Final Examination With Answers: Economics 210A: December, 2016, Ted Bergstrom, UCSB
Final Examination With Answers: Economics 210A: December, 2016, Ted Bergstrom, UCSB
Question 1.
A) State the weak axiom of revealed preference, the strong axiom of revealed
preference and the generalized axiom of revealed preference.
1
If choices maximize x1 +x2 subject to a budget constraint, it must be that
if (x01 , x02 ) is directly revealed preferred to (x1 , x2 ) then x01 + x02 ≥ x1 + x2 .
By the transitivity of the ordering of the real numbers it follows that if
(x01 , x02 ) is revealed preferred to (x1 , x2 ) either directly or indirectly, then
x01 + x02 ≥ x1 + x2 . Therefore it cannot be that (x01 , x02 ) is revealed preferred
to (x1 , x2 ) and x1 + x2 > x01 + x02 . So GARP is satisfied.
2
Wilbur’s indirect utility function is
!1/2
m
v(p, m) =
p1 + 2p2
In city A, his expected utility would be
1 1 1 1
v(1, 2, 125) + v(2, 2, 196) = 5 + 7 = 6
2 2 2 2
In city B, his expected utility would be
1/2
m
v(1, 1, m) = .
3
So he will prefer city B to city A if
1/2
m
> 6.
3
This is the case if m > 108.
C) Wilbur’s friend Charlotte has a von Neumann Morgenstern utility func-
tion
1
u(x1 , x2 ) = min{x1 , x2 }.
2
If Charlotte and Wilbur face the same prices and have the same incomes,
how will their consumptions differ? If Charlotte and Wilbur both believe that
the probability distributions over their prices and incomes in Cities A and B
are as in Part B, will they ever have different preferences about which city
to live in? Explain.
If Wilbur and Charlotte face the same prices and have the same incomes,
they will consume the same bundles. This is seen because their vNM utility
functions, which are monotone transformations of each other, represent the
same preferences over bundles consumed with certainty.
They have different attitudes toward risk, however. Wilbur is more risk
averse than Charlotte. Charlotte’s expected utility from City A would be
1
2
25 + 12 49 = 37. Her expected utility from City B would be m/3. So she
would prefer City A to City B if m < 111 and woud prefer B to A if m > 111.
Question 3. Consider a consumer who consumes three goods and has utility
function
U (x1 , x2 , x3 ) = (x1 + b1 )α (x2 + b2 )β (x3 + b3 )γ
3
where bi ≥ 0 for i = 1, . . . 3 and where α > 0, β > 0, and γ > 0.
A) Why can you assume that α + β + γ = 1 without loss of generality?
1
The function V (x1 , x2 , x3 ) = U (x1 , x2 , x3 ) α+β+γ is a monotone increasing
transformation of U and thus represents the same preferences. Let α0 =
β γ
α
α+β+γ
, β 0 = α+β+γ , and γ 0 = α+β+γ . We see that
0 0 0
V (x1 , x2 , x3 ) = (x1 + b1 )α (x2 + b2 )β (x3 + b3 )γ
where α0 + β 0 + γ 0 = 1.
B)Does this consumer have homothetic preferences? Explain.
Since preferences are continuous and strictly convex, the demand function
is a well-defined, single valued function. We found in Part A that there is no
loss of generality in assuming that α + β + γ = 1.
A shortcut for finding a solution if one exists is to define zi = xi + bi . We
can rewrite the problem as Maximize
4
the zi ’s, with an inequality constraint. Thus it must be that at an interior
maximum,
α
z1 = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 )
p1
β
z2 = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 )
p2
γ
z3 = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 )
p3
Then
α
x1 = z1 − b1 = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 ) − b1 (1)
p1
β
x2 = z2 − b2 = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 ) − b2 (2)
p2
γ
x3 = z3 − b3 = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 ) − b3 (3)
p3
These three equations must be satisfied if there is an interior solution
where x1 > 0, x2 > 0 and x3 > 0.
I gave full credit to those who found this necessary condition for there
to be an interior solution, whether or not they properly characterized the
corner solutions.
A full characterization of corner solutions is a little complicated and I did
not expect everyone to carry this out in detail during the exam. It is not
true, as some exam-takers claimed, that if Equation 3 tells us that x3 < 0,
then there will be a solution with x3 = 0 and x1 and x2 given by Equations
1 and 2.
But, for your enjoyment, I will sketch a full description of corner solutions
and how you would find them. If there is no interior solution, there must be a
corner solution. In general, with three goods, there are 6 possible corner so-
lutions. In three of these, two goods are consumed in positive quantities and
one is not consumed. Since the demand function is single-valued, we know
that exactly one of these corner solutions will obtain. Equations 1-3 don’t
give us an immediate answer to which of them it is. A corner solution must
satisfy the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. These involve a system of 3 inequalities,
along with complementary slackness conditions for each of them.
In general, solving a system of 3 Kuhn-Tucker inequalities can be a pain in
the neck, because there are 6 possible places to look for a corner solution. It
5
could be that the solution has any two of the variables at interior values and
one at a boundary value, or it could be that it has only one of the variables
at an interior value and the others at boundary values. For this problem, our
search is easier, because there is a fairly simple condition that tells us where
a solution could possibly be.
Explaining the answer is a little easier i we use the notation α1 = α, α2 =
β and α3 = γ. The consumer’s maximization problem can be represented as
Maximize
U (z1 , z2 , z3 )) = α1 ln z + 1 + α2 ln z2 + α3 ln z3
subject to the constraints
p1 z1 + p2 z2 + p3 z3 = m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 z3
and zi ≥ bi for i = 1, 2, 3.
Where the Lagrangean for this problem is
3
X
L(z1 , z2 , z3 , λ) = αi ln zi +λ ((m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 z3 ) − (p1 z1 + p2 z2 + p3 z3 )) ,
i=1
the Kuhn-Tucker conditions require that for each i, either zi > bi and the
partial derivative of the Lagrangean with respect to zi is zero or zi = bi and
the partial derivative of the Lagrangean with respect to zi is negative.
The interpretation of the Kuhn-Tucker conditions is as follows. If zi > bi ,
then the bang-per-buck from i is zi /pi = λ. If zi = bi , then the bang-per-buck
from i is less than λ.
In seeking a solution, one might look first for an interior solution where
there is equal bang per buck from all three goods and zi ≥ bi for all i. If you
don’t find such a solution, you can simplify your search for a corner solution
by calculating bi /pi for each of the i’s. This is the bang per buck at the
boundary. Suppose that we have bi /pi > bj /pj > bk /pk . Then there are only
two possibilities for a corner solution. One of them has zk = bk , zi > bi , and
zj > bj . The other has zj = bj , zk = bk and zi > bi . (I will leave it as an
exercise for you to show that this is the case.)
Since strict convexity implies that there is exactly one solution, it is easy
find out which one is the equilibrium by checking which one satisfies the
Kuhn-Tucker conditions.
Having found solutions for the zi ’s, one can then find the xi ’s since xi =
zi − bi .
6
Question 4. For the consumer described in the previous question:
A) Find this consumer’s indirect utility function and verify that Roy’s iden-
tity holds in this case.
(I didn’t expect you to work this out for the corner solutions. You got
full credit if you did it correctly for the interior solutions.)
Let the direct utility function be xα1 xβ2 xγ3 where α + β + γ = 1. If there is
an interior solution, then the indirect utility function is
−β −γ
V (p1 , p2 , p3 , M ) = (M + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 ) αα β β γ γ p−α
1 p2 p3
∂V −β −γ α −β −γ
= b1 αα β β γ γ p−α
1 p2 p3 − b1 αα β β γ γ p−α
1 p2 p3 (M + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 )
∂p1 p1
(5)
∂V −β −γ
= αα β β γ γ p−α
1 p2 p3 (6)
∂M
Substituting Equations 5 and 6 into the right side of Equation 4 and
cancelling, we have
α
xi (p, m) = (m + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b2 ) − b1 .
p1
Looking back at the answer to Question 3, we see that this is the same
answer we found by calculating Marshallian demand directly.
For the masochists among you, we could go on to calculate indirect util-
ities at the corner solutions.
At a corner solution, where x1 = 0 x2 > 0 and x3 > 0, the indirect utility
must be !β !γ
β γ
α
(M + p2 b2 + p3 b3 ) b1 p−β −γ
2 p3 .
β+γ β+γ
7
At a corner solution where x1 = 0, x2 = 0 and x3 > 0, indirect utility
must be
(M + p3 b3 ) bα1 bβ2 p−γ
3
.
B) Find this consumer’s expenditure function.
A fairly quick way to find this is to use the fact that where V is the
indirect utility function,
V (p, e(p, u)) = u.
Using the indirect utility function that we found previously, we then have
−β −γ
(e(p, u) + p1 b1 + p2 b2 + p3 b3 ) αα β β γ γ p−α
1 p2 p3 = u. (7)
C) Find this consumer’s Hicksian demand function and the substitution ma-
trix.
The Hicksian demand functions are the partial derivatives of the expenditure
function.
α α β γ −α −β −γ
h1 (p, u) = u p p p α β γ − b1
p1 1 2 3
α α β γ −α −β −γ
h2 (p, u) = u p p p α β γ − b2
p2 1 2 3
α α β γ −α −β −γ
h3 (p, u) = up p p α β γ − b3
p3 1 2 3
The substitution matrix is the Hessian of the expenditure function. the
ijth element of this matrix is the partial derivative of hi (p, u) with respect
to pj .
8
A)If there are 100 people of each type, write an expression for the aggregate
demand for good 1 as a function of the prices and incomes.
α (M1 + 10(p1 + p2 + p3 ))
x11 (p, m) = − b1 .
p1
and Type 2’s by
α(M2 + 10p1 )
x21 (p, m) = − b1 .
p1
Then aggregate demand for good 1 is
!
M1 + M2 + 20p1 + 10p2 + p3
100 x11 (p, m) + x21 (p, m) = 100 − b1 . (9)
p1
B)Suppose that initially prices and income are such that everybody buys pos-
itive amounts of all goods. Income is redistributed from type 2’s to type 1’s
and after the income redistribution everyone is still buying positive amounts
of all goods. What can you say about the change in aggregate demand for
good 1? Explain your answer.
There will be no change in aggregate demand for good 1. We see this from
Equation 9, since aggregate demand for Good 1 is determined by aggregate
income.
C) Suppose that the prices are p1 = p2 = p3 = 1. Find incomes M1 and
M2 such that a transfer of income from type 1’s to type 2’s must change the
aggregate demand for good 1. Explain your answer.
9
Consumer 1 will demand a positive amount of good 1 only if α(M1 +30) >
10, which is equivalent to M1 > 10
α
− 30. So if M1 < 10
α
− 30, transfers from
1 to 2 will increase aggregate demand for Good 1.
Question 6. Harry consumes just one commmodity and he will live for T
periods. His current preferences over consumption streams are represented
by a utility function of the form
T
X
U (x1 , . . . , xT ) = βt u(xt )
t=1
where xt is the amount of the commodity that he will consume in year t and
where the function u(·) is increasing, strictly concave and twice continuously
differentiable. Harry knows that his income stream will be (w1 , . . . , wT ) where
wt is the income that he will receive in period t. Harry is able to borrow or
save at the constant interest r. At time 1, Harry is able to commit himself
to any time path of consumption that satisfies his budget constraint. His
budget constraint is that the present value of his lifetime consumption does
not exceed the present value of his lifetime income stream.
A) Suppose that for some α where 0 < α < 1, and for all t = 1, . . . T ,
βt = αt−1 . At what interest rate will Harry will choose to consume the same
amount of goods in every period of his life? Explain your answer. Does this
interest rate depend on the time path of his income stream? At this interest
rate, what can you say about the way in which his borrowing and saving
behavior depend on the time path of his income stream?
10
time path of his income but only on the present value of income. Where P V
is the present value of his income and c is his constant consumption, it must
be that
c(1 + r + r2 . . . + rT ) = P V
Since
1 − rT +1
1 + r + r2 + . . . rT =
1−r
it follows that
PV
c = (1 − r)
1 − rT +1
He will spend less than his income in periods where
PV
wt > (1 − r)
1 − rT +1
and spend more than his income when this inequality is reversed.
11
Harry earns income W > 0 in period 1, while wt = 0 for t > 1. Suppose also
that
1
= α.
1+r
If at time 1, Harry can choose his consumption for each period, subject to
his budget constraint, solve for his choice of x1 , x2 , and x3 as a function of
the parameters W and r.
x1 (1 + (1 + r) + 1) = W
and hence
W
x1 = ,
3+r
and
W (1 + r)2
x2 = x3 = .
3+r
D Suppose that Harry can save money in period 1 but he must leave the choice
of allocation between periods 2 and 3 to his future self. Harry is aware of
this and knows that in Period 2 his utility function for consumptions periods
2 and 3 will be
√ √
U (x2 , x3 ) = x2 + x3 .
He also knows that the interest rate will continue to satisfy the equation
1
= α.
1+r
If Harry consumes x1 in period 1, what consumptions will his period 2 self
choose for periods 2 and 3? Write down an expression for Harry’s utility as
a function of x1 , taking into account the fact that he knows that his period
2 self will determine the division of income between his period 2 self and his
12
period 3 self. Find the optimal choice of x1 for Harry. Is this the same as
the amount of x1 that he would choose in Part C above?
x3 = (1 + r)2 x2 .
1 + (1 + r)1/2
!
−1/2
x1 = (W − x1 )−1/2 (12)
(2 + r)1/2
and hence
W − x1 2+r
= (13)
x1 1 + (1 + r)1/2
Looking back at the answer to Part C, we find that when Harry can
commit future consumptions, he chooses x1 such that
W − x1
= 2 + r. (14)
x1
13
Comparing Equation 13 with Equation 14, we see that Harry chooses to
save less and spend more in the case where he can not commit than in the
case where he can commit future behavior.
A) Suppose that α = −1. At the price p, how much of good 2 will Type 2’s
demand for themselves and how much will they be willing to sell? Does the
amount that they are willing to sell increase or decrease as p increases?
Setting p equal to the ratio of the marginal utility of good 2 to the marginal
utility of good 1, we have
xα−1
2
p = α−1 . (16)
x1
Where α = −1, this implies that
x21
p=
x22
and hence
√
x1 = px2 . (17)
Let x22 (p) be the amount that a Type 2 will demand for her own con-
sumption when the price is p. Substituting from Equation 17 into Equation
15, we have
pω2
x22 = √ . (18)
p+ p
14
The amount that a Type 2 will be willing to sell will be
√ ! !
2 p 1
ω2 − x2 (p) = ω2 √ = ω2 √ (19)
p+ p 1+ p
We see from Equation 19 that Type 2’s will offer to sell less of good 2
when its price rises.
Quick method
All consumers have identical homothetic preferences. So if they all face
the same prices, they must all consume the two goods in the same ratio.
Since supply must equal demand in both markets, the ratio in which each
consumer consumes the two goods must be the same as the ratio in which
the goods are available, that is ω2 /ω1 .
15
The equilibrium price p must equal the marginal rate of substitution of a
consumer who consumes the goods in this ratio. So we must have
−2 2
ω2 ω1
p= = .
ω1 ω2
It is easy to see that Type 1’s are made worse off. Their income does not
change and the price of good 2 has increases.
It is less easy to see whether type 2’s are better off. Their income doubles,
but the cost of Good 2 quadruples. (In fact, when I wrote the question, I
didn’t realize that the answer was as difficult as it is.)
One way to check this out is to note that the indirect utility function for
type 2’s when good 1 is numeraire is
m
V (p, m) = √ . (21)
(1 + p)2
In equilibrium, Type 2’s have income
ω12
m = pω2 = . (22)
ω2
√ ω1 2
2
(1 + p) = 1 + . (23)
ω2
Let us define F (ω1 , ω2 to be the utility of Type 2’s in competitive equi-
librium when endowments are such that type 1’s have ω1 units of good 1 and
no good 2 and type 2’s have ω2 units of good 2 and no good 1.
Substituting from equations 22 and 23 into equation 21 and arranging
terms, we have
ω12 ω2
F (ω1 , ω2 ) = (24)
(ω1 + ω2 )2
Now we can check whether reducing the endowment of good 2 by 1/2
benefits or harms Type 2’s. Calculations are just a bit easier if we look at
the effect of doubling ω2 .
16
We have
F (ω1 , 2ω2 ) ≥ F (ω1 , ω2 )
if and only if
2ω2 ω2
2
≥ .
(ω1 + 2ω2 ) (ω + 1 + ω2 )2
This is the case if and only if
which is equivalent to
Question 8.
A) A consumer consumes n goods and his utility function is u(x) where x is
his consumption vector. Define this consumer’s expenditure function.
B)If the utility function u(·) is homogeneous of degree k, what special struc-
ture does the expenditure function have?
17
We show that e(p, u) is concave in p. Let p and p0 be two different
price vectors. Then e(p, u) = ph(p, u) and e(p0 , u) = p0 h(p0 , u). Let p(λ) =
λp + (1 − λ)p0 where 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1. Then e(p(λ), u) = p(λ)h (p(λ)) , u).
Since h(p, u) is the cheapest bundle at prices p with utility u, it must be
that
ph(p(λ)) ≥ ph(p) = e(p, u). (25)
Likewise, since h(p., u) is the cheapest bundle at prices p0 with utility u,
it must be that
p0 h(p(λ)) ≥ p0 h(p0 ) = e(p0 , u). (26)
Now
e(p(λ), u) = p(λ)h(p(λ)
= λph(p(λ)) + (1 − λ)p0 h(p(λ)) (27)
18