0% found this document useful (0 votes)
29 views

Topic 24: Frontiers of Microeconomics

1) Asymmetric information occurs when different parties to a transaction have unequal access to information. This can lead to adverse selection, where hidden private information is exploited before a deal, and moral hazard, where hidden actions are exploited after a deal. 2) Examples of adverse selection include used car markets where sellers know more than buyers, and insurance markets where policyholders know their own health risks better than insurers. This can cause markets to collapse if high-risk parties are all that remain. 3) Moral hazard arises in principal-agent problems like employment, where hidden actions like shirking harm the uninformed principal. It also affects insurance, where policyholders may take less care of insured assets. Better

Uploaded by

Annie Dark
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
29 views

Topic 24: Frontiers of Microeconomics

1) Asymmetric information occurs when different parties to a transaction have unequal access to information. This can lead to adverse selection, where hidden private information is exploited before a deal, and moral hazard, where hidden actions are exploited after a deal. 2) Examples of adverse selection include used car markets where sellers know more than buyers, and insurance markets where policyholders know their own health risks better than insurers. This can cause markets to collapse if high-risk parties are all that remain. 3) Moral hazard arises in principal-agent problems like employment, where hidden actions like shirking harm the uninformed principal. It also affects insurance, where policyholders may take less care of insured assets. Better

Uploaded by

Annie Dark
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 16

TOPIC 24

Frontiers of microeconomics

ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• It is generally assumed all parties to a
transaction have access to the same information.

• A difference in access to relevant information is


called information asymmetry.
– Some parties may have private information that others
don’t have.

• This has implications for how markets work.

1
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• A seller may have better information than buyer
– when buying a second-hand car, vendor knows more
than buyer.

• Buyer may have better information than seller


– when buying health insurance, buyer knows more
than seller

• In context of the global financial crisis


– the borrowers (the sellers of a financial contract) may
have had better info than the lenders (the buyers).

ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• Labour Market
– Workers may have better information than employer &
may undersupply effort if their effort is unobserved.

• Insurance Market
– Having purchased insurance a consumer may
undersupply effort in taking care of the insured object
if the insurer cannot observe this.

2
TYPES OF ASYMMETRIC
INFORMATION
• Info asymmetries can have effects before a
transaction is done by hidden information.
– Taking advantage of private information before a deal
is done is called pre-contractual opportunism or
adverse selection.

• Info asymmetries can also have effects after a


transaction is done by hidden action.
– Taking advantage of private information after a deal is
done is post-contractual opportunism or moral
hazard.

ADVERSE SELECTION – EXAMPLE 1


• The market for used cars (lemon’s problem)
– The vendor of a used car has better info about its
quality than a potential purchaser.
– If it is lemon – a poor quality vehicle – the vendor
may have an incentive to not reveal this info.
– Because of this buyers are apprehensive about
getting a ‘lemon’.
• Potential purchasers of what are claimed to be good cars
will underbid because there is a chance the car is a lemon.
• But at a lower bid price fewer (perhaps no) better quality
used cars will be offered.
– The market for quality cars may disappear!

3
ADVERSE SELECTION – EXAMPLE 2
• The market for labour
– Workers (sellers of labour) vary in their abilities and
they may know their own abilities better than do the
firms that hire them.
– When a firm cuts the wage it pays, the more
talented workers are more likely to quit, knowing
they are better able to find other employment.
– Conversely, a firm may choose to pay an above-
equilibrium wage to attract better workers.

ADVERSE SELECTION – EXAMPLE 3


• The market for insurance
– Buyers of health insurance know more about their
own health problems than do insurance companies.
– Because people with greater hidden health
problems are more likely to buy health insurance
than are other people
• the premium of health insurance reflects the costs of a
sicker-than-average person.
– As a result, people in average health may decide
not to buy it.
• This leaves insurance firms with only high health risks
– So eventually no insurance may be offered.

4
ADVERSE SELECTION – SUMMARY
• Nature of the Problem
– In these examples one side of the market (buyer or
seller) has incentives to conceal info from the other
(seller or buyer).
• Thus it is a hidden information issue.
– One side of the market won’t know the hidden info but
assume the other side has incentives to conceal it.

• Implications
– In extreme situations the market may disappear
completely even though buyers want to buy at prices
sellers would be willing to accept.
– A market fails to exist.

ADVERSE SELECTION – SOLUTIONS


• Signalling is an action taken by an informed
party to reveal private information to an
uninformed party.
– For example, the use of highly paid celebrities in
advertising signals the quality of a product to
consumers.
– Providing evidence of health to insurance companies.
– University degrees signal the abilities of a worker to
the employers.
• A signal must be costly.
– If a signal were free, everyone would use it and it
would convey no information.

5
ADVERSE SELECTION – SOLUTIONS
• Screening is an action taken by an uninformed
party to induce an informed party to reveal
information.
– A person buying a used car may ask that a mechanic
check it over before the sale.
• A seller who refuses this request reveals that the car is most
likely a lemon.
– An insurance company may require medical
examination or exclude claims for a certain period
• A buyer refusing to comply reveals that he has pre-existing
health issues

MORAL HAZARD – EXAMPLE 1


• The Principal-Agent problem
– Tendency of a person who is imperfectly monitored
to engage in dishonest or otherwise undesirable
behaviour.
– the employment relation – the worker is agent,
employer the principle.
• If an employer cannot monitor a worker (check that they
are working hard) there are incentives for workers to be
slack.
• This is shirking - involves agents undersupplying effort as
a hidden action.
– the board-shareholder relation – the board is agent
working for shareholders’.

6
MORAL HAZARD – EXAMPLE 2
• Property insurance
– People who fully insure property may not ‘take care’
of the property sufficiently.
• Firms with fire insurance may be less likely to buy fire
extinguishers
• Similarly households may locate their homes near rivers
with a risk of flooding or near forests with bushfire risks
because insurance companies / governments contribute to
disaster relief while they enjoy the scenic views
• Persons with car insurance may drive more recklessly or
leave their cars unsecured more often

MORAL HAZARD – SUMMARY


• Nature of the Problem
– In these cases one side of a market has incentives to
conceal their behaviour after a deal is done.
• Thus these are hidden action issues.
– One side of the market won’t know the hidden
behaviour/action but assume the other side has
incentives to conceal it.

• Implications
– Again the side of the market subject to the info
disadvantage will change the way they do business &
in extreme cases may not do business at all.

7
MORAL HAZARD – SOLUTIONS
• Better monitoring
– Firms checking on workers through technology such
as spy cams, biometrics, etc
– Parents hiring babysitters have been known to plant
hidden video cameras (nanny cams) in their homes

• Efficiency wages
– Employers may choose to pay their workers a wage
that is above the equilibrium wage
– A worker who earns an above-equilibrium wage is less
likely to shirk, because if they are caught and fired it
will be very hard for them to find a similar high-paying
job.

MORAL HAZARD – SOLUTIONS


• Delayed bonus payments
– If a worker is caught shirking they miss their year-end
annual bonus.

• Employee stock ownership


– Firms can give workers stocks or stock options that
allow them to share in the profitability of the company
directly.
– The ownership stake aligns incentives of the
employees to those of the firm.

8
IN GENERAL
• Asymmetric information gives new reasons to
be wary of markets.
– When some people know more than others markets
may not put resources to their best uses.
• Sellers of high quality cars find it hard to sell their cars
• People with good health may have trouble buying low-cost
insurance
– Indeed, in extreme cases, markets may fail to exist.

POLITICAL ECONOMY
• The application of economic concepts and
methods to the study of how government
works.

• One particular area on interest is majority


voting
– It involves making decisions by taking a vote on
alternatives & choosing the most preferred
alternative.
– Assume that there are three alternatives A, B, C
• what you want after a vote is an ordering telling you which
alternative people prefer most.
– This involves problems.

9
DESIRABLE PROPERTIES FOR A
VOTING SYSTEM
• Transitivity
– if A is preferred over B, and B is preferred to C, then
A is also preferred to C.

• Independence of irrelevant alternatives


– the ranking between any two outcomes A and B
should not depend on whether some third outcome
C is also available.

CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX


• The Condorcet paradox occurs when majority
rule fails to produce transitive preferences for
society.
– Consider the following example

10
CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX
• Following the majority voting system
– Star Wars is majority preferred over Harry Potter.
• Kirk and McCoy both have this ordering
– Harry Potter is majority preferred over Police
Academy.
• David and Spock both have this ordering
– But Police Academy is majority preferred over Star
Wars.
• Spock and McCoy both have this ordering)

• The preference ordering is not transitive


– you cannot choose which is best using ‘majority rule’.

CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX


• One implication of the Condorcet paradox is
that the order in which things are voted on can
affect the result.
– Conducting a vote (Pairwise)
• Start with a comparison of Star Wars and Harry Potter and
then compare the winner with Police Academy

• In a comparison of Star Wars and Harry Potter, Star Wars


is the winner (majority preferred)

11
CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX
– Conducting a vote (Pairwise)
• Now compare Star Wars with Police Academy

• Police Academy is majority preferred over Star Wars.


– Police Academy is chosen.

CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX


– Conducting a vote (Pairwise)
• Now start with a comparison of Harry Potter and Police
Academy and then compare the winner with Star Wars

• In a comparison of Police Academy and Harry Potter, Harry


Potter is the winner (majority preferred)

12
CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX
– Conducting a vote (Pairwise)
• Now compare Harry Potter with Star Wars

• Star wars is majority preferred over Harry Potter.


– Star Wars is chosen.

• The lesson is that majority voting by itself does


not tell us what outcome a society wants.

BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Recently, behavioural economics has emerged
– economists make use of psychology to examine
how people actually make decisions rather than
relying on the assumption of rationality.

• The bases on which people do make decisions


is rich
– a fact appreciated even by Adam Smith in his
Theory of Moral Sentiments.

13
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Experiments by psychologists and economists
have shown that people are not always rational
– there are a number of systematic mistakes that
many people make
• People are overconfident – favour positive outcomes over
negative outcomes; e.g. creation of bubbles in housing
markets
• People give too much weight to a small number of vivid
observations ; e.g. fear of natural disasters
• People are reluctant to change their minds; they interpret
evidence according to their prior beliefs; considering
corona virus as being similar to earlier types of flu

BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Another insight from behavioural economics is
that people care about fairness
• The ultimatum game demonstrates that players
care whether the outcome is ‘fair’ or not
– Structure of the game
• $100 is to be split between two people.
• Player A will propose to share the $100 with B.
• For example A might offer B $30 and keep $70 for herself.
• If B accepts the offer from A, the money is split as A
proposed.
• If B does not agree to the split then neither party gets
anything.
– Problem: How much should A offer B?

14
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Solution to the game
– Rationality suggests
• A should offer B the smallest amount possible amount (say
1 dollar) and keep the other $99 for herself.
• B should accept this since something is better than nothing
(which is what she gets after rejecting).

– Experimental economics indicates


• A’s offer is closer to a 50:50 split
• Moreover if A offers B much less than this B declines. hy?
• This suggests that B not only wants some gains here but
wants a ‘fair’ share of the gains.
• This is not rational but is widely-observed.

BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Relevance to business decisions
– Assume I want to sell you my car.
• The minimum I will accept for my car is $5000 and
• the maximum you will pay is $6000.
– We should be able to agree at a price between
$5000-$6000.
– But suppose I will only sell for $5999 so I get $999
worth of surplus leaving you with $1. Will you
accept?
• You might but you might sense that I am getting an unfair
share of the surplus and not accept even though – as
person B in the ultimatum game – you would be better-off.

15
SUMMARY
• In many transactions, information is
asymmetric.
– With hidden actions, principals may be concerned
that they suffer from problems of moral hazard.
– With hidden information buyers (or sellers) may be
concerned about adverse selection.

• The Condorcet paradox shows that majority


rule may not produce transitive preferences for
society.

SUMMARY
• The study of psychology & economics reveals
that human decision-making is more complex
than assumed in conventional economic
theory.
– People do not always reflect self-interest alone -
they care about the fairness of economic outcomes.
– Thinking about things in this way offers new insights
about a basic issue of economics – namely how
people do a deal & how they share the ‘gains from
trade’.

16

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy