n + 1) „
+ —-+
n!
m(m — 1 )(m — 2) • • • (m — n)
&n+i (n + 1)! m — n
m(m — 1 )(m — 2) • • • (m — n + 1) n + 1
n\
lim,,^ bn+l/bn= — 1, so the interval of convergence is — 1 < x < 1 and the end points must
be tested.
If x = — 1, un 1\ ivml(m — 1) (m — 2) (m — m -h 1)
V
n\
lim u„ = 0
oo
m(m — l)(m — 2) • • • (m — n + 1)
If X = 1, un
n\
lim u„ = 0
00
If x= ±1, \un+l/un\ = |(m —«)/(«+ 1)|, so |mb+1| < || does not hold for unre¬
stricted m.
Thus the power series expansion converges for — 1 < x < 1.
EXAMPLE
Expand the function/(x) = In x in a Taylor’s series about x = 1 and determine the interval of
convergence; use this series to evaluate In 1.04 correct to five decimal places.
312 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
f(x) = \n x
/'M = l-
/"(x) = -1
24
/,v,(x)
„ + i (« ~ !)!
/"(*) = (-!)'
fin~
In x =f(a) + (x “ fl) + (* ~ a f + •• + 4-A. (x - a)”“' + R„
1! 2! (« - 1)!
1
= 0 + (x - 1) -i(x - l)2 + i(x - l)3 -••'+(- 1)"|
n — 1
'(x-ir1 + *„
i
frn + i = _ n _ _ n - 1
bn 1 n
n — 1
bn + l/bn= — 1, so the interval of convergence is 0 < x < 2 and the end points must be
tested.
If x = 0, un =-—t
ft — 1
lim un = 0
n~* oo
u„ + i •• n ft — 1
lim lim = lim = 1
n~* oo n~*oo 1 n-*ao ^
ft — 1
1
un (p-series, p = 1),
ft — i
note:Omitting a finite number of terms from a series does not affect convergence, nor
does multiplying the series by a positive or negative constant.
If x = 2, u„ = (— 1)" + ‘(l/n).
lim u„ — 0
n~+ oo
| +1 | ^ | |
= 0.039221 + /?4
(x — a)n
a < £ < x
nl
1 £ ^ £ 1.04
£4 4!
(0.04)4
4£4
note: Since the series is alternating, the error in truncating is less in absolute value than
the next term, which for this example gives the same bound on the error as above.
EXAMPLE
Expand the function f(x) = ex in a Maclaurin’s series about x = 0 and determine the interval
of convergence; use this series to evaluate el/2 correct to four decimal places.
f(x) = ex
f'(x) = e*
/"(*) = e*
fn(x) = e>
/» „, /» r-"( a)
—Y\~x + 2! x2 4- ••• + x"~1 + R„
(n — 1 )!
2 3 ,n- 1
X X
bn +1 nl (n — 1)! 1
1 n n
(n - 1)!
lim bT1 = °
n-+ oo
,1/2 _
— 1 4* 7 +
(W ^ (W , (i)4 , (i)
+ + + + R,
2! 3! 4! 5!
= 1.648697917 + Re
314 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
a<^<x
n\
0£ t£i
and, since ei/2 <2, \R6 I < 0.000043, so e1/2 = 1.6487, correct to four decimal places.
EXAMPLE
Expand the function f(x) = (1 4 x)1/2 in a Maclaurin’s series about x = 0 and determine the
interval of convergence; use this series to evaluate ^/l.lO correct to six decimal places.
/(x) = (1 + x)1/2
/"(*)- -^ (! + *)'3/2
f"(x) = ~( 1 + x)-5'2
1 -1 1 2 3 • 1 ,
= 14- ^—. . x - xi—x 4- o—— xJ - • • •
2 1 • 2 ! 2 21 • 3!
• !
lim„^ * bn+1/bn= — 1, so the interval of convergence is - 1 < x < 1 and the end points must
be tested.
If x = — 1 ,/(x) = 0, so expansion is unnecessary.
lim u„ = 0
n-+ oo
Un + 1 2n — 3
< 1
2n
2.14 Sequences and Series / 315
3 • 1 5-3-1
(1.10)1/2 = 1 + Wo)3-
2! (A)2 + >3 • 3! 24 • 4! (M
(to) -
2 • 1!
7 • 5 • 3 • 1 . . „
4-25 . 5,— (tt) + Re
= 1.048808867 + R6
Alternating series, so the error is less than the absolute value of next term,
a < i < x
n!
9 • 7 • 5 • 3 • 1
0 < £ < 175
R*=-26 • 6! (1 + «'n/W
975-3*1
R6 <
26 • 6! (A )6
R6 I < 0.0000000205
Note that the accuracy of the approximation obtained from a power series expan¬
sion increases with the number of terms used in the calculation. Fewer terms are
required for a specified accuracy if the series converges more rapidly. The number of
terms required for a given accuracy must be determined for each power series
approximation by considering the remainder term or, for an alternating series, by
considering the next term. Note that the remainder after n terms
n!
is equal in absolute value to the next term of an alternating series if £ = a. Thus, for
an alternating series, the bound on the error determined by obtaining maxa<^<x Rn is
equal to the bound determined by obtaining the absolute value of the next term of
the alternating series, if maxa<^<x Rn occurs for £ = a.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following power series, determine the general term and the interval of
convergence.
X3 X5 X7
*■ X “ 3! + 5! “ 7! +
„ 1 2 , 3 5 4 7
7' 2!X + 3!X +4!X + 5!X +"'
Expand the following functions in power series, determine the interval of convergence, and
choose some appropriate value of x for which to estimate the function.
c t i 1 (2w — l)x” 1 . _
5. (-1)" ----, conv. —2 < x < 2
n
7. x2n l, conv. all x
(n + 1)!
n
9. {— 1J"+1 —:—- xn, conv. — 1 < x < 1
3n — l
11- /M = 1 + 2 1! (* - 1) -^7 (* - v
22 • 2!v" l)2 +' 23 • 3! (* - l)3
1-3-5
(x - l)4 + * .5 . ~ 7 (x - l)5 +
24 • 4! v" ' 25 • 5!
x3 17x7
2x5 i i 71
19. f(x) —
4~ 4" - 4" * * * 9 conv. x <-
3 15 315 1 1 2
x2 5x4 61x6 i i n
21. f(x) —
4 _ —- + •••, conv. x <—
2 24 720 1 1 2
note: For mathematical convenience, the rules for differentiation are not
derived in the same order as they are given in the text.
Algebraic Functions
Rule 1. If y = c,
Ay = 0
A^o
Ax
dy Ay
= lim ~ = 0
dx “‘“o Ax
Rule 3. If y = cu, where u =f(x) is a differentiable function of x,
y + Ay = c(u + A u)
Ay = c Au
Ay Au
Ax Ax
dy Av du
T= lim ~y- = cyr
dx dx
Rule 2. If y = xn, where n is a positive integer,
y + Ay = (x + Ax)”
dx Ax-* 0 Ax
Rule 4. If y = u + v, where u =f(x) and v = g(x) are differentiable functions of
y + Ay = u -f Au + v + Av
Ay = Am + Av
Ay Au Av
Ax Ax Ax
dy Ay du dv
dx Ax-o Ax dx dx
318 / Differential Calculus: Functions of One Variable
y + Ay = (u + A n)(y + Ay)
Ay Av Au (Au)(Av)
— u —1_ v -|--
Ax Ax Ax Ax
dy Ay dv du
= lim —— = u ——F v
dx Ajc->0 Ax dx dx
Logarithmic Functions
Rule 8. If y -= loga n, where u =f(x) is a differentiable function of x,
y + Ay = loga (n 4- An)
Ay = loga (n + An) - Iogfl n
n 4- An^
= lOga
n
An^
= log,, 1 + n
Ay 1 . L A4
loga 1 +
An Au n
1 n An'
!og„ 1 +
n An u
1 A u\u,Au
= - lOga 1 +
n \ u
Ay 1
lim / = -logfl lim (1 4 h)],h
Au-^o An n h->0
dy
- loga e
du u
2.14 Sequences and Series / 319
If u =/(x),
dy 1 , du
- = - log„ e ,
dx u dx
Exponential Functions
Rule 9. If y = au, where u =f(x) is a differentiable function of x,
In y = In au
= u In a
1 dy du
— In a
y dx dx
dy du .
y — In a
dx dx
du
= au In a
dx
Rule 10. If y = uv, where u =f(x) and v = g(x) are differentiable functions of x.
In y = v In u
1 dy 1 du dv
-f In u
y dx u dx dx
dy v- 1
du dv
vu + uv In u
dx dx dx
In y — n In u
1 dy 1 du
y dx u dx
dy du
nu n- 1
dx dx
Trigonometric Functions
Rule 11. If y = sin u, where u = f(x) is a differentiable function of x,
y + Ay = sin (u + Au)
/ Au\ . Au
= 2 cos I u + — \ sin --
If w = /(x),
dy du
— = cos u —
dx dx
= sin ^ - w
and
dy
= cos
dx
du
= — sin w
dx
sin w
y =-
cos w
and
7 du . y du
, cos w — + sin w —
wy dx dx
dx cos2 w
du
dy dx du
sec2
dx cos2 w dx
Inverse Functions
Rule 14. If y = f(x) and x = g(y) are inverse differentiable functions,
That is,
dx 1
dy dy
dx
Composite Functions
Rule 15. If y = <p(u) and u = F(x)
Ay Ay Au
Ax Au Ax
Ay dy du
lim 3T = 1~'
du
~T
uX
y = ax3 + bx2 + cx + d
to have no relative maximum or minimum in the first quadrant. If b2 — 3ac > 0, then
— = 0 if x = (— b ± Jb2 — 3ac)/3a.
dx
— b + Jb2 — 3ac
x =-->0 since a > 0, b < 0 and b2 — 3ac I < I b
3a
Since a>0, h<0, c>0, ^>0 and (— b ± Jb2 — 3ac)/3a > 0, the first term in the
expression for y is positive, the second term is negative, and the third and fourth
terms are positive or zero. Thus y may be positive or negative depending on the
relative value of the coefficients a, b, c, and d, and (x, y) may lie in either the first or
second quadrant. Since
d2y
2( — b ± yjb2 — 3ac + b) = ± 2yjb2 — 3ac
dxz x = [ — b ± fb2 — 3ac]/3a
d2y
7^0
dx2 x = [ — b±fb2 — 3ac]/3a
and y = ax3 + bx2 + cx + d has a relative maximum or minimum at the point for
Assume that the function f(x) has a power series expansion and that the power series
can be differentiated term by term.
If x = a,f(a) = a0.
If x = a,f'(a) = av
If x = a,f"(a) = 2a2 .
If x - a, f"'(a) = 3 • 2a3.
an = fn(a)
— ffor n = 1, 2, rt \
a0 =f(a)
n!
3.1 Introduction
The discussion and examples in previous sections were concerned with functions of
one variable, that is, functions of the explicit form y =f(x) or the implicit form
/(x, y) = 0. Such functions express a relationship between two variables, x and y, and
implicitly assume that the processes being studied can be represented adequately in
terms of only these two variables. Although in many cases this type of representation
provides a reasonably accurate first approximation to reality, there are clearly many
cases in which such a representation is so inadequate as to be virtually useless. In
these cases it is necessary to express a relationship in terms of several variables or to
express one variable as a function of more than one other variable. For example, in
economic theory supply and demand of a commodity frequently depend not only on
its price but also on the prices of related commodities, on income level, on time, and
on various other factors. Profit depends not just on the output of one commodity,
but on the output levels for several commodities and on the combination of several
inputs.
Relations and functions of several variables can be defined by appropriate exten¬
sions of the corresponding definitions for two variables. Geometric representation is
not possible for functions involving more than three variables, but, with this excep¬
tion, the following discussion and definitions are appropriate for any finite number of
variables. Partial differentiation is defined and several applications of partial deriva¬
tives in business and economics are discussed. Constrained and unconstrained
maxima and minima of functions of two variables are considered and constrained
utility maximization is discussed as an application of constrained maximization and
minimization in business and economics.
Continuity
A function /(x, y) is said to be continuous at x = a, y = b, if the following three
conditions are satisfied:
1. f(a, b) exists.
2. lim^a y^bf(x, y) exists.
3. lim,., ^/lx, y) = f(a, b), no matter in what manner x -*■ a, y -»b.
A function of x and y is said to be continuous in a region of the xy-plane if it is
continuous at every point of the region. Analogous definitions are appropriate for
functions of n variables.
In this section partial differentiation, the total differential, and the total derivative are
defined and illustrated. Partial differentiation of implicit functions is also considered
and illustrated.
3.2 Partial Differentiation / 325
z =f(x, y)
dz df
f(x, y) fAx, y) fx
dx dx dx
dz Sf
f(x, y) fJx, y) f
dy dy dy
EXAMPLE
dz
— = 4x -f 3y
dx
~ = 3x - 12y
dy
EXAMPLE
If z — xy + In x,
dz 1
= y +
dx x
dz
— x
dy
326 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
EXAMPLE
If z = (x + y) sin (x — y),
dz
— = sin (x - y) + (x + y) cos (x - y)
dz
— = sin (x — y) — (x + y) cos (x — y)
EXAMPLE
ir x3 - y3 , , dz dz
It z =-—, show that x ~ + y ~ = z.
xy dx dy
2-1
z = xy - x -12
yz
dz
= 2xy 1 + x 2y2
dx
■=- = —xy
dz 2-2 T - 1
- 2x y
dy
2-1
xy — x -12
y = z
dz dz
= tan a = slope of APB at P
dx dx p
dz
tan [I = slope of CPD at P
dy
That is, if z =/(x, y), the partial derivatives — and — are interpreted geometrically
as the slopes of the curves of intersection of the surface z =/(x, y) and the planes
y = constant and x = constant, respectively.
Since, in general, the partial derivatives of a function z =/(x, y) are functions of x
3.2 Partial Differentiation / 327
Figure 3.1
and y, they may be differentiated with respect to either xory; these derivatives, if
they exist, are called the second partial derivatives of z and are denoted, respectively,
by
EXAMPLE
If z = (x *12 + y2)312,
dz
?(x2 4- y ) 1 (2x)
dx
= 3x(x -f y 2 2)1/2
d2z
= ?x(x2 4- y2)~ / (2y) 1 2
dy dx
= 3xy(x 4- y2)~1/2
2
dz
= ?(*2 + y2)l,2(2y)
dy
= 3y(x 4- y 2 2)1/2
d2z
= ?y(*2 + y2) 1/2(2x)
dx dy
dy dx dx dy
EXAMPLE
dx dx dy dx dy dy
24y4x 4- 6By
d3u
6 Bx 4- 4 Cy
~dx2 dy
du
Bx3 4- 2Cx2y 4- 3Dxy 2 4 - 4Ey3
dy
d2u
2Cx2 4- Dxy 4- 12£y
6 2
dy2
d3u
4Cx 4- Dy 6
dy'2 dx
d3u
6Dx + 24£y
dy3
PROBLEMS
1. If u = xy — In xy, find ux and uy.
d2z d2z
11. If z = xy + y In xy, show that x
+ ^ dx dy dy2'
du d2u du d2u
12. If M yjx — y2, show that
dx dx dy dy dx2 ’
d2z
13. If z = xy + xelly, show that -——
dx dy dy dx'
x + y , d2v d2v
14. If v = -, show that
x y dx dy dy dx ’
20. If/(x, y) = x3 + 3x2y + 6xy2 - y3, find/XJC(2, 3),/yy(2, 3), and/xy(2, 3).
21. If/(x, y) = x4 - 4x3y 4- 8xy3 - y\ find/xx(0, l),/yy(0, 1), and fxy(0, 1).
xv
25. If u -, show that xux 4- yuY = 3u.
x + y
Tr Axn 4- By" , .
27. If u = ^ 2 ^ 2 > show that xux 4- yuy = (n — 2)u.
28. If u = /(x, y), y = g(x, 3^), ux = vy, and uy = —vx , show that if x = r cos 9
30. If z = f(x, y), x = g(u, v), and y = /i(w, v), find zuu.
1
32. If u = - and r = yfx1 + y2 + z2, show that wxx + u yy -\- uzz
3. zx = e”>;z, = e*l4l-?\
9. 2z
29. u2 -I- w2
w =/(*> 33 z)
is defined by
dw dw dw
dw = — ax + — ay -I- — dz
dx dy dz
Av = £ f dx,
i =1 CXi
dXi = —- dt
dt
and if the x’s are differentiable functions of two variables, say r and s, then
dx^fdr + fds
dr ds
3.2 Partial Differentiation / 331
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
dw . dw ,
dw -r-dx 4- — dy + — dz
dx dy dz
2x dx + 2y dy + 2z dz
But
dx = cos t dr — r sin t dt
dy = sin t dr + r cos t dt
dz = dr
and thus
- 2(r 4- r) dr
= 4 r dr
EXAMPLE
, du 1 du
du = — dx + — dy
dx dy
= 2
332 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dw dw dx dw dy dw dz
dt dx dt dy dt dz dt
dw. . dw
and — is said to be the total derivative of w with respect to t. Thus — represents the
EXAMPLE
dw
If w = x2 4- y2 4- z2, where x = e‘ cos t, y = e‘ sin t, and z = e', find
It'
dw dw dx dw dy dw dz
dt dx dt dy dt dz dt
dw
= 2[^2r cos2 t — e2t sin t cos t + e2t sin2 t 4- e2t sin t cos t + e2t]
dt
= 2[e2'(cos2 t + sin2 f)] 4- 2e2t
= 4e2t
Alternatively,
dw
= 2e2t cos2 t — 2e2t sin t cos t + 2e2t sin2 t + 2c2' sin t cos t + 2c2'
dt
= 4c2'
EXAMPLE
XV, . 1 ,
If u - + -, where x = 2r, v = -, and z = t ,
y z t
du du dx du dy du dz
dt dx dt dy dt + dz dt
2 x 1 2 yt
4
y y2t2 zt2 z2
3.2 Partial Differentiation / 333
du 1 2
= 2t + 2t-
dt ? 7
3
= 4t —
7
dr dx dr dy dr dz dr
dw dw dx dw dy dw dz
ds dx ds dy ds + dz ds
In general, if w is a differentiable function of xlt x2, .x„ and the x’s are
differentiable functions of a second set of variables ul9 u2, .um, then the partial
derivative of w with respect to a variable in the second set, say Uj, is given by
EXAMPLE
du du dx du dy
dr dx dr + dy dr
= 4 r3 — 3 r2s + 6 rs2 — s3
du du dx du dy
ds dx ds dy ds
EXAMPLE
dw dw dx dw dy dw dz
dr dx dr dy dr dz dr
2x 2j
(1) -P 1(25)
x 4- y 4- 2z (1) + + y 4~ 2 z 4- y + 2z
2(x + y + 2s)
x2 + y2 + 2z
2(r + s 4- r — s + 2s)
r2 + 2 rs + s2 + r2 — 2 rs + 52 + 4rs
4(r + 5)
2(r + s)2
2
r + 5
and
dw dw dx dw dy dw dz
ds dx ds + dy ds dz ds
2x 2y
(1) + Kx + y2 + 2z (2 r)
x2 + y2 + 2 z + _y + 2z
2{x - y + 2r)
x2 + y2 + 2z
2(r + s — r + s + 2r)
2(r + s)2
4(r + s)
2(r + s)2
2
r + 5
The composite function rule, which is valid also for partial derivatives, can be used
to obtain the total derivatives of functions whose independent variables are related in
various ways.
For example, if u = /(x, y, z), where x — t, y = y(t), and z = z(t), then
du du dx du dy du dz
dt dx dt dy dt dz dt
du du dy du dz
= — 4 ~- 4 “-
dx dy dt dz dt
dx
since — = 1.
dt
If u = f(x, y, z), where x = x(t), y = y(x), and z — z(f), then
du dudx dudydx dudz
dt dx dt dy dx dt + dz dt *
If u—f (x, y, z), where x = x(r, 5), y = y(r), and z = z(y), then
du du dx du dy du dz dy
dr dx dr + dy dr + dz dy dr
du du dx
ds dx ds
dy
since — = 0.
ds
If u = /(x, y, z), where x = x(r), y = y(x), and z = z(y), then
du du dx du dy dx du dz dy dx
dt dx dt dy dx dt dz dy dx dt
U =f(x, y)
Then
du df df dy
dx dx dy dx
du
But if/(x, y) = 0, then u — 0, — = 0 and
yJ Jk
df + 8£dy
= 0
dx dy dx
Thus
d£
dy dx
dx df
Ty
, dx
and — can be obtained as the reciprocal Note that the equation
dy
EXAMPLE
dy dx
If ex sin y + ey cos x = 1, find and
dx dy
336 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
df
dy dx
dx df
dy
ex sin y — ey sin x
ex cos y + ey cos x
dy
— can be obtained by either of the methods above or, more easily, as the reciprocal of
dy dx
dx _ 1
dy dy-
dx
ex cos y + ey cos x
ey sin x — ex sin y
EXAMPLE
ay — x2
y2 — ax
dx 1
dy dy
dx
y2 — ax
ay — x2
, dy
Note that and — could also be obtained using the usual procedure of implicit
dx dy
differentiation.
Similar formulas are appropriate for obtaining the partial derivatives of implicit
functions of any finite number of variables; these formulas can be obtained using the
same method of derivation shown above.
3.2 Partial Differentiation / 337
dF
az dx
for ^ + 0
dx ~dF dz
dz
dF
dz dy_
dy dF dz
dz
The choice of z as the dependent variable is arbitrary and other partial derivatives
can also be obtained; for example,
dF
dx
forf ^0
dx ~dF dy
dy
dF
dz dxt dF
for i = 1, 2, ..., n and 7^0
dxt ~dF dz
dz
dx.
Again, choice of z as the dependent variable is arbitrary and —1- can also be obtained
dxj
as follows
dF
dxt dxj_ dF
for i = 1, 2, ..., n, i # j and ^0
dxj dF dxt
d X;
EXAMPLE
dF
— ey — e2
dy
dF
= ex — ye2
dz
338 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dF
dz dx ey — yez
dx dF ex — yez
dz
dF
dz dy ez — ey
dy dF ex — yez
dz
EXAMPLE
dz z cos x + sin y 4- yz
1
dx dF sin x + 2z + xy
dz
^! x
dy _ z cos x 4- sin y 4- yz
1
1
dx dF " x cos y + xz
^4
PROBLEMS
1. If z = x3 4- x2y — y3, find dz.
du
18. If u = x3 — 3xy + y3, x = r2 + s, and y = rs2, find —.
g1 q— 1 du
19. If u = xy + yz, x = —, y = —, and z = t2, find —.
t t dt
0z 02
20. If z = x In y + y In x, x = eu + v, and y = eu~v, find and
du dv
dz
21. If z = In (x2 + y2) + yjx2 + y2, x = eu cos v, and y = eu sin v, find
du
v
26. If u In-w In uv = 0, find uv and uw .
w
3. du = exyz(yz dx + xz dy F xy dz)
7. dz = — (x dx + y dy)/z
9 dy _ by — x2
dx y2 — bx
ii. £-i
dx
n Ax _ By
*3' * Cz ’ 11 Cz
du _t/ v 2
19. Tre *(l-t)-?
21. ~ = 2 + e“
du
yz( 1 - In xz)
^3. / \
x(x - y)
xz(l — In yz)
zy = Hv - x)
ey +
25. zx =
e^h7y
ex + ez
zy = ex -I- ey
340 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
MARGINAL COST
If the joint-cost function for producing the quantities x and y of two commodities is
given by
C = Q(x, y)
then the partial derivatives of C are the marginal cost functions:
dC. ,
— is the marginal cost with respect to x
ex
EXAMPLE
C = x In (5 -f y)
then
dC
- — In (5 + y) is the marginal cost with respect to x
and
dC
-- is the marginal cost with respect to y
Ty 5 + y
EXAMPLE
C = 15 + 2x2 + xy + 5y2
then
dC
^ = 4x + y is the marginal cost with respect to x
and
3C 3C
If x = 3 and y = 6, — = 18 and — = 63. Thus, if y is kept constant at 6, producing an
ex cy
additional unit of x adds $18 to the total cost; if x is kept constant at 3, producing an
additional unit of y adds $63 to the total cost.
DEMAND SURFACES
If there are two related commodities for which the quantities demanded are x and y
and the respective prices are p and q, then the demand functions can be represented
by
assuming that the quantities demanded, x and y, depend only on the prices, p and q,
of the two commodities. If a demand function of two independent variables is contin¬
uous, it can be represented by a surface, referred to as a demand surface.
note : The notation px and py is frequently used for the prices of the two commod¬
ities. It is not used in this section to avoid possible confusion with the subscript
notation for partial derivatives.
In the usual economic situations, the demand functions x =f(p, q) and y = g(p, q)
have the following properties:
note: Usually, it is assumed that related commodities which are either competi¬
tive or complementary at one set of prices have the same relationship at other prices;
however, in some cases the relationship between commodities may differ for different
prices and thus must be defined for a particular set of prices.
Marginal Demand
If the demand functions for two related commodities are
then the partial derivatives of x and y are the marginal demand functions:
dx . .
— is the marginal demand of x with respect to p
op
342 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dx
is the marginal demand of x with respect to q
dq
dy
is the marginal demand of y with respect to p
dp
dy
is the marginal demand of y with respect to q
dq
For the usual demand functions, x increases if its corresponding price p decreases
Sx dy
and y increases if its corresponding price q decreases, so — and are negative for all
dp dq
economically meaningful values of p and q.
Sx d
If and — are both negative for given (p, q), the commodities are complemen-
dq dp
tary, since then a decrease in either price corresponds to increases in both demands.
Sx d
If — and are both positive for given (p, q), the goods are competitive, since then a
dq dp
decrease in either price corresponds to an increase in one demand and a decrease in
the other. If — and — have opposite signs, the commodities are neither complemen-
dq dp
tary nor competitive; in this case, a decrease in the price of one of the commodities
corresponds to increases in both demands while a decrease in the price of the other
commodity corresponds to an increase in one demand and a decrease in the other.
Such a situation is unusual but might occur, for example, if two different grades of a
material could be used and the better grade material could be obtained only by
processing the lower grade material.
note: Complementary and competitive commodities are defined in terms of the
signs of their cross elasticities in Chapter 2. Those definitions and the definitions
above are equivalent, since the signs of the cross elasticities are the same as the signs
of the appropriate partial derivatives representing marginal demand.
EXAMPLE
EXAMPLE
dx 2a dy a
dp p3q dp ~ p2q
dx _ a dy a
dq p2q2 dq pq2
dx dy
Since — < 0 and < 0, the commodities are complementary.
dq dq
EXAMPLE
dx
= — aeq p d/ =
dp dp
dx
= aeq p di=-be’~*
dq dq
0 X- 3
Since —- > 0 and > 0, the commodities are competitive.
dq dp
EXAMPLE
dx dy
= -b^q = 2a2p - b2q
dp dp
dx dy
= 2aIq-b1p = ~b2P
dq dq
dx dy
> 0 if — > hl >0if q-<^
dq 2a i dp P b2
dx bi dy
— < n0 iff -4 < _
dq p 2ai dp p b2
Thus the demand functions are appropriate for values of p and q such that
by k q < di
a\ P b2
and the commodities are competitive for values of p and q such that the demand functions are
appropriate (since /ax < q/p < a2 /b2 => bx /2ax < q/p < 2a2 /b2).
344 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
EXAMPLE
dx dy
Since — <0 and — > 0, the commodities are neither competitive nor complementary.
dq dp
In x
Ex p dx dx the partial elasticity of demand x with respect to
Yp q=c i
x dp price p, for a constant price q =
In p
dx
d
In x
Ex q dx dx the partial elasticity of demand x with respect to
Yq p = c2 x dq d price q, for a constant price p = c2
In q
dx
d
in y
Ey P . dy dy the partial elasticity of demand y with respect to
Ep q = c 3 y dp price p, for a constant price q = c3
In p
dy
d__
In y
Ey q dy dy the partial elasticity of demand y with respect to
Eq P = C4 y dq price q, for a constant price p = c4
In q
dy
Note that Ex/Eq and Ey/Ep are cross partial elasticities of demand; their signs,
which are the same as the signs of the corresponding marginal demands, can be used
to determine whether commodities are competitive or complementary.
EXAMPLE
Ex p dx P Ey _ p dy
(~aeq p) = -p hh^p-q) = p
Ep x dp aeq-p Ep y dp
Ex q dx q Ey _ q dy
(aeq p) = q
Eq x dq aeq~p Eq y dq
and, since Ex/Eq > 0 and Ey/Ep > 0, x and y are competitive commodities (as above).
EXAMPLE
Ex p dx p , u \ bi P
Ep x dp axq —bxpq a^q — b^p
Ex q dx q 2axq - bxp
v- = ' ^- =-2- u-p) =-r—
Eq x dq axq — b^pq a^q-b^p
Ey = q. dy = q <b , _ M
Eq y dq a2p2 — b2pq 2 a2p — b2q
and, since Ex/Eq > 0 and Ey/Ep > 0, x and y are competitive commodities (as above).
PROBLEMS
1. For the following joint-cost functions, determine the marginal cost with respect to x and the
marginal cost with respect to y.
a. C = x2 In (y +10) c. C = ex + ey + xy + 5
b. C = x3 + 2y2 — xy + 20 d. C = x2y2 — 3xy + y + 8
2. For each of the following pairs of demand functions, determine the four marginal demands,
the nature of the relationship between the two commodities, and the four partial elasticities
of demand. Quantities are denoted by x and y and the corresponding prices are denoted by
p and q, respectively.
a. x = 20 — 2p — q
e. x
p2q
y = 9 — p — 2q
16
b. x = 15 — 2p + q y=
M* 1
y = 16 + p - q
4
f. X =
c. x = 5 — 2p + q pq
y = 8 — 2p — 3q 16
346 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dC x2 dC
= ey + x
dy y + 10 dy
dC . dC
-- = 3x2 — y = 2xy2 - 3y
ox ' dx
dC dC
-4 y-x = 2 x2y — 3x + 1
dy dy
PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS
The production of most commodities requires the use of at least two factors of
production, for example, labor, land, capital, materials, or machines. If the quantity z
of a commodity is produced using the amounts x and y, respectively, of two factors of
production, then the production function
Z =f(x, y)
gives the amount of output z when the amounts x and y, respectively, of the inputs are
used simultaneously. For such a representation to be economically meaningful, it is
assumed that the amounts of the inputs can be varied without restriction, at least in
the range of interest, and that the production function is continuous.
Marginal Productivity
dz
If the production function is given by z = /(x, y), then the partial derivative — of z
ox
with respect to x (with y held constant) is the marginal productivity of x or the
dz
marginal product of x; the partial derivative — of z with respect to y (with x held
constant) is the marginal productivity of y or the marginal product of y. Note that the
marginal productivity of either input is the rate of increase of the total product as
that input is increased, assuming that the amount of the other input remains
constant.
Marginal productivity usually is positive for a considerable range, that is, as the
amount of one input increases, with the amount of the other input held constant, the
output also increases. However, as the input of one factor increases with the input of
the other factor held constant, the output usually increases at a decreasing rate until
the point is reached at which there is not further increase in output and, in fact, a
decrease in output occurs with additional inputs of the factor. This characteristic
behavior of production functions is known as the law of eventually diminishing mar¬
ginal productivity.
EXAMPLE
z = 4x3/V/4
dz . . . dz
Note that — is always positive, but decreases as x increases; similarly, — is always positive,
dx dy
but decreases as y increases.
EXAMPLE
z = 4xy - x2 — 3y2
dz
= 4y - 2x
dx
dz
— — 4x — 6y
dy
dz dz dz dz
Note that — > 0 for x < 2y, — = 0 for x = 2y, and — <0 for x > 2y; similarly, — >0 for
dx dx dx dy
dz dz
y < |x, — = 0 for y = fx, and — <0 for y > §x. Thus the marginal productivities at first
dy dy
increase and then decrease as input increases.
EXAMPLE
~ = Sx- 12 y
dx
dF
= lOy - 12x
dy
dF
= 2z
dz
The marginal productivity of x is
dF
dz dx 6 y — 4x
dx dF z
dz
and the marginal productivity of y is
dF
dz dy 6x — 5y
dy dF z
dz
348 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dz
Since z is positive for any economically meaningful region of the production function, — is
dx
-» dz f-
positive for x <^y and negative for x > ^y and — is positive for y < §x and negative for
d\
EULER'S THEOREM
If the function z =f(x, y) has the property that, for any constant A,
dz dz
nf (x, y)
XFx + yFy
This relationship is known as Euler s theorem.
EXAMPLE
= W(x, y)
Thus, according to Euler’s theorem,
dz dz
xrx + ydy = 4f{x’y)
which can be verified as follows:
dz dz
= x(12x3 + 4xy2) + y(4x2y + 28y3)
Xdx + ydy
= 4/(x, y)
EXAMPLE
A2xy
/(Ax, Ay) =
A2(x2 + y2)
= A°f(x, y)
= 0
dz dz v
x
dx
+ yT=f^y)
total due total due
to to
factor x factor y
That is, total production or output is equal to the product of the amount of one input
and its marginal productivity plus the product of the amount of the other input and
its marginal productivity. The total product is thus allocated to the two factors on
the basis of their marginal productivities.
Euler’s theorem plays an important part in the development of the marginal-
productivity theory of distribution. The basic assumptions of this theory are that
each input is paid the value of its marginal productivity and that total output is just
exhausted. As shown by Euler’s theorem, these conditions are satisfied by linear
homogeneous production functions; thus in the development of the marginal pro¬
ductivity theory of distribution, production functions are generally assumed to be
linear homogeneous. Note that if the production function is homogeneous of degree
n and each input is paid the value of its marginal productivity, then total output
exceeds payments for n > 1 and is less than payments for n < 1.
f(x, y) = constant
in the xy-plane. These curves, no two of which intersect, are called constant product
curves, equal product curves, or isoquants. Each curve shows the combinations of
factors x and y which result in a specified output. As discussed below, constant
product curves are such that a decrease in the input of one factor is compensated for
dy
by an increase in the input of the other factor. The slope — of the tangent at a point
dx
on an isoquant is the rate at which x must be substituted for y to maintain the level of
Figure 3.2
Equal product curves are of various shapes, depending on the nature of the
production function, but in general they have negative slopes and are convex to the
origin in the area of interest. However, there are some economic situations in which
portions of the equal product curves have positive slopes, that is, there are some
situations in which marginal productivity is diminishing and additional amounts of a
factor of input result in decreased production. For example, if the two factors of
production are land and labor, so many men might be employed (for a fixed amount
of land) that they would interfere with each other and production would decrease.
However, assuming the objective of profit maximization, portions of equal product
curves having positive slopes would not be used in practice, since the given output
could be obtained at less cost by a factor combination on a portion of the curve
having negative slope. Thus, as shown in Figure 3.2, only the portions of the equal
product curves lying between their respective vertical and horizontal tangents are
relevant; the lines through these points of tangency are known as ridge lines. The firm
would never operate above the upper ridge line or to the right of the lower ridge line,
since this would require more input than necessary to produce a specified output.
The assumption that equal product curves are convex to the origin implies that
the marginal significance of one factor with respect to the other factor decreases
along an equal product curve—that is, as the amount of factor x that is used in¬
creases, the amount of factor y that can be given up in exchange for a further unit of
factor x decreases, if the product remains constant; similarly, as the amount of factor
y that is used increases, the amount of factor x that can be given up in exchange for a
further unit of factor y decreases, if the product remains constant. If the marginal
significance of a factor increased as the amount used increased, as would be the case
for a concave equal product curve, then only that one factor should be used, since
each unit of the factor would be progressively more worth purchasing. Thus, in
practice, any portions of equal product curves for which marginal significance of the
factors is not decreasing are not relevant.
If factors x and y are purchased in a perfectly competitive market at constant unit
prices, then the total cost of production is given by
c = PXX + pyy + b
3.3 Applications of Partial Derivatives in Business and Economics / 351
Figure 3.3
y
where px and py are the respective prices of x and y and b is the cost of the fixed
inputs. Isocost curves give the combinations of input factors that can be purchased
for a specified total cost; for the cost function above, the isocost curves are repre¬
sented by the family of lines
The slopes of the isocost lines are equal to the negative of the input price ratio, since
px b constant
y =-x - —h -
Py Py Py
The greatest total output which can be produced for a specified total cost is given by
the point of tangency of the relevant isocost curve and an isoquant. Similarly, the
lowest possible cost of producing a specified output is given by the point of tangency
of the relevant isoquant and an isocost curve. The curve connecting the points of
tangency of the isocost curves and isoquants is known as the expansion path or scale
line. This line gives the lowest-cost combinations of factors as output increases; the
firm will thus always produce at some point on the scale line (see Figure 3.3). The
expansion path, at all points of which the rate of technical substitution equals
the fixed input-price ratio, is a straight line if the production function is homogen¬
eous of any degree. A straight-line expansion path does not, however, imply a homo¬
geneous production function.
RETURNS TO SCALE
Returns to scale describes the change in output with a proportionate increase in all
inputs. If output increases by the same proportion as the inputs increase, then returns
to scale are constant; if output increases by a greater proportion than inputs, returns
to scale are increasing; if output increases by a smaller proportion than inputs,
352 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
Figure 3.4
y
returns to scale are decreasing. Very frequently, there are increasing returns to scale
for relatively small inputs (economies of scale), returns to scale are then constant for
a range of inputs, and finally there are decreasing returns to scale for large inputs
(diseconomies of scale).
Returns to scale are easily determined for homogeneous production functions. If a
production function is homogeneous of degree n, returns to scale are increasing if
n > 1, constant if n = 1, and decreasing if n < 1. In practice, a degree of homogeneity
other than 1 is seldom assumed for a production function. If a set of equal product
curves (not necessarily homogeneous) represent successive increases in production
of a given amount, then returns to scale increase as output increases if the distance
along the scale line between successive curves decreases; similarly, returns to scale
decrease as output increases if the distance along the scale line between successive
curves increases. Thus, in Figure 3.4, returns to scale increase from 20 to 80 units of
production and decrease from 80 to 140 units of production.
Note that if the proportions of the amounts of the two factors of production vary,
it is necessary to refer to returns to outlay rather than returns to scale, since the
factors are not increased by the same scale.
UTILITY FUNCTIONS
In the theory of consumer behavior, the consumer is assumed to choose among the
alternatives available to him in such a way that the satisfaction derived from consum¬
ing commodities is maximized. This implies that the consumer is aware of his alter¬
natives and is capable of evaluating them. All relevant information concerning the
satisfaction a consumer derives from various quantities of commodities is contained
in his utility function.
The concept of utility is based not on some type of psychological satisfaction on
the part of the consumer, but on his choice behavior. The assertion that a consumer
derives more satisfaction or utility from A than from B means that he would choose
3.3 Applications of Partial Derivatives in Business and Economics / 353
= f\
dqi h
354 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
Figure 3.5
<7 2
q2) c4
q2) C3
q 2)
c2
q2)
The slope of an indifference curve dq2/dqx is the rate at which a consumer would be
willing to substitute Qj for Q2 or Q2 for Qx to maintain a given level of utility. The
negative of the slope—dq2 /dql is the rate of commodity substitution or marginal rate of
substitution of Qifor Q2 or Q2for and equals the ratio of the partial derivatives of
the utility function. Note that the rate of commodity substitution at a point on an
indifference curve is the same for movements in either direction, so the verbal
definition can be in terms of substituting Qx for Q2 or Q2 for Qx.
The partial derivatives fx and f2 are said to be marginal utilities of the commod¬
ities Q1 and Q2 . The magnitudes of the marginal utilities are without meaning when
the utility function is ordinal, but their signs and ratios are meaningful. Note that if
the marginal utilities are positive, an increase in the quantity consumed of one
commodity with no change in the quantity consumed of the other commodity will
move the consumer to a higher indifference curve.
PROBLEMS
1. For each of the following production functions, find the marginal productivities. Output is
denoted by z and the inputs are denoted by x and y.
a. z — 25-at x = 1, y = 1
x y
where z is total product, x is quantity of labor, y is quantity of capital, and a, b, and c are
constants. It is frequently assumed that fr + c = 1. Is this function homogeneous and, if so,
of what degree?
3. For each of the following production functions, determine the degree of homogeneity and
the nature of the returns to scale. Output is denoted by z and the inputs are denoted by x
and y.
, 14 20 25
b. z =- d. Z = —2 d- + -
x y xy y^
4. In addition to the property known as Euler’s theorem, linear homogeneous functions have
the following properties: If z = /(x, y) is a linear homogeneous function, then
z (y\ z y
- that is, - is a function of -
X x) x x
I z
= g2\-\ that is, - is a function of -
Iy \y) y y
dz
= that is, ~ is a function of -
dx \x/ dx x
dz
that is, ^ is a function of -
dy Ky) dy y
dh y d2z
dx2 x dx dy
I
<^z x d2z
dy2 y dx dy
c. z = 3ex + 3ey x2 + xy
k. z
3y
d. z = 6 In 3~2x - In 4“5>’
l. z = 3x2y + 4xy2 + y3 + 10
x4 -I- 3x2y2 4- xy3 + 6y4
e. z =-o-
x xy
m. z =
x + y
f. z = 3x In 5x/y - 9y In 8>/x
n. z = xy — In xy
x2y + y3
g-z' a*1- -
, x2 + 3xy + y2
h. z =-j-
y
5. If a consumer’s utility function is given by U = q^q2 and the consumer purchases 4 units of
Qi and 5 units of Q2, a. what quantity of must he purchase to maintain the same level of
utility if his purchase of Q2 increases to 6 units? b. What quantity of Q2 must he purchase to
maintain the same level of utility if his purchase of^ increases to 6 units ?c. What quantity
of Qx must he purchase to maintain the same level of utility if his purchase of Q2 decreases
to 4 units? d. What quantity of Q2 must he purchase to maintain the same level of utility if
his purchase of Q{ decreases to 2 units?
356 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
6. Find the marginal utilities for each of the following utility functions. Utility is denoted by U
and the amounts of the two commodities consumed are denoted by qx and q2 respectively.
a. U = q\ q2
b. U = qx q2 + q\
dx ’ dy z(9z — 1)
dz dz dz My - 3)
dx ’ dy dy z(9z — 1)
dz 8(x — 5)
dx 32 z — 1
dz 4 (y — 4)
~dy= ~ 32z - 1
3. a. degree 3, increasing returns to scale
b. degree — 1, decreasing returns to scale
c. degree 6, increasing returns to scale
d. degree —2, decreasing returns to scale
5. a. qx = 25/9 c. q, = 25/4
d. q2 = 5^2
b.
determine its maxima and minima, the first-order and second-order partial deriva¬
tives of a function of two variables can be used to determine its maxima and minima.
The procedure becomes more complicated as the number of variables increases, but
the definitions and methods are essentially the same. The discussion below concerns
functions of two independent variables; maxima and minima of functions of n vari¬
ables are discussed in Chapter 8.
A function f(x, y) of two independent variables is said to have a local maximum
value (or minimum value) for x = a, y = b, iff(a, b) is greater (or less) than/(x, y)
for all values of x and y close to x = a, y = b. If/(x, y) has a maximum (or minimum)
value at x = a, y = b, it follows that the function /(x, b) has a maximum (or mini¬
mum) at x = a and the function/(a, y) has a maximum (or minimum) at y = b. Thus,
for the function /(x, y) to have a maximum (or minimum) at x = a, y = b, it is
necessary that
d
/(*> y) = o
dx x — a, y = b
d
f(x, y) =o
dy x = a, y = b
3.4 Maxima and Minima of Functions of Two Variables / 357
These two conditions are used to determine the critical points; the procedure below
is then used to determine whether the critical points are in fact local maxima or
minima.
a
f{x, y) = 0
dx x = a, y = b
If
f(x, y) = 0
dy x = a, y = b
and
d2 d2
maximum at x = a, y = b, if /(x, y) < 0 and ^ /(x, y) < 0
A > 0
d2 d2
then minimum at x = a, y = b, if 2 /(x, y) > 0 and ^ /(*» y) > 0
dx' dy'
test fails and the function must be investigated near the critical
point
where the partial derivatives are evaluated for the critical
point
Note that this procedure is used to identify local maxima and minima. In order to
determine global maxima or minima it is necessary not only to compare the values of
the local maxima or minima, but also to determine the values of the function at the
limits of its range, if its range is limited. The procedure for determining global
maxima and minima for functions of two variables is thus analogous to the
procedure for functions of one variable.
Examples of functions having at the origin (a) a minimum, (b) a maximum, and (c)
a saddle point are illustrated in Figure 3.6. Note that at a saddle point a function has
a minimum with respect to one variable and a maximum with respect to the other
variable. For example, in Figure 3.6(c) the origin looks like a minimum to a person
traveling along the surface in the yz-plane, but to a person traveling in the xz-plane
the origin looks like a maximum.
358 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
Figure 3.6
EXAMPLE
/(x, y) = x2 + xy + y2 - 3x + 2
for maximum and minimum values.
= 2x + y - 3
dx
df
= x + 2y
dy
2x + y = 3
x + 2y = 0
3 y = -3
yi = 2
dx2
= 2
dy2
d2f
= 1
dx dy
3.4 Maxima and Minima of Functions of Two Variables / 359
A = 4 - 1 > 0
d2f d2f
= 2 > 0 = 2 > 0
dx2 dy2
EXAMPLE
6L- 2x
dx ^ x2 + y2
dl-x_ 2y
dy x2 -I- y2
x2y + y3 — 2x = 0
x3 + xy2 — 2 y = 0
— 2x2 + 2 y2 = 0
xz2 = yz2
Substituting for x2 in the first equation and for y2 in the second equation, y3 = x and x3 = y,
so (1, 1) and (-1, — 1) may be a maximum or minimum.
df _ 4 xy
dx dy + (x2 + y2)2
d2j_ syi = 0
dx2 x=y= 1 dx2 x-y-
d2/
-0
dy2 x=y= 1 dy2 x—y— 1
d2f d2f
= 2
dx dy x = y= 1 dx dy x—y— - 1
A =0 — 2 <0
Thus f(x,y) has no maximum or minimum, but does have saddle points at (1, 1) and
(-i. -i)
EXAMPLE
f(x, y) = 1 -f x2 - y2
for maximum and minimum values.
360 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dj_
= 2x
dx
df
= -2y
dy
2x = o if x = 0|
so (0, 0) may be a maximum or minimum
-2 y = 0 if y = 0
ay
= 2
dx2 Hi *•
d2/
= -2
dy2
s2f
= 0
dx dy
A = - 4-0 <0
Thus/(x, y) has neither a maximum nor a minimum at (0, 0), but does have a saddle point at
(0, 0).
EXAMPLE
df
= cos x + cos (x + y)
dx
df
= cos y + cos (x + y)
dy
d*f
= —sin x — sin (x + y)
dx2
d*f
= -sin y — sin (x + y)
dy2
d2f
= —sin (x + y)
dx dy
d_V _ T5 _ 73 = = -A
dx2 x = y = n/3 2 2
d2f
dy2 x = y = n/3 2 2
= -73
d2f 73
dx dy x = y = n/3 2
A = (-73)(-7"3)-(-^)
— 3 —| — | > 0
3.4 Maxima and Minima of Functions of Two Variables / 361
dV <0 and
d2/
<0
dx2 dy2
EXAMPLE
f(x, y) = 25 + (x - yf + (y - 1)'
df
= 4(x - y):
dx
df
= — 4(x - y)3 + 4(y - l)2
dy
(x — y)3 = 0 if x = y
so (1, 1) may be a maximum or minimum
(X - >’)3 = (y - l)3 if X = y = 1j
d2f
= i2(x - yy
dx2
d2f
- 12(x - y)2 + 12(y - 1)^
d/
d2f
dx dy = 712(x ~ y):
ay
dx2 x = y= 1
dV
dy2 x = y=\
d2f
= o
dx dy x — y= 1
= (h- k)4 + k4
But (h — /c)4 + /c4 > 0 for all h and k, so/( 1 + h, 1 + k) > /(1, 1) for all h and k, and thus there
is a minimum at (1, 1).
EXAMPLE
-r- = 2x — 6y 4- 3
dx
~ = —6x + 18 y
dy
2x — 6 y — — 3
— 2x + 6y = 0
EXAMPLE
p — 36 — 3x and q = 40 — 5y
C = x2 + 2 xy + 3 y2
determine the quantities and prices that maximize profit for the monopolist and find the
maximum profit.
P = px + qy — C
dP
= — 8x — 2y 4- 36
dx
dP
= — 16y — 2x + 40
dy
4x + y = 18
x + 8y = 20
31 y = 62
y= 2(
so P may have a maximum or minimum at (4, 2)
x = 4
d2P
= -8
dx2
d2P
= -16
dy2
d2P
= -2
dx dy
d2P d2P
<0 and <0,
dx2 dy2
EXAMPLE
P = 32z - 8x - 4y
= 130 - 4(x - 5)2 - 8{y - 4)2 - 8x - 4y
dP
= ~8(x — 5) — 8 = — 8x -f 32
dx
dP
= — 16(y — 4) — 4 = — 16 y + 60
dy
8x = 32
x = 4
so P may have a maximum or minimum at (4,
16 y = 60
,, — 15
y- t
d2P
= -8
dx2
d2P
= -16
dy2
d2P
-0
dx dy
A = (— 8)( —16) - 0 = 128 > 0
d2P d2P
<0 and <0,
dx2 "w dy2
so P has a maximum value for x = 4, y = ^ and Pmax = 78^.
EXAMPLE
In simple bivariate regression analysis, the model involves the assumption of a linear relation¬
ship between a predicted variable y and an explanatory variable x and a disturbance term u.
For a sample of n observations of x and y,
yt = a + /?x, + Ui i = 1, 2, ..., n
and the problem is to obtain estimates of a and /?. These estimates are customarily obtained
using the least squares principle. Let a and /? denote estimates of a and (3. Then yt = a +
/be, 4- e{ where e, denotes the ith residual yt —a — ^xt. The least squares principle minimizes
the sum of the squared residuals
i=i
= Z O'* - « - hd2
i=i
Mtdh -2Zx,(n-*-**'*
364 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
Zxiyi -
i=1 £= 1
~/?Zx,2 = o
£= 1
Multiplying the first equation by Z?=i xi and the second equation by n and solving the
equations simultaneously,
*£)>£- Zxi
L_\£= 1_
n in \ 2
nZx?- Z*<
£= 1 \i= 1 /
tv,-fit*
~ £= 1 i= 1
a =-
n
are the least squares estimates for the regression coefficients a and /?.
To show that this solution minimizes Z?=i eh the second order condition for a minimum
must be considered.
Z ei) = 2n
lef)=2l xf
dP2\M i=1
d2
dk dp\i Z
= i ei\ =2 Z xi
i= 1
A = (2n){2 Z"=i x?) ~ (2 Z"=i x<)2 > since n Z«=i ~ (Z"=i x<)2 > 0 and
decS.2
lef
,i= 1
>0 I>,2 >0
Thus a, ^ minimize Z^i and are the least squares estimators of a and (3.
EXAMPLE
A manufacturer has a demand of D units per period T. The storage cost per period per unit is
c2 dollars, the shortage cost is c3 dollars per unit short per period, and it costs cx dollars each
time a production run is started (setup cost). Assuming that production orders are filled with
no delay and demand is at a uniform rate, determine the frequency with which production
should be scheduled, and the quantity which should be produced in each run in order to
minimize the total per period inventory cost K. In Figure 3.7, t — interval between production
orders, q = production quantity, z = planned inventory at completion of a production run,
tl = time (during cycle) when stock is on hand, and t2 — time (during cycle) when no stock is
on hand. Note that shortages are assumed to be backlogged and not lost.
h z h
Note that
t q' t D’
setup cost: cx
Figure 3.7
D
since the number of runs per period is —, the total inventory cost per period is
q
r _
CjD + C2 Tz2 + c_3 T(q - z):
V —
q 2q 2q
and, since C is a function of both q and z, partial derivatives must be obtained and set equal to
zero to determine a minimum
dC c2 Tz c3 T(q — z)
dz q q
If ~ = 0,
dz
c2 Tz = c3 T(q - z)
c^q
z =
c2 + c3
if^ = o,
dq
2c i D + c2 Tz2 + c3 Tz2
q2 = c3T
2ci D c2 + c3 ,
+ - z2
c,T Cl
c2q
Substituting z —
C2 + c3
2c i D c3
c3 T(q2 - z2) = +
c3T c2 + c3
366 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
thus
2 ClD
q2 =
(1 1|c3r
\ c2 T C3J
/ 2ci(c2 + c3)D
q- c2 c3 T
£3 2cx c3D
q
Cl + ^3 Ci(c2 + c3)T
t = Tq = /2c1(c2 + c3)T
D \/ c2c3D
The manufacturer should produce q units at intervals of time r, where q and t are determined
by the formulas above.
PROBLEMS
Determine the maxima, minima, and saddle points (if any) for each of the following functions.
Find the quantities and prices that maximize profit and the maximum profit for each of the
following sets of demand functions and joint-cost functions for two commodities. Quantities
are denoted by x and y and the corresponding prices are denoted by p and q, respectively; total
cost is denoted by C.
13. x = 1 — p + 2q 17. p = 26 — x
y = 11 + p - 3q q = 40 — 4y
C = 4x + y C = x2 + 2xy + y2
14. x = 11 — 2p — 2q 18. p = 35 - 2x2
y = 16 — 2p — 3q q = 20 —y
C — 3x + y C — 16 — 2x3 -I- xy + 30x 4- 12y + \x2
15. p = 40-2x2 19. p = 40 - 5x
q = 12 — 3y q = 30 - 3y
C = 8 + 4x -I- 3y C = x2 + 2xy + 3y2
16. p — 16 — x2 20. p = 28 — 3x2
q = 9 - y2 9 = 56 - y2
C = x2 + 3y2 C = 2x2 + y2
21. Determine the maximum profit if the production function is z = 20 - x2 + lOx -
2y2 + 5y, the prices of the inputs x and y are 2 and 1, respectively, and the price of the
output z is 5.
22. Determine the maximum profit if the production function is z = 10 - 2x2 + xy -
y2 + 5y, the prices of the inputs x and y are each 3, and the price of the output z is 6.
3.5 Maxima and Minima Subject to Constraints / 367
23. The Portland Company has a contract to furnish 1350 cement mixers annually. The yearly
storage cost is $40 per cement mixer, the shortage cost is $50 per cement mixer short per
year, and it costs $150 to start a production run. If production orders are filled without
delay and demand is at a constant rate, determine the frequency with which production
should be scheduled and the quantity which should be produced in each run in order to
minimize the total average annual cost.
24. The Filaway Company has a contract to supply 600 filing cabinets at a uniform rate
during a 9-month period. The storage cost during this period is $30 per cabinet, the
shortage cost is $60 per cabinet, and it costs $20 to start a production run. If production
occurs at a constant rate of 2400 cabinets per 9-month period, determine the frequency
with which production should be scheduled and the quantity which should be produced in
each run in order to minimize the total average annual cost.
y=i
Pmax = 24VX6 -
(approximately 57.53)
the function to be maximized or minimized involves more than two variables and
several constraints. The methods discussed in this section are applicable in all cases
and can be generalized for use with any number of variables and constraints.
The method of Lagrange multipliers is used in obtaining maxima or minima of
functions subject to equality constraints, and this method is easily generalized for the
case of one inequality constraint. Maxima or minima subject to multiple equality and
inequality constraints are obtained using the Kuhn-Tucker conditions.
LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS
The most widely used method of obtaining maxima or minima of functions subject to
equality constraints is Lagrange multipliers. Suppose /(x, y) is to be maximized or
minimized subject to the constraint g(x, y) = 0. Form the objective function
fJ±-xf = 0
OX OX OX
8F _ _ 3 dJL = n
dy dy dy
8F , . „
Yx = y>= 0
dF
can be solved for the three unknowns x, y, and X. Note that = g(x, y) = 0 is the
Jx
constraint, so F(x, y, X) really need be differentiated partially only with respect to x
and with respect to y. In many cases the values of the X's (Lagrange multipliers) are
not of interest and are not found; for this reason they are sometimes referred to as
“ undetermined multipliers.” The Lagrange multiplier may be preceded by a plus sign
rather than by a minus sign and this form is used by some authors. The only resulting
change in the solution is a change in the sign of X.
The logic of the method of Lagrange multipliers is quite straightforward. The
problem is to determine possible maximum or minimum values of a function that
will satisfy a constraint. If it can be assumed that the points being considered satisfy
the constraint, this problem reduces to the problem of finding an unconstrained
maximum or minimum. Essentially, the method of Lagrange multipliers screens the
possible maximum or minimum values to obtain only those values that satisfy
the constraint.
Note that, if the constraint is satisfied, g(x, y) = 0 and Xg(x, y) = 0, regardless of
the value of X. In that case, the objective function becomes the unconstrained func¬
tion /(x, y). By considering X to be an additional variable and setting the partial
derivative with respect to X equal to zero, the constraint g(x, y) = 0 is incorporated
into the problem and the possible maximum or minimum values satisfy the
constraint.
Solution of the three equations above provides the critical points of the con¬
strained function. These critical points satisfy the constraint, but must be tested as
maxima or minima of the function by a procedure similar to that for unconstrained
maxima or minima.
3.5 Maxima and Minima Subject to Constraints / 369
dF
0
dx x = a, y = b
If
dF
= 0
sy x = a, y — b
, .r d2F ^ J d2F ^
maximum at x = a, y = b, if —-^ < 0 and <0
dx4 dy4
A* > 0
then . . d2F d2F
minimum at x = a, v = b, if —T > 0 and ——y > 0
dx1 dyz
Note that for unconstrained maxima and minima, if A < 0, the critical point is
neither a maximum nor a minimum; however, for constrained maxima and minima,
if A < 0, the critical point may in fact be a maximum or minimum. This corresponds
to the fact that a point may be a maximum or minimum of the constrained function,
although it is not a maximum or minimum of the unconstrained function.
These conditions can be stated more concisely as follows.
EXAMPLE
Find the maxima and minima (if any) of/(x, y) = 5x2 -I- 6y2 — xy subject to the constraint
x + 2y = 24.
370 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
dF
= 10.x — y — X
dx
dF
— — 12 y — x — 2X
ly
dF
= x + 2y — 24
dl
20 x — 2y — 2/1 = 0
— x + 12 y — 2A = 0
21x - I4y = 0
3x — 2y = 0
x + 2y = 24
4x = 24
x = 6
d2F
= 10
dx2
d2F
= 12
dy2
d2F
= -1
dx dy
d2F d2F
> 0 and > 0
dx2 dy2 %
so (6, 9) is a minimum.
dG
= -504 + 56y
dy
= 0 if 56y = 504
y = 9
x = 6
d2G
= 56 >0
dy2
so (6, 9) is a minimum.
3.5 Maxima and Minima Subject to Constraints / 371
EXAMPLE
Find the maxima and minima (if any) of/(x, y) — 12xy — 3y2 -■ x2 subject to the constraint
x + y = 16.
= 12 y — 2x — 2
ox
dF
— = I2x — 6y — A
dy
k«i |*N
3"
+
II
1
14x - 18y = 0
7x — 9y = 0
7x + 7y = 112
16y =112
y = 7
x = 9
d2F
3x2 " 2
d2F
dy2
dlF = 12
dx dy
(x + /i) + (y + fc) = 16
9 + /z + 7 + /c=16
k = -h
/(9 + h, 7 - h) -/(9, 7) = 12(9 + h)(7 - It) - 3(7 - n)2 - (9 + h)2 -12(9)(7) - 3(7)2 - 92
= -16h2 <0
dG
= - 32y + 224
dy
dG
= 0 if 32y = 224
dy
y= ?
x = 9
d2G
= -32
dy2
EXAMPLE
A factory manufactures two types of heavy-duty machines in quantities x and y. The joint-cost
function is given by
f(x, y) = x2 + 2y2 - xy
To minimize cost, how many machines of each type should be produced if there must be a total
of 8 machines?
The constraint is x + y = 8 and the objective function is
dF
— 2x — y — 2 = 0
dx
dF
= 4y — x — 2 = 0
dy
dF
= — (x + y — 8)
3x — 5y = 0
3x + 3y = 24
8y = 24
y= 3
x = 5
2 = 7
d2F
2
dx2
d2F
= 4
dy2
d2F
= -1
dx dy
so (5, 3) is a minimum.
dG
= 8x — 40 = 0 if x = 5
dx
y = 3
d2G
= 8 > 0
dx2
so (5, 3) is a minimum.
EXAMPLE
The relationship between sales S and the amounts x and y spent on two advertising media is
given by
200x lOOy
5 + x + 10 T y
Net profit is 5 of sales minus the cost of advertising. The advertising budget is 25; determine
how it should be allocated between the two media in order to maximize net profit.
The constraint is x + y = 25 and the objective function is
1 200x lOOy
F(x, y, A) — x — y — A(x + y — 25)
5 5 + x + 10 + y
40^ 20y
+ — x — y — A(x + y — 25)
5 + x 10 + y
200 _ 200
(5 + x)2 ~ (10 + y)2
x + y = 25
374 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
so
30 — y = 10 + y
y = 10
x = 15
X —
d2F 400
= 200( —2)(5 + x)~3 = -
dx2 (5 + x)3
d2F 400
2 = 200( — 2)( 10 4- y)-3 =
dy " [io + yf
d2F
= 0
dx dy
/ -400 \ / -400 \
A = 0 > 0
1(5 + x) \ (io + y)3/
d2F d2F
<0 and <0
dx2 " w dy2
l 200x 100^
p(x, y) = — x — y occurs at (10^/2 — 5, 10x/2 — 10).
5 T x 10 4 y
-
, . 40x 20y
Alternative method: P(x, y) = ---f -x — y, x + y = 25.
v yf 5 + x 10 + y
200 200
(5 4- x)2 (35 — x)2
200 _ 200
(5 + x)2 (35 — x)2
5 + x = 35 — x
x = 15
y 10
d2P
200( — 2)(5 + x)“3 4- 200( — 2)(35 - x)~3
dx2
400 400
<0
(5 + x)3 (35 - x)3
EXAMPLE
Maximum profit for a given production function and given prices of the inputs and output can
be determined using Lagrange multipliers. Suppose the production function is
and the unit prices of the inputs x and y are 8 and 4, respectively, and the unit price of the
output is 32. (See the example on page 363.) Profit is maximized if the net revenue function
32z - 8.x — 4v is maximized subject to the production function constraint
16z - 65 + 2(x - 5)2 + 4(y - 4)2 = 0.
dF
- -32-162 = 0
<3z
2 = 2
g=-8-4(x-5)i-0
X = 4
-7 = -4 - 82(y - 4) = 0
y -~4T
PROBLEMS
Find the maxima and/or the minima of each of the following functions subject to the given
constraint.
KUHN-TUCKER CONDITIONS
The method of Lagrange multipliers can be modified to determine the maximum or
minimum of a function of two variables subject to one inequality constraint as
follows: Assume that the inequality constraint holds as an equality constraint and
obtain the maximum or minimum using the method of Lagrange multipliers; if
376 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
X > 0, this maximum or minimum is also the maximum or minimum subject to the
inequality constraint; ifX < 0, the maximum or minimum determined without regard
to the constraint satisfies the constraint and is thus also the constrained maximum or
minimum.
This procedure can be generalized to include multiple inequality constraints, some
of which may be satisfied as equalities and others as inequalities in any particular
problem. In the more general procedure, the conditions necessary for a maximum or
minimum subject to inequality constraints are known as the Kuhn-Tucker condi¬
tions. These conditions are given for the general case in Chapter 8; for the case of a
function of two variables subject to one inequality constraint, the Kuhn-Tucker
conditions are stated as follows.
A point (x, y) is a local maximum of /(x, y) subject to g(x, y) < 0 only if there
exists a nonnegative X such that X and (x, y) satisfy the following conditions:
df (*> y) _ x 8g(x, y) = 0
dx dx
df (x, y) _ dg(x, y) = Q
dy dy
Xg(x, y) = 0
g{x, y) < 0
These conditions are also sufficient if/ (x, y) is concave and the constraint is concave.
Since a maximum point of/(x, y) is a minimum point of —/(x, y), this result is also
applicable to minimizing a convex function subject to a convex constraint.
/[(l - t)x 1 + tx2, (1 - t)y, + ty2] < (1 - t)f(x!, yY) + tf(x2 , y2)
for 0 < t < 1
The function is strictly convex if < can be replaced by < ; the function is concave if
< can be replaced by > and strictly concave if < can be replaced by >.
is convex if 4AC — B2 > 0 and A > 0, C > 0; it is concave if 4AC — B2 > 0 and
A < 0, C < 0; and it is neither convex nor concave everywhere if 4AC — B2 < 0.
Note that this result is a reformulation of the conditions for a maximum or minimum
of two variables.
As shown in the following examples, the method of Lagrange multipliers modified
for one inequality constraint and the Kuhn-Tucker conditions for one inequality
constraint give the same solution. The advantage of the Kuhn-Tucker conditions is
that they can be generalized for more than one inequality constraint. Although the
method of Lagrange multipliers can be generalized for more than one equality
constraint, it cannot conveniently be modified for more than one inequality
constraint. If the function to be maximized or minimized is linear and the constraints
are also linear, the solution may be obtained using linear programming for both
equality and inequality constraints.
Note that the following examples are modifications of some of the examples for
equality constraints.
3.5 Maxima and Minima Subject to Constraints / 377
EXAMPLE
Find the minimum of/(x, y) = 5x2 + 6y2 — xy subject to the constraint x + 2y > 24.
Assuming the inequality constraint to hold as an equality constraint, 2 = 51 (see page 370).
Since 2 > 0, the minimum, x = 6, y = 9, assuming the equality constraint is also the minimum
assuming the inequality constraint.
Using the Kuhn-Tucker conditions,
Of _ x 12 y — x — 22 = 0
dy dy
Xg - 2(x + 2y — 24) = 0
g = x + 2y — 24 > 0
240 — 20y — y — 2 = 0
12y - 24 + 2y - 22 = 0
2 + 21 y = 240
-22 + 14y = 24
56y = 504
y = 9
x = 6
note: 5x2 + 6y2 — xy is convex, since 4AC — B2 = (4)(5)(6) — (— 1 )2 > 0 and A > 0,
C > 0.
EXAMPLE
Find the maximum of/(x, y) = 12xy — 3y2 — x2 subject to the constraint x + y < 16.
Assuming the inequality constraint to hold as an equality constraint, 2 = 66 (see page 371).
Since 2 > 0, the maximum, x = 9, y = 7, assuming the equality constraint is also the maximum
subject to the inequality constraint.
Using the Kuhn-Tucker conditions,
- 2 CA = 12y — 2x — 2 = 0
ex dx
C[ - X ^ = \2x - 6y - X = 0
dy dy
Xg — 2(x + y — 16) = 0
g = x + y — 16 <0
378 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
12 y — 32 + 2y — X = 0
192 - 12y - 6y - 2 = 0
14 y-X = 32
18 y + 2 = 192
32y = 224
y=?
x = 9
EXAMPLE
A factory manufactures two types of heavy-duty machines, x and y. The joint-cost function is
given by
f(x, y) = x2 + 2y2 - xy
To minimize cost, how many machines of each type should be produced if there must be a total
of at least 8 machines?
Assuming the inequality constraint to hold as an equality constraint, 2 = 7 (see page 372).
Since X > 0, the maximum, x = 5, y = 3, assuming the equality constraint is also the maximum
subject to the inequality constraint.
Using the Kuhn-Tucker conditions,
df_
= 2x — y — X = 0
dx
d]_ _ dg
1
= 4y — x — 2 = 0
dy dy
Xg = 2(x + y — 8) = 0
g = x A- y — 8>0
16 — 2y — y — 2 = 0
4y — 8 T 2 = 0
3y + 2 = 16
5y — 2 = 8
8y = 24
y = 3
3.5 Maxima and Minima Subject to Constraints / 379
note: x2 + 2y2 — xy is convex, since 4AC — B1 = 4(1 )(2) — ( — l)2 >0 and A > 0,
C > 0.
EXAMPLE
The relationship between sales S and the amounts x and y spent on two advertising media is
given by
_ 200x lOOv
5 = -+ — —
5 + x 10 + y
Net profit is 5 of sales minus the cost of advertising. The advertising budget has a maximum of
20; determine how it should be allocated between the two media to maximize net profit.
df = 40(5 + x) - 40x
- 1
dx (5 + x)2
df 20(10 + y)-20y
- 1
dy (10 -f y)2
(5 + x)2 * = 200
x = 10v72 - 5
y = 10./2 - 10
Of _ A dg = 20(10 + y) - 20 y _ _ ^ =Q
dy dy (10 + y)2
kg — k(x + y — 25) = 0
g(x, y) = x + y — 25 <0
200x lOOy
note: /(x, y) = ~ - x -y
5 + x 10 + y
1
(5 + x)2 = 200
1
x = 10^/2 - 5
y = 10^2 - 10
380 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
30 — y = 10 + 4
y = 10
x = 15
200
— 1— 2=0
(5 + x)2
200
(10T w -1 - 2=0
if 2 = /(15, 10) = 15, which is less than/(10^/2 — 5, 10^/2 — 10) = 75 — 40N/2. Thus, as
above, the maximum of
200x lOOy
f(x, y) = ^ — x — y
5 + x + 10 + y
/ = Piqi + p2q2
where y° is his fixed income and p{, p2, qx, and q2 are the prices and quantities of
and Q2, respectively.
The budget line y° = pl qx + p2q2 shows all possible combinations of qy and q2
which the consumer can purchase, given his budget constraint. In order to maximize
his utility, the consumer will choose to purchase a combination of qx and q2 lying on
the highest possible indifference curve. As shown in Figure 3.5, this maximizing point
3.6 Applications of Constrained Maximization and Minimization / 381
is the point at which the budget line is tangent to an indifference curve. Any move¬
ment from this point along the budget constraint puts the consumer on a lower
indifference curve and results in diminished utility.
Mathematically, the problem is one of obtaining a constrained maximum:
/ - P i<?i
y° ~ PiqA
U=f 4i>
Pi )
dU
—/i T f 2 ph=o
dqi pi!
and
fi = Pi
h Pi
Then
= fl+f2i~Ppi)
Thus, for a maximum, the ratio of the marginal utilities must equal the ratio of
the prices, or equivalently,
fi = fi
Pi Pi
that is, marginal utility divided by price must be the same for both commodities. This
condition is necessary, but not sufficient, for occurrence of a maximum. The second-
order condition for a maximum requires that
d2U
< 0
dq]
382 / Differential Calculus: Functions of More Than One Variable
But
d2U d ldU\ldqy\ d idU\ldq2
dq\ dq^dqjydqj dq2\dql)\dql
Pi Pi
fll +/l2 + /l2(~L| f22
Pi Pi,
Pi
= /ll + ?/i 2 ( —
P2/ \ P2)
The second-order condition for a maximum requires that
/n + 2/12(-^J+/22(-^J2<0
or
EXAMPLE
If u = qi q2, Pi = 15, p2 = 5, and the consumer’s income for the period is 150, the budget
constraint is
and
U = 30qi - 3q\
dU
= 30 — 6qi
dq i
dU d2U
If — = 0, then qi = 5, q2 = 15, and —r = —6, so the consumer maximizes utility subject
dqi dq\
to his budget constraint by purchasing 5 units of Qx and 15 units of Q2. Note that
fi = qi = 15 = Pi
h qi 5 p2
as required for a maximum.
EXAMPLE
If U — qiqi — 10qr2, = 2, p2 = 8, and the consumer’s income for the period is 116, the
budget constraint is
116 — 2qi — 8^2 = 0
116 - 8^2
qi = = 58 - 4q2
2
3.6 Applications of Constrained Maximization and Minimization / 383
and
dV
— = 116i72 — 14- 40
dq2
Iff = 0,
dq 2
q 2 = —i, 10
d2U
= 116 — 24q2
dql
dHJ
= 116 - 240 = — 124 < 0
dql q 2 =10
So the consumer maximizes utility subject to his budget constraint by purchasing 18 units of
Qi and 10 units of Q2.
Note that
h = d-jo 90 2 Pi
fi 2^i q2 360 8 Pi
oq i
az
= /2 + ^f>2 = o
5q2
az
si
= y° -Pi<h - Piqi = o
Thus
2 _ /i _ fi
Pl P2
and
a = Pi
fi Pi
PROBLEMS
P = x2 + 5 xy — 4 y2
Find the amounts of x and y which maximize production if a. 2x + 3y — 74, b.
2x + 3y < 74.
8. Sales, S, as a function of the amounts, x and y, spent on two types of promotion is given by
240x 150y
“ 25 + 3x + IU • r
Net profit = tuS - x - y. Find the allocation of x and y which will maximize net profit if
x + y = 15.
9. Cost of production, C, as a function of the numbers produced, x and y, of two types of items
is given by
C = 6x2 + 3y2
To minimize cost, what numbers of the two items should be produced if a. x + y — 18, b.
x + y > 18?
10. The cost of repairs, C, as a function of the numbers, x and y, of inspections at two points in
a process is given by
To minimize repair cost, what number of inspections should be made at each point if
x - y = 2?
11. The number of breakdowns, N, as a function of the numbers, x and y, of replacements of
two parts of a machine is given by
To minimize breakdowns, what numbers of replacements should be made for each part if
2x = y?
12. The cost of repairs, C, as a function of the numbers, x and y, of inspections at two points in
a process is given by
To minimize repair costs, what number of inspections should be made at each point if the
total number of inspections is a. 10, b. not fewer than 10?
13. Using Lagrange multipliers, determine the maximum profit if the production function is
z = 20 - x2 + lOx — 2y2 + 5y, the prices of the inputs x and y are 2 and 1, respectively,
and the price of the output is 5. (See Problem 21, page 366.)
14. Using Lagrange multipliers, determine the maximum profit if the production function is
z = 10 — 2x2 + xy — y2 + 5y, the prices of the inputs x and y are each 3, and the price of
the output is 6. (See Problem 22, page 366.)
15. If the consumer’s utility function is U = q\ q2, Pi = 4, p2 = 5, and y° = 120, determine the
quantities and q2 which he should purchase in order to maximize his derived utility.
16. If the consumer’s utility function is U = qx q2 - q\, pi = 3, p2 = 6, and y° = 90, determine
the quantities ql and q2 which he should purchase in order to maximize his derived utility.
17. If the consumer’s utility function is U = q\ + 2q2 + 5q{q2, pl = 5, p2 = 10, and the
consumer’s income for the period is 90, determine the quantities q^ and q2 which he should
purchase in order to maximize his derived utility.
3.6 Applications of Constrained Maximization and Minimization / 385
18. If the consumer’s utility function is U = q{ q2 — 3q2, P\ = 10, p2 — 15, and the consumer’s
income for the period is 180, determine the quantities q1 and q2 which he should purchase
in order to maximize his derived utility.
d2q2 . dq2
Obtain the total derivative ——T by further differentiating -—
dq^ dqj fi
1_
+
dq] pq\ \dqi) a<ji ,<3<?2 \dqj 3qK
But
fdqi\1 _ 8 | fi 1 fi fi fi 1
8 1 l fl\
dql 1l dqj1 8qdi fi) fl
H
II
t-H
<dq2\|_ 5 |f M f11 fl ~ fi fi 1
5 1
dqf\dqi)1 BqJl fj fi
Sq2 _ fi
Sqi fi
Thus
h
fllfl flfl2 + (fllfl fl fll) I
d2g2 fl,
dq] f:
1
— j-i (fufi If 12 fi fi + fn fi)
fi
Substituting/j = (pjp2)lf2
d2q2 1 2 Pi , , f2Pi
,31/n/l ~2fl2 fl^+fn f i 2
dq] J 2 \ Pi Pi
1
(fnPi ~ 2/12P1P2 +/22P1)
f2Pi
d2q2
>0
dq\
and the indifference curves are convex from below.
MU -
Integral
Calculus
4.1 Introduction
Integration has two distinct interpretations; integration is a procedure which is the
inverse of differentiation, and it is a method of determining the area under a curve.
There are many important applications of integration in each of these contexts.
As an operation, integration is the inverse of differentiation. Thus if a function is
differentiated and the resulting function is then integrated, the result is the original
function. As discussed below, this is precisely true only if the constant of integration
is specified in some way; otherwise the result may differ from the original function by
a constant. In this context, integration is the process of finding a function when its
derivative (or rate of change) is known. In economics, integration can be used to find
a total cost function when the marginal cost function is given, to find a total revenue
function when the marginal revenue function is given, and so forth.
Integration can also be defined as the process of finding the limiting value of a sum
of terms when the number of terms increases infinitely and the numerical value of
each term approaches zero. It is in this context that integration is interpreted as
finding the area under a curve. In fact, integral calculus was developed for the
purpose of evaluating areas by supposing them to be divided into an infinite number
of infinitesimally small parts whose sum is the area required; the integral sign is the
elongated S used by early writers to indicate “sum.” In economics total revenue can
be evaluated as the area under the marginal revenue curve, consumer’s surplus and
producer’s surplus can be evaluated as areas under demand and supply curves, and
so forth.
For either application, integration requires operationally that a function be
determined when its derivative is given. Unfortunately, the techniques of integration
are inherently more difficult than those of differentiation and there are functions,
some of them deceptively simple in appearance, whose integrals cannot be expressed
in terms of elementary functions. The simpler cases of integration are accomplished
by reversing the corresponding formulas for differentiation; more complicated cases
are handled by the use of tables of standard forms, by various procedures of substitu¬
tion, and, if necessary, by numerical (approximation) methods.
The two interpretations of integration and some of their applications in business
and economics are discussed first, using functions that are easily integrated by revers-
387
388 / Integral Calculus
ing the formulas for differentiation. Subsequent sections discuss special methods
useful for integrating more difficult functions and several approximate methods of
integration. Multiple integration, the inverse of partial differentiation, is also defined
and illustrated.
| /(x) dx = F(x) 4- C
where the left-hand member is read “ integral of/of x with respect to x.” The symbol
j is an integral sign,f(x) is the integrand, F(x) is a particular integral, C is the constant
of integration, and F(x) + C is the indefinite integral.
Note that if F(x) is an integral of/(x) with respect to x, then F(x) + C is also such
an integral, where C is any constant, since the derivative of any constant is zero—that
is,
dF(x) dC
^[FW + C] =
dx dx
dF(x)
dx
which is /(x) if F(x) is an integral of /(x) with respect to x. Thus a function whose
derivative is given is not completely determined, since the integral includes an arbi¬
trary additive constant, the constant of integration. It is for this reason that the
function j /(x) dx is referred to as the indefinite integral of f(x).
It can be shown that two functions which have the same derivative differ at most
by a constant; thus if F(x) is an integral of/(x), all integrals of/(x) are included in
the set F(x) + C, where C is any constant. In many applications of integration,
certain information given in the problem, often referred to as an initial or boundary
condition, uniquely specifies the constant of integration.
Geometrically, y = F(x) + C represents a family of curves any one of which can
be obtained by shifting the curve y = F(x) (corresponding to C = 0) through a
vertical displacement C (see Figure 4.1). The curves represented by y = F(x) + C are
parallel to each other in the sense that the slope of the tangent to any one of them at
the point having abscissa x is /(x). Thus this family of curves has the property that,
given any point (x0, y0), there is one and only one curve of the family which passes
through this particular point. For the curve to pass through the point, its equation
must be satisfied by the coordinates of the point, and this uniquely specifies the value
of C, since then
c = y0 ~ F(xo)
4.2 Indefinite Integration / 389
Figure 4.1
EXAMPLE
The integral of /(x) = 4x — 3 can be obtained by reversing the appropriate formulas for
differentiation:
| (4x — 3) dx = 2x2 — 3x + C
2x2 — 3x + C = 5
C = 5
and
F(x) = 2x2 — 3x + 5
which specifies a particular curve of the family given by F(x) = 2x2 — 3x + C. (See Figure 4.2.)
390 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.2
v
The rules (or standard forms) for integration used in the preceding example are
obtained directly by reversing the corresponding rules for differentiation and can be
summarized as follows:
1. j dx = x 4- C.
3. I (du + dv) = du + dv, where u =f(x) and v = g(x) are differentiable functions
J
of x.
r Xn+1
4. xn dx =-- + C, n — 1.
J n+ 1
u n+ 1
5. I un du — 4~ C, n =£ — 1,
n + 1
EXAMPLE
O v-3
2x512
x3/2 dx = + C (rule 4)
5
4.2 Indefinite Integration / 391
u3 du
l^x2
61 4
+ l+,c
2 (rule 5)
(3x2 + 2)4
4- C
24
Alternatively,
27xf
+ 9x6 + 9x4 4- 4x2 4- C
“ 8~~
(3x2 4- 2)A
4- C
24
Note that C in the last step is not equal to C in the preceding step, since
and the value of C in the last step is thus -jJ less than the value of C in the preceding step. It is
customary to make no notational distinction when the value of a constant of integration is
changed by changing the form of the equation.
EXAMPLE
If x = 0, y = 0, then C = 0 and
_ (x + 2)3
~ 3
= x3 4- x2 4- 6x + C
y = x3 + x2 4- 6x + 5
392 / Integra! Calculus
EXAMPLE
For each of the following, find the curve having the given slope and passing through the given
point.
x2 - 4
(a) dx = dx dx
x
4x“1 „
— x H —- + C
— x H-h C
X
Thus
4 r
y = x H-h C
x
1 = 4 + 1 + C
C = -4
so
y = x H-4
x
x2 - 4x + 4
(x - 2):
x 7/2
7 +c
T
= 4*7/2 + C
Thus
y = 4*7/2 + C
2
0 = 4+
7 C
c= -4
so
y = fx7'2 - 4
= +7,2-i)
= +3 i)
is the required curve.
4.2 Indefinite Integration / 393
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following integrals.
1. (X- x 4- 4) dx (1 — 2x)2 dx
9.
Jlx
(2 - 7r)2/3 dt dx
10.
tyflx
dx (x3 — 1) dx
4. 12.
(3x 4- 2)2 x — 1
3r dr
5. 13. (2x 4- 3) dx
(z 4- 1) dz
8.
3 ^z2 + 2z 4- 2
dy
16. Find the equation of the curve having slope — = 2x — 5 and passing through the point
dx
(5, 4).
dy
17. Find the equation of the curve having slope — = (x 4- l)(x + 2) and passing through the
dx
point (-3, -§).
dp
19. If and p = 2a if x = ?a3, find the value of p if x = 2a5.
dx lax
20. Find the equation of the curve for which/" = 2 and which has a slope of —2 at its point of
inflection (1, 3).
21. Find the equation of the curve for which y" = x3 and which is tangent to the line
2x + y = 5 at the point (1, 3).
22. Find the equation of the curve for which y" = 6x2 and which passes through the points
(0, 2) and (— 1, 3).
23. Find the equation of the curve for which y" = x and which passes through the point (1, 2)
with a slope of f.
24. Find the equation of the curve which has a slope of zero at the point (0, 2), has a point of
inflection at (— 1, ^), and for which y" = 4.
5. -3^1 - 71 + C 13. x2 + 3x + C
COST
If the total cost y of producing and marketing x units of a commodity is given by the
function
V = /(*)
y _ f(x)
X X
That is, marginal cost is the derivative with respect to x, /'(x), of the total cost
function y —f (x). Thus total cost is the integral with respect to x of the marginal cost
function; that is,
f'(x) dx = f (x) 4- C
EXAMPLE
y - 1.064 - 0.005x
Find the total and average cost functions if fixed cost is 16.3.
y = [ (1.064 - 0.005x) dx
= 1.064x - 0.0025x2 + C
4.3 Applications of Indefinite Integration in Business and Economics / 395
EXAMPLE
Find the total and average cost functions if fixed cost is 65.
y = | (2 + 60x — 5x2) dx
= 2x + 30x2 — -fx3 + C
REVENUE
For any demand function
y =/(*)
where y is the price per unit and x is the number of units, total revenue, R, is the
product of x and y; that is,
R = xy = x • /(x)
Marginal revenue with respect to demand is the derivative with respect to x of the
total revenue
Thus the total revenue function is the integral with respect to x of the marginal
revenue function; that is,
R = R (x) dx
And, since
R'(x) dx = R{x) + C
EXAMPLE
R'(x) = 8 — 6x — 2x2
R(x) = j (8 — 6x — 2x2) dx
= 8x — 3x2 — §x3 + C
R = 8x — 3x2 — -j*3
y = — = 8 — 3x — -jx2
x
EXAMPLE
R'(x) = 12 - 8x + x2
y = — = 12 — 4x + 3X2
x
= (6 ~ *)2
c =/(x)
where c is total national consumption and x is total national income, then the
marginal propensity to consume is the derivative with respect to x of the consumption
function
Total national consumption is the integral with respect to x of the marginal propen¬
sity to consume,
c = ( f(x) dx =f(x) + C
EXAMPLE
dc 0.2
— = 0.7 + —f=
dx ./x
When income is zero, consumption is 8 billion dollars. Find the consumption function.
c = 0.7 + 74 | dx
= 0.7x + 0.4^/x + C
c = 8 + 0.7x 4- 0.4^/x
EXAMPLE
Ihe marginal propensity to save is 3. When income is zero, consumption is 11 billion dollars.
Find the consumption function.
dc ds 2
dx dx 3
= ix + C
c = f x + 11
CAPITAL FORMATION
The process of adding to a given stock of capital is referred to as capital formation. If
this process is considered to be continuous over time, capital stock can be expressed
as a function of time, K(t), and the rate of capital formation is then given by
= K'(t). The rate of capital formation at time t is the same as the rate of net
dt
investment flow at time t, denoted by I(t). Thus
and capital stock is the integral with respect to time of the rate of capital formation
or, equivalently, the integral with respect to time of net investment. And, since
f /(f) dt = K(t) + C
EXAMPLE
If investment flow is given by 7(f) = 5f3/7 and the initial capital stock at t = 0 is K(0), find the
function representing capital, K.
K = 5t3n dt
= ^10/7 + C
K = it1011 + K(0)
EXAMPLE
If investment flow is given by I(t) = 15r1/4 and the initial capital stock at t = 0 is 30, find the
function representing capital, K.
K = 15t1/4 dt
= 12f5/4 + C
K = 12f5/4 + 30
PROBLEMS
1. If marginal revenue is a constant different from zero, show that price is constant.
2. If R'(x) = 0 and R(0) =/= 0, what is the nature of the demand curve?
3. If marginal cost is constant, show that the cost function is a straight line.
4. The marginal propensity to consume (in billions of dollars) is
dc 0.5
= 0.6 +
dx 2X171
When income is zero, consumption is 10 billion dollars. Find the consumption function.
5. The marginal cost function for production is / = 10 + 24x — 3x* 1 2 3 4; if the (total) cost of
producing 1 unit is 25, find the total cost function and the average cost function.
6. The marginal propensity to save is When income is zero, consumption is 6 billion
dollars. Find the consumption function.
7. If marginal revenue is R! = 15 — 9.x — 3x2, find the revenue and demand functions.
3 2
8. If marginal revenue is K = —r-, find the revenue and demand functions if R(l) = 6.
x x
4.4 Definite Integration / 399
9. If marginal revenue is R' = 10 — 5x, find the revenue and demand functions.
10. If marginal revenue is R' = 20 — 3x2, find the revenue and demand functions.
11. The marginal propensity to consume (in billions of dollars) is
dc 1
0.5 +
dx 3^
When income is zero, consumption is 6 billion dollars. Find the consumption function.
12. The marginal propensity to save (in billions of dollars) is
dc 1
= 1 - 0.4 -
ds 6x2/3
When income is zero, consumption is 9 billion dollars. Find the consumption function.
13. If investment flow is given by I(t) = 20t3/7 and the initial capital stock at t - 0 is 25, find
the function representing capital, K.
14. If investment flow is given by 7(f) = 25f4/11 and the initial capital stock at t = 0 is 22, find
the function representing capital, K.
Z f(x i) Axi
i= 1
400 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.3
note: The same limit would be obtained by circumscribing rather than inscrib¬
ing the rectangles, that is,
exists,/(x) is said to be integrable over the interval [a, b], and it can be shown that
Figure 4.4
y
i AA
bg < —— < ce
and let Ax —► 0. (If it happens that the shape off(x) is such that ce < bg, the inequal¬
ity signs can be reversed without affecting the argument.) Then, since y is a contin¬
uous function of x, ce approaches bg and
dA
— bg = y =f(x)
dx
dA = f(x) dx
Integrating,
0 = F(a) + C
C = -F(a)
and
A = F(x) - F(a)
A = F(b) - F(a)
402 / Integral Calculus
which is denoted by
b b
y dx or f(x)dx
Ja Ja
2. f(x) dx = 0.
r /
3. f(x)dx= f(x)dx+\ f(x) dx, where a < c < b
note: For some problems, definite integrals occur for which one or both limits
of integration are infinite. An integral of the form
. b 00 00
00 b
oo
If the limit exists, the improper integral converges; if the limit does not exist, the
improper integral diverges.
EXAMPLE
(First Property)
(y2 - 4):
J y(y2 - 4)2 dy =
= -V--41
152 76
- —s- - —r
and
(Second Property)
= - W2-[-!(2)3/2]
= 0
(Third Property)
1 -V dv = I (v1/2 + v~112) dv
i ji
= tfv3'2 + 2vll2]t
= ie+4_2_2
_
-T
20
4
vV T
+ 1 , r 2 v 4- 1 l> + 1
dv = dv
1 x/V 1 x/ t?
[i
- r2„3/2
«3'2 + 2d1'2]? + [V'2 + 2i>1,2]‘
n
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following integrals.
„ 2 2 X2
v2 - 1
J. (4x + 1)1/2 dx 10. dx
o i x
. 8
dx
11. (w1/3 — w 1/3) du
o (2x + l)3 i
,“2
5. j f(r + l)2 dt 12. (2x + x2 — x3) dx
J-i
la
6. I ( x2 H—, I dx 13. (a3 + 3ax2 + x3) dx
r3
7. (20 + 1 )(3 — 0) 14. j" (y/a — y/x)2 dx
•'i
404 / Integral Calculus
*T
The importance of this theorem results from the fact that it permits the evaluation
of the limit of a sum of terms by integration and that this limit can be interpreted as
the area under a curve. Specifically, the definite integral \ba f(x) dx can be interpreted
as the area bounded by the continuous positive curve y =/(x), the x-axis, and the
lines x = a and x = b.
EXAMPLE
y = x3 + 3x2
Figure 4.5
x
4.4 Definite Integration / 405
EXAMPLE
x2y = x2 — 4
Figure 4.6
y
dx = [x + 4x ^2
= (4+1)-(2+ 2)
= 1
EXAMPLE
Find the area in the first quadrant bounded by the x-axis and the curve
y = 6x + x2 — x3
2 X3 X4
A = (6x -I- x2 — x3) dx = = (27 + 9 -0 = 15i
*’0 + 3 4
406 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.7
(1.8, 8.3)
y — 6x + x2 — x3
(-1.1, 6.7)
EXAMPLE
y = x2 — 4x
A — 4.x) dx = 8) = lOf
Figure 4.8
y
= x2 — 4x
4.4 Definite Integration / 407
A — | f(x)dx
A = f(x) dx
is negative. Such areas below the x-axis are called negative areas; the total absolute
area between a curve, the x-axis, and two ordinates is given by
EXAMPLE
y = 2x + x2 — x3
i r 3
X
, X X
— —
x 2 -f" --—
4 0 3 4
Figure 4.9
(- 0.55, - 0.63)
408 / Integral Calculus
EXAMPLE_
y = x3 — 4x
Figure 4.10
y
A 4x) dx 4x) dx
x4 0 X4 2
— 2x2 —— 2x2
~4 -2 4 0
oo
)]-[( 4 - 8) - 0]
1
4-(-4)
A = I [g(x) -fix)] dx
a
Note that this formula includes negative areas (with appropriate signs) in the total
area between the curves.
4.4 Definite Integration / 409
Figure 4.11
y
EXAMPLE
y = x2 and y = x
y = x = x2
x(l — x) = 0
x = 0, 1
Figure 4.12
y
410 / Integral Calculus
If x = 0, y = 0; if x = 1, y = 1. Thus
= (i ~ i) ~ 0
i
= z
EXAMPLE
y = x3 and y = 2x2
y = x3 = 2x2
x2(x — 2) = 0
x = 0, 2
If x = 0, y — 0; if x = 2, y = 8. Thus
. 2 [2x3 x4!2
A = (2x2 — x3) dx =
•'o
= (¥ - 4) - 0
_ 34
-
Figure 4.13
y
4.4 Definite Integration / 411
EXAMPLE_
x + 2y = 2 y — x = [ and 2x + y = 7
Figure 4.14
y
x + 2y — 2 x + 2y = 2 y — x = 1
y — x = 1 2x 4- y = 7 2x + y = 7
3y = 3 — 3y = 3 3y = 9
1 -1 y = 3
x =0 x = 4 x = 2
2 4
2 — x 2 — x^
A = (1 + x) — dx + j (7 - 2x) - dx
f2 f4 3x2 2 3x2 4
= |x dx + (6 — fx) dx = + 6x--—
•'o "2 4 0 4 2
= 6
EXAMPLE
y — x2 y = x y — 2x
y = x = x2 y = 2x = x2 y = x = 2x
x(x — 1) = 0 x(x — 2) = 0 x = 0
x = 0, 1 x = 0, 2 y = 0
If x = 0, y = 0 If x = 0, y = 0
If x = 1, y = 1 If x = 2, y = 4
Thus
A =
, 1
(2x — x) dx +
,2
(2x — x2) dx
J0 Ji
x'
+
* -y
i — 0 + (4 — f) — (1 — j)
7
= 6
EXAMPLE
y = x2 and y = x
4.4 Definite Integration / 413
2y 3/2 r
A = (y12 -y)dy = = a - i) - o=i
2
EXAMPLE
y = x3 and y = 2x* 2 3
= (12-¥)-0 =
EXAMPLE
x + 2y = 2 y — x = 1 2x + y = 7
I(y + 1) dy + f 1(3 - y) dy
j -1 ji
i
V , 3y 9y 3y: 3
+
4 2 -i
= (I + f) - (I -!) + (¥-¥)-(!- i)
= 6
EXAMPLE
y = x2 y = x y = 2x
A = 1/2 y
y -\\ dy + y
~2]dy
r +
2 y3/2 y2
4 3 4
= i - 0 + (4f - 4) - (i - i)
7
=5
414 / Integral Calculus
Probability as an Area
One of the most useful applications of definite integration to obtain the area under a
curve is in evaluating probabilities. The probability of an event can be obtained by
determining the corresponding area under a frequency function. A frequency function
for a continuous variable x is a function f(x) having the following properties
1. /(x) > 0
2. f(x) dx = 1
b
3. j f(x) dx = P(a < x < b)
a
note: Iff(x) is continuous, P(a < x < b) = P(a < x < b).
Figure 4.16
fix)
EXAMPLE
In an autoparts warehouse, the proportion of orders filled per day has a frequency function
given by
(a) What is the probability that less than 20 percent of the orders will be filled in a day?
(b) What is the probability that between 90 and 100 percent of the orders will be filled in a
day?
4.4 Definite Integration / 415
0.2
(a) P(x < 0.20) = 20 (x3 — x4) dx
•'o
0.2
= 20
0.00032\
= 20
~5/
= 0.008 - 0.00128
= 0.00672
x X
i
= 20
T T 0.9
= 20
5 r 0.6561
4
0.59049^
5
= (5 - 4) - (3.2805 - 2.36196)
= 0.08146
Figure 4,17
fix)
416 / Integral Calculus
So f(x) dx = 1 as required for a frequency function; note also thatf(x) > 0 for 0 < x < 1
and is zero elsewhere.
EXAMPLE
Suppose that measurements of daily temperature are recorded to the nearest tenth of a degree.
Then the difference between the true and recorded temperatures, the rounding error, is be¬
tween — 0.05 and 0.05 degrees. If the error is uniformly distributed in this interval, its
frequency function is represented by
Note that, in general, if x is uniformly distributed on the interval a < x < b, then
/M — i- a < x < b
b — a
(a) What is the probability that the rounding error is between —0.01 and 0.01?
(b) What is the probability that the rounding error is between 0.04 and 0.05?
o.oi
(a) P(-0.01 < x < 0.01) =| 10 dx
J-o.oi
= [IOxT-Tch
= [iOx]Voi
= 0.5 - 0.4 = 0.1
Figure 4.18
/ (x)
4.4 Definite Integration / 417
Note that
0.05
10 dx = 10 dx = [10x]° o5os
- 0.05
= 0.5 - (-0.5) = 1
So f(x)dx= 1 as required for a frequency function; note also that/(x) > Ofor —0.05 <
x < 0.05 and is zero elsewhere.
PROBLEMS
Sketch each of the following curves and find the area bounded by the curve, the x-axis, and the
given ordinates.
1. y = y/x; x = 1, x = 16
2. y = 2x + l;x = 0, x = 4
3. y = x"; x = 0, x = 1
4. y = 3x2; x = 1, x = 3
5. y = x2 — 3x; x = — 1, x — 4
6. y = — x2 4- 4x (and x-axis)
lx2 x < 2
7. /M = \ — x + 6 x = 0, x = 3
x > 2
|2x + 3 x < 3
8. /(x) = x = 2, x = 5
— x + 12 x > 3
9. Find the area between the curve y = 2x4 — x2, the x-axis, and the two minimum ordinates.
10. Find the area bounded by the coordinate axes and the parabolic arc yfx + y/y — y/a.
Draw a sketch and find the area bounded by the following curves.
11. y2 = 2x 21. y = x2
y = x — 4 y = x + 2
12. x2 = 2ay y = —3x + 18
y — 2a 22. y = 4x — 4
13. y = x — x2 y = W
y = —x y = 6 - x
14. y2 = 4ax 23. y = x3 + 3x2 + 2
x2 = 4 ay y = x3 + 6x2 — 25
15. y2 = x 24. y = 25 - x2
y = x3 y = (5 - *)2
16. y = (x — l)3 25. y = x3 — 3x2 — lOx
>' = x2 - x - 1 y = — 6x
17. y2 = 5a2 — ax 26. y = (x + 2)(x — l)(x — 5)
y2 = 4ax y = (x + 2)(x — 1)
18. x2y = 4 27. y = x(x — 3)(x -I- 3)
y = 7 — 3x y = — 5x
19. y = x2 28. y = x3 4- 3x2 + 6
y = 8 — x2 y = x3 + 4x2 -I- 5x
y = 4x + 12 29. y = x3 — 5x2 — 8x + 12
20. y3 = x2 y = x3 — 6x2 + 21
2x -I- y + 1 = 0
x - y = 4
HINTS
15. y2 = x and y = x3 intersect (0, 0) and (1, 1)
18. x2y = 4 and y = 7 - 3x intersect (1, 4) and (2, 1)
20. y3 = x2 and 2x + y -F 1 = 0 intersect (-1, 1)
y3 = x2 and x - y = 4 intersect (8, 4)
418 / Integral Calculus
1 x2
/M 24 + 1152
0 < x < 12
a. Find the probability that the center is in operation between 10 and 12 hours a day. b.
Find the probability that the center is in operation less than 6 hours a day.
31. A firm has a very large number of company cars for use by its employees. Records of the
time each car is out of service for repairs are kept as the basis for deciding when a car
should be sold. The frequency function for the total number of days a car is out of service
before it is considered too expensive to repair and is sold is given by
3 x2 4x3
b- f(x) — g 576, 0 < x < 24 e- f(x) 1 < x < 2
U'
1. 42 19. 64
23
3. 0.01 21. 6
49
5. T 23. 108
37
7. "5" 25. 160J
7
9. I2T> 27. 8
11. 18 29. 166§
13. 34 31. a. 0.002
15. T2 b. 0.632
17.
CONSUMERS' SURPLUS
A demand function represents the quantities of a commodity that would be
purchased at various prices. If the market price is y0 and the corresponding market
demand is x0, then those consumers who would be willing to pay more than this
4.5 Applications of Definite Integration in Business and Economics / 419
Figure 4.19
market price gain from the fact that the price is only y0 (see Figure 4.19). Under
certain economic assumptions, the total consumer gain is represented by the area
below the demand curve and above the line y = y0 • This area is designated by
Marshall as consumers surplus and is evaluated as
r x°
consumers’ surplus = f(x) dx ~ x0y0
Jo
where the demand function is x = g(y) and m0 is the value of y when x = 0, that is, m0
is the y-intercept of the demand function. Thus
mo
rxo
consumers’ surplus = f(x) dx - x0y0 g(y) dy
jo yo
EXAMPLE
(a) if x0 = 3,
(b) if y0 = 27. (See Figure 4.20.)
3
32x — 2x2 — — - 33
= (96 — 18 — 9) — 0 — 33
= 36
420 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.20
= 32x — 2x2 * — * — 27
3 o
= (32 - 2 - J) - 0 - 27
_ 38
=
EXAMPLE
If the demand function is y = x/9_ — x and x0 = 5, find the consumers’ surplus using two
different methods (see Figure 4.21).
consumers’ surplus =
* 5
(9 — x)1/2 dx — (5)(2) = I
/» (9 — y2) dy
* 0 J2
= —( — 18) — 10 = f
Alternatively,
y3
2
(9 - y2) dy =
h-y]
8\ 8
= ( 27-9)-
4.5 Applications of Definite Integration in Business and Economics / 421
Figure 4.21
y
EXAMPLE
The quantity sold and the corresponding price, under a monopoly, are determined by the
demand function y = 16 — x2 and by the marginal cost y' = 6 + x in such a way as to maxi¬
mize profit. Determine the corresponding consumers’ surplus (see Figure 4.22).
revenue = 16x — x3
Profit is maximized when marginal revenue equals marginal cost—that is, when
16 — 3x2 = 6 + x
3x2 + x — 10 = 0
(3x — 5)(x + 2) = 0
x = -j, -2
Figure 4.22
y
X
422 / Integral Calculus
so x0 = $, yo = H1-
r 5/3
consumers’ surplus = (16 — x2) dx — (iJfH2)
x3l5/3 595
16x —
T o Yf
125 5_9_5
~8rr )-o- 27
3.09
PRODUCERS' SURPLUS
A supply function represents the respective quantities of a commodity that would be
supplied at various prices. If the market price is y0 and the corresponding market
supply is x0, then those producers who would be willing to supply the commodity
below this market price gain from the fact that the price is y0 . Under certain econom¬
ic assumptions the total producer gain is represented by the area above the supply
curve and below the line y = y0 and is known as producers' surplus (see Figure 4.23).
This area is evaluated as
where the supply function is x = g(y) and M0 is the value of y when x = 0, that is, M0
is the y-intercept of the supply function.
* xo ~ yo
producers’ surplus = x0y0 - /(x) dx = g(y) dy
J0 ‘'Mo
Figure 4.23
y
4.5 Applications of Definite Integration in Business and Economics / 423
EXAMPLE
If the supply function is y = (x + 2)2 and the price is y0 = 25, find the producers’ surplus using
two different methods (see Figure 4.24).
3 25
producers’ surplus = (3)(25) — (x + 2)2 dx = f (y1/2 - 2) dy
•'o
(x + 2)' = 75 _ (125 _ 8) = 36
75 (x + 2)2 dx = 75 —
Figure 4.24
y
Alternatively,
25 3/2 25
2y = (150 _ 50) _ _ 8) = 36
(.y1/2 “2)dy = - 2y
(as above).
EXAMPLE
The quantity demanded and the corresponding price, under pure competition, are determined
by the demand and supply functions y = 16 — x2 and y = 4 + x, respectively. Determine the
corresponding producers’ surplus (see Figure 4.25).
y = 16 — x2 = 4 + x
x2 + x — 12 = 0
(x + 4)(x — 3) = 0
x = 3, —4
*o = 3, yo = 7
424 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.25
y
= 21 - [(12 + f) - 0]
note: The area represented by jo (4 + x) dx could have been evaluated also by the
formula for the area of a trapezoid, A = ja(bl + b2) = f(4 + 7) =
EXAMPLE
The quantity demanded and the corresponding price, under pure competition, are determined
by the demand and supply functions y = 36 — x2 and y = 6 + (x2/4), respectively. Determine
the corresponding consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus (see Figure 4.26).
x
y — 36 — x2 = 6 + -~
5x2 = 120
x2 = 24
x = ±2^6
x0 = 2v/6, y0 = 12
2V6
36x — ~ — 24^/6
3 o
= 32n/6 a 78.4
4.5 Applications of Definite Integration in Business and Economics / 425
Figure 4.26
y
2V6
, X
= 24^/6 —
6X+12 0
= 8^/6 « 19.6
EXAMPLE
Find the profit-maximizing output and the total profit at that point if the marginal revenue
and marginal cost functions are given by
MR = 25 - 5x — 2x2
MC = 15 — 2x — x2
If MR - MC = 0,
25 — 5x — 2x2 — 15 + 2x -F x2 = 0
10 — 3x — x2 = 0
(5 + x)(2 — x) = 0
x = —5, 2
426 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.27
MR, MC
The first derivative of MR — MC is the second derivative of total profit and its sign thus
indicates whether profit is maximized or minimized for a particular value of x.
d2P
^ (MR - MC) = jP2= - 3 - 2x and = -7
UA wA dx2 x= 2
= (20 - 6 - f) - 0
_ 34
- ~y
EXAMPLE
A manufacturing company has purchased a machine that has an output representing addi¬
tional earnings (additional revenue minus additional cost of labor and materials) at time t of
Figure 4.28
E(t), Rif)
(30, 0) Time
where E(t) is in units of $10,000 and t is years. The additional repair and maintenance cost at
time t is
R(t) = 2t2
where R(t) is in units of $10,000 and t is years. First, suppose that the machine can be disposed
of at any time with no cost or salvage value. Then the machine should be disposed of at the
time when additional earnings equals additional cost of repair and maintenance (see Figure
4.28).
Additional earnings equals additional cost of repair and maintenance if
225 = 112
t2 = 100
t = 10
Thus the machine should be disposed of after 10 years. The total net earnings (earnings minus
cost of repair and maintenance) after 10 years is
.10 .10
[E(t) - R(t)] dt = (225 - Jr2) dt
*0 ^0
= [225r - Jr3]J0
= (2250 - 750) - 0
= 1500 or $15,000,000
6480
6 T t
where S(t) is in units of $10,000 and t is years. Then the company will maximize its net earnings
if it disposes of the machine at time T when the net earnings after T equals the salvage value at
T (see Figure 4.29).
428 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.29
S(/), Nit)
10
3t:
2251 -
T
6480
= 1500 - 2257 + |73
6 + 7
EXAMPLE
A company is considering adding salesmen to its staff. The cost of employing additional
salesmen is
5y2 = 48x
where y is cost in units of $1,000 and x is number of additional salesmen employed, and the
additional revenue is
Figure 4.30
y,R
The cost of employing additional salesmen equals the additional revenue obtained if R y-
From the first equation,
V
x =
48
(R - 2)2 - 40
x =
5y2 (R - 2)2 - 40
48~ 4
y = 12
x = 15
and 15 additional salesmen should be employed. The total resulting net revenue (total revenue
minus cost) is
[v2 l12
= ~ +9 y — rAy3
^ o
= 96 or $96,000
430 / Integral Calculus
PROBLEMS
1. If the demand function is y = 39 — x2, find the consumers’ surplus if a. x0 = | and b. the
commodity is free, that is, y0 = 0.
2. If the demand function is y = 16 - x2 and the supply function is y = 2x + 1, find con¬
sumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus under pure competition.
3. If the supply function is y = -J9 + x and x0 = 7, find the producers’ surplus.
4. If the supply function is y — 4ex/3 and x0 = 3, find the producers’ surplus.
5. The demand and supply functions under pure competition are y = ^(9 — x)2 and
y = i(l + 3x), respectively. If an additive tax of 3 per unit quantity is imposed on the
commodity, determine the decrease in consumers’ surplus.
6. Under monopoly, the quantity sold and the corresponding price are determined by the
demand function y = ^(10 — x)2 and the total cost function y — (x3/4) -I- 5x so that profit is
maximized. Determine the corresponding consumers’ surplus.
7. Under monopoly, the quantity sold and the corresponding price are determined by the
demand function y = 20 — 4x2 and the marginal cost function / = 2x + 6 so that profit is
maximized. Determine the corresponding consumers’ surplus.
8. If the demand function is that part of the equilateral hyperbola y = [8/(x + 1)] — 2 in the
first quadrant, and the supply curve is y = \(x + 3), find the consumers’ surplus and the
producers’ surplus under pure competition.
9. Under monopoly, the quantity sold and the corresponding price are determined by the
demand function y = 45 — x2 and the marginal cost function y' = 6 + (x2/4) so that profit
is maximized. Determine the corresponding consumers’ surplus.
10. The demand and supply functions under pure competition are, respectively, y = 14 — x2
and y = 2x2 + 2; find a. consumers’ surplus, and b. producers’ surplus.
11. The demand function is y = 20 — 3x2 and the supply function is y = 2x2; find the con¬
sumers’ surplus and the producers’ surplus under pure competition.
12. The demand and supply functions under pure competition are, respectively, y = 32 — 2x2
and y = -3X2 + 2x -I- 5; find a. consumers’ surplus, and b. producers’ surplus.
13. Find the profit-maximizing output and the corresponding total profit, assuming pure
competition, if MR = 20 — 2x and MC = 4-1- (x — 4)2.
14. The marginal revenue function is MR = 25 - 3x and the marginal cost function is
MC = 25 — 7x + x2. Find the profit-maximizing output and the corresponding total
profit under pure competition.
15. If MR = 44 — 9x and MC = 20 — 7x + 2x2, find the profit-maximizing output and the
corresponding total profit under pure competition.
16. Assuming pure competition, find the profit-mqximizing output and the corresponding
total profit if MR = 24 — 6x — x2 and MC = 4 — 2x — x2.
17. If MR = 15 — 5x and MC = 10 — 3x + 3x2, find the profit-maximizing output and the
corresponding total profit assuming pure competition.
18. A manufacturing company has purchased a machine whose output represents earnings at
time t given by y2 = 6(t -I- 9), where y is in units of $10,000 and t is years. The repair and
maintenance cost at time t is given by (y + 4)2 = 8(f -F 17), where y is in units of $10,000
and t is years. Assuming the machine can be disposed of at any time with no cost or
salvage value, how many years should it be kept to maximize total net earnings (earnings
minus cost of repair and maintenance)?
19. A company is considering purchasing additional companion units for its computer. The
savings (in time and mistakes) from added units is given by y = 3x2 + 11, where y is in
units of $11,000 and x is number of units added. The cost of repair and maintenance is
given by y = 4x2 + 2, where y is in units of $1000 and x is the number of units added. To
maximize total net revenue (revenue minus cost of repair and maintenance), how many
units should be added and what is the associated savings? Assume the units are added in a
specified order and that the savings and cost curves are continuous.
20. A company is considering adding advertising personnel. The cost of adding such personnel
is given by y = \x, where y is in units of $5000 and x is the number of personel added.
Additional revenue from adding personnel is R2 = 4x, where R is in units of $5000 and x is
number of personnel added. What number of advertising personnel should be added to
4.6 Special Methods of Integration / 431
maximize profit (revenue minus cost) and what is the associated additional revenue?
Assume continuous functions.
21. If net investment flow is 7(f) = 6r1/2, determine a. capital accumulation during the first
year; b. capital accumulation during the first nine years; and c. total amount of capital
after the first nine years if the initial capital is $500.
22. If net investment flow is 7(f) = 4f1/3, determine a. capital accumulation during the first
year; b. capital accumulation during the first eight years; and c. total amount of capital
after the first eight years if the initial capital is $500.
1. dx = x + C.
.
2. K dx = K dx, where K is any constant.
ft
3. [du + dv] = du dv, where u = f(x) and v = g(x) are differentiable func-
tions of x.
432 / Integral Calculus
xn + 1
f W n+ 1
5. un du =-h C, n + — 1, where u = f(x) is a differentiable function of x.
f 1
6. - du = In u + C, where w =/(x) is a differentiable function of x.
» Vi
9. j sin u du = —cos u du + C.
du 1 a + u ^ ,
19. = — In -+ C, u2 < a2.
a — u 2a a — u
du 1 , u —a ^ ,
20. = — In-1- C, ir > a .
u2 — a2 2a u + a
du
21. = In (n -(- yju2 “t- a ) -I- C.
yju2 + a'
u
22. | x/u2 4- u2 dw = + u2 -f In (w + w “I- a ) -f~ C.
24. j In u du = u In u — u + C.
26. I — = In (In u) + C.
J u In u
The first step in the procedure for integrating a given expression consists of
comparing it with various standard forms. If an expression is identical with a stan¬
dard form, its integral is known; if an expression is not identical with a standard
form, there are various methods by which it may in some cases be reduced to a
standard form. Some of these methods are discussed in later sections.
EXAMPLES
r x dx 1 r 2.x dx
x2 + 1 2 x2 + 1
(standard form 8)
(standard form 5)
a + c tan by be J a + c tan by
f 7C
7t esc Ox dx = - In (esc 0x — cot 0x) 4- C (standard form 18)
J 0
| x cot (x2 -}- 0x) dx = j In sin (x2 4- 0x) + C (standard form 16)
4 + 6x 1 , (V6 + 4x 4- 3x2\
(standard form 20)
. 6 — (4x -I- 3x2)2 2v/6 176 — 4x — 3x2/
In (x2 — 3x — 1) 1
= (x2 — 3x — l)f + C
5 25
x + 1
(x2 4- 2x 4- 6)1/2 4- | In [(x 4- 1) 4- (x2 4- 2x 4- 6)12] 4 C
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following integrals.
cos x dx sin 2x
7. 14. | -dx
1 + sin x cos 2x
dx
9. 16. | (3x2 + 5 cos x) dx
sirr ax
du
10. 17. I* (3x + ex) dx
cos2 u
dt
12.
1 + cos t
19. J 2x sec x2 tan x2 dx
INTEGRATION BY PARTS
When an expression involving products or logarithms cannot be evaluated directly
using standard forms, one of the most useful techniques for transforming it to a
standard form is the formula for integration by parts. This formula is based on the
inverse of the formula for differentiation of a product.
If u and v are both functions of x, then from the formula for the differentiation of a
product,
d dv du
= u - + V
dx dx dx
or
dv d, du
Udx = Tx(Uv)-Vdx
u dv = uv v du
«
This is the formula for integration by parts. The usefulness of this formula depends on
the appropriate choice of u and dv, so that J v du and j dv can be evaluated, even
though j u dv cannot.
436 / Integral Calculus
Unfortunately, there is no general rule for separating a given expression into two
factors u and dv so that the formula for integration by parts can be applied. However,
note that
It may be necessary to apply the formula for integration by parts more than once,
as in example (e) below.
EXAMPLES
xe
(a) I xeax dx = dx + C
a a
xeax eax
+ C u — x dv = eax dx
a a‘
eax 1, ^
— I x-1 + C du = dx v =
a \ ai a
= x In x - x + C u = In x dv = dx
= x(ln x — 1) + C du = - dx V = X
x
x ? • x ^
= —ax cos - + a sin - + C u = x dv sin - dx
a a a
, . x X „ x
= a sin-ax cos - + C du — dx v a cos -
a a a
u — ex dv = cos x dx
du = e> v = sin x
u = e dv = sin x dx
du = ex v = —cos x
4.6 Special Methods of Integration / 437
= —x2e x + 2 — xe x + e x dx + C
*
x2e x — 2xe x — 2e X + C
= — e X(x2
U = X dv = e x dx
du = 2x dx v = —e
u — x dv = e x dx
du = dx v = e
= 2(x + l)1/2[ln (x + 1) - 2] + C
u = In (x + 1) dv = (x + 1)-1/2 dx
dx
du = i; = 2(x + 1)1/2
x + 1
As suggested by examples (a), (b), and (f) above, the formula for integration by
parts is the basis of a number of standard forms for integration.
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following integrals.
xex dx
1. 10. (x + 1) In x dx
(TT^p
2. xe x dx 11. | (x2 + 3x + 4)3(2x + 3) dx
6x2 + 8x + 8
5. t In t dt 14.
? + 2x2 + Ac dX
(x3 + x) dx
6. z2e 3z dz 15.
^/x4 + 2x2 + 1
3x
8. I (x1'2 + x1/4)2 dx 17. xe dx
(x + 1) <ix x3 + 2
9. 18. dx
(x + l)2 + (a + 1): x4 + 8x + 10
438 / Integral Calculus
sin v dv sin x dx
25. j
19-J 1 -1- cos V yj2 — cos X
dx sec2 0 dO
2°.j 26. j
1 4- sin x Vi +2 tan 6
27. j x cos x dx
2LJ u sin u2 du
17. -i<T3x(3x + 1) + C
19. — In (1 4- cos v) 4- C
3. ex(x2 — 2x + 2) 4- C
21. — i cos u2 4- C
5. \t2 In t — \t2 + C
ax / 1
7. ex(x2 4- 1) + C 23.
In a\ In a
9. j In [(x 4- 1 )2 4- (a 4- l)2] 4- C
25. 2VT — cos x 4- C
11. ^.{x2 4- 3x 4- 4)4 4- C
27. x sin x 4- cos x 4- C
13. fx5/3 + x2 4- fx7/3 4- C
29. 0 tan 0 4- In cos 9 4- C
15. i(x4 4- 2x2 + 1)3/4 + C
2. Determine the form of the partial fractions; several cases arise, depending on the
nature of the factors occurring in the denominator:
Factor Occurring
in Denominator Corresponding Partial Fraction
EXAMPLES
(A 4- B)x + (2A 4 B)
2A 4 B = 3
A = 2
B = -1
440 / Integral Calculus
and
(x 4- 3) dx C 2 dx r dx
J (x 3~ 1 )(x 3-2) x 3- 1 x 3- 2
— 2 In (x 3- 1) — In (x 3- 2) + C
= In '(* +1)2 3- C
x 3- 2
(x2 — 3x — 8) x + 9 B
(b) dx = 1 - dx = x — + dx
x2 — 2x 3- 1 1 (x-l);
x + 9 = A(x — 1) 3- B
= Ax — (A — B)
A = 1
A — B = —9
B = 10
and
• (x2 — 3x — 8) dx dx 10 dx
= x —
x2 — 2x + 1 x — 1
10
= x — In (x — 1) + + C
t dt t dt A21 3 Bi
“ A21 3 B2
~
Ay 3- A2 = 0
By 3“ B2 = 0
Ay +5A2 = 1
By 3 5B2 — 0
~
A2 — \
Ay =
By = B2 = 0
and
t dt t dt 1 r t dt
(PTlM^TT) ? + 5+ 4 J F+T
= -i In {t2 3- 5) + i In {t2 + 1) + C
4.6 Special Methods of Integration / 441
dz Aq , A{z + By A2z 4 B2
(d) dz
z(z2 4 1): z + z2 4 1 (z2 -l-l)2
Aq 4 Ay = 0
By = 0
24.Q 4 Ay 4 42 = 0
By 4 B2 = 0
40 = 1
Ay = -1
42 = -1
B2 = 0
and
dz • dz r z dz z dz
J z(z2 4 l)2 z z2 4 1 4 + 4
= In z — j In (z2 4 1) 4 4 C
2(z2 4 1)
1
— i In 4 4 C
z2 4 1 2 4 +1)
dx dx 4 B C
(e) -1-t H-t dx
x3 4 5x2 4 4x J x(x 4 l)(x 4 4) x x 4 1 x 4 4
4 4 B 4 C = 0
54 4 46 4 C = 0
44 = 1
4 = 3i
44 4 3B 0
B
i
'I
C 1
T?
442 / Integral Calculus
and
dx 1 r dx 1 dx 1 dx
4 vx
x(x -I- l)(x + 4) 4 J x 3 x 4- 1 12 . x 4 4
= \ In x — ^ In (x 4 1) 4 yj In (x 4 4) 4 C
x3(x + 4)
= TZ 1° 4c
(* + l)4
(x3 — 2x) dx (x3 — 2x) dx
<f> i 81 (x - 3)(x 4 3)(x2 4- 9)
A B Cx + D
4-x 4 dx
x — 3 ' x 4 3 x2 4 9
3A - 3B 4 D = 0
9A-\-9B—9C= -2
21A - 21B - 9D = 0
D = 0
Substituting C = f&, D — 0, and solving the first two equations,
A 4 B = ye
3A - 3B = 0
6A = fg
A = 3^
B = 3^
and
(x3 — 2x) dx dx 1 r dx lip X dx
= ^ in (x - 3) 4 je in (x 4 3) 4 ^ In (x2 4 9) 4 C
PROBLEMS
Evaluate each of the following integrals using partial fractions.
(4x — 2) dx r (4x2 4 6) dx
x3 — x2 — 2x J x3 4 3x
z2 dz t5 dt
(T^Tp (t2 -f 4)2
(/ - 8) dy r (2t2 — 8f — 8) dt
y3 4- 2y2 ‘J (t - 2)(t2 4 4)
3 - 4z
3. In (z — 1) + +c 7. — 4 In (t2 + 4) - -JL* + C
W^2 2 v ' t2 4 4
x = zn
a 4 bx = zn
EXAMPLES
. . r x1/2 dx
1 4 x3/4
444 / Integral Calculus
x = z4
dx = 4z3 dz
x1/2 dx r z2 • 4z3 dz
1 -I- x 3/4 1 + z3
z5 dz
= 4
z3 + 1
= 4 z2 - dz
z3 + 1
= fz3 — 3 In (z3 -f 1) + C
Substituting to obtain a function of x,
.1/2
dx
= fx3/4 - j In (x3/4 + 1) + C
It + x 3/4
x dx
(b)
(a -I- frx)3/2
Substituting,
a + bx = z2
b dx = 2z dz
dx = T z dz
b
x dx 2 r (z2 — a) • z dz
(a + bx)312 b:
a
1 - dz
V2
2_ a
z + - + C
P z
2_ z2 + a
+c
V2
Substituting to obtain a function of x,
f x dx 2 2a + bx
+ C
(a + bx)312 ~ b2 (u + bx)112
(5x + 9) dx
(c) (x - 9)x3/2
dx = 2z dz
(5x + 9) dx r (5z2 + 9) • 2z dz
(x — 9)x3/2 (z2 - 9)z3
(5z2 + 9) dz
= 2
z2(z - 3)(z + 3)
4.6 Special Methods of Integration / 445
• (5x + 9) dx ^ x4 J5 C D
dz
J (x - 9)x3/2 = z + z2 + z - 3 + z + 3
A + C + D = 0
B + 3C - 3Z) = 5
-9.4 = 0
-9B = 9
^4 = 0
5 = -1
C + D = 0
3C - 3D = 6
6C = 6
C = 1
D = -1
and
(5x + 9) dx dz dz dz
= 2 ~2
9)x3/2 Zz “*■
z — 3 J z + 3
1
= 2 + In (z — 3) — In (z + 3) + C
z
z — 3
= 2 1 + ln . , + C
z \z + 3
(d)r dx
x — x 4/3
x = Z'
dx — 3z2 dz
dx r 3z2 dz
,4/3 _3
Z
_4
— Z
dz
= 3
J z( 1 - z)
dx A B
= 3 dz
x — x 4/3 z 1 — z
1 = z4(l — z) + Bz
446 / Integral Calculus
-A + B = 0
A = 1
B = 1
and
dx dz dz
1 x — x 4/3
= 3
Z
+
J 1 — z
= 3[ln z — In (1 — z)] + C
z
= 3 In + C
1 — Zj
dx ( x1/3
= 3 !n |--J73 + C
x — x 4/3 1 — X
a + y = z3
dy = 3z2 dz
= 3 J (z6 — az3) dz
z7 az4
= 3 + C
7 4
A[z4(4z3 - 7a)] + C
x2 dx
(4x + 1)5/2
4x + 1 = z2
4 dx = 2z dz
dx = \z dz
4.6 Special Methods of Integration / 447
x2 dx Mz2-l)2-iz dz
(4x + 1)5/2
1 r (z4 — 2z2 + 1) dz
32 J
1 i 2 1
1-2 + “4
dz
32 ZZ Z*
1 2 1
z + - + C
32 z 3z3
1 3z4 + 6z2 — 1
+ C
32 3z3
6x2 + 6x + 1
+ C
12(4x + 1)3/2
z z
EXAMPLES
(x - x3)1/3 dx
(a)
x
1
dx
i yi3dz
r (x — x3)1/3 dx z3] z2
J x^ 1
= — z(z2 — 1)1/3 dz
= -i(z2 - 1)4/3 + C
448 / Integral Calculus
dx
(b) using the standard form
ZyJ 1 4- x 4-
du
= —t= In (2cu 4- b 4- 2y/cy/cT+ bu 4- cu2) 4- C
yja 4- bu 4- cu:
x =
z
dz
dx =
dz
dx 22
cyiTx + xj 1,11
“ / 1 + - + -2
2 V Z ZZ
dz
z2 + z + 1
dz
z2 4 z + 1
dx
XyJ 1 4- x 4- x"
In 4- C
,2 4- x 4- 2-y/l + x +
PROBLEMS
Evaluate each of the following integrals by rationalization.
y dy A | (V* 4-14-1) dx
1.
yj 2 4- 4y -y/x 4- 1 — 1
dt dx
lj~t 4- 1 4- x 4 2
(x 3/2 _ v 1 /3
) dx dx
6.
6x1/4 1 4-
dx ^fx2 — a2 dx
7. 8.
x x2 4- a2
4.7 Numerical (Approximate) Methods of Integration / 449
— dx
9. 11.
Xy/l + 4x + 5x2
y/4 — x2 dx dx
10. 12.
3- A*9/4-A*13/12 +C
1 4- 2x 4- yj\ 4- 4x + 5x2'
11. In 4- C
Figure 4.31
Ax bo + Z1 yi+ bn
i—
/(x) dx — Ax + y„) + i=
X yi
1
< I f(x) dx - Ax X yi
'a i=0
and
n— 1
or
n b n— 1
EXAMPLE
Evaluate j* x(16 — x2)1/2 dx by the trapezoidal rule using n = 4. (See Figure 4.32).
Figure 4.32
v
i 0 1 2 3 4
,*■
j x(16 — x2)1/2 dx « Ax i(yo + n) + Z ^ i= 1
0.5[3.464 + 22.522]
12.993
b n— 1
,4
11.261 < j x(16 — x2)1/2 dx < 14.725
SIMPSON'S RULE
Simpson’s rule uses a series of parabolic arcs to approximate the given function f(x);
it is in this sense a method of quadratic approximation. Simpson’s rule provides a
closer approximation than the trapezoidal rule for any given number of subdivisions
of the interval over which the integral is to be evaluated.
452 / Integral Calculus
Figure 4.33
A parabola with vertical axis can be passed through any three points. The equa¬
tion of this parabola can be obtained from the coordinates of the points; however, for
the purpose of using Simpson’s rule this is not necessary, since the area under an arc
of the parabola can be evaluated without finding the equation of the parabola.
If a parabola with vertical axis is passed through three points (x0, y0), (xx, yx) and
(x2, y2), where x2 — xx = xt — x0 = Ax, then the area bounded by the parabola, the
x-axis, and the ordinates at x0 and x2 is given by
A = y (yo+ 4y‘ + y^
Again suppose the probiem is to evaluate J'J f(x) dx. Divide the interval [a, b] into
n equal parts, where n must now be an even number, each of length Ax, and denote the
points of division by a = x0, xl,..., xn = b; the corresponding ordinates are y0, yl,
..., yn; consider these ordinates in groups of three: y0, yx, y2, y2 , ^3, y4; y4, y5, y6;
...; yn-2, y„~u yn> and Pass a parabolic arc with vertical axis through each set of
three points (see Figure 4.33). The areas under these parabolic arcs are, respectively,
As in the case of the trapezoidal rule, as the number of divisions, n, increases, the sum
of the areas under the parabolic arcs more closely approximates the area under the
curve.
EXAMPLE
i 0 1 2 3 4
% 13.523
note:
and, as noted above, Simpson’s rule gives a closer approximation than does the trapezoidal
rule. Note also that the exact answer is in fact within the bounds given by the trapezoidal rule.
TAYLOR S EXPANSION
Taylor’s theorem may be used to expand a function f(x) in an infinite series;
\dc f(x) dx may then be evaluated approximately by integrating the series term by
term and evaluating as many terms as necessary to obtain the required accuracy. For
this procedure to be valid, the series must converge to f(x) for all values of x in the
interval [c, d] over which the integral is to be evaluated. The required accuracy
usually can be obtained with fewer terms by expanding the series about a value of a
such that c < a < d.
Thus, providing the convergence conditions are met,
EXAMPLE
1/2 x2 dx
Evaluate using Taylor’s series.
x + 1
1
/M = x + 1 20
2x(x + l)-x2 x2 + 2x T6 + T 9
J 11 (x + l)2 (x+Tp (i)2 25
2
~(TTTf
n\ n!
/("’(x) = (-!)" /'”>( i) = (-!)" 5 \n + 1
(x + 1)"+1 (J)
+ ^ (X - u)"+1 +
(« + i)!
Letting a = i,
1/2 x2 dx JL x 4- ^ tv; _ 1 \2 , ^8 (x _ 1 \3
i x + 1 20 + 25 • 2! X ^ 125 • 3! ( ^
1/2
1536 24756
625 • 4!
(x - i)4 +
3125 • 5! (* ~ i)5 0
3
128
125 • 3!
1 re
* 0.0304613
EXAMPLE
Evaluate jo x3 dx using (a) trapezoidal rule, (b) Simpson’s rule, (c) Taylor’s series, and (d)
exactly.
Divide the range into 10 equal parts as summarized in the following table:
i 0 1 2 3 4 5
i 6 7 8 9 10
rb n— 1
(a) trapezoidal rule: f(x) dx % Ax i(yo + yn) + Z yt
a i= 1
1
x3 dx % 0.1 [i(0 + 1.000) + 2.025]
% 0.2525
b Ax
/(x) dx % — [y0 + 4yt + 2y2 + 4y3 -f • • • + 4y2„_ x + y„]
, 1 01
X3 dx % — [(0 + 1.000) + 2(0.800) + 4(1.224)]
J0 3
« 0.2499
d
(c) J /(x) dx (x — a)3 + • • •
C
Letting a = j,
1
f(i)x + (* - i)2 + -f •••
/(x)-x3 f(i) = i
/"(*) = 6x /"(i) = 3
/,,V|M = 0 /<IV>(i) = 0
456 / Integral Calculus
= 0.125 + 0.125
= 0.250
i
= i - 0 = 0.25
o
note: Both Simpson’s rule and the Taylor’s series expansion provide the exact answer for
this particular problem. Because of the nature of the approximation (quadratic), Simpson’s
rule is exact for any quadratic or cubic function. The Taylor’s series expansion is exact if all
further terms are zero—that is, if n terms are used and the nth derivative of /(x) is zero.
Because Simpson’s rule is exact, the answer could have been obtained by dividing the range
into only two parts:
i 0 1 2
Xi 0 0.5 1
/(*.-) = yi 0 0.125 1
0.5
x3 dx = [It 4(0.125)] = 0.25
'o 3
However, using n = 2 instead of n — 10 would reduce the accuracy of the trapezoidal rule:
i
EXAMPLE
dx
Evaluate using (a) trapezoidal rule, (b) Simpson’s rule, (c) Taylor’s
1
i 0 1 2 3 4
Xi 2 3 4 5 6
i i i i
fM = yi i s IT Ti T5
rb
n— 1
(a) trapezoidal rule:
* n
f(x) dx % Ax i(yo + yn)+ Z yt
i= 1
^ dx
--- « l[j(0.3333 + 0.0286) + 0.2334]
j X — I
% 0.4143
b Ax
(b) Simpson’s rule: /(x) dx ^ — [y0 + 4yx + 2y2 + • • • + 4yln-1 + yn]
3
dx
2 t ^ i[(0.3333 + 0.0286) + 4(0.1250 + 0.0417) + 2(0.0667)]
% 0.3874
f'(a) f"(a)
(c) f /(x) dx = f (a)x + —y1 (x — a)2 + J t 7 (x — u)3 + ■ • •
2! 3!
Letting u = 4,
•6 dx r(4)
/(4)x + ^ (x 4)2 + (x - 4)3 + f '(4> (x - 4 Y
J2 x2 - 1 3! 3!
f(X) = (x2 - 1) - 1
1
/(4) = 15
-8
/'(4) = 2
(15)
98
3
(15)
~ (96)(17)
f"( 4) (15)4
/•••( 4, -
458 / Integral Calculus
6
1 8 98
(x - 4)* 2 + (x - 4)'
^2 (15)2 • 2! (15)3 • 3!
6
(96)(17) (24)( 1441)
(x - 4)4 + (x - 4)5
(15)4 • 4! (15)5 • 5! 2
(24)(1441) \
(15)5 • 5! '' ’ j
^071^ (24)0441)
' (15)5 • 5! 1
0.3684
dx x - 1
(d) 7 In = i[ln 4 - In i]
x2 - 1 X + 1
= i[ln 5 — In 7 + In 3]
* 0.3811
note: -^ln (- -) + C.
2a \u + a)
It should be noted that the seemingly better results from part (b) are due to the truncation
effects of using only 4 terms in (c). Taylor’s series is more accurate than Simpson’s rule, if a
sufficient number of terms are computed.
PROBLEMS
Evaluate each of the following integrals approximately using a. trapezoidal rule, b. Simpson’s
rule, c. Taylor’s series, and d. exactly.
3 2
1. (x4 + 3x2) dx, n = 6 3. e2x dx, n = 4
•'o J _2
e(1,2)x dx, n = 4
Evaluate each of the following integrals by expanding the function in a Taylor’s series; com¬
ment on the interval of convergence and the accuracy of the evaluation.
5. (x4 — x3 + j) dx + x3 + 2x2 + 1 dx
*'0
| f(x, y) dy dx
R
is defined with respect to the function /(x, y) over a bounded region, R, of the
xy-plane.
Just as the definite integral of f(x) can be interpreted in terms of area, the definite
double integral of /(x, y) can be interpreted in terms of volume. (See Figure 4.34.)
The function f(x, y) is assumed to be positive over the region R and the volume
computed is that below the surface z = f(x, y) and above the region R in the
xy-plane.
The evaluation of double integrals is most easily accomplished by successive
partial integration, which is the inverse of partial differentiation. That is, to evaluate a
double integral, a function of two independent variables is integrated with respect to
one of the variables while the other variable is considered as constant; the result of
this partial integration is then integrated with respect to the other variable. For this
purpose the double integral
b „ 0(x)
/ (x, y) dy dx or /(x, y) dy dx
1a Jh(x)
Figure 4.34
z
460 / Integral Calculus
f{x, y) dy dx
h(x)
, g(y)
f (x, y) dx dy or
h(y)
The limits of integration must involve only variables with respect to which integra¬
tion is to be performed subsequently, and the limits of integration must be rewritten
in this manner. Thus
/(x, y) dy dx = /(x, y) dx dy
Ja ' h(x) Jc J n(y)
where the new limits of integration are determined so that, for example, if y = g(x),
then x = m(y).
For functions of more than two independent variables, this process can be gener¬
alized using multiple integrals; there are relatively few applications requiring more
than triple integration. It is important to note that multiple integration is performed
from the inside outward; thus the first integral sign belongs to the last differential and
so forth. Note also that when an integration is performed with respect to a variable,
that variable is eliminated completely from the remaining integral, including the
limits of integration.
EXAMPLE
dy dx = [2x1/2y1/2]F dx
o Jx2 V y
— I (2x — 2x3/2) dx
■'o
4x5/2
x2 -
= d -})-o = i
4.8 Multiple Integrals / 461
EXAMPLE
Ja2-y2 s/ai — y2
A
x dx dy = dy
~T
ra a2 - y2...
u y
0 2
a
a2y y3l
2 6 0
o
K fl3i
II
\2 6/ 1
EXAMPLE
n x . n
I x sin y dy dx = [ —x cos y]o dx
'0
= ( — x cos x + x) dx
‘'o
X
= — x cos x dx +
*'o
u = x dv = cos x
du = dx v = sin x
and
= (0-1)-(0 + 1)
= -2
Thus
71
x sin y dy dx = — (— 2) + —
4 H- re2
2
462 / Integral Calculus
EXAMPLE
. i e*
- In X d
-J 1 - y i
dy
= M-i
= 1 - (-1) = 2
EXAMPLE
\*y\ dz dx dy = [ y f
•*1 Jy
[e*]o*x dx dy
2 y2
= j y (x — 1) dx dy
•'l •'v
y2
y dy
y _x
2 xy-y3-y + y2|^
V5 3y:
+ )'2U)'
y
12 8 3
= (-x — 6 + f) ~ (it - i + i)
47
24
Note that the integrand in the example above can also be written
f2 In x
yez dz dx dy
1
and y can be carried as a constant in the first two integrations. However, when an
integrand includes a factor which is constant with respect to one or more integra¬
tions, that factor can be moved outside the integral(s); usually it is more convenient
to separate the integrand in this manner.
EXAMPLE
Evaluate the triple integral jo jo6 josin(,r2 cos 9 sin (f> dr dO d(f>.
4.8 Multiple Integrals / 463
a sin 0
rn,6>
r2 cos 9 sin </> dr d9 d(f) = sin <i> cos 9 |
COS 6 r2 dr d6 d(f)
Jo J0 J *0 Jn
a sin 0
sin 4> cos 9 d6 d(j)
0
. ft/6
a3
= sin <f) cos 9 sin3 9 d9 d(J)
J no 3
a
- f’ sin (f)[i sin4 9]o/6 d(j)
3 J0
a3 „ TL
sin </>(iV) #
12 J0
„ 71
a3
sin (f> d(f)
192 J0
a3
[-cos (f)]l
192
a3 n v a3
192 1 + ^ “ 96
PROBLEMS
Evaluate the following multiple integrals.
1 .2 a „ b .2 a
1. [ [ (x + 2) dy dx 7. j j x2y2z dz dy dx
Jn
o J•'o
n b J0 Ja
2 . 3 1 . 1 . 1-x
(x -I- y) dx dy 8. x dz dx dy
0 1 •J n
0 J ->,2
Jy2 n
JJ0
l-x l — y2
1
3. j j x112 dx dy z dz dy dx
y 0 •'o Jo
2 . x2 1 x x+y
y dy dx 10. f j” ex + y + z dz dy dx
o 1 Jn Jq Jq
. -1 2y 1 „ 2y
xy dx dy 11. I x2y dx dy
o Jy+i J - i J?
0 y
•1 rx2
6. ey,x dy dx 12. [ [ y2exy dx dy
o Jq J — 3 Jq
464 / Integral Calculus
f2 r x2
13. (xy + 1) dy dx
1 •'o
. 3 , x+ 1
14. (x + y) dy dx 17. x2 f exy dy dx
•'0 JX •'o *'o
1 x+ 1 . x+y
15. (x — y — 1) dy dx (x + y + z) dz dy dx
- 1 'x- 1 o
1. f(x, y) > 0
2- J^oo l-oo f(x. y) dx dy = 1
3- 1«2 lo! /(x> y) dx dy = P(aI < x <b^, a2 < y < b2)
These properties are similar to those for a frequency function of one variable and
state that (1) probability is always nonnegative; (2) the probability of an event that is
certain to occur is one; and (3) the probability that the value of x is in the interval
(alt bx) and the value of y is in the interval (a2, b2) is given by the corresponding
integral. Geometrically, /(x, y) is a surface in three dimensions and the volume
under the surface lying above the rectangle determined by al < x < bl and
a2 < y < b2 is the probability that x and y will assume values corresponding to
points in this rectangle. (See Figure 4.29.) If f(x, y) is continuous, P(al < x <b{,
a2 < y < b2) = P(al < x < bu a2 < y < b2).
EXAMPLE
In a study of costs for a certain type of fluorescent tube, a company has determined that the
frequency function for size of order, x, and total cost for the order, y, is approximately
/(x, y) = - 1 < x < 6 0.1 -I- Q.9x < y < 0.1 4- l.lx
6 . 1.05x
P( 1 < x < 6, 0.1 + 0.9x < y < 1.05x) = dy dx
0.1+ 0.9x 3.5
= 3^ | Moil+0.9* dx
1 r6
= — (0.15x — 0.1) dx
3.5 Ji
= ~ [0.075x2 - 0.1x]i
2.125
3.5
= 0.6071
6 0.1 + 1.1*
note: dy dx = — | [^]o;i + o;9*
0.1 + 0.9x 3.5
1 r6
= — [(0.1 + 1.1 xc) — (0.1 + 0.9x)] dx
3.5 J i
0.2x dx
3.5 J
1 216
= B[0-1x2]1
= ^[3.6-0.1]
= 1
EXAMPLE
The joint frequency function for the time (in microseconds) required for two switches to close
is given by
(a) Find the probability that the first switch requires less than 0.1 microsecond and the second
switch requires more than 0.5 microsecond to close.
(b) Find the probability that the first switch requires more than 0.2 microsecond and the
second switch requires more than 0.5 microsecond to close.
466 / integral Calculus
0.1 „ oo
(a) P(0 < Xi < 0.1, x2 > 0.5) =15 f e (3xi + 5x2) dx2 dxi
J•'o
n n *
•'o.s
0.1
= —e~28 + e~25
= -0.061 + 0.082
= 0.021
00 , 00
oo
= -3 [ [e~(3xi + 5x2)]q.5 dxt
*'0.2
e-(3x,+2.5) dX]
= 3
0.2
= [-e~(3xi+2-5)]£:
= 0 + e~3A
= 0.045
00 00 00
note: I | 15e~{3x' + 5x2) dxx dx2 — | [ — 5e_(3xi + 5x2)]o dx2
J0 jo *' 0
OO
= 5e 5x2 dx2
*'o
= [-e-5x>]$
= 0 - (- 1)
= 1
Note also that/(xl9 x2) = f(xt)f(x2) = (3c~3xi)(5e_5x2). Thus
5X2
P{x 2 > 0.5) = 5jr«- dx2 -l-e-
0.5
r0'1 e - 3xi
P(x 1 < 0.1) = 3 dx! = [-«'- 3xil0.1 _ .,-0.3
•
0
These probabilities are referred to as marginal probabilities, and the joint probabilities ob¬
tained above can be obtained as the products of the corresponding marginal probabilities.
This is characteristic of probabilities of independent events.
EXAMPLE
/(x, y) > 0
4.8 Multiple Integrals / 467
X2e 2y Xy]yo dy
dy
Integrating by parts,
u = y dv = e~ky
= [~Xye~Xy - e~Xy]$
= (0-0) -(0-1)
= i
PROBLEMS
1. Show that/(x, y) = |(x + y)* 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8, 0 < x < 1, 0 < y < 1 is a frequency function.
2. Show that /(x, y) = ^f(y — x)1/2, 0<x<y<lisa frequency function.
3. Show that /(x, y) = 8xy, 0 < x < 1, 0 < y < x, is a frequency function and find a.
P(0 < x < 0.5, 0 < y < x) and b. P(0.2 < x < 0.5, 0.1 < y < x).
4. Show that/(x, y) = 12(y — x)2, 0<x<y<lisa frequency function and find a. P(0.5 <
x < y < 1) and b. P(0 < x < y < 0.5).
5. Determine the value of k for which
is a frequency function.
6. Determine the value of c for which
is a frequency function.
7. The joint frequency function for the errors in measuring two variables is given by
a. Find the probability that the measurement error x is between 0 and 0.5 and the measure¬
ment error y is between 0 and 0.2x. b. Find the probability that the measurement error x is
between 0.8 and 1 and the measurement error y is between 0.8 and 1. c. Show that/(x, y) is
a frequency function.
8. The waste from a chemical plant consists of soluble and nonsoluble substances. The nonsol¬
uble substances are of two types, A and B. The plant’s engineers have studied data and have
determined that the composition of the nonsoluble waste on one day does not depend on its
composition on preceding days. The joint frequency function for the proportion of all
soluble substances (A and B), denoted by x, and type B nonsoluble substances, denoted by
y, is given by
a. For what proportion of the days does the waste contain more than 20% of type B
nonsoluble substances? b. For what proportion of the days does the waste contain less than
50% of nonsoluble substances? c. For what proportion of the days does the waste contain
more than 50% nonsoluble substances and more than 20% type B substances? d. Show
that f(x, y) is a frequency function.
5.1 Introduction
In many problems the relationships between or among variables are most appro¬
priately stated in terms of rates of change. The rate of change of any given variable
may be expressed as a function of the rates of change or the values of other variables.
For example, in physics equations involving rates of change in energy are used in the
derivation of the laws of conservation of energy; in economics it is assumed that the
rate at which price approaches its equilibrium value depends on the magnitude of
the discrepancy between the quantities supplied and demanded.
Rates of change can be stated in either of two mathematical forms, depending on
whether time (or, more generally, any variable with respect to which changes are
considered) is viewed as continuous or discrete. When changes are considered to
occur continuously or instantaneously, rates of change are stated as derivatives and
equations involving them are differential equations. When changes are considered as
occurring discretely or discontinuously at certain points in time or as average
changes over a period of time, rates of change are stated as differences in the values of
variables at different points in time and equations involving them are difference
equations. Differential equations are the limiting case of difference equations as the
time period between changes or over which an average change is computed
approaches zero.
Differential equations, that is, equations involving derivatives, are discussed in
this chapter; difference equations, that is, equations involving differences between
values of variables at different points in time or with respect to different values of
another variable are discussed in Chapter 6.
In this chapter, the definition and classification of differential equations are dis¬
cussed and types of solutions of ordinary differential equations are considered and
illustrated. A classification of differential equations of first order and first degree is
given and the solutions of these classes of equations are discussed. Applications of
differential equations in economic models are illustrated.
469
470 / Differential Equations
EXAMPLE
Many of the equations in Chapter 4 are differential equations, since any equation
involving at least one derivative is a differential equation. If a differential equation
can be written in the form
EXAMPLE
If ^ = cos x + 2x,
ax
y — sin x + x2 4- C
EXAMPLE
d2y
Find the general solution of the differential equation = 20x3 - '
dx2
If ^ = 20x3-i.
dxz xz
dl
ax
= 5 x‘ + xi + C,
and
y = x5 + In x + C1x + C2
The methods discussed later in this chapter are appropriate for solving several
types of differential equations whose solutions cannot be obtained by straightfor¬
ward integration. Five types of differential equations of first order and first degree are
discussed in some detail; second-order differential equations and first-degree differ¬
ential equations of higher order are discussed briefly.
/(x, y) + Cj + c2 + ••• + c„ = 0
EXAMPLE
x2 C . . dy
Show that y = —- H— is a solution ol x — + y = x 2
3 x ax
If y = x3/3 + C/x,
dy 2x C
dx 3 x2
and thus
dy
xTx + y
EXAMPLE
d2y
Show that y = c^ekx -I- c2e~kx is a solution of - k2y = 0.
dx2
If y — cy ekx + c2 e~kx,
dy
Ci kekx — c2ke -kx
dx
d2y 2 „-kx
= Ci k2ekx + c2k2e
dx2
5.3 Solutions of Ordinary Differential Equations / 473
and thus
d2y
— k2y
dx“
EXAMPLE
,2 d2y dy 1
Show that 4y = l/(3x) + c^x5 + c2 x is a solution of x1 — 5x — + 5y
dx dx .X
If 4 y = l/(3x) + c^5 + c2x,
41AA + 20c‘x3
and thus
1
\(k+ 20cix5) - *( ” Tx+ 5cix5 + CjX)+ + Ci x5 + C2X X
.2^1 - 5x ^ + 5y
dx2 ~"dx
1
0 0
X
EXAMPLE
d2y dy
Show that y = c1ex + c2 e 2x is a solution of + — — 2y = 0 and find a particular solution
dx2 dx
dy
that satisfies the condition y = — = 1 when x = 0.
dx
- 2x
I f y = c1ex + c2e
dy
Y~ = cxex -lc2e 2x
dx
d2y 2x
= cx ex + 4c2c
dx2
and thus
d2y dy
dx2
+ dx
-r-.-'iy
474 / Differential Equations
If y = y' = 1 when x = 0,
ci + c2 = 1
c{ — 2c 2 = 1
c2 = 0
Ci = 1
EXAMPLE
1dy\2 dy
Show that y = 2Cx + C is a solution of — + 8xJ = 16x2y and find a particular
\dxj dx
solution that satisfies the condition y = — 1 when x = 1.
If y = 2Cx2 + C2,
dy
4 Cx
dx
and thus
If y = — 1 when x = 1,
-1 = 2C + C2
C2 + 2C + 1 = 0
(C + l)2 = 0
C= -1,
EXAMPLE
2y , IM2 + 1 0
dx2 \dxj
dy
and find a particular solution that satisfies the condition y 3, and —f when x = 5.
dx
If (x - cj2 + y2 = c2,
2y%= ~2(x ~ ^
dy x — Ci
1
dx
^
>2
1
dx2 c2 - (x - Ci) 4
-1 _ (x - CX)2_
Jc2 - (x - Ci)2 [c2 - (x - Ci)2f12
5.3 Solutions of Ordinary Differential Equations / 475
and thus
(x - cx): X — Ci
-1 - + + 1=0
c2~ (x- cx)2 Jc2 - (x - Cly
d2y 'dyx 2
y dx' dxi
If v = 3 and ~ = — f when x = 5,
dx
3 = Jc2 - (5 - cx)2
4 _ 5-Cj
3 Jc2 - (5 - c,)2
5 - Ci =4
Ci = 1
c2 = 25
PROBLEMS
State the type, order, and degree of each of the following differential equations.
d2y d2z dz
1. + 6x + y = 0
dx2 dx2 dy
2. x2 dy = xy2 dx d2y dy
8. + --3x = 0
dx2 dx
d2y^ 2
3 + 5 xy = 0
dx* d2yx 2 dy ,
v dx* ~Tx = Ay
dz dz
4 rx + ¥y = xyz d3y
10. = 10y
dx3
6. - 4x,
11. Verify that y2 = Cx + iC3 is a solution of y = 2x — + y2(—) and find the particular
dx \dxj
solution if / = 1 when x = 0.
d2y (dy \2
12. Verify that (x - cj2 + y2 = c2 is a solution of y +1 — 1 +1=0 and find the particu¬
ei)
1 d2y
13. Verify that In y = c2c* + c2 e x + x2 + 2 is a solution of = x2 — In y.
y dx2
d2x
14. Verify that x = cos 2r + 2c2 cos 3r + 3c2 sin 31 is a solution of ^2 + 9x = 5 cos 21
r , d3y d2y dy
15. Verify that y = (cl + c2 In x)^x + c3 is a solution of 4xz — + 8x + — = 0.
dx: dx2 dx
476 / Differential Equations
d2y 1 dy
16. Verify that y = x3 + c1x2 + c2 is a solution of - 3x = 0 and find the particu-
dx2 x dx
lar solution if y = 1 when x = 1 and y = 5 when x = 2.
d2y
17. Verify that y = cos x + c2 sin x — 3 cos 2x is a solution of + y = cos 2x.
dy
18. Verify that y = e *(x + C) is a solution of + y = e x.
dy
lar solution that satisfies the condition y = 2 and — = 1 when x = 1.
dx
di
= F(x, y)
dx
There is one difference between these equations which should be noted. In the first
equation y is the dependent variable and x is the independent variable; thus the
solution expresses y as a function of x and an arbitrary constant. In the second
equation the relationship is expressed implicitly and the choice of the dependent and
independent variables is a matter of convenience; the solution is frequently also
expressed as an implicit function.
Methods for the solution of the following types of differential equations of the first
order and first degree are discussed in considerable detail; note that facility in solving
a differential equation of any order and degree depends to a very considerable extent
on classifying it correctly.
5.4 Differential Equations of First Order and First Degree / 477
dF cF
form — dx + — dy = 0, where F(x, y) is the solution of the differential equation.
of the first degree in /(y) and ~ f (y) or in x and ~ f (x) and thus is of the form
M(x) dx + N(y) dy = 0
j M(x) dx + j N(y) dy — C
and
f(x) + giy) = c
EXAMPLE
dy
Solve the equation (1 + x2) + xy = 0.
dx
(1 + x2) dy + xy dx = 0
1
dx + - dy — 0
1 + x2 y
The variables are separated and, integrating,
i In (1 + x2) + In y = C
In (yv/T+ x2) = C
478 / Differential Equations
Note that the constant in the last equation is actually ec in terms of the preceding equations.
As mentioned in the discussion of constants of integration above, until a constant is evaluated
to obtain a particular solution, its form is arbitrary and the constant is thus written in the most
convenient way.
EXAMPLE
1 , 1 ,
-- dx H—i dy = 0
x - 1 y2
In (x — 1) — = C
y In (x — 1) — 1 = Cy
y In [C(x — 1)] = 1
or
C(x — 1) = e1,y
EXAMPLE
If the interest rate is lOOz % compounded continuously and A is the amount at any time
(principal plus any accumulated interest), then
dA
= iA
dt
dA
— = idt
A
and, integrating,
r dA r
J ~a J
= idt
In A = it + c
A = eit+c
or
A = celt
If A = T0 at t = 0, then c = A0 and
A = Aq elt
y = x l +
5.4 Differential Equations of First Order and First Degree / 479
where y is the amount after n years (principal plus any accumulated interest) and interest rate
is i% per year compounded k times per year. In the notation of this section, the discrete
formula can be written
kt
A — A0\ 1 + - ]
and the formula for the continuous case can be obtained by taking the limit as k oo of the
formula for the discrete case, since
1
e = lim 1 +
k~* oo
EXAMPLE
The relationship between net profit P and advertising expenditure x is such that the rate of
increase of net profit as advertising expenditure increases is proportional to a constant minus
net profit. Find the relationship between net profit and advertising expenditure if P = P0 when
x = 0.
dP
k(a - P)
dx
— In (a — P) = kx + C
In (a — P) = —kx + C
a- P = Ce~kx
P = a - Ce~kx
Figure 5.1
P
480 / Differential Equations
so
C = a — P0
and
P = a — (a — P0)e~kx
Thus net profit is P0 with no advertising expenditure and increases, as advertising expenditure
increases, toward an (asymptotic) maximum of a. (See Figure 5.1.)
M(x, y) dx + N(x, y) dy = 0
y = vx
dy — v dx + x dv
x = vy
dx — v dy + y dv
The resulting differential equations can then be written, respectively, in the form
M(x) dx + N(v) dv = 0
or in the form
M(v) dv + N(y) dy = 0
and solved by the usual methods of integration. The general solution of the original
equation is then obtained by substituting, respectively,
y x
v - or v = —
x y
dy M(tx, ty)
dx N(tx, ty)
5.4 Differential Equations of First Order and First Degree / 481
Ml](i, A
dy \ x)
dx
N\(i,y)
X
dx X,
, dy dv , .
Substituting y vx and — = v + x —, this equation can be written
dx dx
dv . .
v + x— = F(v)
dx
(v — F(v)) dx + x dv — 0
dx dv
— + - = 0
X V F(v)
EXAMPLE
v2x2 dx + x3 dv = 0
- dx H—~ dv = 0
x v
In x-= C
v
Substituting v = y/x,
In x — - = C
y
x
^ In x — C
EXAMPLE
y2(v + 1) dv + y(v2 + 2v — 1) dy = 0
v + 1 , 1 , A
dv + - dy = 0
tr + 2t> — 1 y
i In (t?2 + 2t; — 1) + In y = C
y2(u2 +2v — \) = C
Substituting v = x/y,
x2 + 2.xy — y2 = C
EXAMPLE
The relationship between the manufacturing cost per item, M, and the number of types of items
manufactured, N, is such that the rate of increase of manufacturing cost as number of types of
items increases is equal to the ratio of the cost per item plus the number of types of items
divided by the number of types of items. Find the relationship between manufacturing cost per
item and number of types of items manufactured if M = M0 when N = 1.
dM _M + N
dN ~~N-
N dM = (M + N) dN
M = vN
dM = v dN + N dv
vN dN + N2 dv = vN dN + N dN
dN
v = In N + C
Substituting v = M/N,
M
= In N + C
aT
M = N In N + NC
M0 = 0 + C
c = M0
and
M = N In N + NM0
M = N(M0 + In N)
Figure 5.2
EXAMPLE
Suppose that the rate of increase in the cost of ordering and holding, y, as the size of the order, s,
increases is equal to the ratio of the sum of the squares of the cost and the size divided by twice
the product of the cost and the size. Find the relationship between the cost of ordering and
holding and the size of the order if y = 3 when s = 1.
dy y2 + s2
ds 2sy
y vs
dy v ds + s dv
s2(v — 1) ds + 2t;s3 dv 0
ds 2v .
- + -2-r dv= 0
s v — 1
/
In s + In (v2 - 1) = c
s(i;2 — 1) = c
Substituting v = y/s,
y' -1 =c
2 2
yl — sL = Cs
y (Cs + s2)1/2
so
3 = (C + 1)1/2
484 / Differential Equations
Figure 5.3
and
C = 8
y = (8s + s2)1/2
PROBLEMS V
Find the general solution for each of the following differential equations.
3. y3 dx — x3 dy = 0 16 ldP = P2 tan 6
p dO p2 + 1
4. (y + 3) dx + cot x dy = 0
17. r dO + 0 dr = 2 dr
_ dx .
5. — = 1 — sin 2f
dt 18. dp + p tan 9 d6 = 0
d3y dr
= c 19. (r2 + 1) d9 + = 0
dx3 sec2 9
d2y 1 x
20. (xy — y2) dx + ^y2 ——j dy = 0
dx2 x2
Find the particular solution for each of the following differential equations under the given
conditions.
37. ~ = —, y = 3 when x = 1
dx x
43. x dx — 4y dy = 0, y = 2 when x = 5
1 ey2
49. — dx H—r-dy = 0, y = 0 when x = 1
xy x — 1
dy y y
50. -7— = —b tan -, y = n when x = 6
dx x x
52. The relationship between price, p, and quantity demanded, x, is such that the rate of decrease
in demand as price increases is proportional to the quantity demanded and inversely
proportional to the price plus a constant. Find the demand function if p = p0 when x = 1.
Sketch the relationship obtained.
53. The rate of increase of total cost, y, as number of units manufactured, x, increases is
proportional to the number of units manufactured plus a constant and inversely propor¬
tional to the total cost. Find the cost function if y = y0 when x = 0. Sketch the relationship
obtained.
54. The rate of increase in sales, s, as advertising effort, x, increases is equal to a constant plus
advertising effort. Find the relationship between sales and advertising effort if s = s0 when
x = 0. Sketch the relationship obtained.
55. The relationship between revenue, R, and quantity demanded, x, is such that the rate of
increase in revenue as quantity demanded increases is equal to twice the cube of the
revenue minus the cube of the quantity demanded, all divided by three times the product
of the quantity demanded and the square of the revenue. Find the relationship between
revenue and quantity demanded if R = 0 when x = 10. Sketch the relationship obtained.
486 / Differential Equations
56. The relationship between average cost, y, and number of units produced, x, is such that the
change in average cost as the number of units increases is equal to the ratio of the number
of units minus average cost divided by number of units. Find the relationship between
average cost and the number of units produced if y = § when x = 1. Sketch the relation¬
ship obtained.
57. The rate of increase in cost, y, as the number of units manufactured, x, increases is equal to
the ratio of twice the square of the cost minus the square of the number of units divided by
the product of the cost and the number of units. Find the relationship between cost and the
number of units manufactured if y = 3 when x = 1. Sketch the relationship obtained.
58. The rate of increase of sales volume, s, as price, p, decreases is proportional to sales volume
and inversely proportional to price minus a constant. Find the relationship between sales
volume and price if s — s0 when p — p0.
59. If interest is compounded continuously, a. find the amount available after 10 years if $5000
is deposited at 4%; and b. find the amount available after 20 years if $20,000 is deposited at
6%. (Compare the answers with those obtained for the example on page 118 and Problem
2 on page 123, respectively.)
60. If growth is continuous and the rate, r, is proportional to the number, N, present in the
population, then
dN
= rN
dt
dy k
—V a, 1 < x < 10
dx x
where y is monthly rent (in dollars) and x is distance (in miles) and k and a are constants. If
y = 225 when x = 1, find y as a function of x and sketch the relationship obtained.
64. The relationship between the cost of operating a warehouse and the number of gallons of
oil stored in the warehouse is given by '
dy /
— = kx + a
dx
where y is the monthly cost of operating the warehouse (in dollars) and x is the number of
gallons of oil in storage. If y = y0 (fixed cost) when x = 0, find y as a function of x and
sketch the relationship obtained.
= l b. $5421.69
41. In x 4- e~
61. 329.8
43. x2 — 4y2 = 9
63. y = 225 4- a — ax — k In x
45. 2 / - - In v = 4
V y
j , x dF J dF J
dF(x, y) = — dx + — dy
dF dF
dx + dy = 0
dx dy
has the general solution F(x, y) = C and is said to be an exact differential equation.
A differential equation of the general form
M(x, y) dx + N(x, y) dy — 0
d_(dF\ _ _d/dF\
dy \ dx / ex \ cy J
Thus if a differential equation of the form M(x, y) dx -I- N(x, y) dy = 0 is exact,
3 d
- M(x, y) = - N(x, y)
It can be shown that this is also a sufficient condition for exactness; that is,
5
M(x, y) N(x, y)oM(x, y) dx + N(x, y) dy — 0 is exact
dy dx
2. Differentiate F(x, y) = G(x, y) + f (y) obtained from step 1 with respect to y and
compare this with N(x, y) from the differential equation to be solved to obtain the
Va‘Ue °f Jy /
8G d ,, . dN
dy + dy y dy
8 dN dG
Tyf[y) = ^y dy
f(y ) dy =/(y)
dy
clearly the solution may also be obtained by integrating first with respect to y.
EXAMPLE
dF y(2 + x3y)
dx x3
8F 1 ^^
-=--2 a i + ,2xy
+ 2xy + -f(y)=--2
SO
Ty'W-O (step 2)
f(y) = c (step 3)
and
Thus
x3y2 — y = Cx2
is the solution.
EXAMPLE
d d
— (x2 — x + y2) = 2y = — (— yey + 2xy), so the equation is exact.
dF
= x2 - x + y4
dx
dF d
ey=2xy + Tyf{y}= ~ye, + 2xy
so
and
3 2
= y ~ y + xy2 - (y - l)ey + C = 0 (step 4)
Thus
is the solution.
note: Alternatively, the terms of the original equation can be considered in two sets:
x2 dx — x dx — yey dy is exact by inspection and can be integrated by the usual methods;
y2 dx + 2xy dy can be shown to be exact and can be integrated by the method above. When
this method is used,/(y) is a constant, as illustrated in the following example.
EXAMPLE
Solve the equation [(2xy — l)/y] dx + [(x + 3y)/y2] dy = 0 and find the particular solution if
y = 1 when x = 2.
3 1 x
2x dx + - dy-dx -\—y dy = 0
_____ j_ y y2
exact, integrable d l
by usual methods dy \ y) y2 ~ dx\y2J
to obtain x2 + 3 In y
dF x d r. x x
dy y2 + dy y y2
(step 2)
f(y) = c (step 3)
Thus
x2 + 3 In y — - = C
y
and
x2y — x + 3y In y = Cy
is the solution.
If y = 1 when x = 2,
4 — 2 = C
C = 2
and
x2y — x — 2y + 3y In y = 0
EXAMPLE
The change in price, y, with change in quantity demanded, x, of a particular commodity is given
by
dy 2 xy + 24x
dx x2 + 16
Find the relationship between price and quantity demanded if the price is 7.5 when the
quantity demanded is 4.
dF = .
— 2xv -f 24x
ex
Figure 5.4
so
^/M = 16 (step 2)
3
VO
(step 3)
li
and
thus
is the solution.
If y = 7.5 when x = 4,
C = 432
and
be shown that any linear first-order differential equation has the integrating factor
e$ P(x)dx
^ + yP(x) = Q(x)
e, PM dx^l + yP(x)eI PM dx = PM dx
dx
since
dx dx
^ + yP(x) = Q(x)
y _ e~ 5 P(x)dx
es P(x)dxQ(x) dx + C
dx
+ xP(y) = Q(y)
dy
x = e ~f P(y)dy efp(y)dyQ(y) dy + C
note: Every differential equation of first order and first degree, which has a
solution, can be shown to have an infinite number of integrating factors. However,
determining these integrating factors may not be easy; in general, only linear first-
order differential equations are solved using integrating factors. As discussed in the
following section, first-order differential equations which are linear in a function of a
variable can also be integrated using integrating factors.
EXAMPLE
dy
dx
+y
5.4 Differential Equations of First Order and First Degree / 493
p~
[(1 - 2x)lx2] dx _ £-(l/x)-ln *2 _ _
x2
and
2e 1/x
dx
= 2e~1,x + C
y = 2x2 + Cx2ellx
= x2(2 + Ce1,x)
EXAMPLE
dx
Solve the equation y — = 2ye3y + x(3y + 2).
dx
Writing the equation in the form = Q(y)»
dy +
dx
dy -m
The integrating factor is
- -
y
and
xe~3y
2
y
-- + C
y
X -2 ye3y + Cy2e3y
ye3y(Cy - 2)
EXAMPLE
Solve the equation 2y dx = (yA + x) dy and find the particular solution if y 1 when x = 0.
dx
Writing the equation in the form -- + xP(y) = Q(y),
dx / 1 \ y3
dy~X\Tyj=i:
xy 1/2 = ^ j y5/2 dy
= W2+c
x = 4/ + c//2
7x = / + Cy1/2
If y = 1 when x = 0,
0 = 1 + C
C = -1
and
7x = / - y1/2
EXAMPLE
A manufacturing company has found that the cost, c, of operating and maintaining its
equipment is related to the length, x, of the interval between overhauls by the equation
dc b — 1 ba
dx x x2
dc l(b — 1)\ ba
dx \ x / x2
and
cx (b = —ba j x ft-1
= ax b + C
a ^ i
c = - 4- Cxb 1
x
If c = c0 when x = x0,
a
Cq — — + Cx0ft- i
x0
Co-^o —
C =
xbo
a Cq Xq — a -1
c = - + ^- .ft
X xbo
Figure 5.5
dx
f(y) +f(y)p(x) = Q(x)
is a linear differential equation in the variable f(y); that is, it is of the first degree in
eS P(x)dxQ(xj dx -f C
f(y) —
= a~S
e P(x) dx
is a linear differential equation in the variable f(x); that is, it is of the first degree in
EXAMPLE
dx
x3y 3
dy
, dx ,/T
x-3 — + x 2 -
dy \y
dx 2^
-2x~3~ + x_21 - -2y3
dy y>
d_
-2 y3
dy
eS~(2/y)dy __ e~2\n y _ y-
and
x -2 y V dy + C
y dy + C
= y2[-y2 + c]
1 = — x2y4 + Cx2y2
1 + x2y4 = Cx2y2
EXAMPLE
dy 2
Solve the equation-1- xy In y = xye x and find the particular solution if y = 1 when x = 0.
dx
1 dy
+ (In y)(x) = xe~
y dx
- v2
(In y) + (In >)(x) = xc
dx
e5 xdx _ ex2/2
and
In y = e *2/2 I xex2/1e x2 dx + C
= e~x212 xe x2/1 dx + C
= e-x2l2[-e~x212 + C]
= —e~x2 + Ce~xl/2
5.4 Differential Equations of First Order and First Degree / 497
If y = 1 when x = 0,
0 = -1 + C
C = 1
and
In y = —e~xl + e~x2/1
= e~x2l2(l - e~x2/2)
EXAMPLE
The cost control unit of a large public accounting firm has found, as the company has
increased in size, that the average monthly cost, y, of office supplies is related to the number, x, of
employees (in addition to the unit director) by the equation
+ 2y = y2e x
dx
y 2 + 2y 1 = e x
dx
-y-2t~2y-'= ~e'
{y x) - 2y 1 = -e
dx
and
y 1 = e2x e 2xe x dx + C
= e 2x e 2x dx + C
— 3x
= e 2x
+c
+c
3ex = y + Cyex
If y = 3 when x = 0,
3 = 3 + 3C
C = 0
and
y = 3ex
Figure 5.6
note: In general, there is no rule for determining the function f(y) or f(x) in terms of
which a differential equation is, or can be made, linear. The equation must be put in the form
— + f(y)P(x) = Q(x) or the form g(x) — +f(x)P(y) = Q(y) so that it can be determined
dx dy
by inspection whether the differential equation can be made linear in f(y) or f(x). However,
there is one class of differential equations for which the appropriate function is known. An
equation of the form
or
- + xP(y) = x"S(y)
Except for special cases, methods of solution of differential equations of the second
order or degree are somewhat complicated and, in general, solution becomes more
difficult as the order or degree of the differential equation increases. In many cases,
methods for obtaining an exact solution are not known and numerical methods for
5.5 Differential Equations of Higher Order and/or Higher Degree / 499
obtaining approximate solutions must be used. It should be noted that there are, in
fact, some types of differential equations of first order and first degree for which exact
solutions are not known. With electronic computers, highly accurate approximate
solutions can be obtained; these solutions may sometimes be preferred, for reasons of
convenience, even though methods for exact solution are known.
PROBLEMS
Find the general solution for each of the following differential equations.
1. x dy — 3y dx = x2 dx
2 . + 2xy — 2xe~xl = 0
dx
3. yj~ + { 1 + y)x — ey = 0
dy
4. y -—b 2x — 3y = 0
dy
7. y dx + 3x2ex dx = dy
16- + p) dx -(?
(4 + ~3rl
=
r
dy
3 dy 4 -
17. ^ + 2y-x = 0 23. yJ -—K xy = xc
dx dx
ds . 7
35. — 4- s tan t = 2t + t2 tan t
dt
2
38. 3y2 -xy3 _= ^(1/2)jc2
e COS X
dx
,2 dy ,
42. y2 ^ + (y2 4- 2y)x — 1=0 47. x2 -—I- y2? _
= xy
dx
y
50. x + v = v2x2 cos x
dx
45. ^ = x + e”
dy
dx . .
51. --x cot y = ey( 1 — cot y)
dy
46. x^ +2y = 3xV/3
dx
Find the particular solution for each of the following differential equations under the given
conditions. v
dy
52. -—by tan x = sec x, y = — 1 when x = 0
dx
dx
54. (y2 4- 1) —4- 2xy = y2, y = — 1 when x = 0
64. dx + dy = 0, y = 2 when x = 1
69. The change in net profit, P, as advertising expenditure, x, changes is given by the equation
— = k — a(P 4- x)
dx
,
dC
dx
=
C
a-
x
dC _ , .
——K aC = h 4- kx
dx
dc
= c + ke1
dl
47. x = y In Cx
65. x2y 4- 3(x + 1) = lex~1
49. 2ex esc y 4- e2x = C
67. y = 2x2 — 2x2e_*3_1
51. x = ey + C sin y k + 1
k + 1 t-ax
69. P = - x 4- P0 -
53. y sin x 4- In cos x = 0 a a
S(t) = a y(t)
«■>-'£
s(t) = i(t)
y(0) = y0
a>0 f>0
5.6 Applications of Differential Equations in Economic Models / 503
dy a
dt ~P
is obtained for solution.
1 dy a
y dt p
ln y=+c
y = CeMn
If y — yo at t = 0, then
= C
and the particular solution is
y — y0 e(alp)t
Note that this solution gives income, y, as a function of time, t. Since a > 0,/?> 0, the
function has an increasing positive slope, the rate of increase depending on a/p.
Solutions for the remaining variables of the model, / and S, are as follows:
y(0) = y0
0(0) = D0
a >0 p>0
where D is national debt and y is national income (both endogenous). In this model,
national income increases at a constant rate p over time and the rate of increase of
national debt is a fixed proportion of national income. The third and fourth equa¬
tions state the initial conditions. Integrating the second equation,
y — pt -V C
504 / Differential Equations
y = pt + y0
Substituting in the first equation of the model,
dD
—- = <xpt + Gcy0
at
D = {apt2 + a y0t + C
D — fit2 + ay0t + D0
y(t) = fit + y0
or
As t -*■ oo,
(a constant)
pt + yo P
{cf.pt2
—-► 00
Pt + yo
\
Thus, as t -+ oo, D(t)/y(t) -> oo and, for this model, the ratio of national debt to
national income increases over time without limit.
dy
dt
y(0) = ya
0(0) = D0
a > 0 p > 0
5.6 Applications of Differential Equations in Economic Models / 505
1 dy
= P
y dt
In y = fit -I- C
y = Cept
y = y0 e"'
Substituting in the first equation of the model,
dD
= a y0efit
dt
a
D = -y0eV + C
oe
Since D = D0 when t — 0, C = D0 — - y0 and
y. a nt
D = Do~^y0 + gy«ee
or
a
D = D0 + jy0(e»- 1)
D(t) = D0 +^y0(eIH - 1)
y(t) = y<>e0'
m _ Do .«/. _ m
At) yOe0’ n e>1}
As t -*■ oo,
D,
0
fit
a 1 a
1 -
,fit
d(t) = a0 + alp(t)
s(t) = Po + PiP(t)
fry(d-s)
where d is demand, s is supply, and p is price. Substituting the first two equations into
the third equation,
Yt = - Po + («1 -PM
where pe — (a0 — Po)/(Pi — ai) is the equilibrium price in the model obtained in the
usual way by solving d(t) = s(t) for p(t), the equilibrium price. Letting X — y(a1 — Pi),
jt = x{p~ p‘]
= x
p - pedt
In (p - pe) = At + C
P - Pe = Ceu
P = Pe + Cex'
P = Pe + (PO ~ Pe)eM
where, as above, pe — (a0 — p0)/(Pi — ax) and X = y(ax — Pi). Since X < 0, p -> pe as
t -> 00.
INCOME-CONSUMPTION-INVESTMENT MODEL
Consider a differential-equations form of the income-consumption-investment model
where current consumption and investment are linear functions of current income
and income changes at a rate that is proportional to excess demand, that is, to
consumption plus investment minus income.
Cd(t) = a Y,(t)
hit) = 7 hit)
dY
-jf = Hcs + Is — Ys)
»i(0) =Y0-Ye
where Cs, Id, and Yd are deviations of consumption, investment, and income, respec¬
tively, from their equilibrium values Ce, Ie, and Ye. Substituting the first two equa¬
tions into the third equation,
^ = X(a + y - l)y4
= X(a + y — 1) dt
In Yd — A (a + y — l)t + C
Yd = CeMa+y~l)t
Yd = (Y0-Ye)e^ + y~l)t
That is,
PROBLEMS
1. Demand, x, and supply, y, of a product are given as a function of unit price, p, by the
following equations:
x = ap + b y = cp + d
Suppose that price changes in such a way that the excess of demand over supply is de¬
creased at a rate proportional to the excess. Show that
P = P + (Po ~ P)e
y(t) + P
*= yy{t)
y(°) = yo
0(0) = D0
dR a
dt S(t)
?■- -As(t>
R( 0) = 0
a > 0 A > 0
where JR is running cost of a car and S is resale value. Solve the model.
4. The increase in the number of new products tested, y, as amount, x, allocated to research and
development increases equals a constant times the product of the number of new products
tested and the amount allocated to research and development plus another constant times
the ratio of the amount allocated to research and development divided by the number of
new products tested. Find the relationship between the number of new products tested and
the amount allocated to research and development if y = y0 when x = 0.
5. Consider the model
dR a
dt S(t)
ft = -m
R( 0) = R0
S(0) = S0
where R is the cost of repairing and operating a machine and S is salvage value of the
machine. Find R and S as functions of time, t.
6. Consider the model
dw 1
+ kept
dt ccy(t)
dy
Mt)
dt
w(0) = w0
)>(0) =
k
0 > 0 a >
Pyo
where w is per capita consumption of wheat products and y is per capita income. Find w
and y as functions of time and determine the limit as t —► oo of the ratio of per capita
consumption of wheat to per capita income.
6.1 Introduction
When variables are considered as changing discretely or discontinuously rather than
continuously or instantaneously, difference equations rather than differential equa¬
tions are appropriate for expressing relationships among the changes. Difference
equations are frequently useful in business and economic analyses, since many eco¬
nomic data are recorded for uniformly spaced periods of time, for example, gross
national product may be given for a year; net profit for a quarter; quantities
produced, bought, or sold for a month.
In many econmic analyses, time is the independent variable and changes in other
variables over time are studied. Such studies of variables over discrete sets of time
values are referred to as period analyses, and difference equations provide the basis
for such analyses. Recall that when the time periods (or, more generally, the changes
in the independent variable) are made smaller and smaller, difference equations
approach differential equations as a limiting case.
For generality, the following discussion of the classification and solution of differ¬
ence equations is in terms of an independent variable x. In many economic and
business analyses, including the models discussed later, the independent variable
time is denoted by t.
After the definition and classification of difference equations are discussed, the
solution of a difference equation is defined. The method of solution and the behavior
of the solution sequence are considered for linear first-order difference equations
with constant coefficients and applications of these difference equations in economic
models are illustrated. The methods of solution, the behavior of the solution
sequence, and applications in economic models are then discussed for second-order
difference equations.
509
510 / Difference Equations
Note that Ayx is also a function of x; A is an operator and provides the rule for
computing Ayx from the sequence y0, yl9 y2,... . Similarly, higher-order differences
are obtained as differences of differences by applying the operator A:
EXAMPLE==========
If y = 2x2 -3,
A2y = Ayx+1 - Ayx
= 4
Alternatively,
EXAMPLE
If y = 3x + 5,
6.2 Definition and Classification of Difference Equations / 511
+ [3(x + 1) + 5] — [3x + 5]
= 0
Alternatively,
= 0
where a0, al9..., a„_ l5 an and g are functions of x (but not of yx) defined for x = 0,1,
2
Jm* J • • • •
A linear difference equation is of order n if, when written in this form, both a0 and
an are unequal to zero for all values of x under consideration; that is, a linear
difference equation is of order n if it involves values of y corresponding to values of x
differing by n but by not more than n. Difference equations that are not linear are, in
general, very difficult to solve and are seldom used. The following discussion is
confined to linear difference equations.
EXAMPLE
Each of the following difference equations is linear and of the order indicated.
EXAMPLE
yx + i-yx = Q (order 1)
y*+i - yx - 2yx = 5
yx + 3 - 2yx + 2 + 2yx+1 = 0
(order 2)
EXAMPLE
yx+ i - >x = 1
(x + 1 + c) — (x + c) = 1
so
y* = x + c
is a solution.
Ifyo = L
1=0 + c
c = 1
and
yx = x + 1
EXAMPLE
Show that yx = [x(x — l)/2] + c is a solution of yx+1 — yx = x and find a particular solution if
yo = 2.
If = x(x - l)/2,
>y+i ~ yx = *
= X
x(x + 1 — X + 1)
= X
2x
= X
T
so
x(x — 1)
yx = —- + c
is a solution.
ify0 = 2,
2 = 0 + c
c = 2
and
x(x - 1)
yx = —- + 2
EXAMPLE
yx+2 - yx = o
Ci + c2(-l)x + 2 - [d + c2(-i)x] = o
c2[(-i)*+2- (-1)1=0
so
yx = Ci + C2(~l)x
is a solution.
If yo = 2, yx = 5,
2 = d + c2
5 = Cj - c2
2d = 7
C\ = \
c2 = — i
and
yx = J-l(-ir
is the particular solution for y0 = 2, yx = 5.
PROBLEMS
1. Determine the order of each of the following linear difference equations,
a. 3yx + 2 - 3yx+1 = 3x c. 7yx+1 - 5yx = 3
b- 8yx + 3 - yx = 4 d. 6yx + 2 - 7yx = 5x
2. If y — x2 + 2x, find A2yx.
3. If y = ex, find A2yx.
4. If y = x3 -I- 3, find A2yx and A3yx.
C y
5. Show that yx =- is a solution of yx+1 =--— and find a particular solution if
1 + cx 1 + yx
>’o = — 4.
6. Show that yx = cx -f c2 2X is a solution of yx + 2 — 3yx+1 + 2yx = 0 and find a particular
solution if y0 = 1, yt = 2.
6.4 Linear First-Order Difference Equations with Constant Coefficients / 515
ai(x) , g(x)
1 / \ ' / \
a0(x) a0(x)
If a0(x), ai(x)> an(l dix) are constants, that is, are not in fact functions of x, then
y*+i =Ayx + B
4 i = Ay0 4 B
y2 = Ayx = A(Ay0 4 B) 4 B
— A2y0 4 AB 4 B
y3 = Ay2 = A(A2y0 4 AB 4 B) 4 B
= A3y0 4 A2B 4 AB 4 B
516 / Difference Equations
1 - A:
>4 = Axy0 + B for A 1 x = 0, 1,2,...
1 - A
yx = y0 4. Bx for A — 1 x = 0, 1, 2, ..
For For A —— 1,
=Ayx + B yx+i = yx + B
(1 — Ax
Axy0 + B j—j I + B = (Fo + Bx) + B
IX+
. 1, —
,A - Ax+1 + 1 - A"
1
= A*+1y0 + B = y0 + B(x 4- 1)
1 - A
1 - Ax+1
= Ax+1y0 + B
1 - A
There are three special cases of the difference equation yx+l = Ayx + B which
occur frequently in descriptions of business and economic data.
1
Solution: yx = >4
1 — or
EXAMPLE
Solve the equation 2yx+l = Ayx + 3 and find the particular solution if y0 = i-
2 Vx +1 = 4yx + 3
y*+i = 2yx + i
yx = (yo + !)2" -1
if y0 = i
yx = 2x+1
EXAMPLE
Solve the equation 3yx+1 = 3yx — 7 and find the particular solution if y0 = 3.
3y* + i = 2>yx-l
y^+i = y, - ix
yx = yo - ix
If y0 = 3,
yx = 3 - ix
EXAMPLE
Solve the equation 6yx+1 + 2yx = 0 and find the particular solution if y0 = 2.
6yx +1 +2yx = 0
yx+i = —
yx = (~i)xyo
If y0 = 2,
y* = 2(-i)*
EXAMPLE
Solve the equation 3yx+1 — 9yx + 8 = 0 and find the particular solution if y0 —
518 / Difference Equations
3y*+i - 9yx + 8 = 0
yx+i = 3y,-f
8 /I - 3J
= 3xy0
3 \ -2
yx = y0 + Bx for A = 1 x = 0, 1, 2, ...
Figure 6.1
y* yx y*
J L J 1 I L -*► x ► X
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 • • • • • «
(a) (b)
6.4 Linear First-Order Difference Equations with Constant Coefficients / 519
(j) (k)
520 / Difference Equations
Behavior of the
Case A B y0 yx, x = 1, 2, ... solution sequence
Constant: yx = y*
it
(a) A± 1 yx = y
II
o
(b) A > 1 yo > y* yx > y* Diverges to + oo
(monotone increasing)
(c) A > 1 yo < y* yx < y* Diverges to — oo
(monotone decreasing)
(d) 0 <A < 1 yo > y* yx > y* Converges to y*
(monotone decreasing)
(e) 0 <A < 1 y0 < y* yx < y* Converges to y*
(monotone increasing)
(f) -1 <A <0 y0 + y* Converges to y*
(damped oscillatory)
(g) A = —1 yo + y* Diverges
(oscillates finitely)
(h) A < —1 yo t4 y* Diverges
(oscillates infinitely)
(i) A = 1 B = 0 yx = yo Constant: yx = y0
(j) A = 1 B > 0 yx > yo Diverges to + oo
(monotone increasing)
00 A = 1 B <0 yx < yo Diverges to — oo
(monotone decreasing)
The results given in the table can be summarized in the following theorem.
EXAMPLE
Solve each of the following difference equations, determine the behavior of the solution
sequence, and calculate the first few values of the solution sequence.
(a) 6yx+1 + 2yx - 3 = 0, y0 = 1.
yx+ i = ~iyx + i
= (-1)^0+i(i-(-in
= (~i)*(yo -1) +1
If y0 = l,
yx = ■§( ~i)* + I
6.4 Linear First-Order Difference Equations with Constant Coefficients / 521
y*+i = hx + 3
y* - (?) yo + 3I yz|'
~
= (f)x(y0 - 15) + 15
If y0 = 10,
y* = 15 - 5(f)*
yx+1 = 5y* + f
^ = 5>>’»+! (r:-y)
= 5*y0 — ys(l -5*)
If yo = 0,
yx - 2t>(5x - 1)
EXAMPLE
If money earns simple interest, the amount on deposit at any interest date is equal to the
amount on deposit one period (usually a year) previously plus the interest earned in that
period on the initial principal invested. If S0 is the initial deposit, St is the amount on deposit
after t periods, and r is the interest rate per period, then
When the initial amount accumulates at compound interest, the interest earned during any
period is computed on the total sum on deposit at the beginning of that period, rather than on
the initial deposit, and
Sf = (1 4 i)*So t = 0,1,2,...
The amount on deposit diverges to + 00 linearly for simple interest [case (j)] and more rapidly
for compound interest [case (b)].
522 / Difference Equations
y* = y~Ta if A^ 1
Note that this theorem is closely related to the preceding theorem, which states
that the solution sequence converges to y* if — 1 < A < 1 and diverges otherwise,
unless yx = y0. Stable equilibrium occurs only for cases (a), (d), (e), (f), and (i) of
Table 6.1.
PROBLEMS
Solve each of the following difference equations.
Solve each of the following difference equations, determine the behavior of the solution
sequence, and calculate the first few values of the solution sequence.
II
o
yo = T
11. Tx+1 == 3yx - b To = T 21. 4yx + i ~Tx - 3 == 0, yo = j
12. Tx+ i + 3yx + 1 = 0, y0 = 1 22. 4yx + i + 3yx -- 4 = 0, y0 = 1
13. 2 yx+1 - yx = 2, yo = 4 23. 3yx + i - 2yx -- 6 = 0, y0 = 4
14. yx+i == Vx -- b y0 = 5 24. 9yx + i + 5yx -- 18 = 0, y0 = 1
11. yx = i; constant
9
13. yx = 2ft)x + 2; monotone decreasing, converges to y* = 2;y0 = 4, yx = 3, y2 = -f, y3 = T,
17 _ 33
y4 = y 5 — T6
15- yx = i{~i)x + 7 damped oscillatory, converges to y* = J; Vo = 1, ^1
,, _ 5
— 7? ,, _ 39
y 2 — T9,
265 1871 13065
y 3 = JTS, y 4- = TTUT y s = 16807
17. y* = + i; monotone decreasing, converges to y* = f; y0 = 1, yi = ■$, y2 = i,
,, _ 97 ,, _ 55 ,, _ 29
y3 — T75> y4 — ¥T> ^5 — *5
19. yx = ¥( — 4)x — 4^; divergent, oscillates infinitely; y0 = 6, yx — -36, y2 = 132,
y3 — 540, y4 = 2148, y5 = -8604
31
21. yx — (i)(i)x + 1; monotone increasing, converges to y* = 1; y0 = i, yi = J, y2 T2>
127 _ 511 ,, _ 2047
y3 TTS> y4 ~ JTJ, y5 — 2048
_ 14 46
23. y* = -2ft) + 6; monotone increasing, converges to y* = 6; y0 = 4, yx “ T> y2 =
146 ,, _ 454 1394
t lOi
.V 3 y 4 - “8T~ >’5 = TTT
I, = P(Y,-Y,_,)
S, = I,
Y0 = Y0 (known value at t = 0)
a>0 p>0
where S is saving, I is investment, Y is income, and each of these variables is a
function of time t.
From the first three equations of the model, the difference equation
aY, = P(Y,-Y,.l)
is obtained for solution and
P
Y,-
p — a.
I, = S, = aj
P
lo
P — a,
Assuming Y0 > 0, the behavior of the solution sequence depends on the value of the
constant p/(p — a). Since Y represents income and is assumed to be nonnegative,
P >0
p — a
524 / Difference Equations
Supply: q, = a + ppt.i
Demand: pt = y + Sqt
q0 = q0 (known value at t — 0)
where p is price, q is quantity, and both are functions of time t. Substituting the
second equation into the first equation,
q, = cc + py + Pdq.-t
p, = y + aS + Pdp,-!
Difference equations can be solved in the usual way; however, it is the behavior of
the solution sequence that is of interest. Since p > 0, S < 0, their product pS < 0, and
the solution sequences are thus always oscillatory. The equilibrium point is
y + ocS a + py\
(P*5 q*) =
i-ps'
If — 1 < PS < 0, the sequences {pt} and {qt} are damped and converge to (p*, q*); if
PS = —1, the sequences oscillate finitely; if pS < —1, the sequences oscillate
infinitely. Thus the equilibrium is stable only if — 1 < p3 < 0.
note: If the supply curve is written so that its slope is with respect to the
quantity variable, the slope is 1/p. Thus the equilibrium is stable if and only if the
slope of the demand curve is less (in numerical value) than the slope of the supply
curve.
CONSUMPTION MODEL
The following simple model for consumption has been proposed.
Ct + St = Yt
Yt = aSf _ i
Y0 = Y0 (known value at t = 0)
Yt = (a - ay)%
C, = yY,
so
C, = y(a - ay)' Y0
c, = (a - ay)'C0
S:=Yt-C,
so
s, = (1 - y)(a - ay)%
St = (oc- ocy)‘S0
Since 0 < y < 1, a — ay>0; the sequences {1J}, {Cj, and {,St} are monotone increas¬
ing and diverge to + 00 if a(l — y) > 1, monotone decreasing and converge to y* = 0
if a(l — y) < 1, and constant at Y* = 0 if a(l — y) = 1.
INCOME-CONSUMPTION-INVESTMENT MODEL
When changes over time are considered to occur periodically rather than contin¬
uously, the income-consumption-investment model stated in terms of differential
equations in Chapter 5 can be stated in terms of difference equations, as follows.
Ct = <xYt + p
it = yYt + g
A Yt_l=6[Ct.1Ylt-l-Yt_1]
Y0=Y0
1 - [% + y) + (1 - 0)J
= [% + y) + (i - 0)]% + 0(P + a)
1 - [9(a + y) + (1 - 0)]
526 / Difference Equations
__<a+?+__i<_
1 1 i 1
2
1—- < a + y < 1
0
Since 0 < 0 < 1 and a + y > 0, the left-hand part of the inequality 1 - (2/0) < a + y is
satisfied. Thus the stability condition is a + y < 1, as for the differential equations
form of the model.
PROBLEMS
1. In the Cobweb model, if the supply curve has negative slope, state the conditions for stable
equilibrium.
2. Derive the solution of the Kahn model:
Ct = «Yt.l + p
Yt = Ct + /,
where C is consumption, Y is income, and / is investment.
3. Solve the following model, determine the behavior of the solution sequences, and state any
additional “ logical ” restrictions on the parameters.
St = (xYt + (J
It = y(Yt-Yt.l)
St = SIt
Y0= Y0
yt = ut + v0
ut = pyt-1
yo = y0
0 < p < 1
where y is income produced, u is the number of units produced for sale, with units of
measurement appropriately chosen, v0 is the constant noninduced investment, and p is the
marginal propensity to consume of one year’s consumption with respect to the previous
year’s income.
5. Consider the model
Pt = 2 - qt
qt + i = pTV i + 1
Po = Po
0 < a < 1
where q is the quantity supplied, p is the actual price, p* is the supplier’s estimated price for
the next period, and p is a public forecast for the price. Note that a = 1 implies that the
6.5 Applications of Difference Equations in Economic Models / 527
suppliers have perfect confidence in the public forecast; a = 0 implies they have no
confidence in the public forecast. Defining At+1 by the equation
+1 = P*+1 — pt +1
Yt = Ct + It
Ct = a + pYt
Yt +1 - Yt = ylt
Y0 =Y0 C0 = C0 /„ = I0
Qdt = Qst
where Pf denotes the expected price in period t and sellers have an “adaptive” price
expectation so that
a. Show that the model can be represented by the first-order difference equation
P t +1 >?(« + y)
—
P
Hint: Solve the supply equation for Pf and note that Qst = Qdt = a - pPt-
b. Determine the nature of the solution sequence.
2 S
c. Show that the solution sequence, if oscillatory, converges only if 1-<-.
V P
8. In the Harrod model, graph {7f} for each of the following cases and comment on the
plausibility of each.
Case a P ^0
i 2 100
(a) 3
1 2 100
(b) ~3
(c) -4 2 100
i 2 -100
(d) 3
3.
P approaches + oo
cc
approaches + oo
Sy > cc
rjd
7. b. converges (nonoscillatory)
yx+2 + Aiyx+i + A2 y x = 0
An equation whose constant term is zero is sometimes said to be homogeneous.
Thus yx+ 2 + yx+1 + A2yx = 0 is the general homogeneous second-order linear
difference equation with constant coefficients. The definition of a homogeneous
equation should not be confused with the definition of a homogeneous function; the
two uses of the word homogeneous are not related.
In order to obtain the solution of
yx+2 + Aiyx+i + a2 yx = o
form the auxiliary equation
m2 -f At m + A2 = 0
and solve for its roots, using the quadratic formula (if necessary):
_ -At+y/Al- 4A2
m\ 2
These roots mx and m2 may be real and unequal, real and equal, or complex
(involving the square root of a negative number). The form of the solution of the
equation yx+2 + yx+1 + A2yx = 0 depends on the nature of the roots mx and m2,
as summarized below. The general solution of a second-order difference equation
includes two arbitrary constants and a particular solution is specified by two boun¬
dary conditions, that is, by two consecutive values of y.
Note that a and b can be interchanged in these definitions, since the trigonometric
functions are periodic. For convenience, the solution is usually written for 0 in the
first quadrant.
EXAMPLE
y^ + 2 - 5yx+i + 6y* = 0
m2 — 5m + 6 = 0
and
5 + 25 - 24
m{ =- = 3
5 - v/25“T4 ,
m2 =-^-= 2
yx = Cl3x + C22x
If y0 = 2, yx = 5,
2 = Cj + C2
5 = 3 Cx + 2C2
C2 = 1
C, = 1
yx = 3X + 2X
530 / Difference Equations
EXAMPLE
m2 — 4m + 4 = 0
and
4 + VI6 - 16 ,
m,= V2 =2
4-^16-16 ,
m2 = 2 =2
yx = C{2X + C2x 2X
If y0 = Uy i = 6,
1 = Cj + 0
6 = 2CX + 2 C2
Ci = 1
C2 = 2
yx = 2x + x2x + 1
EXAMPLE
Tc+2 ~ Tc+1 + bx = 0
OJ
II
m2 — m + j = 0
and
1 +s/l -2 , ,
mi = ^ = I + l1
l-v/T-2 , i.
m2 = ^ —IV
r=yifFMip=
tan 9 = 1
0 =b
6.6 Linear Second-Order Difference Equations with Constant Coefficients / 531
If y0 = 3, yi = i
3 = me Ml) + (C2)(0)]
Cj = 3
i = I + tC:
C, = 2
and the particular solution is
C
limiting behavior of the solution sequence {Clmxl + C2m2) is the same as that of
{Ci mj), provided Cx ± 0.
This can be shown by writing
Cxm\ Cx Cj
= 1 as x 00
C1m^-fC2m2 Ci + C2(m2/m1)x Cl
Thus the limiting behavior of {Ct mx -f C2 m2} is the same as the limiting behavior of
{Ci mi} if | mi | > \m2\. The limiting behavior of {Ci mx} is discussed in the preced¬
ing sections concerning solution sequences of first-order difference equations. This
limiting behavior can be summarized in the notation of the present section as follows.
yx+2 + + A2yx — 0
then p < 1 is a necessary and sufficient condition for the solution sequence {yx} to
converge with limit 0 for all initial values y0 and yx.
EXAMPLE
In the preceding example the general solution for the difference equation yx + 2 ~ $yx + i +
6yx = 0 is found to be
yx = CX3X + C22x
and, since — 3 and m2 = 2, p > 1 and the solution sequence diverges, as can be seen from
the first few values of the particular solution yx = 3* + 2X: y0 = 2, yx = 5, y2 = 13, y3 = 35,
y4 = 97, y5 = 275, and so forth.
In another previous example, the general solution for the difference equation
yx + 2 — 4yx+l + 4yx = 0 is found to be
yx = Ci2x + C2x2x
and, since = m2 = 2, p > 1 and the solution sequence diverges, as can be seen from the first
few values of the particular solution yx — 2X + x2x + 1: y0 = 1, y i = 6, y2 = 20, y3 = 56,
y4 = 144, y5 = 352, and so forth.
In another previous example, the general solution for the difference equation
y* + 2 - yx+1 + iyx = o is found to be
and p = yj2/2 < 1, so the solution sequence is oscillatory and converges to zero, as can be seen
from the first few values of the particular solution
/v/2\x
yx = \— |‘ (3 cos \nx -f 2 sin lynx)
6.6 Linear Second-Order Difference Equations with Constant Coefficients / 533
>\+2 + ^i^+i + A2 yx = K
First try a solution of the form: yp equals a constant; say, yp = k. If the solution
yp = k satisfies the difference equation, then
k Ayk A2k = K
and
1 4- Ay + A2
k = J^2
and yp = F^xJ(A1 + 2), unless 1 + + A2 = 0 and A1 -1-2 = 0.
If both 1 + Ax + A2 ~ 0 and Ax — —2, that is, if A1 — —2 and A2 = 1, then try a
solution of the form yp = kx2. It can be verified that, in this case, yp = (K/2)x2. Note
that this solution is appropriate only for the difference equation yx + 2 — 2yx+1 +
yx = K. Except for this one case, if g(x) is a constant, the difference equation
yx + 2 + Ai yx+l + A2yx — ^(x) has a particular solution, yp, which is a constant.
In summary, when g(x) is constant, the difference equation yx + 2 -I- Atyx+1 +
A2 yx — g{x) has a particular solution as follows:
K
if 1 + -|- A2 ^ 0
p 1 + Ai + A2
Kx if 1 -f- Ax + A2 — 0
Vp = A, + 2 Al + 2 =£ 0
if 1 —F Ay -f- A2 = 0
Ay 4-2 = 0
(that is, if Ay — —2, A2 = 1)
534 / Difference Equations
EXAMPLE
y* + 2 ~ 6y*+1 4- 8y*= 9
and a particular solution if y0 = 10, yx = 25.
The auxiliary equation of the homogeneous equation is
m2 — 6m + 8 = 0
(m - 4)(m — 2) = 0
—4
m2 = 2
The general solution of the homogeneous equation is thus
yx = Ct4x + C22x
and the general solution of the nonhomogeneous equation is
y, = C, 4X + C2 2X +
where yp = K/( 1 + + A2) = 9/(1 — 6 + 8) = 3 and thus
yx = Cl 4* + C22x + 3
If y0 = 10, yx = 25,
Ci+C2 = 10-3 = 7
4Ci + 2C2 = 25 - 3 = 22
2 Ci = 8
C\ =4
C2 = 3
and the particular solution is
yx = 4x+l + (3)2* + 3
EXAMPLE
y* + 2 + 3yx+i - 4yx = 10
and a particular solution if y0 = 5, yx = 20.
The auxiliary equation of the homogeneous equation is
m2 + 3m — 4 = 0
(m + 4)(m - 1) = 0
mj = —4
m2 = 1
The general solution of the homogeneous equation is thus
y« = c,(-4)* + c2(i)*
and the general solution of the nonhomogeneous equation is
y, = c,(-4)* + Cj + y,
6.6 Linear Second-Order Difference Equations with Constant Coefficients / 535
yx = Ct(-4 )* + C2 + 2x
If y0 = 5, yx = 20,
Ci + C2 = 5
— 4C1 + C2 = 20 - 2 = 18
-5Cj = 13
Ci = ~2.6
C2 = 7.6
and the particular solution is
1 + Ai A A2
The equilibrium value is said to be stable or the difference equation
y*+2 + Aiyx+i + A2 yx = K is said t0 t>e stable if every solution of the difference
equation converges to y* for every possible set of initial conditions y0 and yl9 that is,
if
lim yx = y* for all y0 and yx
536 / Difference Equations
It can be shown that a necessary and sufficient condition for the equilibrium value
y* = K/( 1 4- Ax + A2) to be stable is p < 1, where,as above, p = max (\ml \ m- )
and Wj and m2 are the roots of the auxiliary equation m2 + A1 m + A2 = 0.
It can be shown that p < 1 if and only if2±Al>l — A2>0. Thus these inequal¬
ities are necessary and sufficient for stability of the equilibrium value y* and
y* = K/( 1 4- Ax 4- A2) is a stable equilibrium for the difference equation
y* + 2 + ^iFx+i + ^2 y x = K if and only if 2 ± At > 1 - A2 > 0.
PROBLEMS
Obtain the general solution for each of the following difference equations.
1. yx + 2 + 2yx+l 4- yx = 0
2- y* + 2 - y* = 0
3. 2yx + 2 - 5yx+1 4- 2yx = 0
4. 3yx + 2 - 6yx +, 4- 4yx = 0
5. Find the general solution for the difference equation yx + 2 + 2yx = 0 and the particular
solution if y0 = 1, yi = J2.
6. Find the general solution for the difference equation yx + 2 4- 3yx+1 4- 3yx = 0 and the
particular solution if y0 = 3, yx = 0.
For each of the following difference equations, obtain the general solution and the particular
solution for the specified initial values.
Solve each of the following difference equations, determine the behavior of the solution
sequence, and calculate the first few values of the solution sequence.
Second-order difference equations are used in many economic models to indicate the
dependence of the value of a variable on its value for two preceding periods. Second-
order difference equations may be associated with various types of relationships
among variables in the model; some of these relationships are illustrated in Samuel-
son’s interaction model and Metzler’s inventory model, which are discussed in this
section.
Yt = Ct + It + Gt
Ct = a yr_!
It = p[Ct-Ct_l\
Yo=Y0
Yi = Yl
a >0 p >0
where Y is national income, C is consumption, / is investment, and G is government
expenditure. G is assumed constant (exogenous) from period to period and, for
convenience, the units are assumed to be such that G = 1. Note that investment in
any period is equal to a constant times the increase in consumption of that period
over the preceding period; this is referred to as the acceleration principle.
Substituting the second and third equations into the first equation,
Y, = «Y,~i + ~ +1
Yt- a(l +P)Y,.l +cgSy,_2 -1=0
The three types of general solution of the homogeneous equation, depending on the
nature of the roots of the auxiliary equation, are as follows:
a(l
+ — - P) v/a2(l + P)2 4a/?
m =--—--
2 2
(b) Yt = Cl mx + C2 tm\ where
m= + P)
538 / Difference Equations
a(l + /?)
sin 0 =
2v^
cos 6 =
4a p — a2(l + p2) «(1 + P)
4ap 4/J
A particular solution of the nonhomogeneous equation
Yt-a(l+P)Yt-1+aPYt-2-l=0
is given by
1
^p 1 — a(a + P) + ap
1
1 —a
assuming that 1 — a ^ 0. Since a is the marginal propensity to consume, a < 1 and
1 — a =/= 0.
Thus the solution of the nonhomogeneous equation has the form
(b) Yt = Ct mf + C2 tm1 + --
1 —a
where ml9 m2, m, r, and 6 are defined as above and the arbitrary constants can be
determined from the initial conditions T0 and Yl. Whenever the sum of the first two
terms of the solution (in any of the three possible forms) tends to zero, y* = yp =
1/(1 — a) is an equilibrium solution.
The stability conditions 1 + T1+T2>0, 1 — ^ + T2 > 0 and 1 — A2 > 0
become
1 — a(l + p) + ap > 0 or 1 — a > 0
1 — aP > 0
Since a > 0, p > 0, the second condition is satisfied and the necessary and sufficient
conditions for y* to be a stable equilibrium value are
a < 1
ap < 1
That is, both the marginal propensity to consume (one year’s consumption with
respect to the previous year’s income) and its product with the accelerator parameter
must be less than 1 for the sequence of income values to converge to y* for all
possible initial conditions. The convergence to y* is oscillatory if the roots of the
auxiliary equation are complex numbers. This is the case if A\ — 4A2 is negative, that
is, if a2(l + p)2 — 4aP < 0.
6.7 Applications of Second-Order Difference Equations in Economic Models / 539
yt = Mr + St + V0
u, = Py,-i
s, = P(y,-i - >’,-2)
0 < p<1
where yt is total income produced in period t, ut is consumers’ goods produced for
sale in period t, st is consumers’ goods produced for inventories in period t, and v0 is
the constant noninduced net investment in each period.
The total income produced in any period is equal to the total production of
consumers’ goods plus net investment. Sales in any period are a constant proportion
of the income in the preceding period. Production for inventory is equal to the
difference between actual and anticipated sales of the preceding period; that is, there
is an attempt to keep inventory at a constant level. It is assumed that inventories are
sufficient to meet differences between production and consumer demand.
Substituting the second and third equations into the first equation,
y, - + py,-2 = v0
equivalently, so the f-values can begin at t = 0,
m2 — 2 pm + P = 0
m =
2p ± jW - 4^
Since 0 < p<ip2-p < 0 and the roots are complex numbers
m = P ± iy/ftl - P)
Thus
r = V/;2 + M - J) = VP
cos v =
Sp
sin 6 =
^pj^p) = VTzr~p
■Jp
The general solution of the homogeneous equation
is given by
Vo
since 0 < ft < 1 and thus 1 — p ± 0. The general solution of the nonhomogeneous
equation thus has the form
The term involving sines and cosines results in cyclical fluctuations because of its
oscillation between positive and negative values. These fluctuations are damped by
the factor (v//?)f since 0 < p < 1. Thus
and
Vq
yt-+ as t 00
1-p
as an equilibrium value.
PROBLEMS
1. For the Samuelson model, verify the expressions for ml5 m2, m, r, and 9 given in the text.
2. For the Samuelson model, show that the roots of the auxiliary equation are complex if and
only if
3. For the Samuelson model, obtain the solution and determine the behavior of the solution
sequence if a. a = 0.8, p = 0.3 and b. a = 0.5, P = 0.1.
4. For the price-adjustment equation
y,+2--yi+, + -y, = o
S S
where Y is warranted income and C and s are positive constants. Show that for C > 4s this
equation gives an explosive (divergent) solution for warranted income, but for C < 4s
warranted income is cyclic.
6. For the Metzler model, note that (total) inventory, denoted by i, is given by
it = it_1 + st + ut - yt
Obtain an expression for change in inventory, it — it-u in terms of yt and determine the
behavior of this solution sequence.
7.1 Introduction
In many economic analyses, variables are assumed to be related by sets of linear
equations. Matrix algebra provides a clear and concise notation for the formulation
and solution of such problems, many of which would be almost impossibly com¬
plicated in conventional algebraic notation.
In this chapter, vectors, matrices, and operations involving them are defined.
Special types of matrices, the transpose of a matrix, partitioned matrices, and the
determinant of a matrix are considered. Linear dependence of a set of vectors and the
rank and inverse of a matrix are also discussed and are applied to the solution of
simultaneous equations. Vector differentiation is defined and illustrated. In Chapter
8 further applications of matrix algebra are considered.
In this section matrices are defined and illustrated. A matrix is a rectangular array of
numbers written in the form
EXAMPLE
10-26 is a 2 x 4 matrix
4 8 3 -9
6 6 3
3 8 -2 is a 3 x 3 (square) matrix
-1 0 0
5 -8 -2
12 10 -1
13 9 -3 is a 5 x 3 matrix
2 7 6
6 4 10
1 -1
is a 2 x 2 (square) matrix
-1 1
Two matrices of the same order are said to be equal if and only if all the corre¬
sponding elements are equal, that is, if the matrices are identical.
EXAMPLE
A = D, but A ^ B, A ^ C, B ^ C, B ^ D, and C ^ D.
DEFINITION OF A VECTOR
A matrix that consists of a single column, that is, an m x 1 matrix, is said to be a
column vector and is written
ui «i
u2 u2
u = or u =
Um
The letters u{ stand for real numbers, the components of the vector; is the ith
component of the vector u. A column vector that has m rows is said to be an
m-component or an m-dimensional vector.
7.2 Definition of a Matrix / 543
Similarly, a matrix that contains only a single row, that is, a 1 x n matrix, is said
to be a row vector and is written
EXAMPLE
-1
is a 2 x 1 matrix, a 2-dimensional column vector
-1
'O'
0
3 is a 5 x 1 matrix, a 5-dimensional column vector
0
_2_
Two row vectors having the same number of rows or two column vectors having
the same number of columns are said to be equal if and only if all the corresponding
elements are equal, that is, if the vectors are identical.
EXAMPLE
u = [1, 3]
T
V=1 J 3
w = [1, 3]
x = [3, 1]
1 -6 "
2 2
-3 4
can be regarded as consisting of the two column vectors
r "-6"
-
L._
4^ N)
2 and
-3
i
ai i • a In
am 1 • a mn
b\ l
B=
_bml b mn
then
A + B = C
where
• • •
a\ 1 ± &11 •" Ain ± bln cn c 1n
... r,
_ aml ± bml •' ‘ amn i bmn _ Cm 1 ^mn
that is, (au) + (bI7) = (c0), where ci;- = atj + btJ for all i and j.
EXAMPLE
i
i
oo
O
m
_
"3 2 -4 ‘ “3 5 4"
o o
H-
4^ O
(a) 5 6 8 + -5 -6 2 = 0
_3 0 0 _ 0 0 —4 _ _3
1
i
3 --10 -6 -4' 9 -6
(b)
-11 25. 22 -21. -33 46.
2 3 1 1 0 3 4
(e) +
6 4 -1 2 6 4 -1 2.
7.3 Matrix Operations / 545
' 1' " 3" " 6 ' ' O' " -2“
_1
_1
i-
i_
— —
<N rf
oo O
^ -p*.
(f) 1 + + 1
1 1
_ 1. _ 0_
i
i
(g) [2, 1] + [3, 4] + [6, 7] -[11, 12] = [0,0]
PROBLEMS
Obtain the matrix resulting from each of the following operations.
—
O <N
3. 3 + 1
_ 4 . _ —2 _
i
2 1 -1 0 '2 2
'
1 2 . 0 -1 2 2.
1. 5 6 3. 4
OO
_ -1 -1 _ 0 _
1
5. [1,2, 1, -1]
aj ^ * a In
A = and k is any scalar (constant)
ami a mn
then
kalx ••• kaln
t-
n. x A
a rkmXn — Is A k(aij)m x n ~ (kau)
ijfm x n
kami kamn
EXAMPLE
4 ' -3 “ ‘ 12 -9 '
(a) 3 8 -2 — 24 -6
_-l 0 _ _ -3 0 .
546 / Matrix Algebra
0 ' 0 "
-1 = -5
0 _ 0 _
5 6 2 4 5a 6a 2a 4a
(d) a
-3 -1 0 -6 — 3a —a 0 — 6a
0 “ 0 "
-2 2b
3 = -3 b
-1 b
5 _ — 5b _
MULTIPLICATION OF MATRICES
Two matrices can be multiplied if and only if the number of columns in one matrix is
equal to the number of rows in the other matrix. In particular, the matrix product AB
is defined if and only if the number of columns in A is the same as the number of rows
in B, in this case the matrices A and B are said to be conformable for multiplication
and the product matrix has the same number of rows as A and the same number of
columns as B. Thus an m x n matrix may be multiplied times an n x p matrix to
obtain an m x p matrix.
X aljbjm
j= 1 j= i
C = (cik) m y p
n
I amjbj\ X amjbjn
j= 1 j= 1
EXAMPLE
where
3 0
4 0
(b) [-1,0,6, 3, 2]1x5 2 3 = [-12, 38]i x2
1 8
0 -2
where
EXAMPLE
(a) If
1 2
4 6-13 -1 1
and B =
0-121 1 6
2 3
then
1 2"
4 6 -1 3 -1 1 3 17
AB =
0 -1 2 1 2x4 1 6 5 14 2 x 2
2 3 _ 4x2
1 2 “ 4 4 3 5 '
-1 1 4 6 -1 3 ' -4 -7 3 -2
BA =
1 6 0 -1 2 1 2x4 4 0 11 9
oo
2 3 _ 4x2 9 4 9 __ 4 x 4
(b) If
5 -6
-1 8 3
A = 1 0 and B =
0 10 4
0 3
548 / Matrix Algebra
then
i_i
i
-20
vo O m
" 5 9"
1
1
-1 8 -3
-8
t-h o
AB = -1 3
0 3x2
0 10 —4 2x3 30 12 J 3x3
i
" 5 -6 _
▼-H
m i—H
-1 8 -3 -3
1 1
BA = -1 0
O
0 10 -4 2x3 -12 2x2
0 3 _ 3x2
(c) If
-1 3 1 ' 0 2 3 "
A = 2 0 -2 and B = 8 -1 9
-
0 4 5 _ . -2 0 5 _
0 " 2 3
-
~ -1 3 1 “ 4 12 11 '
BA = 8 -1 9 2 0 -2 = — 10 60 55
_ -2 0 5 3x3 0 4 5 _ 3x3 2 14 23 _
note: When a row vector premultiplies a column vector, the result is their inner
product, a scalar whose value is the sum of the products of the elements of the two
vectors. When an n x 1 column vector premultiplies a 1 x n row vector, the result is
an n x n square matrix whose elements are the products of the elements of the
vectors; thus if
then, as above, ux x„v„xl = w (a scalar) where w = u{ v{, and v„x jiij x„ = xnXn
(a square matrix), where xtj =
EXAMPLE
(a) [1, 3, 6] — 2 + 12 — 6 = 4
Although the sequence in which two matrices are multiplied affects the result, the
order in which three or more matrices are multiplied does not affect the result,
provided the sequence is preserved. That is,
EXAMPLE
B BC
ABC
0 4-2
0 -2 1
0 -2 1 J 3 x 3
Alternatively, by associativity,
B = A B
_ 3 _
' 1 -1 0“ " 2 ■
2 -3 4 1 [0, 2, -l]lx3 = -1 [0, 2, — 1] 1 X 3
_ 0 0 1 . 3x3 _-l 3 x 1 _ -1 _
ABC
0 4 2
0 -2 1
0 -2 1 _ 3 x 3
EXAMPLE
= ABC
-1
-262 2 x 1
550 / Matrix Algebra
Alternatively, by associativity,
A B c — A B c
"- 1 " ~-l"
1 - i 1 5 -2 3 13 -2 -3
o
_
0
6 10 j 2 x 2 -8 0 6 2x3 -50 -12 78 . 2x3
_ —4_
1
3 x l
i
= ABC
-1
-262 2 x l
EXAMPLE
A B C A B C
3 4 0 1 -6 -8 10 3 4 -5 5 4
4 3. 2x2 -1 0 2x2 -5 5 4 2x3 4 3 2x2 6 8 10 2 x 3
ABC
9 47 28
-2 44 14 2 x 3
Alternatively, by associativity,
A B = A B
3 4 0 1 -6 -8 10] -4 3 -6 -8 10
4 3 2x2 -1 0 2x2 -5 5 4]2x 3 _ . -3 4. 2x2 -5 5 4. 2x3
ABC
9 47 -28
-2 44 —14 J 2x3
EXAMPLE
A B c = A B C
0“ r o 0 01
2 -2 0 12
L—i
o
'sO
r—i
-1 1 0 -6
0_ 4x 1 0 0 0
= ABC
= [6, 0, -36]! x 3
Alternatively, by associativity,
A B C =A B C
0
2
[1, -1, 4, 2]
1
[ — 1, 0, 6] 1 x 3 -6 X [ — 1, 0, 6]! x 3
0 4x 1
= ABC
= [6, 0, — 36] i x 3
7.4 Special Types of Matrices / 551
PROBLEMS
Obtain the matrix resulting from each of the following operations.
-1 2 3 4
1. 3 0 - 1-1 2
12 0 3
2 -r
2 1
2. i o
1 0
3 -3
2 1
1 3
3. [1, -1,0,2]
-1 0
0 2
1 -f
4. [1, -2,0] 3 0
2 1
-i r '2 0 T 1 1
5.
i -1 0 2. 111
2 O'
1 0
6. [1, -1, 1] 0 2
0 1
2 2
1. -3 -3 6
6 0 9
3. [1/2]
rooo
*"000
DIAGONAL MATRICES
A diagonal matrix is a square matrix that has zeros everywhere except on the main
diagonal, that is, the diagonal running from upper left to lower right; thus
A = ij/n x n
= (aij)n
_ani
au = 0 for i ± j
ai} ± 0 for at least one i = j (if all the elements of a matrix are zero, it is a null
matrix discussed below)
552 / Matrix Algebra
a\i 0 ~ a\ 0"
A = • or
-1s:
0 0 an_
c
or by
~d1 0
0 ' dn
EXAMPLE
-10 0 0
"1 0 0“
0 0 0 0
0-3 0 and
0 0 0 0
_0 0 10 _
0 0 0 7
IDENTITY MATRICES
An identity matrix is a diagonal matrix each of whose diagonal elements is postive
one;thus
rfl i i aln
A = ij/n x n
= (aij)n
L^ni ®nn
ai} = 1 for i = j
EXAMPLE
1 0 0 0 0 0
"1 0 0"
0 1 0 0 0 0
0 1 0 and I6 0 0 1 0 0 0
I3
0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0
0 0 0 0 1 0
0 0 0 0 0 1
are the 3x3 and 6x6 identity matrices.
EXAMPLE
A2 x 4 = I2 A2x4
2 -3 -6 4 0 2 -3 -6 4
-1 -1 0 3. 2x4 1 2x2 -1 -1 0 3 2x4
A2 X 4 I4
1 0 0 0"
2 -3 -6 4 0 1 0 0
- 1-1 0 3 2x4 0 0 1 0
0 0
A2 4 X
2 -3 -6 4
- 1-1 0 3 2x4
EXAMPLE
A3 X 3 — 13 A3 x 3
‘3 0 o' "l 0 0 ■ "3 0 0 '
0 -2 0 = 0 1 0 0 -2 0
_0 0 6 _ 3x3 .0 0 1. 3x3 _0 0 6_
= A3 3 X i3
[3 0
°1
ri 0 01
= 0 -2 0 0 1 0
_0 0 6_ 3x3
_o 0 1_
= A3 3 X
r3 0 O'
= 0 -2 0
_0 0 6. 3x3
NULL MATRICES
A null matrix is an m x n matrix all of whose elements are zeros; it is denoted by O.
When the appropriately sized null matrix is added to or subtracted from another
matrix that matrix is unchanged, that is,
a +0
x n —— x n ~
— A x n
Ofc x m Am X n ~ ^k x n and Am x n 0„ x 1 = xj
EXAMPLE
A2 X 3 ± O2 X 3 =
A2 3 X
0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 0
+
10 0 -3J 2x3 [0 0 oj 2x3 [10 0 -3J
554 / Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
O 3x2 l2 x 4 o 3x4
“0 0 " 0 0 0 0
1 6 4 -10
0 0 0 0 0 0
-1 20-13 11 2x4
_0 0 _
3x2 0 0 0 0J 3x4
l2 x 4 o 4X1 =o 2 X 1
1-
1
O
_
O
1 6 4 -10 0
-1 20 -13 11 2x4 0 0 2x1
0 4 x 1
” al 1 " ' al n~
x n ! ! \®ij)m x n
- 1 &mn-
EXAMPLES
"3
2
If A = then A'= 2
0 2x3
Lo 3x2
5 x 1
~ 6 -8 -10" 6 -2 30 "
If A = -2 0 7 , then A'= -8 0 40
30 40 0 _ 3x3 _-io 7 0_
7.5 The Transpose of a Matrix / 555
3
0
If A = , then A' = [3, 0, -1, 4] 1 X 4
1
4 J 4 x 1
"6 0 0 O' 6 0 0 0
0 -2 0 0 0 -2 0 0
If A = ,then A'
0 0 3 0 0 0 3 0
_0 0 0 5. 4x4 - 0 0 0 5J 4 x4
If a (square) matrix and its transpose are equal, that is, if a0 = ayi for all i and
then the matrix is said to be symmetric (about its main diagonal). In the last two
examples above, the matrices are symmetric.
A' = A
and
A A = A
EXAMPLE
I„ = In
and
In In
EXAMPLE
The matrix
i
3 i
4
3
is idempotent, since
1 2 I /
3 3 3 3
2 4
17 3j -3 3.
and
3 ilfy 3 3 3
3 3JI3 3 3 3
556 / Matrix Algebra
that is,
i^ij)m X n {dji)n x m
EXAMPLE
If
0 2 0 0 6
A =
8 -1 -2 5 25
then
"2 -5"
2 6 6 f
[A + B + C]' = 6 11
-5 11 25
_6 25 _
or, alternatively,
EXAMPLE
If
6 8 0
B = C =
.10 --12. 0
then
f
-4 -10 —4 - 10
[A - B + C]' =
-10 11 -10 11
or, alternatively,
2 0 6 10 0 0 -4 -10
A - B' + C' = +
-1 -1 8 -12 -1 0 -10 11
x n x p Cp x J ^q x P x « An x m
7.5 The Transpose of a Matrix / 557
EXAMPLE
If
" 6 ‘
3 0 ' 3 5 -7'
A = B = C = -1
-4 -1 0 -1 8
0_
then
39
ABC =
-53
39
[ABC]' =
-53
= [39, -53]
or, alternatively,
3 0
3 -4
[ABC]' = C'B'A' = [6, -1, 0] 5 1
0 -1
7 8J
= [39, -53]
EXAMPLE
If
6 O'
0
[3, -1,0] B = -7 2 c =
1
1_
o
i
then ABC = — 2 and [ABC]' = — 2 (the transpose of a scalar is that scalar) or, alternatively,
3"
6-7 0
[ABC]' = C'B'A' = [0, 1] -1 = -2
0 2 3
o
i
PROBLEMS
Obtain the transpose of each of the following matrices.
2 6
1.
5 -3
-3'
2. 6
5
-2
-7 -5 6
3.
8 10 -3
r 1 -6 3
4. -1 4 -8
0 5 7
-1 3
6. 2 1
L-4 2
558 / Matrix Algebra
1 2 2
7. If A find:
2 1 4 0
a. [A + B]'
b. [B + C]'
c. [AB]'
d. [ABC]'
‘ 2 -1“
0 2
8. If A = 1 2 B =
-i 2 -4
_ 0 1_
and D =
a. [AB]'
b. [C + D]'
c. [D'C]'
d. A + D' + C'
8
3. 10
-3
5.
6
7. a.
1
6
b.
3
6 0
c.
3 6
6 12
d.
3 18
A = ; A2)
EXAMPLE
If
'4 -3 i 5 0 "
A = [Aii A2] = 2 -1 : 1 6
_8 -2 j 3 -7.
then
B
[b2]
where B is m x n, Bj is mi x n, B2 is m2 x n, and + m2 = m, then
Ai ± Bi
A+ B
A2 ± B2
EXAMPLE
If
‘ 3 4 -2 0“ 3 0 2 4
A= -1 0 5 6 and B = — 1 -1 -2 5
7 3 3 2_ 5 4 3 1
then
0 4 0 4
-2 -1 3 11 — [Ai -}- Bx! A2 + B2]
12 7 6 3
560 / Matrix Algebra
A + B= +
B2
' 3 4 -2 0“ "-3 0 2 4
_ -1 0 6 -1 -1 -2 5
5 +
_ 7 3 3 2_ _ 5 4 3 1
r o 4 0 4 1 Ai -f Bj
=
-2 -1 3 11 =
At Bi
L 12 7 6 3 _
Many other partitionings are possible and will give the same result.
B,
AB = [Ai A2] — A i B j -f- A2B2
B2
EXAMPLE
If
3 0 -1 7 r 2 i i
A = -2 4 1 and B = i 3
1 -1 2_ -l 1 _
then
AB =
r -2 3
0
4
-1 1
1
r 2
l
17
3
L i -1 2_ L-i 1J
3 0 1
2 1
2 4 + 1 [-1, 1]
1 3
1 -1 2
6 3 1 -1
0 10 + -1 1
1 -2 J -2 2.
7 2
-1 11
-1 0
Matrices may be partitioned into more than two submatrices. In fact, it is possible
to partition an m x n matrix into a maximum of mn submatrices; note that maximum
partitioning is equivalent to no partitioning, since each element is treated as a scalar
matrix. Unless there is a logical partitioning in terms of the variables in a problem,
matrices should be partitioned for ease of computation; this involves some reason¬
able compromise between minimizing the number of submatrices and minimizing
their maximum size.
Frequently matrices are partitioned once horizontally and once vertically. Thus
the m x n matrix A may be partitioned
Al 1 Ai2
A =
^21 A22.
where An is mi x nx, A12 is ml x n2, A21 is m2 x nlf A22 is m2 x n2, and
mi + m2 = m, nx + n2 = n. Then
^11
i Ai2.l lBu..i.. ®12
^21 i ^22 -1 Ib21 i ®22
EXAMPLE
If
1 3 l'
3 -2 1 0 -1
-1 0 i
A = and B = 5 -1 4 3 2
2 -1 4
3 -2 0 1 -1
0 2 -3 _
then
AB =
An ; An 1 [Bn b12
A2i | A22| IB2i i b22J
r i 3 i 1
0 1 1
-2 ; 1
i ■
-
-l 0 1 r3
5 -1 i 4 -3 2
2 -i i 4
-3 --2 | 0 1 - 1_
. 0 2 ; 3 J
and
1 3“ " r
[3 -2
»i i + a12 B2 i = -1 0 + i [3, -2]
5 -1
2 - 1 _ _ 4_
18 -5" 3 -2“
-3 2 + 3 -2
. 1 —3 J L 12 — 8J
21 -7
0 0
13 -11 J
562 / Matrix Algebra
1 3 " T
1 0-1
An ®i2 T Ai->
12 B->?
D2 2 — —
-1 0 + 1 [0, 1, -1]
4-3 2
2 -1 _ _4_
-1
13 -9
0
51 r° 1
1 + 01
-1
-1
-2 3 -4J |_0 4 -4
13 -8 4
-1 1 0
-2 7 -8
-2
A21 Bi 1 4- A22 B2i — [0, 2] + [ —3][3, -2]
-1
= [10, —2] 4- [ — 9, 6]
= [1, 4]
0
A2i Bi2 4- A22 B22 — [0, 2] + [ — 3] [0, 1, -1]
-3
= [8, -9, 7]
Thus
PROBLEMS
1. Compute the following.
6 r 4 2"
a. 2 0 -3 -3 0 1
_ -1 2. _—5 -1.
a UV + XY
b. 5UV 4 10[X(2V - Y)]
4. If
find 2(AB — BA) and use partitioned matrices to check the result.
5. If
6. If
show that A2 — 11A + 101 = O. Use partitioned matrices to check the result.
7. If
2 2 3
2 5
find a. AB — 2CD
b. A2
c. (BC)2
8. If
9. If
show that
a. U2 = U and V2 = V
b. UV = VU = O
c. U + V = I
Use partitioned matrices to check the results.
10. If
2 3"
X = 2 3
-2 -3.
11. If
show that AX = AY (although X ^ Y) and use partitioned matrices to check the result.
12. If
"-1
i
1 UJ to
_1
" 1 -2"
1
0 -2 3
0 3 B = C = D = 1
0 1 3
_2 -1_ [_— 3 J 2_
find AB - CD .
29 13
-6 -3
3. a. 2 x 3
b. 3 x 3
c. 2 x 2
d. 4 x 3
e. 3 x 3
f. 4 x 3
1 0
b.
1 0
0 0
16 16
^ _ a\ 1 al2
a2\ a22
is given by
EXAMPLE
3 -6 3 -6
If A then A| = 3 - (-24) = 27
4 1 4 1
-1 0 -1 0
If A then I A = -10 - 0 = -10
6 10 6 10
— a33a2la12
The terms can be obtained by the rule illustrated in Figure 7.1, where positive
product terms are formed of elements connected by solid lines and negative product
terms are formed of elements connected by dashed lines. Note that similar rules are
not valid for higher-order matrices.
Figure 7.1
566 / Matrix Algebra
I My |
is a minor of the matrix A. The scalar
Ctj = (— 1)I + J | My |
is referred to as the cofactor or signed minor of the element of the matrix A. The
n x n matrix
(<+)'
is referred to as the adjoint of A and is denoted by adj A.
As noted above, the determinant of a matrix can be obtained by a procedure
known as expansion by cofactors. The determinant of A can be expanded in terms of
row i by the formula
n
a 22 a 23 a 21 a 23 a2l a22
= ai i — a 12 a 13
a32 a33 a 31 a 33 a3l a32
can be written
3
EXAMPLE
"3 0 -2
A = 6 -8 1
0 3 4
A| = -96 - 36 + 0 -(0 + 9 + 0)
= -141
1 6
+ 0-2
4 0
= 3( —32 — 3) — 2(18 — 0)
= -105 - 36 = -141
7.7 The Determinant of a Matrix / 567
3-2 3-2
A = 0 — 8 -3 , *
11 0 4 6 1
= -96 - 45 = -141
Note that cofactors are essentially determinants and can be evaluated by further
expansion in terms of determinants of lower order. By repeated expansion, an nth-
order determinant can be written in terms of second- or third-order determinants
which can be evaluated easily. To simplify computation, a determinant should be
expanded in terms of the row or column having the largest number of zero elements.
PROPERTIES OF DETERMINANTS
The following properties of determinants are frequently useful in their evaluation:
EXAMPLES
" 1 3 —3“
If A = 2 0 1 9
-1 4 -2
(Property 1)
1 3 -3
= 201
-1 4 -2
= 0 - 24 - 3 - (0 + 4 - 12)
= -19
568 / Matrix Algebra
1 2-1
A'| = 3 0 4
-3 1 -2
= 0 - 3 - 24 - (0 + 4 - 12)
= -19
(Property 3)
3 3 -3
M*l = 6 0 1
-3 4 -2
= 0 - 9 - 72 - (0 + 12 - 36)
= -57
= 3|A|
(Property 4)
1 3 -3
B 1 4 -2 = 4 + 0 - 12 - (-24 + 0-3)
2 0 1
= 19
= - | A|
(Property 6)
1 3 -3
C| = 3 4 0 = 4 + 0 + 0 - (-24 + 0 + 9)
2 0 1
= 19
= \B\
(Note: Second row of C is equal to second row of B plus two times the third row of B.)
(Property 2)
1 3 -3
If A = 0 0 0 , then
-1 4 -2
1 3 ■3
AI = 0 0 0
-1 4 2
0 +0+ 0-(0 + 0 + 0)
0
(Property 5)
1 1 -3
If A = 2 2 1 then
-1 1 -2 J
7.8 The Inverse of a Matrix / 569
1 1 -3
A! = 2 2 1
1 -1 -2
= -4 + 6 -- 1 - (6-1-4)
= 0
(Property 7)
‘ 1 3 -3" "-1 0 2“
If A = 2 0 1 and B = 3 -2 -2 , then
_-l 4 -2_ 1 0 —! _
5 -6 -1
| AB = -1 0 3
11 -8 -8
= --38
1 3 -3
|A| = 2 0 1 = -19
-1 4 -2
-1 0 2
|B| = 3 -2 -2
1 0 -1
= —2 + 0 + 0 — (-4 + 0 + 0)
= 2
and | AB | = | A j | B |.
(Property 8)
3 0 0
If A = 0 -2 0 , then
0 0 1
3 0 0
AI = 0 -2 0
0 0 1
= -6+ 0 + 0-(0 + 0 + 0)
= -6
The inverse of a matrix is used in solving simultaneous linear equations and in other
applications. In this section the inverse of a matrix is defined and several methods of
inversion are discussed; these methods include inversion by Gaussian elimination,
inversion using adjoints and determinants, and inversion of partitioned matrices.
Properties of inverses are also considered.
If for an n x n (square) matrix A there is another n x n (square) matrix B such
that their product is the identity matrix of size n, that is, if
B,
x n "n x n = I„ = B
U/1 X n
A X n
570 / Matrix Algebra
can be written
If m = n and A has an inverse, that is, if A is square and nonsingular, then the set of
simultaneous linear equations represented by
xn x 1 C„xi
Xnx 1 Anx n x 1
A2 x 2 ^2 x 1 = ^2 x 1
ai i fli12
A =
a21 a22
and A 1 is denoted by
^11 ^12
B =
b2 i b 22
then, be definition, AB = I, that is,
al 1 fl121f ^11 b 12 1 0
^11 b 12 “ “1 ^ 12^22 = 0
a2ib\\ + a2 2 b21 = 0
d2 lb 12 “E a22b22 = 1
Solving these four equations for the four 6,/s,
a22
bU =
d\l d22 do21i w12
Cl
a 12
b 12 —
^11^22 a21a12
~fl21
bo i —
al 1 a22 ~ a21a12
al 1
^22 —
al 1 a22 ' a21a12
ai i a 12
det A = — $11 d22 do21i a
w12
a 21 a 22
If det A = 0, the 6,/s are not defined and A -1 cannot be obtained. It can be shown
that a square matrix of any size has an inverse if and only if its determinant is
nonzero.
EXAMPLE
-1 6
4 3
-1 6
— 3 - 24 — 27, so the inverse exists.
4 3
1
b 11
9
-6 _2
b 12
— 27 " 9
-4 _ 4
bn
^27 27
-1 _ 1
b22
^27”27
and thus
-1 6 -1 1 21
4 1
4 3 17 17
Note that
1 0
0 1
EXAMPLE
-3 15
1 —5
-3 15
= 15 — 15 = 0, so the inverse does not exist, that is, the matrix is singular.
PROBLEMS
For each of the following matrices, evaluate the determinant and find the inverse, if it exists.
Use partitioned matrices to check the results.
1 6 -1 3
1. 7.
0 1 2 7.
1 0 -1 -1
2. 8.
0 1 -1 -1
0 1 ■ o -2 -r
3.
1 0 9. 1 -3 4
-1 -1 -1
0 1
4. "3 1 3“
1 6
10. 3 3 1
'2 -3 _2 0 3_
5.
4 -6
2 2
6
-4 -4
7.8 The Inverse of a Matrix / 573
" 1 2 — r “2 3 4"
12. 0 -3 2 14. 4 3 1
_4 1 0 _ _1 2 4_
‘ 2 4 6"
13. -1 2 3
1 4 9_
a 11 ^12
A = a21 a22 a2n
m
anl “n2 @nn
_^n
a21 ai„ ••• h2„ ••• /-»
a22 ^21 ^22 = C21 C22 c2n
1 0
0 ' 1
where cik = Yj=i aijbjk and the n2 elements of the inverse matrix (bjk) can be ob¬
tained by solution of the n2 equations
n
L au bJk = 1 if i = k
i= i
Z aa bjk = 0 if i^k
1= i
where i = 1, 2, ..., n and k — 1, 2, ..., n.
For a matrix of size 3 x 3 or larger, this method of inversion is tedious. For¬
tunately, numerous alternative computational procedures for inverting a matrix are
574 / Matrix Algebra
available and inversion is also a standard program for most electronic computers.
Two methods of inversion are discussed in following sections; both of these are
feasible unless the matrix is quite large or its elements consist of several digits.
n. Divide the nth row by the element in its nth column; use the resulting row to
obtain zeros in the nth column of each of the other rows.
note: In the above procedure, if at the kth step the element in the kth column is
zero, interchange that row with a subsequent row having a nonzero element in the
kth column. Then proceed with the kth step.
[A 11]
and change it by the standard procedure given above to the tableau
[I|B]
Then, by the theorem above, R is A-1.
7.8 The Inverse of a Matrix / 575
Even if A has no inverse, this procedure can be started. At some point a tableau
will be obtained which is not of the appropriate form and which cannot be changed
in the manner outlined above. It can be shown that if the above procedure cannot be
completed to obtain [I I B] from [A 11], then A does not have an inverse.
EXAMPLE
‘ 0 -2 -3"
1 3 3
_-l -2 -2.
0 -2 -3 1 0 0
1 3 3 0 1 0
_-l -2 -2 0 0 1 _
" 1 3 3 0 1 0 ~
0 -2 -3 1 0 0 Step 1
0 1 1 0 1 1.
" 1 3 3 0 1 O'
0 1 3 1 0 0
I
0 1 1 0 1 1 _
fStep 2
3 3
' 1 0 ~I I 1 O'
0 1 3 1 0 0
1
o 0 1 1 1 1.
1
3 3
' 1 0 —? 1 1 0 ~
0 1 3 1 0 0
1 ~J
o 0 1 -1 -2 -2 _
VStep 3
■ 1 0 0 0 -2 -3 '
0 1 0 1 3 3
0 0 1 -1 -2 —2 _
Thus
—i
-1
o
_1
_1
o
OJ
O
K>
CM
1
1
1
1 3 3 1 3 3 = 0 1 0
_1
_i
_1
o
o
CM
CM
CM
<N
1
1
1
1
EXAMPLE
■ 1 2 3"
-1 0 4
0 2 2_
■ 1 2 3 1 0 0 '
-1 0 4 0 1 0
0 2 2 0 0 1 .
1 2 3 1 0 0 ~
0 2 7 1 1 0 Step 1
. o 2 2 0 0 1.
" 1 2 3 1 0 0 "
7 1 1 0
0 1 I I 1
0 2 2 0 0 1 _
^Step 2
" 1 0 -4 0 -1 0 "
7 1 1 0
0 1 I 1 I
0 0 -5 -1 -1 1 _
■ 1 0 -4 0 -1 0 “
7 1 1 0
0 1 I 1 T
1 1 1
0 0 y y -y J
J^Step 3
4 i 4•
" 1 0 0 y -y -1
i i 1
0 1 0 —y -y IT)
1
— i*
i i
0 0 1 y y
Thus
" 2 3 “ -1 r 4
-y
i
-y
4 “1
1 y
i i 7
-1 0 4 = -y —y TO
i i 1
0 2 2 . L y y -y J
Note that
1 4 1 "1
^*|v>
2 3 " 3 0 O'
1
-y
-i 0 4
1
"3 -y
i 7
TO
= 0 1 0
L o 2 2 J 1 i
LO 0 1J
1
3 y
1
and
r 4
y -y
i
--y
4
1 2 3 ' "i 0 0 "
i
-y -y
i 7
TO -1 0 4 = 0 1 0
L y
i
y
i
--y
1
L o 2 2 j LO 0 1J
EXAMPLE
■ i 2 -r
-3 4 5
i—
-4 2 6 —*
" 1 2 -1 1 0 0 '
-3 4 5 0 1 0
-4 2 6 0 0 1 .
" 1 2 -1 1 0 0'
0 10 2 3 1 0 Step 1
0 10 2 4 0 1 .
7.8 The Inverse of a Matrix / 577
1 2-1 1 0 01
0 1 i A A o
_ 0 10 2 4 0 1 J
\ Step 2
" 1 2-1 1 0 01
0 1 i 3
TO
i
TO
n
u
0 0 0 1-1 1 J
.
The procedure cannot be continued and thus the matrix has no inverse. Note that the
procedure can be discontinued at the end of Step 1; at the end of Step 1 the left-hand matrix
has two identical rows and thus the determinant of the matrix is zero (Property 5) and it has
no inverse. The determinant of the original matrix is also zero (Property 6) and it has no
inverse.
A- i adj A
EXAMPLE
0 2 -3
A = 1 3 3
-1 2 -2
| A | = 0-f6-l-6 — (9 + 0 + 4)= -1
1 3 1 +3 1 3
A | = 0 + (— 2)( — 1) 1 + 2 + (— 3)( — 1)
-1 -2 1 -2
= 0 + 2( —2 + 3) + ( —3)( —2 + 3) = -1
1 3 0 3 0 -3
A | = (— 2)( — 1)
1 +2
+ (3)( —1)
2 +2
+( 2)( 1) 3 + 2
-1 -2 -1 2 1 3
= 2( — 2 + 3) + 3(0 - 3) + 2(0 + 3) = -1
3 3
Cu = (-l)1 + 1 =-6+6=0
-2 -2
1 3
c12 i
= (- )1 + 2
-1 -2
= -(-2 + 3) = -1
1 3
C13 = (-l)1 + 3 =-2+3=1
-1 -2
-2 -3
c21 l
= (- )2+1
-2 -2
= -(4-6) = 2
578 / Matrix Algebra
0 -
c22 = (- l)2 + 2 -1 -
> = 0 - 3 = -3
0 -
c23 = (- l)2 + 3 -1 -
; = -(0-2) = 2
-2 -
c31 =(-l)3+1
3
* =-6+9=3
0 -3
c32 = (- l)3 + 2 1 3
= -(0 + 3) = -3
0 -2
c33 = (- l)3 + 3 1 3
=0+2=2
Thus
" 0 2
adj A = (Cy)' = -1 -3
1 2
0
A"1 1
-1
(as obtained in the example above by the standard procedure for row operations).
EXAMPLE
'12 3
A = -10 4
0 2 2
0 4 2 3
(~1)1 + 1 (-1)2 + 1 +0
2 2 2 2
= (0 - 8) + (4 - 6) = -10
1 2
I A | =(-l)(-l)2 + 1 2 3 + 0 + 4( — 1)2 + 3
0 2
= (4 — 6) + 0 + ( —4)(2 - 0) = -10
Cu (-1 r1 - 8 = -8
-1 4
Cl2 (-1)1+2 — (— 2 + 0) = 2
0 2
-1 0
C13 (-1)1+3 -2 + 0 = -2
0 2
7.8 The Inverse of a Matrix / 579
2+ 1
2 3
C21 — (~ 1) -(4-6) = 2
2 2
2+2
1 3
C22 — (— 1) 2 + 0 = 2
0 2
2+3 1 2
c23 = (- )i 0 2
-(2 + 0)= -2
3+ 1 2 3
C31 — ( 1) 8 + 0 = 8
0 4
3+2 1 3
^32 — ( 1 ) = — (4 + 3) = -7
-1 4
3+3 1 2
C33 = (“I) =0+2=2
-1 0
Thus
-8 2 8
adj A = (Cuy = 2 2 7
-2 2 2
4 1 4
7 y -y
1 1 1 7
A 1 = adj A = T y TO
A 1 1 1
y y -y
(as obtained in the example above by the standard procedure for row operations).
EXAMPLE
2 - 1 "
4 5
2 6_
40 - (16 + 10 - 36) = 0
Thus A is singular.
since
= 0
— A21 A111A12 B 1 + A22 B 1 = [ —A21 A111A12 + A22]B
= BB_1
= I
EXAMPLE
" 0 -2 -3"
1 3 3
-1 -2 -2 _
and
J3 1 /[ 0 ’ -3 3
1
An1 [I + A12 B !A2i Aj/] - 1 [ — 2] E
~2 0. (to 1 3 —T 0
3 0 -6 —12
I 11 ([1
+
i i
1 1 6
“I 0] llo 12. — 7 0
3 0 -3
J 11 1 ~61\
1 +
oj llo 1 3
3 n ' -2 -6
I
1 3 7
—2 0]
0 ■2
1 3
where
4 11 ' —3
»■
-1
B = A22 [ — 2] — [ — 1, -2]
O
3
1
-3
= [-2]-[-i -1]
3
= -2 - (-1)
1
I
and
B -1 = [-2]
3
■1 -3
-Ar/A^B"1 = 1 [-2]
1 3
3
i
1
1 ill.
-3
3
3
1 1
-B-^, An1 [2][ — 1, -2] 1
I 0 = [-1, -2]
3
1 1
= [ —2, -4] 1
1 0
= [-l, -2]
Thus
" 0 -2 -3 “ -1 " 0 -2 -3“
1 3 3 = 1 3 3
_-l -2 -2 _ _-l -2 —2 _
as above.
EXAMPLE
"12 3"
-10 4
0 2 2_
582 / Matrix Algebra
r * 1 22 334- : Ai i ; A12
-1 : 0 4 A21 ;
L 0 : 2 2J A22.
and
1 7
-1
t TO
An1 [I + A12 B xA2i An1] — [1]^[1] + [2, 3] 1
3 S
1 0 [1]
-1
= [!]([!] +[it] 0
-i(i-i)
_ 4
=T
where
0 4 -1
B = A22 — A21 A! I1 A1 2 = [1][2, 3]
2 2 0
0 4 -2 3
2 2 0 0
2 7
2 2
and
7
TO
B1 = i 1
5 “5
7
i- i TO
-Ar/AnB*1 = [-l][2, 3] i 1
= [-i -f]
i
-i = J
~B_ 1A21 A^1 i
■J
Thus
1 2 3 " -1 —T
1
-J^ 1
-1 0 4 = 1 1 7
-J —J TO
. 0 2 2 _ 1
L ?
1 1
J —1 J
as above.
PROPERTIES OF INVERSES
The following properties of inverses are frequently useful in their evaluation.
1. The inverse of the inverse of a matrix is the original matrix; that is, [A - *] "1 = A.
2. The determinant of the inverse of a matrix is equal to the reciprocal of the
determinant of the matrix; that is, | A ~11 = 1/1A |.
3. The inverse of the transpose of a matrix is equal to the transpose of the inverse of
the matrix; that is, [A']-1 = [A-1]'.
4. The inverse of the product of two matrices is equal to the product of their inverses
in reverse order; that is, [AB]1 = B_1A“‘.
7.8 The Inverse of a Matrix / 583
EXAMPLES
" 1 1 4 -i
—i
2 3 " “7 5
If A = -1 0 4 , then A 1 = i 1 7
“7 ~7 115
0 2 2_ 1 1 1
L 7 7 ~7 J
(Property 1)
4 1 4 -1
7 7 “7
[A"1]"1 = 1 1 7
7 iry
1 1 i
7 5
12 3
-10 4
0 2 2
= A
Thus [A~*]~1 = A.
(Property 2)
1 2 3
AI = -1 0 4
0 2 2
-10
4 1 4
I '7 ~5
-1 1 1 7
'7 '7 ITT
1 1 1
7 7 ~7
= (tt?)(~¥)
1
IT)
Thus I A -1
(Property 3)
1 -i 0 T~1
(a r1- 2 0 2
3 4 2
4 1 1
? “7 7
1 l 1
5 -7 7
4 7 1
J 115 t
4 1 4
7 ‘7 “7
1 1 7
[A-J]' = ■7 •7 115
l 1 1
7 7 “7
4 1 1
7 “7 7
1 1 1
■7 ~7 7
4 7 1
7 TO ‘7
(Property 4)
"-1 3 r ' -2 3 r
If B = 0 2 0 ,then B i _ 0 i o
_ —2 0 4_ _-l 3 1
T IJ
1 2 3" — 1 3 r
AB = -1 0 4 0 2 0
_ 0 2 2_ 2 0 4_
"-7 7 13"
= -7 -3 15
_—4 4 8.
- i
7 7 13
[AB]-1 = 7 3 15
_ —4 4 8 -
i 18 “I
-to "T
i 7
= “TO TO TO
7
_ -1 0
1 n 4 1 4 ^
"-2 3 2 5 —1 ~5
1 7
B -1 A =
A 'I - 0
i
t 0 — 11 —7 TO
3 1 1 1 1
-1 T I J - I 3 “3 J
1 18 -1
’-ft ~T0
i 1 7
= “TO “TO TO
7
-1 0 4-i
!- 1 A -1
Thus [AB]"1 = BXA
PROBLEMS
1. If
" 3 2 -2~ "1 0“
111
A = 0 1 4 B= 0 1 c= 1 1 1
_-l 0 5_ _0 1_
A = B = -1 -2 C =
1
2 2
2 1_ 1 1 .
find a. [A - BC]'
b. [A'B]’1
3. If
"1 2 “
'2 1 1 0 0 1 0
1 2.
B=
1
c= 3 4 D =
0 .
1 1 1
_ 1 2.
find a. A + B - 2DC
b. A^B1
c. C[A + B]B“1
d. CA“1B”1D
7.9 Simultaneous Linear Equations / 585
4. If
'0 1 -1 “ " 4 -3 3"
A= 3 -2 3 B= 2 -1 2
_2 -2 3. _ —3 3 -2.
^1«1 + A2 a2 + •• • + Xm am = Xxi ai = 0
i= 1
then the set of vectors at, a2,..., am is said to be linearly dependent. If there is no set
of A’s (except all zeros) such that 1 A,-a= 0, the set of vectors is said to be linearly
independent.
A matrix can be thought of as a set of row vectors or a set of column vectors. It can
be shown that, for any matrix, the number of linearly independent rows is equal to
the number of linearly independent columns; this number is the rank of the matrix.
Thus if a matrix is m x n and its rank is denoted by r, then r < min(m, n).
EXAMPLE
" 1 4"
5 10
_3 2_
586 / Matrix Algebra
Since 2(first row) -I- (third row) — (second row) = 0, the three rows are linearly dependent.
However, each pair of two rows is linearly independent; the two columns are also linearly
independent. The rank of the matrix is 2.
EXAMPLE
"3 6"
1 2
_2 4_
Note that the two columns are also linearly dependent, since
The following very useful result provides a systematic method of testing for linear
dependence: Consider all the square submatrices of A whose determinants are non¬
zero. The rank of A is the order of the determinant of largest order. Thus one method
of computing the rank of a matrix is to look for the largest nonzero determinant; the
order of this determinant is the rank of the matrix.
The following properties of rank are useful in determining the rank of a matrix:
1. Since the determinant of a diagonal matrix is equal to the product of its diagonal
elements, if A is a diagonal matrix, then r(A) is the number of nonzero diagonal
elements in A. In particular, r(I„) = n.
2. Since any submatrix of A' is the transpose of a submatrix of A and since B =
| B' |, r(A') = r(A).
3. The rank of the product of two matrices cannot exceed the smaller rank of the two
matrices; that is, r(AB) < min{r (A), r(B)}.
4. If A is an n x n (square) matrix, then r(A) = n if and only if A is nonsingular;
r(A) < n if and only if A is singular. Thus if a square matrix is singular, its rows
(and also its columns) are linearly dependent; if a square matrix is nonsingular, its
rows (and also its columns) are linearly independent.
y = Ax
More generally, if y = Ax, then the whole set of equations is consistent and has at
least one solution if r(A) = r(A:y). The solution is unique if and only if r(A) =
r(A:y) = n, that is, if and only if A is nonsingular.
In the special (homogeneous) case y = 0, if A is nonsingular, the unique solution is
x = 0 and there cannot be a nonzero solution. Thus, when the set of equations
Ax = 0 does have a nonzero solution, A must be singular.
Suppose that y = Ax and A is m x n (not square), that is, there are m equations in
n variables where m may be less than, equal to, or greater than n; then
r(A) < min(m, n).
The following summary concerning solution of simultaneous linear equations
applies to the general case of m equations in n variables and also to the special case of
n equations in n variables.
If r(A i y) = r(A), the equations in the set are logically consistent and there is at
least one solution
If r(Ai y) = r(A) < n, there are infinitely many solutions and the rows (and
columns) of A are linearly dependent
If r(Aj y) ^ r(A), the equations in the set are not logically consistent and
there is no solution
EXAMPLE
x + 2y — z = 10
2x + 4y — 2z — 5
x + y + z — 6
1 2 -1
2 4 -2 = 4- 2- 4-(-4- 2 +4) = 0
1 1 1
so the rank of the matrix is not 3; the rank is 2 since, for example,
2 4
=2-4=-2^0
1 1
"1 2 -1 10 "
2 4-2 5
1116
2-1 10
4-2 5 -24 4- 40 - 5 - (-20 + 10 - 24) = 45 =£ 0
1 1 6
1 hus r(A) ± r(A; y) and the set of equations has no solution since they are not all consistent.
Note that the first and second equations are clearly inconsistent.
588 / Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
x + 2y — z = 10
2x 4- 4y — 2z = 20
x + y + z = 6
The coefficient matrix is the same as that for the preceding example and its rank is 2. The
augmented coefficient matrix (A j y)
"1 2 -1 10”
2 4 -2 20
_1 1 1 6_
is also rank 2, since
1 2 10 1 -1 10 2 -1 10
2 4 20 —
2 -2 20 = 4 -2 20
1 1 6 1 1 6 1 1 6
Thus r(A) = r(A; y) = 2 ^ n = 3, and the set of equations has infinitely many solutions; the
rows (and columns) of the coefficient matrix are linearly dependent. Note that the first and
second equations are linearly dependent.
EXAMPLE
x + 2y — z = 10
2x — 4y — 2z — 5
x + y 4- z = 6
1 2-1
2 -4 -2 = -4-2-4 -(4-2 + 4)= -16
1 1 1
and the rank of the matrix is 3; the rank of the augmented coefficient matrix is also 3. Thus
r(A) = r(A:y) = 3 = n and the set of equations has a unique solution.
PROBLEMS
Determine the rank of each of the following matrices.
T 2 " 1 -1 0
1.
0 1 4. -1 1 0
2 -2 0
1 2 3"
o -1 0 1 T 3
J.
0 4 8_ 2 6.
3 -1 0 2'
7. 9. -2 1 5 -2
0 -4 6 -3
-3 5 -6 1
8. 2 -1 3 0
10. -3 3 4 2
4 -5 -11 -4
-1 2 7 2
There are various methods for obtaining the solution of a set of simultaneous linear
equations which have a unique solution. Several of these methods are discussed in
this section. If one of the methods is applied to a set of linear equations not having a
unique solution, the method cannot be completed, thus indicating that there is no
unique solution.
As noted above, a set of n simultaneous linear equations in n unknowns can be
written in matrix notation as
xAnxl = Cnx l
(A 111 c)
(I | A"1 | x)
An xn i ==CnXl
590 / Matrix Algebra
Cl a 12
••• al n
C2 a22 a2n
cn an2
••• ann
x, =
A|
an CT
... ain
c'2
... a2n
a21
Cn
••• ann
x? =
|A
l
a 12
... Cl
al 1
a21 a 22 C2
anl a n2 ••• Cn
=
Aj
ch Xf, i = i. 2 ^ • • ., n, the
matrix and the numerator is the determinant of the coefficient matrix with the ith
column replaced by the column of constant terms from the right-hand side of the
equations. If there is no unique solution for a set of linear equations, | A 0 and
these quotients are not defined.
EXAMPLE
3xx + x2 — x3 = 2
xv — 2.x 2 + x3 = —9
(A 111 c)
(I I A -11 x)
or obtained as
x = A- xc
"3 1 -1 1 0 0 2 '
1 -2 1 0 1 0 — 9
_4 3 2 0 0 1 1 _
"1 -2 1 0 1 0 _9 "
3 1 -1 1 0 0 2
4 3 2 0 0 1 1 .
"1 -2 1 0 1 0 _9 "
0 7 -4 1 -3 0 29
_0 11 -2 0 -■4 1 37 _
i i
"1 0 ~7 4 7 0 "
4 1 3 29
0 1 “7 7 —7 0 ~T
30 11 60
_o 0 ~T -T 4 1 T J
7
"1 0 0 TO i A -1
1 i
0 1 0 ~T5 “T T5 3
11 1
_0 0 1 — TO 0 TO -2
'Xj " ■ -r
x2 3
_*3_ _ -2
r 7
TO
1
0 TO ■ 2~ ' -r
1 1
*2
—
~TT T A -9 —
3
11 1
-*3- L —TO 0 TO . 1_ _ -2.
In practice, the solution would be obtained from x = A-1c only if A-1 had been obtained
without obtaining the tableau (I | A“11 x).
Using Cramer’s rule,
3 1 -1
1 -2 1 = —12 — 3 + 4 — (8 + 9 + 2)= -30
4 3 2
2 1 -1
-9 -2 1
1 3 2 — 8 + 27+1— (2 + 6 — 18) 30
= 1
-30 - 30 ~ - 30 ~
3 2 -1
1 -9 1
4 1 2 -54 - 1 + 8 - (36 + 3 + 4) -90
*2 =
-30 -30 _ — 30 _
3 1 2
1 -2 -9
4 3 1 -6 + 6 - 36 - (-16 - 81 + 1) 60
*3 =
-30 -30 ~ -30
592 / Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
2xx 4- 5x2 + x3 = 0
(A|I|c)
to obtain the tableau
(I | A-11 x)
1 1 1 1 0 0 6
3 -4 2 0 1 0 -2
_ 2 5 1 0 0 1 o .
" 1 1 -1 1 0 0 6 “
0 -7 5 -3 1 0 -20
0 3 3 -2 0 1 —12 _
2 4 1 22
1 0 “7 7 7 0 ~T
0 5 3 l 20
1 “7 7 '7 0 ^T
36 23 3 144
0 0 ~T 7 1 T~
7 1 1
1 0 0 TS 6 TS 2
1 1 5
0 1 0 76 12 77 0
23 1 7
0 0 1 77 17 77 -4
*2 = 0
_*3 . L —4
_1
On
—i
__i
23 1 7
o
■77
1
_*3_
1 6
3 2
2 0 -2 + 0 + 24 - (4 + 0 + 18)
*2 =0
-36 ’ -36
1 1 6
3 4 -2
2 5 0 0 + 90 - 4 - (-48 - 10 + 0) 144
*3 = = -4
-36 -36 ^36
7.10 Vector Differentiation / 593
PROBLEMS
For each of the following sets of simultaneous linear equations, determine whether there is a
unique solution and obtain the solution if there is one.
xl
X2
a'x = [al9 a2 , an\
x„
the partial derivatives of a'x with respect to the scalar xi9 i = 1,2, .., n, are
d(a'x)
dxx
a,
d(*'x)
= <3-
dx->
d(a'x)
that is, the partial derivatives are the elements of the vector a. Thus if the n partial
derivatives are arranged as a vector a, the process of vector differentiation is defined
by
d(a'x)
——- = a
^x
a(a'x).
where indicates the operation of differentiating a'x with respect to the elements
dx
of the vector x
EXAMPLE
and
(a'x) = 2 a
dx{
_a_
(a'x) = —a
dx2
(a'x) = 3 a
dx3
_d_
(a'x) = a
dx4
Thus
2a
—a
(a'x) = = a
dx 3a
a
7.10 Vector Differentiation / 595
yi fi (* i» *2 » • • •» ) i 1, 2, ..., n
then each yt can be differentiated partially with respect to each Xj and these partial
can be arranged in an
sy2 8yn
i-H
dxm
Tn Sxm 8x„
EXAMPLE
If
x\ + 2x2 — 3xi x3
3xixj - x\ + 4x2x]
then
01n 02 n 0/i«
+ a„nx2n
596 / Matrix Algebra
^ (x'Ax)
~ 2(Ui2Xi T U22X2 T U23X3 4" T ^2ti-^n)
rs
— (x'Ax) = 2Ax
dxx '
or
~ (x'Ax) = 2x'A
dxx '
In practice, the choice between these two forms usually depends on the context in
which differentiation occurs, since matrices can be equated only if they are the same
order and, specifically, a row vector cannot be set equal to a column vector.
EXAMPLE
"Xi“ ‘ 3 1 -2
If x = x2 and A = 1 0 3 then
_* *3_ -2 3 2
‘ 3 1 -2" "xi"
* = [xl5 x2 , x3] 1 0 3 *2
-2 3 2 _ -*3_
Xi
= [3*! 4- x2 — 2x3 , xl 4- 3x3 , — 2xt + 3x2 4- 2x3] x2
*3
and
Thus
3xi + x2 — 2x3
_d_
(x'Ax) = 2 x, + 3x3 2Ax
dx
— 2xj + 3x2 + 2x3
or
~ (x'Bz) = B'z
dzK '
EXAMPLE
If
"xr ~ 2b, b i + b2
X — x2 B= b2 + 2b3 3b2 ' z=
-•^3 -
_ b, + b3 4b32 _
then
b, T b2
^z,1
x Bz — [*1> x2, x3] b2 + 2 b3 3b2 ‘ =
Z2_
_ b, + b3 4 b\ _
Zl
— [2b,x, -I- b2x2 + 2b3x2 + />1x3 + b3x3, blxl + b2x, + 3 b2x2 + 4fr3x3]
z2
= 2 b,x,z, + b2 x2 z i + 2 b3x2z, + b,x3z, + b3x3z, + b,x,z2
+ b2 x i z2 + 3 b2x2z2 + 4 b\x3z2
arid
Thus
2 b,z, + b,z2 + b2z2
b2z, + 2b3z, + 3b2z2 = Bz
b,z, + b3z, + 4fr3z2
598 / Matrix Algebra
and
Thus
~xf
2/?! /? 2 + 2/73 /?! + Z?3
x2
bx 4 h2 3b2 4/?|
-*3_
= B'x
where
. _
i X2n Xkn
'Pi' ux
Pi u = U2
Jk_
The intercept p0 is represented by the column of ones in the x matrix. As a result of
the convention of denoting the ith observation on the kth variable by xki, the sub¬
scripts in the x matrix are the reverse of the usual pattern, which indicates the row by
the first subscript and the column by the second subscript.
The problem is to obtain estimates of the p's. These estimates are customarily
obtained using the least squares principle. Let
7.10 Vector Differentiation / 599
i= 1
= (y - xP) (y - xp)
= y'y - 2p'x'y + p'x'xp
Note that (y — xp)' = y' — P'x' and p x'y is a scalar and thus equal to its transpose
yxp. To obtain the estimate p which minimizes the sum of squared residuals, differ¬
entiate e'e with respect to p,
— 2x'y + 2x'xp
If | ^ = °-
x'xp = x'y
and
p = (x'x) Vy
Alternatively,
If jp {e'e) = °’
p x X = y'x
p'^y'xtx'x]1
and
p = [x x] ' x'y
note: To show that p = [x'x]~ *x'y is a minimizing solution, the second deriva¬
tive must be examined
^ 2x'y + 2xxl*J
= 2x'x
Thus the second order condition for minimization requires that x'x is positive
definite, that is, that y'[x'x]y' > 0 for all y > 0. In practical examples, x'x is positive
definite.
600 / Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
1 -1
1 1 1 1 1 0
x'x 1 1
-1 0 1 -2
1 -2
4 -2
-2 6
x'x = 24 - 4 = 20
3 1
ITT TO
[x'x]1 = 1
TO
and
3 1 1 1 1
TO TO
p = [x'xJ-Vy = 1 1
TO 5 0 1 -2
19
TO
16
"TJ
PROBLEMS
" 3 ‘ ' Xi "
1. If b = -2 and x = X2 find — [b'x].
_ 1 - - *3_
—C yi
2. If c
0
and y =
y2 find
2c y3
— 3c _
■
c2 4- 1 Xi
2x\ — 3x2x3
4. If y = Xi — 4*! X2 X3 find
dx'
xj — 2x2 + x3 _
x\ + 3x2
2xj x2 — x2
5. If y find
2xj + XjX2 — 3x2 dx ’
3xj — x\x2 — x2
7.10 Vector Differentiation / 601
3 + bi b! + 2b2 4b2
6. If x = B =
*2 b2 4b i bxb2
yr
and y= yi find — [x'By] and — [x'By].
ox dy
ya
~*r " 3 0 -1"
7. If x = x2 A = 2 1 4
_*3_ _-l 0 3_
yr
and y = y2 find — [x'Ay] and — [x'Ay].
ox dy
y3
"1 -r ’-3“
8. If x = 1 i and y= 5
.1 2. . 11.
find the least squares estimate p for the regression y = xp + u.
c2 + 1
3c
4c - 5
3yi - y3
7. 2yi + y2 + 4y3
- -yi + 3y3 _
Applications
of Matrix
Algebra
8.1 Introduction
There are many applications of matrix algebra in various areas. The applications
discussed in this chapter are maxima and minima of functions of n variables, input-
output analysis, linear programming, game theory, and Markov processes.
d£ df_ df
= 0 = 0, = 0
dxx dx. dx„
37
A, =
dx\
37 37
dxj dxl dx2
A, =
82f 37
dx2 dx1 dxl
37 37 37
dxl dx± dx2 dx1 dx
A, =
37 37 37
dx2 dxx dx\ dx2 dx
37 37 37
dx3 dxx dx3 dx2 dxl
A„ =
The stationary point x* = (xf, xf, ..., x*) is a
If neither of these conditions holds, the function must be examined in the region of
the stationary point. Note that the conditions given previously for maxima and
minima of a function of two variables are a special case of those given above for n
variables.
EXAMPLE
~~ = 2xi + x2 - 7
CX 1
~ = 4x2 + xt
0X2
If 7 = 0, then
CX3
2x1 + x2 = 7
Xi + 4x2 = 0
2x3 = 2
604 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Thus
x2 — — 1
X! = 4
x3 = 1
d2f a2/
= 2 = 1 = 0
dx2 dxi dx2 dx3
W = 4 d2f
= 0
dxj dx2 dx3
dV = 2
dxj
Aj = 2
2 1
A2 — 1 =8-1=7
4
2 1 0
A3 — 1 4 0 = 16+ 0 + 0-(0 + 0 + 2) = 14
0 0 2
Ai > 0, A2 > 0, A3 > 0, so the point (4, — 1, 1) is a local minimum of the function f(xu x2,
x3) = x2 + 2xj + x3 + xi x2 — 2x3 — 7xi + 12.
EXAMPLE
df
= ( —2x + z)e~x2~y2~z2 + 2y+xz
dx
df
= (-2y + 2)e~x2~y2~z2 + 2y+xz
dy
df
-f- = (-2 z + X)e-x2-y2~z2 + 2y+xz
oz
If ~ = 0, ^ = 0, f = 0, then
dx dy dz
— 2x + z = 0
2y = 2
x — 2z = 0
Thus
x = z =0
y = i
d2f
= [( —2x + z)2 — 2]e — x2 — y2 — z2 + 2y + xz = -2c
dx2 dx2 (0, 1.0)
d2f d2f
= ( — 2x + z)( — 2y + 2)c -x2— y2 — z2 + 2y + xz = 0
dx dy dx dy (0. 1, 0)
8.2 Maxima and Minima of Functions of n Variables / 605
d2f
= [(lx + z)( — 2z + x) + 1 ]e-*2-y2-*2+2y+xz = c
dx dz dx dz (0, 1, 0)
d2f - x2 - y2 — z2 + 2y + xz d2f
= ( — 2y + 2)( — 2z + x)e = 0
dy dz dy dz (0, 1. 0)
d2f
= [( —2z + x)2 - 2]e-x2~y2-z2+2y+- = -2e
dz2 dz2 (0, 1.0)
Aj = -2c
-2e 0
A2 = = 4c
0 — 2e
-2c 0 c
a3 = 0 — 2c 0 = -Se3 + 2e3 = -6c3
e 0 — 2c
Ai < 0, A2 >0, A 3 < 0, SO the point (0, 1, 0)
f(x, y, z) = e~x2~yl — z2 + 2y + xz
EXAMPLE
Total profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost. In a perfectly competitive market, total
revenue is equal to the product of the number of units sold and the fixed unit price; thus
P = pq-C
where P is profit, p is price per unit, q is quantity sold, and C is total cost. If the production
function is
q =/(xl5 x2)
where and x2 are the variable inputs, and the cost function is
C = p^Xi + p2x2 + b
where px and p2 are the unit prices of xx and x2, respectively, and b is the cost of the fixed
inputs, then
Profit is thus a function of x1 and x2 and is maximized with respect to these variables as
follows.
dP
^ = pfl-p' = 0
g = P/2-P2 = °
or
Pfi = Pi
Pf2 = Pi
Since fi and f2 are the marginal products of the two inputs, pf{ and pf2 are the values of these
marginal products, that is, the rates at which revenue would increase with increase of the
respective inputs. Thus the first-order conditions for profit maximization require that each
input be increased until the value of its marginal product equals its price. Note that the
606 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
maximum profit-input combination lies on the expansion path since the conditions pfi = P\
and pf2 = p2 are a special case of the condition jf2 = p 1 /pi.
Second-order conditions require that the principal minors of the Hessian determinant
d* 1 2 3p d2P
dxj dx i dx
d2P d2P
dx2 dx{ dx2
2 <°
dxj
d2P d2P
dxj dxi dx
>0
d2P d2P
dx2 dxi dx 2
d2P d2P
Since —■ < 0 (first condition) and >0,
dxj [dx1dx:
d2P
<0
dx7
d2P
= Pf n < 0
dxj
d2P
= Pfl2 < 0
dx2
and, since p > 0, the second-order conditions for maximization require that
/u <0
f22 < 0
Thus the second-order conditions for maximization require that both marginal products be
decreasing. This is reasonable, since the price of a variable is constant under free competition
and thus, if the marginal product of a variable were increasing, profit could be increased by
increasing the quantity of the variable.
PROBLEMS
1. Determine the values of xl, x2, and x3 (if any) that maximize or minimize the function
2. Determine the values of x, y, and z (if any) that maximize or minimize the function
f(x, y, z) = £4*2 + 2>>2 + z2-5xy-AZ'
3. Determine the values of x, y, and z (if any) that maximize or minimize the function
/(x, y, z) = g-*2-2>*-z2-2*y
8.2 Maxima and Minima of Functions of n Variables / 607
4. Determine the values of x1? x2, and x3 (if any) that maximize or minimize the function
LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS
Consider a function of n variables f(xu x2,..., xj subject to the constraint g(xu x2,
x„) = 0at a point x* = (xf, x*, ..., x*) which satisfies the n + 1 equations
Sf x dg
= 0
dxx dxx
--- X — = 0
dx2 dx2
df dg
- 2. C = 0
oxn oxn
dX
Note that for x* = (x?, X?, ..., x*), X = (fXi/gXi), i = 1, 2, ..., n. Define the
determinant
0 9xi 9x2 • •
9x„
9xi fx 1*1 X9X \ X1 fx 1X2 X9x 1X2 fxiXn ~ XgxlXn
^n+ 1 — 9x2 fx 2X1 X9x 2x1 fx 2X2 — Xgx 2X2 fx 2Xn — XgX2xn
If neither of these conditions holds, the function must be examined in the region of
the stationary point. Note that the conditions given previously for constrained
maxima and minima of a function of two variables are a special case of those given
above for n variables.
EXAMPLE
dF
= x2 + x3 — Ax2x3
dxx
dF
— Xi + X3 — AxjX3
dx2
5F
— Xi + x2 — Xxxx2
dx3
dF_
= — (x!x2x3 — 125)
Jx
dF dF dF
If r = 0, *— = 0, — = 0, — = 0, then
UX\ OX2 DX3 dA
Xi = x2 = x3 = ^/l25 = 5 X = \
fX1 X2 = 1
fx 1,3 = 1 fx 2x3 = 1
= xx = 5
X
x2 5
II
II
u>
0 25 25
A, = 25 0 -1 = 0 - 625 - 625 - (0 + 0 + 0) = - 1250
25 -1 0
0 25 25 25
25 0 -1 -1
Aa = 25 -1 0 -1
25 -1 -1 0
25 -1 -1 25 0 -1 25 0 -1
0-25 25 0 -1 + 25 25 -1 -1 -25 25 -1 0
25 -1 0 25 -1 0 25 -1 -1
A3 < 0, A4 < 0, so the point (5, 5, 5) is a local minimum of the function f(xu x2, x3) = Xi x2 +
X! x3 + x2 x3 subject to xx x2 x3 = 125.
EXAMPLE
dF
— 2x + y — X
dx
dF
— 4y + x — X
dy
dF_
— 2z+ 1 — A
dz
M = -(x + y + z-35)
^ 17
If^-0 ^ = 0,
0 d-L = 0, — = 0, then
dx <7y <5z 0/1
— 2x + y = k
— 4y + x = X
— 2z + 1 = X
3x = 5 y
x = iy
1 + iy
l + iy
■fy + y + 2
35
+ 2y + 1 + iy = 70
¥>’ = 69
y = 9
x = 15
z = 11
A = -21
-2 = -2
II
1
fxx = fzz
gx = i Qy = 1 = 1
O
o 0
II
gxx = Gyy =
N
N
0 1 1 1
A* 1 -2 1 1
1 1 -4 0
1 1 0 -2
1 1 1 1 -2 1 1 -2 1
0 - 1 -4 0 + 1 1 0 — 1 1 -4
1 0 -2 1 1 -2 1 1 0
-[0+ 1 + 8 - (1 - 4 + 0)]
= 0-14-6-11= -31
A3 > 0, A4 < 0, so the point (15, 9, 11) is a local maximum of the function f(x, y, z) = — x2
— 2y2 — z2 + xy + z subject to x + y + z = 35.
EXAMPLE
If utility analysis is generalized to the case of n commodities, the utility function is given by
where qu q2,..., qn are the quantities of the n commodities, and the budget constraint is given
by
y - ILPiVi= 0
i=i
where pu p2, p„ are the unit prices of the n commodities. Then the function to be
maximized is
\
n
a- = fi + tyi = 0 i = 1, 2, ..., n
cqi
n
dF
y- LPiQi = 0
~dX i= 1
The demand curves for the n commodities can be obtained by solving for the q s. The
conditions
dF
=f + = o i = 1, 2, ..., n
dq,
can be written as
8.2 Maxima and Minima of Functions of n Variables / 611
That is, the rate of substitution of commodity i for commodity j must equal the price ratio
Pj/Pi. The second-order conditions for maximization require that the principal minors of the
bordered Hessian determinant must alternate in sign; that is,
KUHN-TUCKER CONDITIONS
Consider a function of n variables/(x1? x2, ..., xn) subject to the constraint g(xu x2,
..., x„) < 0. A point x* = (x*, x2, ..., x*) is a local maximum of/(xl5 x2, ..., x„)
subject to g(x1, x2, ..., x„) only if there exists a nonnegative X such that X and (x*, x2,
.x*) satisfy the Kuhn-Tucker conditions:
, _ df , dg
X~ = 0 i = 1, 2, ..., n
h‘ dXi dxt
These conditions are also sufficient if/(x1} x2,..., x„) is concave and the constraint is
concave. Since a maximum point of/(xl9 x2, ..., x„) is a minimum point of —f{xl,
x2,..., x„), this result is also applicable when a convex function is minimized subject
to a convex constraint.
note: A function f(xl9 x2, ..., x„) is convex in a region if for any two points (xl5
x2, ..., x„) and (xl9 x2, ..., x„),
EXAMPLE
Assuming the inequality constraint to hold as an equality constraint, X = f (see page 608).
Since X > 0, the minimum (5, 5, 5) assuming the equality constraint is also the minimum
assuming the inequality constraint.
Alternatively, using the Kuhn-Tucker conditions,
df_
— x2 + x3 — Xx2 x3 = 0
dxi dxi
df ;t dQ = Xi + X3 — Xx! x3 = 0
dx2 dx2
x dg
= x{ + x2 — Xx! x2 = 0
dx2 dx2
A(x! x2x3 — 125) = 0
Xix2x3 > 125
Either X — 0 or X! x2 x3 — 125 = 0. If X = 0,
x2 + x3 = 0
Xi + x3 = 0
xi -I- x2 — 0
and Xi = x2 = x3 = 0; but then xx x2 x3 > 125 is not satisfied. If xx x2 x3 — 125 = 0,
x2 + x3 _Xi + x3 _Xj + x2
X2X3 X'i X3 Xj X2
and xx = x2 = x3 = 5; this solution satisfies the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. Thus, as above, the
minimum of /(xl5 x2, x3) = XjX2 + xtx3 + x2x3 subject to XjX3x3>25 is
Xi = x2 = x3 = 5.
EXAMPLE
8f d2f = d2f
2 = 1
Xx=~2x + y dx2 dx dy
CO
d2f
'Tt
f=-4y + X = 0
II
1
dy dx dz
5f , _L1 d2f
— — — 2z -f 1 = 2 = 0
cz 5z2 dy dz
lf^ = 0 £ = 0 d± = 0, then
8x ' dy ’ dz
2x — y = 0
x — 4y = 0
and thus
x = y = 0
2 =j
A! = -2
8.2 Maxima and Minima of Functions of n Variables / 613
2 1
A2 — =8-1=7
1 -4
-2 1 0
A3 = 1 -4 0 = -16 - (-2) = -14
0 0 ■2
8f_ _ xdl _
2x 4 y — A = 0
dx dx
df-Xd^=-Ay + X-X=0
cy oy
dj_ _ , dg -2z 4 1 - A = 0
dz dz
Either 2 = 0 or x + y + z — 35 = 0. If X = 0,
x = v = 0 z =j
— 2x 4- y — A = 0
x — 4_y — 2 = 0
2z 4 X = 1
3x — 5y = 0
x — 4y 4 2z = 1
x 4 6y = 69
3x — 5y = 0
23y = 207
y = 9
x = 15
z = 11
PROBLEMS
1. Determine the values of x1? x2, and x3 that minimize the function
2. Determine the values of x1? x2, and x3 that maximize the function
Table 8.1
User
Final Total
Producer 1 2 ••• n demand output
1 b 12 •• b i„ by Xi
2 ^2 1 bn bjn h2 *2
n b»i bn 2 ■ •• bnn bn xn
the final demand for the products of industry i, and xt = ]T"= j + ht is the total
output of industry i.
The structure of the economy can be described by the technological matrix
A = (fly)
where = (b^/xj) = dollar value of the output of industry i that industry j must
purchase to produce one dollar’s worth of its own products. Note that this definition
of a{j assumes that the purchases of intermediate product of an industry are propor¬
tional to the level of output of the industry. This assumption of constant proportion¬
ality between inputs and outputs is standard for input-output analysis.
The ith industry must produce outputs
in order to supply the needs of all industries. The interindustry demand vector X can
thus be written AX, where
an 1 an2 ’ • • ann_ Xn
the production of the economy must be adjusted to fulfill both interindustry needs
and final demand. If the final demand vector is
K
h2
H = ht> 0 i = 1, 2, ..., n
h„
X = AX + H
Thus
[I - A]X - H
and
X = [I — A] XH
nonnegative; otherwise, the solution is not economically meaningful. There are also
problems concerning industry classification and stability of the technological matrix.
Given a set of positive final demands, consider the problem of determining the
conditions under which there is a unique set of positive production levels consistent
with the set of final demands. First, since [I-A]'1 must exist, 11 — A | must be
nonzero. In addition, each element of [I — A] 1 must be nonnegative, since other¬
wise an increase in final demand would result in a decrease in production at some
point in the production process. It can be shown that, in order for positive gross-
output levels to be associated with any given set of positive demands, the following
conditions are required
EXAMPLE
Consider a very simple hypothetical economy of two industries, A and B, represented in Table
8.2, where data are in millions of dollars of products.
Determine the output vector of the economy if final demand changes to 200 for A and 100 for
B.
i 7 '
A =
i T5
8 9
15 TO -
i 7
T ~T0
I - A = 8 11
"15 T0\
11 7
200 TO TO
[I-A]"1 = 17" 8 1
15 1
• ll A I 1.11 7.8 27
NOTE. | ! - A | —-j T0~ TO T5 ~ TTT0-
As must be the case,
1 1 1000
1[15011
X = [I-A]-‘H = ^
TO ■re] -
8
15 il 120 800
Table 8.2
User
Final Total
Producer A B demand output
And, if H = , then
11 7 200 1138|
175 T3
X = [I-A]‘1H = ^ 8 1
33 3 100 8444
That is, industry A must have an output of 1138f and industry B must have an output of 844|,
where output is given in millions of dollars of products.
EXAMPLE
A = 1 1 1
4 4 3
1 -5«-1 1
L3 3 3 J
j— 5 1 1■
6 — cf '4
[I - A] = 1 3 1
4 P ’3
1 1 2
L 3 3.
r 7 13 ■
T8 4 45
[I-A]"1 = 864 1 31 49
109 3 72 T44
11 29 9
l_34 72 T3 .
note : = 35 . 43 . 32
11 - A I| - 1.1.1
4 3 4 ~ 3
1.1.1
3 4
/I . 3 . 1 , 1 . 1 . 5 , 2 . 1 . 1\
“ (i
“IT 4 3+3 3 3 + 3 4 4j
1 09
864
3 1 5 1
1+1 4 —3 7 2+3 3 'T 29
ci i — (~ 1) 1 2 = T5 C23 — (~ 1) 1 1 73
3 3 ’3 -3
1 — -31 1 1
1 +2 4 1 3+ 1 'T T 13
C12 — ( — 1) 1 2 3 C31 — ( — 1) 3 1 45
1 3 T -3
1 3 5 1
1+3 4 4 11 3+2 3 '4 49
C13 — (~ 1) 1 1 34 C32 - ( — 1) 1 1 T44
3 'T '3
1 1 5 1
2+ 1 4 —4 1 3+3 3 4 9
C21 ~ 1) 1 2 4 C33 — ( — 1) 1 3 T3
3 1 "T 4
5 1
2+2 6 —4 31
c22 ~ ( ~ 1) 1 2 73
2 3
Table 8.3
User
Final Total
Producer A B C demand output
" 50 "
(a) If H = 10
100
r 7 1 13 -|
17 4 47 r 5o~
Ai-ln _ 864 1 31 49
X = [i -- AJ H — 7 72 144 10
11
l_74
29
72
9
17 J Lioo J
"388.62"
435.96
_659.45_
100 '
(b) IfH = 20
60
r 7 1 13 i
O
o
17 4 47
1 31 49
X = [I — A]- 'H = 7 72 144 20
11 29 9
L 24 72 T7 J . 60 _
"476.70"
494.31
694.68
' 80'
(c) If H = 100
120
r 7 1 13 -i
17 4 47 r 80]
at-Iij _ 864 1 31 49
X = [I AJ H — JU7 7 77 144 100
11 29 9
L74 72 17 J |_120_
" 702.39"
876.33
1144.95
PROBLEMS
1. A simple hypothetical economy of three industries, A, B, and C, is represented in the
following table (data are in millions of dollars of products):
User
Final Total
Producer A B c demand output
Determine the output vector for the economy if the final demand changes to a. 120 for A, 40
for B, and 10 for C; b. 60 for A, 60 for B, and 60 for C.
2. A simple hypothetical economy of two industries, A and 5, is represented in the following
table (data are in tens of millions of dollars of products):
8.4 Linear Programming / 619
User
Final Total
Producer A B demand output
A 14 6 8 28
B 7 18 11 36
Determine the output vector for the economy if the final demand changes to a. 16 for A and
3 for B; b. 2 for A and 4 for B.
3. A simple hypothetical economy of two industries, A and B, is represented in the following
table (data are in millions of dollars of products):
User
Final Total
Producer A B demand output
Determine the output vector for the economy if the final demand changes to a. 100 for A
and 200 for B,b. 50 for A and 60 for B.
4. A simple hypothetical economy of three industries, A, J3, and C, is represented in the
following table (data are in tens of millions of dollars of products):
User
Final Total
Producer A B C demand output
A 5 4 3 3 15
B 3 10 6 1 20
C 3 4 4 1 12
Determine the output vector for the economy if the final demand changes to a. 1 for A, 2 for
B, and 10 for C; b. 2 for A, 3 for B, and 2 for C.
The mathematical techniques for planning such allocations are referred to as math¬
ematical programming; the special case in which the measure of performance or cost
is a linear function and the restrictions on the availability or utilization of resources
are expressible as linear equations or inequalities is referred to as linear programming.
More specifically, the general linear programming problem involves maximizing
or minimizing a linear function of several primary variables, referred to as an objective
function, subject to a set of linear equalities or inequalities referred to as constraints.
None of the variables may be negative. (Note, however, that a negative variable may
be written as the difference of two positive variables.)
Mathematically, the linear programming problem for maximization is written
Xj> 0 7=1,2,...,«
This may be written more compactly as
Maximize Z = ]T CjXj
j= 1
n
Maximize Z = CX
xo
x2
X =
#11 a12
a21 a22 a2 n
A =
l a mi am2 a mn J
b1
^2
B=
lb m
Similarly, a linear programming problem involving minimization may be stated in
matrix notation as
Minimize Z = CX
8.4 Linear Programming / 621
subject to AX > B, X > 0. These formulations are referred to as the standard forms
for the problems of linear maximization and minimization, respectively, because the
constraint inequalities are all expressed in the form < for the maximization problem
and in the form > for the minimization problem. In order to write a problem in
standard form, it may be necessary to reverse the direction of an inequality by
multiplying by a negative one. For example,
anxi + a 12x2 ^ b
can be written
Although the standard form may be convenient, it is not necessary for the solution
of a linear programming problem. The standard form is necessary for obtaining the
dual, as discussed later in this section.
It can be shown that when there are m constraints in a linear programming
problem, there are at most m variables or allocations in its solution. Various methods
are available for determining which combination of m of the X/s maximizes or
minimizes the objective function Z. Linear programming problems involving no
more than two primary variables can be solved geometrically; although algebraic
solution is usually more efficient, even for these problems, geometric solution is
intuitively appealing and helps develop a basic understanding which is applicable to
more complicated problems. For this reason, geometric solution is discussed below.
There are several algebraic methods for solving linear programming problems; for
more complicated problems, involving many variables and many constraints, the
simplex method is the most efficient of these. The simplex method is an iterative
computational routine, based on matrix algebra, which develops successively better
solutions until the optimal solution is obtained. Most computer packages include a
program for simplex solution of linear programming problems. Simpler solution is
discussed and illustrated in this section. The interpretation of the dual of a linear
programming problem is also considered.
GEOMETRIC SOLUTION
Linear programming problems involving two primary variables are solved geome¬
trically by graphing the inequality constraints as equalities and thus determining a
polygon of feasible solutions. A solution is said to be feasible if it satisfies all the
constraints of a linear programming problem. Once the polygon of feasible solutions
has been obtained, the next step is to determine which feasible solution optimizes
(maximizes or minimizes) the objective function and is thus the solution of the
problem. The following theorem is used to reduce the number of feasible solutions to
be checked.
Thus the value of the objective function need be computed only for solutions
corresponding to vertices of the polygon of feasible solutions in order to determine
the optimal solution. (In some cases certain of these solutions are clearly inferior to
others and the corresponding values of the objective function need not be computed.)
622 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
A manufacturer produces bicycles and motor scooters, each of which must be processed
through two machine centers. Machine center 1 has a maximum of 120 hours available and
machine center 2 has a maximum of 180 hours available. Manufacturing a bicycle requires 6
hours in machine center 1 and 3 hours in machine center 2; manufacturing a motor scooter
requires 4 hours in machine center 1 and 10 hours in machine center 2. If profit is $45 for a
bicycle and $55 for a motor scooter, determine the number of bicycles and the number of
motor scooters that should be manufactured in order to maximize profit.
If X i = number of bicycles and X2 — number of motor scooters, the problem can be stated
as follows:
subject to 6Xx + 4X2 < 120, 3*: + 10*2 < 180, and Xu *2 > 0. The polygon of feasible
solutions is obtained by graphing the equations
*i =0
*2=0
Any point lying within or on the edge of the shaded polygon in Figure 8.1 corresponds to a
pair of values *x and X2 which satisfy the constraints of the problem and thus are a feasible
Figure 8.1
*2
solution. The optimal solution corresponds to one of the vertices of the polygon; the objective
function thus must be evaluated for the solutions (0, 0), (0, 18), (10, 15), and (20, 0).
Since (0, 0) is clearly inferior to (0, 18), it need not be considered. Thus the optimal solution
is (10, 15); that is, manufacture 10 bicycles and 15 motor scooters.
8.4 Linear Programming / 623
EXAMPLE
A company produces two commodities in quantities Xx and X2, respectively, and wishes to
minimize Cost = 2Xx + 10X2 subject to the constraints
2X, + A2 < 6
Xu X2 >0
Determine the optimal quantities of each commodity to be produced and the associated cost.
Figure 8.2
A2
2Xt + X2 = 6
5Xx + 4X2 = 20
Xx =0
X2 =0
Any point lying in or on the edge of the shaded polygon in Figure 8.2 corresponds to a feasible
solution. The optimal solution is one of the vertices (0, 5), (0, 6), and (3, -x).
(0, 5) $50
& $36
Note that (0, 6) need not be evaluated, since clearly it is associated with a higher cost than
(0, 5). The optimal solution is (4 ^); that is, produce 3 units of the first commodity and 1y
units of the second commodity. The associated cost is $36.
624 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Figure 8.3
*2
Note that the constraints determine the polygon of feasible solutions. The objec¬
tive function is used in determining which of these feasible solutions is optimal. It is
possible to write sets of constraints for which there is no feasible solution. For
example, there is no set of values for X1 and X2 which satisfies the constraints
2X1 +X2<6
Figure 8.4
*2
8.4 Linear Programming / 625
There are also some sets of constraints for which the polygon of feasible solutions
is not bounded. For example, if the inequality sign of the first constraint above is
reversed and the second constraint is unchanged,
2Xx +X2>6
the polygon of feasible solutions is unbounded. (See Figure 8.4.) In this case, the
linear programming problem has a solution if it involves minimization, but not if it
involves maximization.
subject to
Xj> 0 j = 1, 2, ..., n 4- m
In this problem there are n primary variables and m constraints. The addition of
slack variables results in m equations involving m + n unknowns. Note that the slack
variables are omitted from the objective function or, equivalently, are given a value of
zero in the objective function.
If an inequality is of the form >, a positive slack variable is subtracted from the
left-hand side of the inequality; this slack variable is given a value of zero in the
objective function. In order to obtain a feasible solution, an artificial variable is
added to the left-hand side of the inequality; this artificial variable is given a value of
— M in the objective function for a maximization problem and a value of 4- M in the
objective function for a minimization problem, where M is very large in absolute
value. The artificial variable is thus assigned a value in the objective function that
precludes its appearance in the final solution. For example, if an inequality is of the
form
Table 8.4
Profits per unit
Variables in the solution
Quantities of the variables
{ | in the solution
cx C2 • •• cn 0 0 • • 0
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity X, X 2 ■ •• Xn Xn+1 Xn + 2 • Xn + m
0 Xn + m bm am 1 am2 ®mn 0 0 • i
x n *m x m
where the value of Xn+x in the objective function is zero and the value of Xn + 2 in the
objective function is — M for maximization and +M for minimization.
For convenience, the data are arranged in a simplex tableau on which the compu¬
tational routine is performed. The initial tableau for the maximization problem
stated above is of the form shown in Table 8.4. In the simplex method, two rows are
usually included in addition to the rows representing the constraints: these are the Zj
row, representing the total profit from the solution, and the C} — Z7 row, represent¬
ing the net profit from adding one unit of a variable.
The simplex method consists of the following basic steps, which are illustrated in
detail in the examples:
Table 8.5
$45 $55 $0 $0
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity Xt X2 X3 X4
$0 x3 120 6 4 1 0
$0 X4 180 3 10 0 1
2, $0 $0 $0 $0 $0
Cj - Zj $45 $55 $0 $0
T
Optimal column
With the necessary slack variables included, the data are arranged in a simplex
tableau, and an initial feasible solution is indicated in the tableau (steps 1 through 3).
The initial simplex tableau is shown in Table 8.5.
Note the following characteristics of the initial simplex tableau:
a. Any unknown that occurs in one equation occurs (implicitly at least) in all equa¬
tions ; the unknowns that do not appear explicitly in an equation are considered to
have zero coefficients in that equation. Thus the zeros in the X4 column of the first
row and the X3 column of the second row correspond to those in the equations
b. The initial tableau is constructed for the solution having zero profit. The objective
function can be written
Step 4. Check for optimality: The C; — Z-} row gives the net profit from adding one
unit of a variable. For a maximization problem, the presence of at least one positive
number in the C7 — Zj row indicates that profit can be improved; absence of positive
numbers in the Cj — Zj row indicates that profit cannot be improved, that is, the
optimal solution has been obtained. For a minimization problem, the presence of at
least one negative number in the Cj — Zj row indicates that cost can be decreased;
absence of negative numbers in the C7 — Zj row indicates that cost cannot be de¬
creased, that is, the optimal solution has been obtained. In this example, there are
positive numbers in the C, — Zj row of the initial tableau, so the corresponding
solution is not optimal.
Step 5. Entering and departing variables: The largest contribution to profit per
unit ($55) is made by variable X2, so it is the entering or replacing variable. To
determine the departing variable, the quantities of X3 and X4 in the initial tableau
are divided respectively by their corresponding entries in the optimal column:
Table 8.6
$45 $55 $0 $0
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity x2 X3 X 4.
$0 X3 48 fl4\ 0 1 2
—1
$55 T2 18
© 1 0 TO
The variable corresponding to the smaller positive ratio is the departing or replaced
variable; thus X4 is the replaced variable in the example. (Note that 18 is the largest
number of units of X2 than can be added without violating the constraints.)
Step 6. Recompute the simplex tableau: The X2 row of the revised tableau is
computed by dividing each number in the replaced row X4 by the element in the
optimal column of the replaced row, which is 10 in this example (Table 8.6).
The entries in the X2 row are
18 & 1 0 ^
All the remaining rows corresponding to variables in the tableau are computed using
the formula
120 - (4 x 18) = 48
6 - (4 x i) = ^
4 — (4 x 1) = 0
1 - (4 x 0) = 1
0 - (4 x -[L) =
10
60
8.4 Linear Programming / 629
Table 8.7
$45 $55 $0 $0
Variables -
Cj allocated Quantity X2 *3 Z4
5
$45 10 1 0 14 T2
1 1
$55 X2 15 0 1 ~T6 ~5
<p 95 <r 25
2, $1275 $45 $55 4>T5
<r 95 <r 25
Cj - Zj $0 $0 ~ T5 -8“
The smallest positive ratio corresponds to X3, and X3 is thus the departing variable.
The simplex tableau is recomputed the same way as in the preceding stage (see Table
8.7). The absence of positive entries in the Cj — Zj row indicates that the optimal
solution has been obtained: Manufacture 10 bicycles and 15 motor scooters, as was
also determined above using the geometric method.
Note the following characteristics of the simplex tableau:
a. Slack and artificial variables are included in the constraint equations as follows: If
an inequality constraint is of the form <, a slack variable is added and is given a
value of zero in the objective function for both maximization and minimization
problems. If an inequality constraint is of the form >, a slack variable is sub¬
tracted and is given a value of zero in the objective function for both maximization
and minimization problems; in addition, an artificial variable is added and is
given a value in the objective function of — M for maximization problems and
+ M for minimization problems.
b. The elements of the body and identity matrices of the simplex tableau represent
marginal rates of substitution between the variables in the solution and the var¬
iables heading the columns. For example, in Table 8.6, X3 must be decreased by ^
units if 1 unit of X1 is added; X3 must be increased by f units if 1 unit of X4 is
added, and so forth. Note that a variable always has a marginal rate of substitu¬
tion of 1 with itself and a marginal rate of substitution of 0 with a variable with
which it is not substitutable.
c. The body matrix of the initial tableau has become an identity matrix in the final
tableau; the identity matrix of the initial tableau has become the inverse of the
initial body matrix in the final tableau.
d. In the final tableau, the C} - Z; row consists of zero or negative numbers for a
maximization problem and of zero or positive numbers for a minimization
problem.
EXAMPLE
Consider the problem of cost minimization discussed above (see page 623). Adding the slack
variables X3 and X4 and the artificial variable X5, the linear programming problem can be
stated as follows.
2 X i + X2 + X3 = 6
X 1, X 2 , X 3 , X 4. , X 5 >0
Table 3.8
$2 $10 $0 $0 $M
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity Xi X2 *3 *4 *5
$0 *3 6 2 1 1 0 0
$M V5 20 5 4 0 -1 1
Zj $20M $5 M $4M $0 $ - M $M
Cj - Zj $(2 - 5M) $(10 - 4M) $0 $M $0
Optimal column
The variable to enter at the next step is and the variable to be replaced is X3 since
X3:f = 3
*5:^ = 4
Table 8.9
$2 $10 $0 $0 $M
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity X1 X2 *3 *5
$2 *1 3 1 h 0 0
3 5
$M *5 5 0 —? -1 1
Zj $(6 + 5 M) $2 $(X + 3 M/2) $(1 5 M/2) $ - M $M
Cj - Zj $0 $(9 - 3M/2) $( - 1 + 5M/2) $M $0
T
Optimal column
The variable to enter at the next step is X2 and the variable to be replaced is X5 since
X,:~ = 6
1
The revised simplex tableau is shown in Table 8.10. The absence of negative entries in the
Cj — Zj row indicates that the optimal solution has been obtained: manufacture § units of the
first commodity and ^ units of the second commodity at a total cost of $36, as was also
determined above by the graphical method.
Table 8.10
$2 $10 $0 $0 $M
Variables
allocated Quantity Xx X2 X3 X4 X5
$2 4 1 0
$10 10 0 1
X2 T
Zj $36 $2 $10 $-14 $-6 $6
~Zj $0 $0 $14 $6 $(M - 6)
8.4 Linear Programming / 631
There are several variations of the standard simplex method, although none differs
substantially from the one discussed above. In addition, there are some linear pro¬
gramming problems in which the coefficients in the constraints have special forms
and special cases of the simplex method, which require less computation, can be used.
The simplex method must be modified if the solution variables are required to be
integer-valued.
subject to
Yj> 0 j = 1, 2, ..., m
Maximize CX
subject to
AX < B
X>0
then its dual, written in standard form, is
Minimize BY
subject to
AY > C
Y > 0
and, similarly, if a linear programming problem, written in standard form, is
Minimize CX
subject to
AX > B
X > 0
632 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Maximize BY
subject to
AY < C
Y > 0
The correspondence between the primal and dual problems can be summarized as
follows:
1. The constants in the constraints of the primal are the coefficients in the objective
function of the dual.
2. The coefficients in the objective function of the primal are the constants in the
constraints of the dual.
3. The inequality signs in the constraints of the primal and dual are reversed.
4. The matrices of coefficients in the constraints of the primal and dual are trans¬
poses of each other; for example, the ith row of coefficients in the constraints of
the primal is the ith column of coefficients in the constraints of the dual.
EXAMPLE
subject to
5Xi + X2 > 10
X! + 10Y2 > 9
*!>() *2 >0
Writing the problem in standard form, v
subject to
+ X2 > 10
Xl + 10X2 > 9
X,>0 X2>0
subject to
subject to
X^ 4 X 2 “I- X 3 > 15
subject to
subject to
-37i - 72 > 1
— 2Y1 - Y2 4 873 > 9
The solution of the dual problem also provides the solution of the primal problem.
The number of iterations required for simplex solution depends in part on the
number of rows of variables in the simplex tableau; thus, if m < n, solution of the
dual problem usually requires less computation and is therefore preferable.
The correspondence between the primal and dual solutions can be summarized as
follows:
1. The value of the objective function is the same for the primal and dual solutions.
2. The criteria for the primary variables of the primal are the solutions for the slack
variables of the dual.
3. The criteria for the slack variables of the primal are the solutions for the primary
variables of the dual.
4. The solutions for the primary variables of the primal are the negative values of the
criteria for the slack variables of the dual.
5. The solutions for the slack variables of the primal are the negative values of the
criteria for the primary variables of the dual.
EXAMPLE
Table 8.11
$120 $180 $0 $M $0 $M
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity Yx y2 >3 Ya Y5 Y6
95 5 1
$120 T6 1 0 — J4 16 — T5
1 1 1
$180 y2 ¥ 0 1 ~8
1
T2 —5
27
Zj $1275 $120 $180 $ - 10 $ - 15 $15
©
Cj - Zj $0 $0 $10 $15 $(M - 15)
subject to
Xu X2>0
the dual is given by
subject to
Yu Y2>0
With slack and artificial variables, the dual problem is
subject to
6Yx 4- 3Y2 - Y3 + Y4 = 45
4Yx 4- 10Y2 - Y5 4- Y6 = 55
Yu Y2,Y3,Y4,Y5,Y6>0
\
The final tableau of the simplex solution of the dual is given in Table 8.11. Note the correspon¬
dence between Tables 8.7 and 8.11 with respect to the properties listed above.
EXAMPLE
subject to
2Xx + X2<6
Xu X2 >0
the dual is given by
Table 8.12
$ - 6 $20 $0 $0
Variables
Cj allocated Quantity yi y2 y3 Y4
$20 6 0 1 -4 2
^2 3
4 5
$ - 6 V! 14 1 0 ~7 3
Z, $36 $ - 6 $20 $4 $^
Cj - Zj $0 $0 S-j $-^
subject to
Yu Y2 > 0
Max —6 Yx + 20 72
subject to
-2 Yx + 5Y2 + Y3 = 2
- Yi + 4Y2 + Y4 = 10
Yu Y2 , Y3, Y4 > 0
The final tableau of the simplex solution of the dual is given in Table 8.12. Note the correspond¬
ence between Tables 8.10 and 8.12 with respect to the properties listed above.
Thus the dual problem is completely symmetric to the primal problem and the
solution of one problem provides the solution of the other problem. Since the
number of iterations required for simplex solution depends in part on the number of
rows in the simplex tableau, the dual can provide a simpler computational problem
than the primal when the simplex tableau of the dual has fewer rows than the simplex
tableau of the primal.
The solution of the dual provides implicit, imputed, or shadow prices that can be
used as the basis for efficient allocation of resources. These shadow prices are also
used in sensitivity analysis, which determines the effect on the optimal solution if
constraints or objective function coefficients change. These analyses are discussed in
economics and are only mentioned here to indicate some of the applications of the
dual.
PROBLEMS
1. A company manufactures two types of novelty souvenirs made of plywood. Souvenirs of
type A require 5 minutes each for cutting and 10 minutes each for assembling; souvenirs of
type B require 8 minutes each for cutting and 8 minutes each for assembling. There are 3
hours and 20 minutes available for cutting and 4 hours available for assembling. The profit
is 50^ for each type A souvenir and 60^ for each type B souvenir. How many souvenirs of
each type should the company manufacture in order to maximize profit?
636 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
/(x, y) = 3x + 2y
Type 1 4 5 6
Type 2 5 7 9
Type 3 6 7 7
Total available 80 100 120
In order to maximize profit, determine the number of ladders of each type that should be
manufactured.
9. The Capsize Yachting Company produces two models of racing boats. Their profit is $520
for Model 1 and $450 for Model 2. Model 1 requires 40 hours for cutting and assembling
8.4 Linear Programming / 637
and 24 hours for finishing. Model 2 requires 25 hours for cutting and assembling and 30
hours for finishing. There are 400 hours available for cutting and assembling and 360
hours available for finishing. Determine the optimal number of each model for the com¬
pany to produce and the resulting profit.
10. The Duoply Company can make three products; their profit is $10 per unit for Product 1,
$14 per unit for Product 2, and $15 per unit for Product 3. Each of these products is
manufactured using three raw materials according to the following requirements:
subject to
4Xi + X2 < 12
*ls*2 >0
13. Obtain the solution for the following linear programming problem.
subject to
Xx - 2*2 > 3
X, - X2 > 4
X! > 1
*l5 X2 >0
XU *2, *3 >0
subject to X 1 + X2 + X3 > 6
6 *! + 1X3 > 12
Xu X2 , X3 > 0
subject to X 1 + X2 + X3 > 15
x,-x2 > 0
X1, X 2 , X 3 > 0
subject to X 1 + x2 + X3 > 5
X2 + 3^3 > 10
X1, X 2 , x3 > 0
Xu X2>0
*1, X2,X3>0
xu X2,X3>0
Number of Persons
Games are classified according to the number of distinct sets of interests or objectives
present in the game. From the game theory point of view, the number of persons in
the game is not necessarily the same as the number of people playing the game—that
is, if two or more players form a coalition in which they agree to pool their winnings
or losses, game-theory analysis treats them as a single person.
Most of the work done thus far in game theory deals with two-person games and
the discussion in the following sections is confined to this case. Analysis of games
640 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
involving more than two persons is usually very difficult. Note that many situations
that are not strictly two-person games may be analyzed as though they were—for
example, the interests in a game of cards can be considered as “his” and “everybody
else’s.”
The Payoff
Games are also classified with respect to the nature of the payoff, that is, what
happens at the end of the game. The distinction in this respect is between zero-sum
games and nonzero-sum games. If the sum of the payoffs to all players of a game is
zero, counting winnings as positive and losses as negative, then the game is zero-sum;
otherwise, it is nonzero-sum. In a zero-sum game, anything won by one player is lost
by another player. The importance of this distinction lies in the fact that a zero-sum
game is a closed system and a nonzero-sum game is not. Almost all parlor games are
zero-sum, and many other situations can be analyzed as zero-sum games. Most of the
work in game theory has concerned zero-sum games and the discussion in the
following sections is confined to such games. Note that a nonzero-sum game may be
made zero-sum by adding a fictitious player, say Nature, but this necessitates a more
difficult analysis, especially if the original game was a two-person game.
Strategies
In game theory, a strategy for a particular player is a plan which specifies his action
for every possible action of his opponent, that is, a strategy is a complete plan for
playing the game, without any connotation of skillfulness on the part of the player. In
a game completely amenable to analysis, it is possible, at least conceptually, to
foresee all eventualities and thus to catalogue all possible strategies. Games are
classified according to the number of strategies available to each player: if player 1
has m possible strategies and player 2 has n possible strategies and they are the only
players, then the game is m x n, that is, m by n. The important distinction in classify¬
ing games on the basis of strategies is between finite games and infinite games. If the
greatest number of strategies available to any player is finite, then the game is finite; if
at least one player has an infinite number of available strategies, then the game is
infinite. The theory of infinite games is very difficult and is not discussed in the
following sections. For the analysis of finite games, it is convenient to distinguish
three cases: those in which the player having the least number of strategies has two,
three, or more than three.
In summary, the discussion in following sections will generally concern finite,
zero-sum, two-person games.
of the game—that is, for determining which choice of strategies each player should
make—assuming that each player wishes to maximize his minimum expected profit
or minimize his maximum expected loss. The minimax theorem, the key result of the
theory of games, states that such a minimax solution exists for every finite, zero-sum,
two-person game. Note that minimax is not the only possible criterion for solving a
game matrix and that its use leads to a conservative theory, since the opponent is
assumed to be skillful and to use his best strategy.
The value of a game is the expected or average payoff per play over a long series of
plays, assuming that both players consistently use their optimum strategies. It is
conventional to regard value from the point of view of the player whose strategies
correspond to the rows of the payoff matrix. A game is said to be fair if its value is
zero; in a fair game neither player has an advantage. In a game that is not fair, one
player will win from the other in the long run if both play their optimum strategies; if
the value of the game is positive, the row player has the advantage; if the value of the
game is negative, the column player has the advantage.
Saddle Points
If a game matrix contains an entry that is simultaneously a maximum of row minima
and a minimum of column maxima, this minimax entry is said to be a saddle point of
the game and the game is said to be strictly determined. In this case, according to the
criterion of game theory, the optimum strategies for the respective players are repre¬
sented by the row and column whose intersection is the saddle point. The value of a
strictly determined game is the value of its saddle point.
The first step in the solution of a matrix game is to check for the existence of a
saddle point; if one is found, the game is solved; if not, further analysis is necessary.
Checking for a saddle point is usually done by writing the row minimum beside each
row and the column maximum at the bottom of each column and then determining
the maximum of the minima and the minimum of the maxima. A saddle point can
also be determined by checking for an entry which is simultaneously the minimum of
the row in which it occurs and the maximum of the column in which it occurs (see
Table 8.13).
Table 8.13
Player Y
1 2 ••• n
EXAMPLE
12 2 25 -10 -10
16 (D 4 10 3 . ,
max mm = 3
-2 -1 26 0 -2
14 -4 8 6 -4
16 3 26 10
min max = 3
There is a saddle point at the intersection of the second row (player X's optimum strategy) and
the second column (player Ys optimum strategy); the value of the game is 3.
-2 22 10 10 6 22 -6
min max = — 6
There is a saddle point at the intersection of the third row (player 3Ts optimum strategy) and
the seventh column (player Ys optimum strategy); the value of the game is —6.
(c) -3 2 4 -3
6 1 3 1
3 10 12 3 max min = 3
5 0 -2 -2
0 -4 6 -4
6 10 12
min max = 6
2 0 6 14 9 12 25 0 12 14
min max = 0
2x2 Games
The most easily analyzed two-strategy games are 2x2, that is, games in which each
player has only two possible strategies. Solution of 2 x 2 subgames is also frequently
necessary as a step in the solution of larger (2 x n or m x 2) two-strategy games.
The existence or nonexistence of a saddle point is easily determined for a 2 x 2
game, either directly by the method above or using the following theorem.
a b
c d
That is, a 2 x 2 matrix game is nonstrictly determined if and only if the two entries
on one diagonal of the matrix are each greater than each of the two entries on the
other diagonal.
EXAMPLE
The game
Player Y
1 2
1 1
Player X
-3 10
is strictly determined and fair. Player X’s optimum strategy is 1; player Ts optimum strategy
is 1.
EXAMPLE
The game
Player Y
1 2
1 5 ©
Player X
-7 -4
is strictly determined, but not fair (its value is 2). Player X's optimum strategy is 1; player P’s
optimum strategy is 2.
644 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
The game
Player Y
1 2
1 0 1
Player X
2 0
represents the game matrix, then the expected payoff to player X if player Y uses
strategy 1 is
bpi + d( 1 - p,)
px{a — b — c + d) d — c
d — c
Pi =
a — b — c + d
a -b
Pi = i - Pi =
a — b — c + d
8.5 Game Theory / 645
a{(a — b — c + d) = d — b
d-b
<?i =
a — b — c + d
a — c
q2 = i - q. a — b — c + d
The value of a game has the same meaning for strictly and nonstrictly determined
games: The value of a game is the payoff that a player can expect to obtain per play;
on the average, a player cannot win more than the value of a game unless his
opponent plays poorly, nor can he win less than the value of a game unless he plays
poorly.
The value of the game
a b
G =
c d
(to player X) is
EXAMPLE
2 0
The game is nonstrictly determined. The optimal mixed strategies are
0 2
Pi
2 _
4-1
1
n _ 2 _ 1
Pi — * — 1
— 2 — 1
qn i —t —i
q2 - * — i
and the value is f = 1; the game is biased in favor of player X.
EXAMPLE
-1 0
The game is nonstrictly determined. The optimal mixed strategies are
0 -2
EXAMPLE
7 -6
The game is nonstrictly determined. The optimal mixed strategies are
5 8
Pi — TZ
Pl=U
■g
14 7
<h T6
„ _ 2 _ 1
<?2 - T5 - S
EXAMPLE
10 -30
The game is nonstrictly determined. The optimal mixed strategies are
-10 20
_ _ 30 _ 3
Pi — TO — 7
n _ 40 _ 4
Pi ~ TO ~ 1
„ _ 50 _ 5
<7l ~ 7(5 — 7
<?2 = ^8 = T
EXAMPLE
8 1
4 6
11 4
7 9
16 2
8 12
_ all a12
a2l a22-
8.5 Game Theory / 647
[I, l][adj A]
[pi. Pi\ =
[1, 1 ] [adj A]
v =
[1, 1] [adj A]
The examples on pages 645 and 646 can be used to illustrate this method of solution.
EXAMPLE
2 0
The game is nonstrictly determined.
0 2
[1, 1] [adj A]
Ip i, Pi\ =
[1, 1] [adj A]
2 0
[1, 1]]
[° 2 [2, 2] 1 1
2 0 1 2’2
[1, 1]
0 2 1
2 0
[1, 1]
0 2 [2,2] 1 1
4
n
o
T 2 2
’
[L 1] 1
0 2
[1» 1] [adj A]
4-
A- I1
648 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Alternatively,
a 11 a 12 91
v = [pl, Pl\
a2i a22 92
01 12
= a i] 1
2
= [i, i]
= 1
(as obtained above using algebraic methods).
EXAMPLE
-1 0
The game is nonstrictly determined.
0 -2
[1, 1] [adj A]
[Pi> P2J =
[1, 1] [adj A]
‘-2 0
[1, 1]
0 -1 [-2, -1] 2 1
-2 0] 1] -3 3’ 3
[1, 1]
0 -1
■2 0
[1, 1] 0 1 2 1
[-2, -1]
-2 0 -3 3’3
[1, 1]
0 1
v =
[1, 1] [adj A]
2 2
^3 3
Alternatively,
a 12 91
v = [pi, P2]
a21 a 22 92
2
i o 3
= ti ti 0 -2 i
3.
[2
3
[-4 -f] 1
.3 .
_ _ 2.
3
EXAMPLE
7 -6
The game is nonstrictly determined.
5 8
[1, 1 ] [adj A]
[PoP2] =
[1, 1] [adj A]
' 8 6
[i, i;]
-5 7 [3, 13] 3 13
8 6] 1] 16 !6’ 16
[<?i> <?2] =
[L 1] 7 [14, 2] 7 r
6
8 6 T 16 8’ 8
[1, 1] -5 7 1
v =
[1, 1] [adj A]
86 _ 43
16 ” ¥
Alternatively,
all al2 <h
v = Ipi, P2]
a21 a22 <?2
7 -6
r_3_ 13t
L1 6’ 1 6 J
5 8
■i
r43 43-1 8
L 8’ 8 J 1
.8 .
_ 43
— S’
EXAMPLE
10 -30
The game is nonstrictly determined.
-10 20
[L 1] [adj A]
[Po P2]
[1, l][adjA]
'20 30
[i, i;]
10 10 [30, 40] [3 4
'20 30 1 70 [7 ’ 7
[i, i]
10 10 1
650 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
20 10
[1,1]
30 10 [50, 20] 5 2
'20 30 r 70 7’7
[1,1]
10 10 1
A
v=
[1, 1] [adj A]
-100 _ 10
^ 70“ _T
Alternatively,
EXAMPLE
The game 4 4
5 3
6 ©
1 3
5 4
has a saddle point at the intersection of the third row (player X’s optimal strategy) and the
second column (player Ts optimal strategy); the value of the game is 5.
EXAMPLE
The game 1 7 3
4 8 -1 6
8.5 Game Theory / 651
has a saddle point at the intersection of the first row (player X's optimal strategy) and the third
column (player Y’s optimal strategy); the value of the game is zero.
Dominance
In an m x n matrix game, row i is said to majorize or to dominate row h if every entry
in row i is as large or larger than the corresponding entry in row h. Similarly, column
j is said to minorize or to dominate column k if every entry in column j is as small as or
smaller than the corresponding entry in column k. Note that any dominated (ma¬
jorized) row or dominated (minorized) column can be omitted from the matrix game
without affecting its solution, since such strategies are clearly not optimal. If a 2 x n
or an m x 2 game does not have a saddle point, that is, is not strictly determined, all
majorized rows and minorized columns should be eliminated as the next step in the
solution.
The solution of a 2 x n game consists of probabilities and p2 = 1 — with
which player X selects, at random, his strategies 1 and 2, respectively, and probabili¬
ties ql9 q2, qn, where Ya=i qt = 1, with which player Y selects, at random, his
strategies 1,2respectively. Similarly, the solution of an m x 2 game consists of
probabilities pl9 p2,..., pm, where i Pi = 1, for player X and probabilities ql and
q2 — 1 — q± for player Y.
EXAMPLE
The game z C
J
A -5
J
3 6
5 4
A A
has no saddle point. However, row 3 dominates row 1 and row 4 dominates rows 2 and 5. Thus
the game is reduced, for calculation, to the subgame
3 6
“TT"
EXAMPLE
has no saddle point. However, columns 3, 4, 5, and 7 dominate column 2. Thus the game is
reduced, for calculation, to the subgame
-6 -1 4
7 -2 -5
After dominance has been used to reduce a2xrcoranrax2 game for calcula¬
tion, all possible 2x2 games derived from the matrix of this reduced game can be
solved. The value of the original game is the value of one of these derived 2x2
652 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
games and the optimal strategies of the original game are also those of that derived
2x2 game, extended for one player by the addition of zeros. Which of the derived
games provides the solution of the original game can be determined either by trial
and error or graphically.
The trial-and-error procedure consists of solving the derived 2x2 games until
one is found for which the two-strategy player does at least as well (usually better)
against all his opponent’s other strategies as he does against the pair appearing in the
2x2 subgame. When such a game is determined, its solution provides the solution
of the original game.
EXAMPLE
3 6
_5__4_
EXAMPLE
A(4) + A(~ 5) = A
which is greater than — ff, so the solution of this 2x2 game extended is the solution of the
original game:
Pi = A Pi =A
<?i = A qi =A <?3 = <?4 = <?5 = <?6 = qi = o
note: The 2x2 game
-1 4
-2 -5
has a saddle point; thus p{ = 1, p2 = 0, and the value of the game is —1. Against the other
remaining strategy of player Y, column 1 of the reduced game, p1 = 1, p2 = 0 has the value
— 6, which is not greater than — 1, so the solution of this game is not the solution of the original
game. The 2x2 game
-6 4
7 -5
8.5 Game Theory / 653
has the solution px = fi, P2 = rn and the value of the game is — yy Against the other remain¬
ing strategy of player Y, column 2 of the reduced game, = rr, P2 = tt has value — {f, which
is not greater than —yy so the solution of this game is not the solution of the original game.
Graphical Solution
Graphically, the 2x2 game whose solution is the solution of a 2 x n game is
determined as follows. Plot the pairs of payoffs of the n strategies of player Y on two
vertical axes and connect the pairs of points by straight lines; locate the highest point
on the line segments that form the lower boundary of the graph. The lines that
intersect at this point identify the strategies player Y should use in his optimum
strategy. Note that it may be possible to reduce a game by dominance before doing
graphical analysis.
EXAMPLE
column 5 dominates column 4 and column 2 dominates column 1. The 2x3 game to be
solved is
-2 3 6
5 1 0
-2 3
5 1
Figure 8.5
The solution of this 2x2 subgame is px = p2 = f; qx = f, q2 = its value is J^z. Thus the
solution of the original game is p2 = I; q\ = 0, q2 = f, <?3 = l, q4 = 0, q5 = 0; its value
Similarly, for an m x 2 game, the payoffs of the m strategies of player X are plotted
and the lines that intersect at the lowest point on the line segments that form the
upper boundary of the figure identify the strategies player X should use in his
optimum strategy.
654 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
EXAMPLE
In the game -3 6
6 3
8 -2
-3 6
6 3
The solution of this 2x2 subgame is px = i, p2 = J; <7i = i, 4 2 = 15 its value is Thus the
solution of the original game is px = i, P2 = i P3 = 0; = i, <72 = 15 its value is
Figure 8.6
EXAMPLE
An automobile manufacturer has five proposed designs for next year’s new cars. Which of
these is likely to sell best depends largely on whether his competitor’s standard model is
excellent, good, fair, or poor. If the model is excellent, his net profit (millions of dollars) will be
100, 150, 50, 125, and 90, respectively; if the model is good, his profit will be 80, 55, 55, 60, and
70, respectively; if the model is fair, his profit will be 150, 100,100,100, and 125, respectively; if
the model is poor, his profit will be 50, 80, 25, 80, and 75, respectively. What design should he
choose in order to maximize his minimum expected profit?
Competitor’s model
1 1( X) 80 1 ! 50 50
2 1 i 50 55 1( K) 80
Design 3 i 50 55 1 ( K) 25
4 i: !5 60 1 )0( 80
5 5 '0 70 i: !5 75
80 50
70 75
The solution of this 2x2 subgame is px = 7, p2 = 7 and qx = 7, <72 = -7* Thus the manufacturer
should produce model 1 with probability 7 and model 5 with probability 7; his competitor
8.5 Game Theory / 655
Figure 8.7
should produce a good model with probability 7 and a poor model with probability 7; the
value is Note that the payoffs in this problem are all positive and the competitor must
therefore have some external reason (such as trying to enter the market) for manufacturing at
an inevitable loss. This is assuming that the matrix literally represents net profits and not some
type of additional revenue.
EXAMPLE
The Defense Department plans to award a contract for a new missile range at one of two
locations, A or B. A real estate speculator intends to invest $5000 in land—all at location A, all
at location B, or half at each location. If he buys at location A, the land will be worth $10,000 if
the missile range is built there, but $3000 if it is built at location B. If he buys at location B, the
land will be worth $4000 if the missile range is built at location A and $8000 if it is built at
location B. If he buys at both locations, the land will be worth $6000 if the missile range is built
at location A and $5000 if it is built at location B. In order to maximize his minimum expected
profits, what should the speculator do?
Missile range
A B
A 10,000 3,000
Investment B 4,000 8,000
10,000 3,000
4,000 8,000
The solution of this 2x2 subgame is px = yj, p2 — it- Thus the speculator should invest his
money in property A with probability yj and property B with probability yx\ the value is
$6181.82. If the Defense Department is considered to be somehow plotting against the specula¬
tor, it should choose location A with probability yx and location B with probability yx.
656 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Figure 8.8
and Ts optimum strategies are represented by (q{, q2,..., qn), the inequalities which
express the expectations of Y are given by
01 + 02 + " ‘ + 0n = 1
8.5 Game Theory / 657
Substituting q{ = qjv,
Maximize YOi
i= 1
subject to
n
PROBLEMS
Find the optimal strategies for the players of each of the following matrix games using the
minimax criterion.
8 10 13 16 9 14 3 5 8 4
10 12 6 15 10 -3 -1 6 -2 5
16 18 9 13 25 2 12 10 13 16
4 9 18 20 6
15 -20 -12 3
5 8 7 4 2 -10 -6
-1 -3 10 20 -18 -15 -8
2 12 -6 -12 8 -10 6
10 9 -11 4
10 8 6 2
15 12 2 4 3 10 20 18 0
-4 6 -3 1 -9 -8 46 10 4
12 -2 8 -6 2 0 17 18 0
16 13 7 12 -1 1 13 5 3
658 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Find the optimal strategies for the players of each of the following matrix games using the
minimax criterion and determine the value of each game.
17. A contractor is going to build a large number of houses for a housing development. Four
types of houses have been discussed: colonial, ranch, split-level, and contemporary; the
development committee will choose two of these types for the contractor to construct. The
contractor has the opportunity to buy materials in carload lots, thus saving considerable
money, but he must order in advance of the committee’s decision and can order only one
type of material. If the committee chooses colonial and ranch, the contractor will make an
(extra) profit (in thousands of dollars) of 125, 120, 60, and 50 if he orders colonial, ranch,
split-level, and contemporary materials, respectively. If the committee chooses colonial
and split-level, he will make 90, 40, 80, 75, respectively; if the committee chooses colonial
and contemporary, he will make 150, 30, 75, 100, respectively; if the committee chooses
ranch and split level, he will make 70, 70, 75, 65, respectively; if the committee chooses
ranch and contemporary, he will make 90, 80, 80, 120, respectively; if the committee
chooses split-level and contemporary, he will make 80, 40, 130, and 80, respectively. How
should the contractor order to maximize his minimum expected extra profit?
18. A plant manager must set up his reactors to produce a certain type of polythene using
either process 1, 2, 3, 4, or 5. Unfortunately, the chemical raw material varies in nitrogen
8.5 Game Theory / 659
content and may contain 3, 4, 5, or 6% nitrogen. The nitrogen content affects the relative
efficiency of the five processes. With 3% nitrogen, the five processes have an output of 50,
45, 60, 50, and 30 tons, respectively. With 4% nitrogen, the outputs are 60, 70, 75, 90, and
60 tons, respectively; with 5% nitrogen, the outputs are 30, 55, 60, 45, and 70 tons,
respectively; with 6% nitrogen, the outputs are 45, 80, 80, 65, and 85 tons, respectively.
Testing for nitrogen content is too expensive to be practical. What process should the
plant manager use to maximize the minimum expected output?
19. A firm builds construction machinery whose performance depends on the reliability of a
gasoline motor. The firm can buy an expensive motor, fully guaranteed including replace¬
ment costs, for $500; the firm can also buy a moderately expensive motor for $400,
guaranteed for half its cost and the cost of replacement, so that a failure means the firm
pays $600 for the motor; or the firm can buy a cheaper motor for $300; if it buys this
cheaper motor it can either guarantee replacement for a total cost of $700, or it can pay
$50 to have the motor examined before installation, so total cost, if the motor is defective,
is $650. To minimize maximum expected costs, what should the firm do?
20. Mr. Smith and Mr. Jones each have a small hothouse in which they grow plants to sell.
Each of them grows either tomatoes, flowers, or strawberries in any particular year but
they are very secretive about their plans. If Mr. Smith grows tomatoes, his profit is $100 if
Mr. Jones grows tomatoes, $150 if Mr. Jones grows strawberries, and $200 if Mr. Jones
grows flowers. If Mr. Smith grows strawberries, his profit is $180, $125, $200 if Mr. Jones
grows tomatoes, strawberries, flowers, respectively. If Mr. Smith grows flowers, his profit is
$140, $125, $100 if Mr. Jones grows tomatoes, strawberries, flowers, respectively. For each
to maximize his minimum expected profit, what should Mr. Smith and Mr. Jones grow?
21. Mr. Reno has decided to bet $5 on a basketball game between Anglewood and Barleyville.
Mr. Las and Mr. Vegas have each offered Mr. Reno a bet. Mr. Las wants to bet on
Barleyville and is willing to pay Mr. Reno $10 if Anglewood wins and collect $5 if
Barleyville wins. Mr. Vegas wants to bet on Anglewood and is willing to pay Mr. Reno $4
if Barleyville wins and collect $5 if Anglewood wins. If he wants to maximize his minimum
expected winnings, what should Mr. Reno do?
22. Casey has a concession at the Yankee Stadium for the sale of sunglasses and umbrellas. He
has observed that he can sell about 500 umbrellas when it rains, and about 100 when it
shines; and in the latter case he can also dispose of 1000 sunglasses. Umbrellas cost $0.50
and sell for $1.00; glasses cost $0.20 and sell for $0.50. He is willing to invest $250 in the
project. Assuming that everything that isn’t sold is a total loss, what should he purchase to
maximise his minimum expected profit?
23. Mr. Hilton Conrad is faced with the following decision: The State Medical Society would
like to use his hotel for their annual convention; they would essentially take over all
facilities of the hotel (so business from other sources would be negligible) and would pay
$20,000 for this privilege. Ordinarily the hotel would do $10,000 business during the time
the convention would be in session; however, there is a chance that the World Series will
be played in the city at that time and, in this event, the hotel would do $50,000 business.
Should Mr. Hilton Conrad accept or decline the Medical Society’s offer in order to
maximize his minimum expected business?
24. An investor has a choice of buying one of three stocks: A, B, or C. The outcome of his
purchase depends on whether a particular company executes a merger, divests itself of a
subsidiary, or maintains the status quo. In case of a merger, stock A results in a gain of 20,
stock B in a loss of 25, and stock C in a gain of 12. In case of divesting, stock A results in a
loss of 5, stock B in a loss of 10, and stock C in a loss of 12. If the status quo is maintained,
stock A results in a gain of 5, stock B in a gain of 30, and stock C in a loss of 4 (amounts are
in thousands of dollars), a. In order to maximize his minimum expected gains, what stock
should the investor buy? b. If divesting were impossible, but the gains and losses from the
other possibilities were unchanged, what stock should he buy to maximize his minimum
expected gains?
25. A commuter must decide what to do about buying insurance for his car. He will definitely
carry liability insurance, but the car is rather old and he is not sure whether collision
insurance is worthwhile. He can either carry no collision insurance, buy a $50 deductible
660 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
policy for $60, or buy a full-coverage policy for $70. The commuter drives this car only to
and from work and he thinks one of three things will happen during the year: He will have
no accident, he will have one minor accident not exceeding $50 damage, or he will have
one more serious accident not exceeding $250 damage (the car is worth only about $400 so
this is not unreasonable optimism). The commuter realizes he could possibly have more
than one accident during the year, but on the basis of his past performances he is willing to
assume that he won’t. What should he do to minimize his maximum expected cost?
26. In the summer Mr. Smith is considering the winter coal problem. During a normal winter,
it takes about 15 tons of coal to heat his shop, but he has observed extremes where as little
as 10 tons or as much as 20 tons were used. The price per ton seems to fluctuate with the
weather, being $10, $15, and $20 a ton during mild, normal, and severe winters, respec¬
tively. He can buy now at $10 a ton. Mr. Smith considers three possible alternatives: to
buy 10, 15, or 20 tons now and the rest, if any, later. Assuming that all coal not used is a
total loss (Mr. Smith plans to sell the shop in the spring), what should he do to minimize
his maximum expected cost?
27. A student must decide how to study for a final exam in history. He studies differently for
true-false, multiple-choice, and essay exams, and he doesn’t know which type this exam
will be. The student thinks that if he studies for a true-false test, he will score 85 on a
true-false test, 80 on a multiple-choice test, and 75 on an essay test. If he studies for a
multiple-choice test, he will score 85 on a true-false test, 90 on a multiple-choice test, and
85 on an essay test. If he studies for an essay test, he will score 80 on a true-false test, 90 on
a multiple-choice test, and 90 on an essay test. To maximize his minimum expected score,
for what type of test should the student study?
28. A service station must have its service and parking area plowed after every heavy snowfall.
The manager can pay $5 every time the area needs plowing; he can buy a contract for $25
which provides blowing for up to and including six snowfalls, with each additional plow¬
ing at a cost of $3; or he can buy a contract for $30 which provides plowing as many times
as it is needed. What should the manager do to minimize his maximum expected cost of
plowing if he is willing to assume (based on past records) that there will be between 3 and 8
(inclusive) snowfalls during the winter?
13. Pi = 0, p2 = i p3 = o, p4 = i p5 = 0
q\ = ?, <?2 = i
v = 3^
15. Pi = 0, p2 = i, p3 = 0, p4 = i
q\ = I, q2 = i
,, _ 3
17. buy for colonial with probability ^ and for split-level with probability
19. buy expensive motor
8.6 First-Order Markov Processes / 661
Note that the sum of the elements in each row of the matrix P is 1, since the elements
of the zth row represent the probabilities for all possible transitions when the process
is in state a,. That is,
r
Thus if the probability distribution of the states on trial n is [pls p2,..., pr], the
probability distribution of the states on trial n + 1 is
P21 P22 P 2r r r r
• • • =
[Pi, P2 > •••> Pr] Zp.P.i X>iPi2 . • * • » Xi PiPir
i= 1 i= 1 i= 1
I>;= 1
i= 1
Note that these equations actually define equilibrium: If [pls p2, ..., pr] is the
probability distribution of the states for a given observation, the product
gives the probability distribution of the states for the next observation. If that distrib¬
ution is also [pi, p2, •.., pr], the same as for the preceding observation, the system is
in equilibrium.
EXAMPLE
Suppose that, on September 1, of the subscribers in a fixed area, the Herald hasf, the Tribune
has i, and the Gazette has During the month of September, the Herald retains t of its
subscribers and loses f of them to the Tribune; the Tribune retains yj of its subscribers and
loses i of them to the Herald and t of them to the Gazette; the Gazette retains f of its
subscribers and loses f of them to the Herald and t of them to the Tribune. Assume there are
no new subscribers and that none quit subscribing.
(a) What proportion of the subscribers does each paper have on October 1 ?
(b) If the same pattern of gains and losses continues for October, what proportion of the
subscribers does each paper have on November 1 ?
(c) If the same pattern of gains and losses continues each month, what proportion of the
subscribers will each paper have in the long run (that is, in equilibrium)?
The transition matrix is
Tribune 33 1
TJ
1
E
Gazette L 1
1 E
1 1
3
(a)
r
37 31 0"
[i, i, i] 3
3 TZ
1 E1 = [f, i, i]
Li
1
E
1 31 J
Thus on October 1, of the subscribers, the Herald has f, the Tribune has -g, and the Gazette has
i-
(b)
1
3
1 1
TZ E = [ft, 3, fs]
1 1
E 3 J
Thus on November 1, of the subscribers, the Herald has ft, the Tribune has i, and the Gazette
has ye-
(c)
1
3
1
[Pi, Pi, Pa] T2 [Pi, Pi , P3]
1
E
ip 1 + IPi + ip 3 = Pi
3P1 + T2P2 + ip 3 = Pi
zPi + ip 3 = P3
Pi + P2 + P3 = 1
664 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Multiplying the first equation by 8, the second equation by 24, and the third equation by 6,
~P i + 6 p2 + 4 p3 — 0
Pi ~ 4p3 = 0
Pi + Pi + Pi — 1
Solving the first, third, and fourth equations simultaneously (any three of the four equations
are independent),
1 1 1 1
0 1 -4 0
_ - 1 6 4 0
'1 1 '
1 1
0 1 -4 0
_0 7 5 1 .
'1 0 5 1 "
0 1 -4 0
_0 0 33 1
"10 0
4
0 1 0 33
1
0 0 1 33 J
Thus in the long run, of the subscribers, the Herald will have f§, the Tribune will have-33, and
the Gazette will have 33.
EXAMPLE
In the community of Gardenville, each year 5 percent of the residents in the city proper move
to the suburbs and 2 percent of the people in the suburbs move to the city. Assuming that the
total number of people in the community remains constant, determine the long-run propor¬
tions of city and suburban residents.
The transition matrix is
City Suburbs
0.95 0.05
lPu Pi\ = [Pi, P2I
0.02 0.98
0.95 pi + 0.02p2 = Pi
0.05pj + 0.98 p2 = p2
Pi + Pi = 1
Multiplying the first two equations by 100,
-5 Pi + 2p2 = 0
5pi ~2p2=0
Pi + Pi = 1
8.6 First-Order Markov Processes / 665
Solving the first and third equations simultaneously (any two of the three equations are
independent),
1 1 1
-5 2 0
1 1 1
0 7 5 .
1 1 1
0 1
5
2
1 0 7
5
0 1 7
Thus, eventually, of the people in the community, 7 will be city residents and 7 will be residents
of the suburbs. Note that in this equilibrium state each year 0.05 x 7 = ^ of the people move
from the city to the suburbs and 0.02 x 7 = 73 of the people move from the suburbs to the
city—the numbers of city and suburban residents thus are unchanged or stable.
EXAMPLE
A broker is studying the price movements of various stocks on the market and is particularly
interested in a company called Astronaut Instruments. He has observed that if this stock goes
up on a given day, then the next day it has a 50: 50 chance of going up again, a 3 chance of
staying the same price, and a 3 chance of going down. If the stock stays the same on a given
day, then it is equally likely to go up, stay the same, or go down the next day. If the stock
goes down on a given day, then the next day it has a 50 : 50 chance of going down again, a 3
chance of staying the same price, and a 3 chance of going up. What proportion of the time (in the
long run) does the stock go up, stay the same, and go down?
The transition matrix is
Up Same Down
1 1 1
Up 7 7 7
1 1 1
Same 7 7 7
1 1 1
Down 7 7 7
Pi + P2 + P3 = 1
Multiplying the first equation by 6, the second equation by 2, and the third equation by 6,
— 3pi + 2p2 + p3 = 0
Pi - 2p2 + p3 = 0
Pi + 2p2 — 3p3 = 0
Pi + P2 + P3 = 1
666 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
Solving the second, third, and fourth equations simultaneously (any three of the four equations
are independent),
" 1 1 1 1 "
1 2 -3 0
_ 1 -2 1 0.
" 1 1 1 r
0 1 4 -1
_0 -3 0 -1 _
" 1 0 5 2
0 1 -4 1
_0 0 - 12 -4
"1 0 0 1 1
3
0 1 0 1
3
_0 0 1 1
3 J
Thus, in the long run, the stock goes up 3 of the time, stays the same 3 of the time, and goes
down 3 of the time.
PROBLEMS
1. A country has a three-party political system and the results of elections follow a definite
pattern: If a party wins an election, its chance of winning the next election are 50 : 50 and if
it loses the next election, each of the other two parties has a 50 : 50 chance of winning.
What proportion of the elections does each party win over a long period of time?
2. A trucking company offers its drivers three approved routes between two cities: over the
Mystic Bridge, on the Interstate Parkway, and on Route 1. If a trucker goes on the Mystic
Bridge, the chance of his getting into a traffic jam is 3; if he does get in a traffic jam, the
next day he takes the Interstate Parkway with probability 3 and Route 1 with probability
3; if he doesn’t get in a traffic jam, the next day he takes the Mystic Bridge again with
probability 3, the Interstate Parkway with probability 4 and Route 1 with probability 3. If
he takes the Interstate Parkway the chance of his getting into a traffic jam is 3; if he does
get in a traffic jam, the next day he takes the Mystic Bridge; if he doesn’t get in a traffic
jam, the next day he takes the Mystic Bridge, the Interstate Parkway, and Route 1 with
equal probability. If he takes Route 1, the trucker is invariably late, so he never takes
Route 1 two days in a row and the next day he takes the Mystic Bridge with probability 3
and the Interstate Parkway with probability 3. What proportion of the time does the
trucker go on the Mystic Bridge, the Interstate Parkway, and Route 1, respectively?
3. Every year the Smith family goes on a vacation—a camping trip (preferred by the chil¬
dren), a visit to the city (preferred by Mrs. Smith), or a winter vacation (preferred by Mr.
Smith). They never take the same kind of vacation 2 years in a row. Each year they flip a
coin to decide which of the two types of vacation they did not take the previous year they
will take that year. What proportion of the time do the Smiths go on a camping trip, visit
the city, and take a winter vacation, respectively?
4. A mechanic has a very unreliable automobile. Every morning he goes out to the garage
hoping to start it; some days it starts by itself, some days it starts if he gets a push from a
neighbor, other days no amount of pushing is effective and the service station must be
called. If it starts one day, the chances are 3 it will start, 3 it must be pushed, and 3 the
service station must be called the next day. If it is pushed one day, the chances are 3 it will
start and 3 the service station must be called the next day (it is never pushed 2 days in a
row). If the service station is called one day, the chances are | it will start and \ it must be
pushed the next day (the service station is never needed 2 days in a row). In the long run,
what proportion of the days will the auto start, be pushed, and need the service station,
respectively?
8.6 First-Order Markov Processes / 667
5. The students of Professor Geology never know what’s going to happen in class; the
professor may give them a surprise quiz, take them on a field trip, discuss the daily
assignment, or deliver a lecture. If he gives a quiz one day, the next day there is always a
field trip. If there is a field trip one day, there is never a quiz or a field trip the next day, but
discussing the assignment and a lecture are equally likely. If he discusses the assignment
one day, there is \ chance of a quiz, \ chance of a field trip, \ chance of discussing the
assignment, and 3 chance of a lecture the next day. If he lectures one day, there is \ chance
of a quiz, 3 chance of a field trip, 3 chance of discussing the assignment, and \ chance of a
lecture the next day. One of the students has calculated that they can expect quizzes of
the days, field trips 3^7 of the days, discussion of the assignment ^7 of the days, and
lectures 337 of the days. Is he correct?
6. Mr. S (who prefers steak), Mr. C (who prefers chicken), and Mr. H (who prefers ham) are
invited frequently to the home of a friend who serves only these three entrees. They have
decided to bet before each dinner engagement on which entree will be served. Suppose that
if the hostess serves steak on one occasion, she never serves it next time; she tosses a fair
coin and serves chicken if it comes up heads and ham if it comes up tails. If she serves
chicken on one occasion, then the next time she tosses two dice and serves chicken if the
dice come up the same; if the dice come up different on the first toss, she tosses them again
and serves steak if they come up the same and ham otherwise. If she serves ham on one
occasion, then the next time she draws a card randomly from a deck and serves chicken if
it is a diamond and steak otherwise. If each man always bets on his preference, what
proportion of the time, in the long run, will each win?
7. Every summer the Stormy Lakes Yachting Association must decide whether to hold its
annual regatta in June, July, or August. If the regatta is in June, the probability of good
weather is -J; if there is good weather, the next year the regatta will be held in June with
probability 3, in July with probability 4 and in August with probability i; if there is bad
weather, the next year the regatta will be held in July and August with equal probabilities.
If the regatta is in July, good and bad weather are equally probable; if there is good
weather, the next year the regatta will be held in July; if there is bad weather, the regatta
will be held in August with probability 3 and in June with probability 3. If the regatta is in
August, the probability of good weather is 3; if there is good weather, the next year the
regatta will be held in July and August with equal probabilities; if there is bad weather, the
regatta will be held in June with probability 3 and in July with probability 3. What
proportion of the time is the regatta held in June, July, and August, respectively?
8. A scientific book club has three mailing lists: a selected list consisting of members of 3
years or more of active membership, a membership list consisting of current members, and
an augmented list consisting of current members and others who have shown interest in
the club’s activities in the past. For each new publication, it must be decided which list to
use for mailing the sales literature. If after the preceding mailing there were too few copies
ordered, the secretary uses the member list with probability \ and the augmented list with
probability j; if after the preceding mailing there was a satisfactory response, the secretary
uses the member list and the augmented list with equal probability; if after the preceding
mailing, the publication was oversold, the secretary uses the selected list with probability 3
and the member list with probability 3. If the selected list is used, there are too few sold, or
a satisfactory number sold with equal probability; if the member list is used, there are too
few sold with probability \ and an adequate sale with probability |; if the augmented list is
used, there is an adequate sale with probability 3 and an oversale with probability 3. What
proportion of the time are the sales too small, adequate, and an oversale, respectively?
9. A housewife always buys one of three brands of detergent: A, B, or C. Which brand she
buys depends partly on which, if any, of the three companies are having a promotional
campaign (free combs, plastic roses, etc.). The companies time these campaigns at random,
paying no attention to whether the competition is running one at the same time. Company
A runs a campaign 3 of the time, company B runs a campaign 3 of the time, and company
C runs a campaign 3 of the time. If the housewife buys brand A one time, the next time she
buys brand A if brand A is running a campaign or if none of the brands is running a
campaign, she buys brand B if brand B is running a campaign but brand A is not, and she
buys brand C if brand C is running the only campaign at the time. If she buys brand B one
668 / Applications of Matrix Algebra
time, the next time she buys brand A if it is running the only campaign at the time and
brand B otherwise. If she buys brand C one time, the next time she buys brand A if it is
running the only campaign at the time, brand C if it is running a campaign and B is not,
and brand B otherwise. What proportion of the time does the housewife buy brands A, B,
and C, respectively?
helpful hint: From P(A) = P(B) = 3, P(C) = 3 given above, the following probabili¬
ties can be obtained with a little arithmetic:
10. Computeronics Corporation orders 2-foot lengths of wire for use in its experimental
models from a supplier who claims that the wire has a specified strength desired by the
Computeronics engineers. Each shipment is classified by the engineers who use it as
satisfactory in strength (no report is made to the supplier), below standard (the supplier is
notified by letter that the shipment was not as claimed), or unacceptable (the shipment is
returned and a replacement which has been subjected to a 100% test is sent by the supplier
in accordance with the guarantee). The classification depends upon the extent to which a
shipment fulfills or fails to fulfill the supplier’s claim regarding strength. The engineers
have observed that if a shipment is classified as satisfactory, the next shipment is satisfac¬
tory 3 of the time, below standard ^5 of the time, and unacceptable ^ of the time; if a
shipment is classified as below standard, the next shipment is satisfactory of the time,
below standard ^ of the time, and never unacceptable. What proportion of the shipments
is satisfactory, below standard, and unacceptable in the long run, respectively?
EXPONENTS
I. PROBLEMS
Answers
12. ,_
A“b2
II. PROBLEMS
1
1. 2.
Vm - 1
7. x^a2b3> 8. v^x — 5,/y
669
670 / Algebra Review Problems
Answers
III. PROBLEMS
Answers
1. -2 2. 3 3. x2y 4. — 3x 5. -4 6. -a4y2 7. -3
8. jxy3 9. — a2b3 10. 3n2
IV. PROBLEMS
Change each of the following to simplest form.
Answers
V. PROBLEMS
— ab
1. 7.
y
Answers
j y _ yy _ y 2.
yy
yy = xy
‘ y yy 6 y
_ j_ .y = _y
y y 3 m
— ab^/b o >y y
7.
yy ■yy 2
Algebra Review Problems / 671
VI. PROBLEMS
12x3y3z3 48 x3,2y315
6. 8. (3x2)2 9. (3ah1/2)2 10. (x2/3y4/3)3
— 6 xyz 16x1/2y1/5
4a3b (x3/"1j/2/m)m 6a 3 x2
19. 20. 21. 22. (a2/?-3)"1 23. x° • y"
(a4b6)112 xmy1_w 3(y2c 4)1/2
4 “VlT3 x~2y 1
2 1
24. 25. 26. a~1 + /T2 27. (n 1 + n 2) \ —
T2 aby4
'n1-flX“2
28. 29. (x)(x2/3) 30. n(n 3/5 — n 2/5)
<n 2 — a
Answers
x3 4a
14. y6fc 15. x"y4 !7. ^ 18. 19.
16- X- b2 2a2
2c 2„2
x
20
3 — m ,,1 + m
. xJ_my 21. 22. 23. y" 24. 4a5b 25.
a3v a 3x 2,y,2
LOGARITHMS
I. PROBLEMS
Write each of the following as the sum or difference of simpler logarithmic quantities.
/ ttiTi \ v3 (a\ /—
1. logJ —I 2. logx(ahc) 3. logJ-l 4. \ogxJy 5. loga n5
10 . log10^
672 / Algebra Review Problems
Answers
EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS
I. PROBLEMS
1. Find the second component of each of the following ordered pairs (x, y) if y = 2X:
( — 3, ), (0, ), (3, ), (6, ). 2. Find the second component of each of the following
ordered pairs (x,/(x)) if,f(x) = (j)*: ( — 3, ), (0, ), (3, ), (5, ). 3. State the equations
, 1
a = bx if b = 10 ,
e
Answers
I. PROBLEMS
Answers
II. PROBLEMS
Answers
III. PROBLEMS
Answers
1. x = 2 2. y = 3 3. x = 0 4. z = 1 5. y = 2 6. y = — 1
1. x= -2 8. z = — 1 9. x = 3 10. y = 2 .
11 x= 16
12. x = 9 13. y = 2 14. z = 2 15. x = 100 16. y = 3
Tables
Exponential Functions
X ex e x X ex e x
675
676 / Tables
Common Logarithms
N 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
10 0000 0043 0086 0128 0170 0212 0253 0294 0334 0374
11 0414 0453 0492 0531 0569 0607 0645 0682 0719 0755
12 0792 0828 0864 0899 0934 0969 1004 1038 1072 1106
13 1139 1173 1206 1239 1271 1303 1335 1367 1399 1430
14 1461 1492 1523 1553 1584 1614 1644 1673 1703 1732
15 1761 1790 1818 1847 1875 1903 1931 1959 1987 2014
16 2041 2068 2095 2122 2148 2175 2201 2227 2253 2279
17 2304 2330 2355 2380 2405 2430 2455 2480 2504 2529
18 2553 2577 2601 2625 2648 2672 2695 2718 2742 2765
19 2788 2810 2833 2856 2878 2900 2923 2945 2967 2989
20 3010 3032 3054 3075 3096 3118 3139 3160 3181 3201
21 3222 3243 3263 3284 3304 3324 3345 3365 3385 3404
22 3424 3444 3464 3483 3502 3522 3541 3560 3579 3598
23 3617 3636 3655 3674 3692 3711 3729 3747 3766 3784
24 3802 3820 3838 3856 3874 3892 3909 3927 3945 3962
25 3979 3997 4014 4031 4048 4065 4082 4099 4116 4133
26 4150 4166 4183 4200 4216 4232 4249 4265 4281 4298
27 4314 4330 4346 4362 4378 4393 4409 4425 4440 4456
28 4472 4487 4502 4518 4533 4548 4564 4579 4594 4609
29 4624 4639 4654 4669 4683 4698 4713 4728 4742 4757
30 4771 4786 4800 4814 4829 4843 4857 4871 4886 4900
31 4914 4928 4942 4955 4969 4983 4997 5011 5024 5038
32 5051 5065 5079 5092 5105 5119 5132 5145 5159 5172
33 5185 5198 5211 5224 5237 5250 5263 5276 5289 5302
34 5315 5328 5340 5353 5366 5378 5391 5403 5416 5428
35 5441 5453 5465 5478 5490 5502 5514 5527 5539 5551
36 5563 5575 5587 5599 5611 5623 5635 5647 5658 5670
37 5682 5694 5705 5717 5729 5740 5752 5763 5775 5786
38 5798 5809 5821 5832 5843 5855 5866 5877 5888 5899
39 5911 5922 5933 5944 5955 5966 5977 5988 5999 6010
40 6021 6031 6042 6053 6064 6075 6085 6096 6107 6117
41 6128 6138 6149 6160 6170 6180 6191 6201 6212 6222
42 6232 6243 6253 6263 6274 6284 6294 6304 6314 6325
43 6335 6345 6355 6365 6375 6385 6395 6405 6415 6425
44 6435 6444 6454 6464 6474 6484 6493 6503 6513 6522
45 6532 6542 6551 6561 6571 6580 6590 6599 6609 6618
46 6628 6637 6646 6656 6665 6675 6684 6693 6702 6712
47 6721 6730 6739 6749 6758 6767 6776 6785 6694 6803
48 6812 6821 6830 6839 6848 6857 6866 6875 6884 6893
49 6902 6911 6920 6928 6937 6946 6955 6964 6972 6981
50 6990 6998 7007 7016 7024 7033 7042 7050 7059 7067
51 7076 7084 7093 7101 7110 7118 7126 7135 7143 7152
52 7160 7168 7177 7185 7193 7202 7210 7218 7226 7235
53 7243 7251 7259 7267 7275 7284 7292 7300 7308 7316
54 7324 7332 7340 7348 7356 7364 7372 7380 7388 7396
Tables / 677
Common Logarithms
N 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
55 7404 7412 7419 7427 7435 7443 7451 7459 7466 7474
56 7482 7490 7497 7505 7513 7520 7528 7536 7543 7551
57 7559 7566 7574 7582 7589 7597 7604 7612 7619 7627
58 7634 7642 7649 7657 7664 7672 7679 7686 7694 7701
59 7709 7716 7723 7731 7738 7745 7752 7760 7767 7774
60 7782 7789 7796 7803 7810 7818 7825 7832 7839 7846
61 7853 7860 7868 7875 7882 7889 7896 7903 7910 7917
62 7924 7931 7938 7945 7952 7959 7966 7973 7980 7987
63 7993 8000 8007 8014 8021 8028 8035 8041 8048 8055
64 8062 8069 8075 8082 8089 8096 8102 8109 8116 8122
65 8129 8136 8142 8149 8156 8162 8169 8176 8182 8189
66 8195 8202 8209 8215 8222 8228 8235 8241 8248 8254
67 8261 8267 8274 8280 8287 8293 8299 8306 8312 8319
68 8325 8331 8338 8344 8351 8357 8363 8370 8376 8382
69 8388 8395 8401 8407 8414 8420 8426 8432 8439 8445
70 8451 8457 8463 8470 8476 8482 8488 8494 8500 8506
71 8513 8519 8525 8531 8537 8543 8549 8555 8561 8567
72 8573 8579 8585 8591 8597 8603 8609 8615 8621 8627
73 8633 8639 8645 8651 8657 8663 8669 8675 8681 8686
74 8692 8698 8704 8710 8716 8722 8727 8733 8739 8745
75 8751 8756 8762 8768 8774 8779 8785 8791 8797 8802
76 8808 8814 8820 8825 8831 8837 8842 8848 8854 8859
77 8865 8871 8876 8882 8887 8893 8899 8904 8910 8915
78 8921 8927 8932 8938 8943 8949 8954 8960 8965 8971
79 8976 8982 8987 8993 8998 9004 9009 9015 9020 9025
80 9031 9036 9042 9047 9053 9058 9063 9069 9074 9079
81 9085 9090 9096 9101 9106 9112 9117 9122 9128 9133
82 9138 9143 9149 9154 9159 9165 9170 9175 9180 9186
83 9191 9196 9201 9206 9212 9217 9222 9227 9232 9238
84 9243 9248 9253 9258 9263 9269 9274 9279 9284 9289
85 9294 9299 9304 9309 9315 9320 9325 9330 9335 9340
86 9345 9350 9355 9360 9365 9370 9375 9380 9385 9390
87 9395 9400 9405 9410 9415 9420 9425 9430 9435 9440
88 9445 9450 9455 9460 9465 9469 9474 9479 9484 9489
89 9494 9499 9504 9509 9513 9518 9523 9528 9533 9538
90 9542 9547 9552 9557 9562 9566 9571 9576 9581 9586
91 9590 9595 9600 9605 9609 9614 9619 9624 9628 9633
92 9638 9643 9647 9652 9657 9661 9666 9671 9675 9680
93 9685 9689 9694 9699 9703 9708 9713 9717 9722 9727
94 9731 9736 9741 9745 9750 9754 9759 9763 9768 9773
95 9777 9782 9786 9791 9795 9800 9805 9809 9814 9818
96 9823 9827 9832 9836 9841 9845 9850 9854 9859 9863
97 9868 9872 9877 9881 9886 9890 9894 9899 9903 9908
98 9912 9917 9921 9926 9930 9934 9939 9943 9948 9952
99 9956 9961 9965 9969 9974 9978 9983 9987 9991 9996
,
Selected
References
MATHEMATICS
Andree, Richard V. Introduction to Calculus with Analytic Geometry. New York: McGraw-
Hill, 1962.
Birkhoff, G., and MacLane, S. A Survey of Modern Algebra. 3d ed. New York: Macmillan,
1965.
Britton, J. R., Kriegh, R. B., and Rutland, Leon W. Calculus and Analytic Geometry. San
Francisco, Calif.: Freeman, 1966.
Buck, R. C. Advanced Calculus. 2d ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1965.
Burkill, J. C. The Theory of Ordinary Differential Equations. New York: Wiley, Halstead Press,
1956.
Coddington, E. A., and Levinson, N. Theory of Ordinary Differential Equations. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1955.
Courant, R. Differential and Integral Calculus. Translated by E. J. McShane. Vols. I and II.
New York: Interscience, 1955 printing.
Cullen, Charles. Matrices and Linear Transformations. 2d ed. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley,
1972.
Garvin, W. W. Introduction to Linear Programming. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1960.
Glicksman, A. M. Linear Programming and The Theory of Games. New York: Wiley, 1963.
Goldberg, S. Introduction to Difference Equations. New York: Wiley, 1958.
Golomb, M., and Shanks, M. Elements of Ordinary Differential Equations. 2d ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1965.
Hadley, G. Linear Algebra. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1961.
Hadley, G. Linear Programming. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1962.
Ince, E. L. Ordinary Differential Equations. New York: Dover, 1953.
Jolley, L. B. W. Summation of Series, 2d ed. New York: Dover, 1961.
Kaplan, W. Advanced Calculus. 2d ed. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1973.
Kemeny, J. G. Snell, J. L., and Thompson, G. L. Finite Markov Chains. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall, 1960.
Kuhn, H. W., and Tucker, A. W., eds. Linear Inequalities and Related Systems. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press, 1956.
Lang, S. A First Course in Calculus. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1964.
Llewellyn, R. W. Linear Programming. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston, 1964.
Luce, R. D., and RaifTa, H. Games and Decisions. New York: Wiley, 1957.
McKinsey, J. C. C. Introduction to the Theory of Games. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1952.
Mirsky, L. An Introduction to Linear Algebra. 2d ed. New York: Oxford University Press,
1961.
679
680 / Selected References
Nelson, A. L., Folley, K. W., and Coral, M. Differential Equations. 3d ed. Boston: D. C. Heath,
1964.
Nemhauser, G. L. Introduction to Dynamic Programming. New York: Wiley, 1966.
Niven, Ivan. Calculus, An Introductory Approach. 2d ed. Princeton, N.J.: D. Van Nostrand,
1966.
Orchard-Hays, W. Advanced Linear Programming Computer Techniques. New York: McGraw-
Hill, 1968.
Perlis, S. Theory of Matrices. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1952.
Peterson, T. S. Elements of Calculus. 2d ed. New York: Harper & Row, 1960.
Richardson, C. H. An Introduction to the Calculus of Finite Differences. New York: Van
Nostrand, Reinhold, 1954.
Sasaki, Kyohei. Introduction to Finite Mathematics and Linear Programming. Belmont, Calif.:
Wadsworth, 1970.
Sisam, C. H., and Atchison, W. F. Analytic Geometry. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston,
1955.
Smail, L. L. Calculus. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts, 1949.
Spitzbart, A., and Bardell, R. H. College Algebra and Plane Trigonometry. 2d. ed. Reading,
Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1964.
Steen, F. H., and Ballou, D. H. Analytic Geometry. 3d ed. Lexington, Mass.: Xerox College
Publishing, 1963.
Stoll, R. F. Linear Algebra and Matrix Theory. New York: Dover, 1969.
Thomas, G. B., Jr. Calculus and Analytic Geometry. 4th ed. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley,
1968.
Thrall, R. M., and Tornheim, L. Vector Spaces and Matrices. New York: Dover, 1970.
Whipkey, K. L., and Whipkey, M. N. The Power of Calculus. 2d ed. New York: Wiley, 1975.
Widder, D. V. Advanced Calculus. 2d ed. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1961.
Wooton, W., and Drooyan, I. Intermediate Algebra. 3d ed. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth, 1972.
Wylie, C. R., Jr. Calculus. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1953.
APPLICATIONS OF MATHEMATICS
IN BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS
Arrow, K., and others. Studies in Linear and Non-Linear Programming. Stanford, Calif.: Stan¬
ford University Press, 1958.
Arrow, K., and Karlin, S. Studies in the Mathematical Theory of Inventory and Production.
Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958.
Beatty, William E. Mathematical Relationships in Business and Economics. Morristown, N.J.:
General Learning Corporation, 1970. '
Beatty, William E. and Gage, R. William. Introductory Calculus for Business and Economics.
Morristown, N.J.: General Learning Corporation, 1973.
Bierman, H., Bonini, C. P., Jr., and Hausman, W. H. Quantitative Analysis for Business Deci¬
sions. 4th ed. Homewood, Ill.: Irwin, 1973.
Bowen, E. K. Mathematics—With Applications in Management and Economics. 3d ed. Home-
wood, Ill.: Irwin, 1972.
Buffa, E. S. Production Inventory System: Planning and Control. Rev. ed. Homewood, Ill.:
Irwin, 1972.
Carr, C. R., and Howe, C. W. Introduction to Quantitative Decision Procedures in Management
and Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1964.
Chiang, Alpha C. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. New York: McGraw-
Hill, 1974.
Churchman, C. W., Ackoff, R. L., and Arnoff, E. L. Introduction to Operations Research. New
York: Wiley, 1957.
Daus, P. H., and Whyburn, W. M. Algebra With Applications to Business and Economics.
Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1961.
Daus, P. H., and Whyburn, W. H. Introduction to Mathematical Analysis. Reading, Mass.:
Addison-Wesley, 1958.
Dorfman, R., Samuelson, P. A., and Solow, R. Linear Programming and Economic Analysis.
New York: McGraw-Hill, 1958.
Selected References / 681
Fowler, F. P., Jr., and Sandberg, E. W. Basic Mathematics for Administration. New York:
Wiley, 1962.
Horowitz, I. An Introduction to Quantitative Business Analysis. 2d ed. New York: McGraw-
Hill, 1972.
Horst, P. Matrix Algebra for Social Scientists. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston, 1963.
Howell, J. E., and Teichroew, D. Mathematical Analysis for Business Decisions. Homewood,
Ill.: Irwin, 1963.
Intriligator, M. D. Mathematical Optimization and Economic Theory. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall, 1971.
Karlin, S. Mathematical Methods and Theory in Games, Programming and Economics. Reading,
Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1959.
Kemeny, J. G., Snell, J. L., and Thompson, G. L. Introduction to Finite Mathematics. 2d ed.
Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1966.
Kooros, A. Elements of Mathematical Economics. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1965.
Levin, R. I., and Kirkpatrick, C. A. Quantitative Approaches to Management. 3d ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1971.
Naddor, E. Inventory Systems. New York: Wiley, 1966.
Sasieni, M., Yaspan, A., and Friedman, L. Operations Research—Methods and Problems. New
York: Wiley, 1959.
Teichroew, D. An Introduction to Management Science, Deterministic Models. New York:
Wiley, 1964.
Tintner, G., and Millham, C. B. Mathematics and Statistics for Economists. 2d ed. New York:
Holt, Rinehart & Winston, 1970.
ECONOMICS
Ackley, G. Macroeconomic Theory. New York: Macmillan, 1961.
Allen, C. L. Elementary Mathematics of Price Theory. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth, 1962.
Baumol, W. J. Economic Dynamics. 3d ed. New York: Macmillan, 1970.
Beach, E. F. Economic Models. New York: Wiley, 1957.
Boulding, K. E. Economic Analysis, 4th ed. New York: Harper & Row, 1966.
Cyert, R. M., and March, J. G. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall, 1963.
Dernburg, T. F., and Dernburg, J. D. Macroeconomic Analysis. Reading, Mass.: Addison-
Wesley, 1969.
Dernburg, T. F., and McDougall, D. M. Macroeconomics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968.
Gale, David. The Theory of Linear Economic Models. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1960.
Henderson, J. M., and Quandt, R. E. Microeconomic Theory, A Mathematical Approach, 2d ed.
New York: McGraw-Hill, 1971.
Hibdon, James E. Price and Welfare Theory. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1969.
Keynes, J. M. The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt,
Brace, Jovanovich, 1935.
Neumann, J. von, and Morgenstern, O. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. 3d ed.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1954.
Samuelson, P. A. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 1947.
Samuelson, P. A. Economics: Introductory Analysis, 9th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1973.
Schultz, H. The Theory and Measurement of Demand. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1957.
Shapiro, Edward. Macroeconomics: Selected Readings. New York: Harcourt, Brace and
World, 1970.
Stonier, A. W., and Hague, D. C. A Textbook of Economic Theory. 4th ed. New York: Wiley,
Halstead Press, 1973.
.
'
Index
Abscissa, 16. See also 607. See also Hessian Compound interest, 118, 521.
Rectangular coordinates determinant; Maximum See also Exponential
Adjoint of a matrix, 566, 577, of a function of n function; Interest; Simple
647-650. See also variables interest
Determinant of a matrix; Boundary conditions. See also Concave function, 611
Inverse of a matrix; Constant of integration; Concavity, 231-236, 240. See
Matrix Initial conditions; also Convexity; Point of
Algebraic function, 50, 174-177, Particular solution inflection; Second
201, 317-318. See also for a difference equation, 512 derivative
Function for a differential equation, 472 concave downward, 231-232,
Alternating series, 299-300. See for integration, 389 240
also Infinite series Break-even analysis, 44-46 concave upward, 231-232, 240
Angle of inclination, 19-20 Conic section, 71-90. See also
Antiderivative, 388 Capital formation, 397-398. See Circle; Ellipse;
Approximate integration, 449- also Integration; Net Hyperbola; Parabola;
458. See also Integration, investment Quadratic equation
approximate methods of Cauchy’s test ratio, 299-300. circular, 72-74
Approximation, 204-206. See See also Convergence of degenerate, 71, 73, 75, 79, 83
also Differential an infinite series directrix of, 71
Area. See also Integration; Proba¬ Circle, 72-74. See also Conic eccentricity of, 71
bility beneath a curve, section elliptic, 72, 74-76
404-408, 414-417 center of, 72 foci of, 71
between two curves, 408-413 radius of, 72-73 hyperbolic, 72, 81-90
negative, 407-408 standard form of, 72-73 parabolic, 72, 77-81
Asymptote, 57-59 Cobweb model, 524 standard forms for, 72-73, 74-
horizontal, 58-59 Cofactor of a matrix, 566. See 75, 77-79, 82-83, 86-87
vertical, 58-59 also Determinant of a Constant. See also Constant of
Average cost, 168, 245-246, 394- matrix; Matrix integration
395. See also Cost Column vector, 542. See also absolute, 6
Average revenue, 170, 266-267, Vector arbitrary, 6
395-396. See also Competitive commodities, 341— numerical, 6
Revenue 344. See also parametric, 6, 33
Complementary Constant of integration, 388-
Base e, 114-115. See also commodities; Demand 389. See also Boundary
Logarithm; Logarithmic surface conditions; Initial
function Complementary commodities, conditions; Integration
Bernoulli equations, 498 341-344. See also Constant product curve, 349-
Bilinear form, 597-598. See also Competive commodities; 351. See also Equal
Vector differentiation Demand surface product curve; Isoquant;
Bivariate regression analysis, Completing the square, 72, 134— Production function
363-364. See also Least 137 Constrained optima, 367-383,
squares estimates; Composite function, 10, 196-197, 607-613. See also Kuhn-
Regression analysis 202, 321, 334-335. Sec Tucker conditions;
Bordered Hessian determinant, also Function Lagrange multipliers
683
684 / Index
Extent, 56-57. See also inverse, 13-14, 55, 117, 194— Harrod model, 523-524
Graphing, general 195, 202, 320-321 Hessian determinant, 605, 607.
methods of linear, 17-25 See also Bordered
logarithmic, 114-117, 185— Hessian determinant;
187, 202, 318-319 Maximum of a function
Factorization, 60-61, 62. See also nonlinear, 50-133 of n variables
Graphing, general polynomial, 50, 177, 201, 317 Higher-order derivative, 207-
methods of power, 108 212. See also Derivative
Fair game, 641. See also Matrix quadratic, 70-90 Homogeneous differential
game; Value of a game range of, 8 equation, 477, 480-484.
Family. See also Parameter smooth, 218-219 See also Differential
of curves, 90 step, 155-159 equation
of straight lines, 33-36 transcendental, 50 Homogeneous function, 348-349,
Finite discontinuity, 152. See trigonometric, 123-131, 133, 477, 480-484
also Discontinuity 191-193, 202 Hyperbola, 72, 81-90. See also
Finite game, 640. See also Game value of, 9 Conic section
theory; Matrix game Function value, 9. See also asymptotes of, 82-83, 86
First derivative, 161-230. See Function center of, 81
also Derivative; equilateral, 82, 86-90
Maximum; Minimum generalized equilateral, 87-90
interpretation of, 165-168 Game matrix, 640-641. See also of Fermat, 87
First difference, 510. See also Dominance; Game rectangular, 82, 86-90
Difference equation theory; Matrix game; standard form of, 82-83, 86
Foci of a conic, 71. See also Minimax solution; Payoff transverse axis of, 81
Conic section matrix; Saddle point;
Frequency function, 414-417, Strategies; Value of a Identity, trigonometric, 129. See
464-467. See also Area; game also Trigonometric
Joint frequency function; Game theory, 639-657. See also function
Probability Dominance; Game Identity matrix, 552-553. See
Function, 8-10, 323-324. See matrix; Matrix game; also Diagonal matrix;
also Consumption Minimax solution; Payoff Inverse of a matrix
function; Cost function; matrix; Saddle point; Imaginary locus, 61-62. See also
Curve; Demand function; Strategies; Value of a Locus
Growth function; game Implicit differentiation, 213-215.
Joint-cost function; Gaussian elimination, 574-577. See also Differentiation
Production function; See also Inverse of a Implicit function, 213-215, 335—
Rate of change of a matrix 338. See also Function;
function; Relation; General solution. See also Implicit differentiation
Revenue function; Constant of integration; Implicit prices, 635. See also
Supply function; Particular solution Dual; Imputed prices;
Variable of a difference equation, Shadow prices
algebraic, 50, 174-177, 201, 512-514 Improper integral, 402. See also
317-318 of a differential equation, Convergence;
composite, 10, 196-197, 202, 471-475 Divergence; Integral
321, 334-335 Generic constant, 472. See also Imputed prices, 635. See also
concave, 611 Constant of integration; Dual; Implicit prices;
continuous, 151, 159 Differential equation Shadow prices
convex, 611 Gompertz function, 120-121. Income, 46-48, 172-174, 396-
decreasing, 219-220, 230 See also Function; 397, 506-507, 525, 526.
dependent variable of, 8-9, 141, Growth function See also Consumption
324 Graph, 18. See also Equation; function; Consumption
differentiable, 162 Locus model
discontinuous, 151-159 Graphical solution of a matrix Increasing function, 219-220,
discrete, 155-159 game, 653-656. See also 230. See also First
domain of, 8 Game theory; Matrix derivative; Function
explicit, 213 game; Minimax solution Indefinite integral, 388-398.
exponential, 111-114, 117-122, Graphing. See also Asymptote; See also Constant of
187-190, 202, 252-254, Extent; Factorization; integration; Integration
319 Intercepts; Maximum; interpretation of, 388-389
frequency, 414-417, 464-467 Minimum; Point of Independent variable, 8-9, 141,
Gompertz, 120-121 inflection; Symmetry 324. See also Function;
growth, 119-122 general methods of, 50-70 Variable
homogeneous, 348-349, 477, using first and second Indeterminate expression, 7, 20.
480-484 derivatives, 219-244 See also Indeterminate
implicit, 213-215, 335-338 Growth function, 119-122. See form; Undefined
increasing, 219-220, 230 also Curve; Function expression
independent variable of, 8-9, biological, 119-120 Indeterminate form, 148-149,
141, 324 Gompertz, 120-121 289-296. See also
integrable, 400 learning, 121-122 Discontinuity;
Index / 687
Indeterminate form (Continued) Simpson’s rule, 449, 451- Kuhn-Tucker conditions, 375—
Indeterminate expression; 453, 455-458 380, 611-613. See also
L’Hospital’s rule; Limit Taylor’s expansion, 449, Constrained optima
Type & 148-149, 289-290, 296 453-458
Type §, 148-149, 289-290, 296 trapezoidal rule, 449-451,
Type oo-0, 291-295, 296 455-458 Lagrange multipliers, 368-375,
Type 1®, 291-295, 296 definite, 399-429 607-611. See also
Type 0°, 291-295, 296 double, 459-461, 464-467 Constrained optima
Type oo°, 291-295, 296 fundamental theorem of, Law of diminishing marginal
Type oo — oo, 295, 296 404 productivity, 346
Indifference curve, 353. See also indefinite, 388-392 Least squares estimates, 363-364,
Indifference map; Utility multiple, 459-463 598-599. See also
Indifference map, 353. See also partial, 459 Regression analysis
Indifference curve; by partial fractions, 438-442 Leibnitz, Gottfried, 139
Utility by parts, 435-437 Leontief matrix, 615. See also
Infinite discontinuity, 152. See by rationalization, 443-447 Input-output analysis
also Discontinuity by standard forms, 390-392, L’Hospital’s rule, 289-296. See
Infinite games, 640. See also 431-434 also Indeterminate form;
Game theory; Matrix by substitutions, 443-448 Limit
game Intercepts Limit, 141-149. See also
Infinite sequence, 298. See also of a curve, 51 Asymptote; Convergence;
Difference equation, of a straight line, 18-19 Divergence;
solution sequence of; Interest. See also Compound Indeterminate form;
Infinite series; interest; Simple interest L’Hospital’s rule
Recursion formula compound, 118, 521 of a function, 141-149
Infinite series, 298-315. See also simple, 521 left-hand, 144-146
Convergence of an infinite Interval of convergence, 304. See properties of, 146-149
series; Infinite sequence; also Infinite series; Power right-hand, 144-146
Maclaurin’s series; series; Radius of of a sequence, 298
Recursion formula; convergence of a series, 298
Taylor’s series Inventory models, 285-288, of a variable, 141-142
alternating, 299-300 539-540 Limits of integration, 402. See
convergent, 298-299 Inverse of a function, 13-14, also Definite integral
divergent, 298-299 55, 117, 194-195, 202, Linear dependence, 585-588.
oscillating, 298, 520 320-321. See also See also Rank;
Inflection, point of, 236-239, 240. Function Simultaneous linear
See also Second Inverse of a matrix, 569-584. See equations
derivative also Determinant of a Linear difference equation, 511—
Initial conditions. See also matrix; Elementary 540. See also Difference
Boundary conditions; operations; Game equation
Constant of integration; matrix; Gaussian Linear differential equation, 477,
Particular solution elimination; Identity 491-498. See also
for a difference equation, 512 matrix; Input-output Differential equation
for a differential equation, analysis; Linear Linear equation, 17-25. See also
472 programming; Markov Linear function;
for integration, 389 chain process; Simultaneous linear
Inner product of two vectors, Simultaneous linear equations; Straight line
548. See also Vector equations, solutions of Linear function, 17-25. See also
Input-output analysis, 614-618 by adjoint and determinant, Function; Linear
Integrable function, 400. See 577-579 equation; Maximization;
also Integration by canonical procedure using Minimization; Straight
Integral, 388. See also row or column line; Vector
Integration operations, 574-577 differentiation
definite, 402 of a partitioned matrix, Linear programming, 619-635.
double, 459-461, 464-467 580-582 See also Constrained
improper, 402 Inverse of a relation, 13-14. See optima; Inverse of a
indefinite, 388 also Relation matrix; Simplex method
multiple, 459-463 Isocost curve, 351 artificial variables of, 625-626,
particular, 388 Isoquant, 349-351. See also 629, 633
Integrand, 388. See also Constant product curve; constraints of, 620-621, 624-
Integration Equal product curve 625, 629, 631-632
Integrating factor, 491-492. See dual of, 631-635
also Differential equation feasible solution of, 621, 624-
Integration, 387-467. See also Joint-cost function, 340-341. See 625
Constant of integration; also Cost function geometric solution of, 621-625
Integral; Multiple Joint frequency function, 414— of a matrix game, 656-657
integration 417, 464-467. See also objective function of, 620-621,
approximate methods of, 449- Area; Frequency 631-632
458 function; Probability primal of, 631-632
688 / Index
Nonlinear curve, 50-133. See Initial conditions general equation of, 70-71
also Curve; Function of a difference equation, 512—
Nonsingular matrix, 570. See 514 Radian measure, 124-128. See
also Determinant of a of a differential equation, 471— also Trigonometric
matrix; Inverse of a 475 function
matrix; Singular matrix Payoff matrix, 640-641. See also Radius of convergence, 304. See
Nonstrictly determined game, Game matrix; Matrix also Infinite series;
643-645. See also Game game Interval of convergence;
matrix; Matrix game; Period analysis, 509. See also Power series
Minimax solution; Mixed Difference equation Range. See also Function;
strategy Point locus, 61-62. See also Relation; Variable
Non-zero-sum game, 640. See Locus of a function, 8
also Game theory; Point of inflection, 236-244. See of a relation, 8
Matrix game; Zero-sum also Second derivative of a variable, 6
game Polar coordinates, 129-131. See Rank of a matrix, 585-588. See
Null matrix, 553-554. See also also Coordinates of a also Linear dependence;
Matrix point; Function; Matrix; Simultaneous
Numbers Trigonometric function linear equations
complex, 7 Polynomial, 50. See also Rate of change of a function. See
imaginary, 7 Polynomial function also Derivative
real, 7 Polynomial function, 50, 177, average, 167-168
201, 317. See also instantaneous, 167-168
Objective function, 620, 631-632. Function, polynomial Rate of technical substitution,
See also Linear Postmultiply, 547. See also 349. See also Equal
programming Matrix operations, product curve
Operator, 510 multiplication; Reciprocal substitution, 447-448.
Ordinate, 17. See also Premultiply See also Integration, by
Rectangular coordinates Power function. 111. See also substitution
Oscillating series, 298, 520. See Exponential function; Rectangular coordinates, 16-17.
also Difference equation, Function See also Coordinates of a
solution sequence of; Power series, 304-315. See also point; Polar coordinates
Infinite series Infinite series; axes of, 16-17
Maclaurin’s series; origin of, 16
Parabola, 72, 77-81. See also Taylor’s series plotting points in, 17
Conic section Premultiply, 547. See also quadrants of, 16-17
axis of, 77 Matrix operations, Recursion formula, 298. See also
orientation of, 77-79 multiplication; Infinite sequence; Infinite
standard form of, 77-79 Postmultiply series
vertex of, 77 Primal, 631-632. See also Reduced form equations, 502.
Parameter, 6, 33. See also Dual; Linear See also Economic model;
Constant, parametric; programming Structural equations
Family, of curves Principal minors of a matrix, Regression analysis, 363-364,
Pareto, Vilfredo, 107 603. See also Matrix; 598-599. See also
Pareto’s law, 107-109. See also Minors of a matrix Bivariate regression
Power function; Scientific Probability, 414-417, 464-467. analysis; Least squares
notation See also Area; Double estimates; Multivariate
Partial demand, 341-344. See integral; Frequency regression analysis
also Demand surface function; Integral Relation, 8. See also Function;
Partial derivative, 324-328. See Producers’ surplus, 418, 422-425. Variable
also Derivative; Mixed See also Consumers’ binary, 8
partial derivative; surplus dependent variable of, 8
Partial differentiation Production function, 346-349, domain of, 8
Partial differential, 330-331. 351-352, 605. See also independent variable of, 8
See also Differential Euler’s theorem; inverse, 8
Partial differentiation, 324-328. Function; Marginal range of, 8
See also Differentiation; product Relative maximum, 220-228,
Partial derivative linear homogeneous, 348-349 230, 235. See also
Partial elasticities of demand, Product transformation curve, Maximum
344-345. See also 98-104 Relative minimum, 220-228,
Demand surface; Properties of limits, 146-149. 230, 235. See also
Elasticity; Partial See also Indeterminate Minimum
differentiation form; L'Hospital’s rule; Returns to outlay, 352. See also
Particular integral, 388. See also Limit Equal product curve;
Boundary conditions; Expansion path; Returns
Constant of integration; Quadratic form, 595-597. See to scale; Ridge line; Scale
Initial conditions also Vector differentiation line
Particular solution. See also Quadratic function, 70-90. See Returns to scale, 351-352. See
Boundary conditions; also Conic section; also Equal product curve;
Constant of integration; Function Expansion path; Returns
690 / Index
Returns to scale (Continued) Simplex method, 625-631. See process, 661. See also
to outlay; Ridge line; also Inverse of a matrix; Markov chain process
Scale line Linear programming Stationary probability
Revenue, from taxation, 271-275. steps in solution by, 626 distribution, 662. See also
See also Revenue function tableau of, 625-626 Markov chain process
Revenue, 44-46, 170-171, 266- variations in, 631 Stationary value, 535-536. See
271, 395-396, 425-429, Simpson’s rule, 449, 451-453, also Difference equation;
605. See also Demand; 455-458. See also Equilibrium
Elasticity Integration, approximate of a difference equation,
average, 170, 266-267, 395-396 methods of 535-536
and elasticity of demand, 266- Simultaneous linear equations, Steady state, 662-666 See also
271 26-32, 585-592. See also Equilibrium; Markov
marginal, 170, 266-271, 395- Economic model; Linear chain process
396 dependence; Rank Step function, 155-159. See also
total, 170, 266, 395-396, 605 consistent, 27, 28, 587-588 Function
Ridge line, 350. See also Equal dependent, 27, 28, 585-588 Straight line. See also Linear
product curve; Expansion inconsistent, 27, 28, 587-588 equation; Straight lines
path; Returns to outlay; independent, 27, 28, 585-588 general equation of, 18, 25
Returns to scale; Scale solution of, 28-32, 589-592 horizontal, 25
line by elimination, 29-32 intercept form of, 22-23, 25
by matrix algebra, 29-32, intercepts of, 18-19
Saddle point, 357-358, 641-642. 589-592; Cramer’s rule point-slope form of, 23-24, 25
See also Game matrix; 589-590; inversion slope-intercept form of, 24,
Matrix game; Maximum; procedures, 589 25
Minimax solution; by substitution 29-32 two-point form of, 21-22, 25
Minimum; Second Sine, 125, 127, 130. See also vertical, 24, 25
derivative Trigonometric function Straight lines, 17-36. See also
Samuelson’s interaction model, Singular matrix, 570. See also Simultaneous linear
537-538 Determinant of a matrix; equations; Straight line
Scalar, 545. See also Matrix Inverse of a matrix; families of, 33-35
Scale line, 351-352. See also Nonsingular matrix intersecting, 27-32
Equal product curve; Slack variables, 625-626, 629, parallel, 26
Expansion path; Returns 633. See also Linear perpendicular, 26'
to outlay; Returns to programming; Simplex Strategies, 640. See also Game
scale; Ridge line method matrix; Matrix game;
Scientific notation, 112 Slope of a line, 19-20, 161. See Minimax solution; Saddle
Secant, 125, 161-162. See also also First derivative; point
Trigonometric function Rate of change of a mixed, 641-642
Second derivative, 207, 231-244. function; Tangent to a pure, 644-646
See also Concavity; curve Strictly determined game, 641.
Derivative; Partial Smooth function, 218-219. See See also Game matrix;
derivative; Point of also Continuity; Matrix game; Minimax
inflection Function; Second solution; Saddle point
interpretation of, 231-232 derivative Structural equations, 502. See
Separable differential equation, Solution. See also Difference also Economic model;
477-480. See also equation; Differential Reduced form equations
Differential equation equation; Equation; Supply function, 40-42, 43-44,
Sequence, 298. See also Infinite Simultaneous linear 92-98, 170, 257-265. See
sequence equations also Demand function;
Series, 298-315. See also Infinite of a difference equation Market equilibrium
series general, 512-514 linear, 40-42, 43-44
Set, 2-5. See also Venn Diagram particular, 512-514 quadratic, 92-98
complement, 4 of a differential equation Symmetric matrix, 555. See also
defining relation of, 2 general, 471-475 Matrix
difference, 4 particular, 471-475 Symmetry
element of, 2 of simultaneous linear with respect to an axis, 51-55
empty, 3 equations, 28-32, 589- with respect to the origin,
intersection, 3 592 51-55
proper subset, 3 Square matrix, 541. See also with respect to a point, 55-56
subset, 3 Matrix with respect to a straight line,
union, 3 Standard forms for conics, 72- 55-56
universal, 4 73, 74-75, 77-79, 82-83, with respect to the x-axis,
universe, 4 86-87. See also Circle; 51-55
Shadow prices, 635. See also Conic section; Ellipse; with respect to the y-axis,
Dual; Implicit prices; Hyperbola; Parabola 51-55
Imputed prices Standard forms for integration, Tangent of an angle, 19-21, 125,
Simple interest, 521. See also 390-392, 431-434. Sec 127, 130, 161, 204, 326.
Compound interest; also Integration See also Angle of
Interest States of a Markov chain inclination; First
Index / 691
Tangent of an angle (Continued) 458. See also Integration, game; Minimax solution;
derivative; Slope of a approximate methods of Strategies
line; Trigonometric Trigonometric function, 123-131, Variable, 6-7, 8. See also
function 133, 191-193, 202. See Function; Relation
Tangent to a curve, 162. See also Function continuous, 6
also First derivative; cosecant, 125-129 dependent, 8-9, 141, 324
Rate of change of a cosine, 125-129 discrete, 6
function; Slope of a line identities, 129 independent, 8-9, 141, 324
Taxation polar coordinates, 129-131 range of, 6
maximization of monopolistic radian measure of, 124-125 Vector, 542-543. See also Inner
profit under, 280-284 secant, 125-129 product of two vectors;
maximization of revenue from, sine, 125-129 Matrix
271-275 tangent, 125-129, 326 column, 542
Taylor’s series, 308-315. See also components of, 542-543
Infinite series; dimension of, 542-543
Maclaurin’s series of functions, 595
Taylor’s theorem, 308-315, 321- Undefined expression, 7, 20. See row, 543
322, See also Taylor’s also Indeterminate Vector differentiation, 593-600.
series expression; Indeterminate See also Maximization;
Technological matrix, 615. See form Minimization; Partial
also Input-output Undetermined multipliers, 368- differentiation; Vector
analysis; Leontief matrix 375, 607-611. See also of a bilinear form, 597-598
Total derivative, 332-335. See Lagrange multipliers of a linear function, 593-595
also Derivative Utility function, 352-354, of a quadratic form, 595-597
Total differential, 330-331. See 610-611. See also of a vector of functions, 595
also Differential Marginal analysis, of Venn Diagram, 4. See also Set
Transcendental function, 50. See utility Von Neumann, John, 639
also Function constrained maximization of,
Transition probabilities, 661. See 380-383
also Markov chain
process Zero-sum game, 640. See also
Transpose of a matrix, 554-557, Game theory; Matrix
558-559. See also Matrix Value of a game, 641, 645. See game; Non-zero-sum
Trapezoidal rule, 449-451, 455- also Game matrix; Matrix game
1
'
81 82 83 9 8 7
SBN 06-041762-