Chapter 1
Chapter 1
1
2 Utility functions
If the preference relation is continuous, then there is a continuous utility function
u(x) that represents < :
Lexicographic preferences do not satisfy continuity, and thus, have no utility
representation.
The utility function that represents < is not unique. Any strictly increasing
transformation f (u(x)) also represents < : This implies that u(x1 ; x2 ) = x1 x2
and v(x1 ; x2 ) = ln x1 + ln x2 represent the same preferences. This is a conse-
quence of the fact that preferences are ordinal (and not cardinal) rankings of
bundles. We will normally assume u( ) to be twice continuously di¤erentiable.
If preferences are convex, then the utiliy function is quasiconcave, i.e. fy 2
RL+ : u(y) u(x)g is a convex set, 8x: Increasing MRS violates convexity and
hence, quasiconcavity. Quasiconcavity does not necessarily imply concavity.
maxu(x)
x 0
s.t. p x w
with p >> 0 and w > 0: The Walrasian budget set (the set of feasible alloca-
tions) is Bp;w = x 2 RL + :p x w
The solution to the consumer’s utility maximization problem is the Wal-
rasian demand correspondence (function if single-valued) x(p; w): If preferences
are not strictly convex, the Walrasian demand may fail to be a correspondence.
The indirect utility function is v(p; w) = u(x(p; w)), where x(p; w) is the Wal-
rasian demand.
Equivalently, we can de…ne the consumer’s expenditure minimization prob-
lem as
minp x
x 0
s.t. u(x) u
with p >> 0; u > u(0): The solution to this problem is the Hicksian demand cor-
respondence (or function) h(p; u): This is the Hicksian or compensated demand,
in the sense that the level of utility is maintained constant. When comparing
the Walrasian and Hicksian demands, slopes are di¤erent due to the income
e¤ect. The expenditure function is e(p; u) = p h(p; u).
2
If w = e(p; u), then it holds that h(p; u) = x(p; w). At this point, the
Hicksian and Walrasian demands intersect.
There is a relationship between the two formulations of demand, which is
known as the Slutsky Equation:
@hl (p; u) @xl (p; w) @xl (p; w)
= + xk (p; w)
@pk @pk @w
which relates the slopes of the Walrasian demand function and the Hicksian
(compensated) demand function when l = k. In particular, the last term takes
into account the existence of income e¤ects. However, we will usually focus on
the utility maximization problem and on the Walrasian demand correspondence.
max ln x1 + (1 ) ln x2
x1 ;x2
s.t. p1 x1 + p2 x2 w
$(x1 ; x2 ; ) = ln x1 + (1 ) ln x2 (p1 x1 + p2 x2 w)
p1 0 = 0 if x1 > 0
x1
1
p2 0 = 0 if x2 > 0
x2
(p1 x1 + p2 x2 w) = 0
3
Example 2 Suppose that the consumer’s utility function is given by u(x1 ; x2 ) =
x1 + x2 ; and that income is 10: Then, the consumer’s utility maximization prob-
lem is
max x1 + x2
x1 ;x2
s.t. p1 x1 + p2 x2 10
and the Lagrangian is $(x1 ; x2 ; ) = x1 + x2 (p1 x1 + p2 x2 10) : Then, the
…rst-order conditions are, respectively,
1 p1 0, = 0 if x1 > 0
1 p2 0, = 0 if x2 > 0
(p1 x1 + p2 x2 10) = 0
This leads us to consider four possible cases:
1) x1 = x2 = 0: Impossible, since the utility function is increasing.
2) x1 = 0; x2 > 0: Then, it must be true that 1 p1 < 0; = p12 =) pp12 > 1:
Using the budget constraint yields x2 = p102 ; x1 = 0:
3) x1 > 0; x2 = 0: Then, it must be true that 1 p1 = 0; 1 p2 < 0 =)
p1
p2 < 1: Using the budget constraint yields x1 = p101 ; x2 = 0:
4) x1 > 0; x2 > 0: Then, it must be true that 1 p1 = 0; 1 p2 = 0 =)
p1
p2 = 1 (a necessary condition). From the budget constraint we get x1 + x2 =
10 10
p2 ) x1 = p2 x2 , with x2 2 [0; p102 ]. In this case, the Walrasian demand is a
correspondence.
The Walrasian demand correspondence (function) has the following proper-
ties:
1) x(p; w) is homogeneous of degree zero in (p; w) : x( p; w) = 0 x(p; w):
2) x(p; w) satis…es Walras’law: p x = w8x 2 x(p; w):
3) If u( ) is strictly quasiconcave, then x(p; w) is a function.
In economic terms, the MRS is the ratio of marginal utilities, and the in-
terpretation of the multiplier is the marginal utility of wealth. The multiplier
is the marginal utility of wealth because the change in utility from a marginal
increase in w is given by
4 Welfare analysis
A welfare analysis evaluates the e¤ects of changes in the consumer’s environment
on his well-being. Consider the welfare e¤ect of a price change, from p0 to p1 ,
given a constant wealth level w > 0. Thus, for any indirect utility function
v(p; w), and for an arbitrary price vector p, the expression
e(p; v(p1 ; w)) e(p; v(p0 ; w))
4
is itself an indirect utility function and provides a measure of the welfare change
expressed in monetary units. Depending on our choice of p; we have the equiv-
alent variation or the compensating variation:
Using the fact that the Hicksian demand function is the derivative of the
expenditure function and that w = e(p0 ; u0 ) = e(p1 ; u1 ), we may rewrite, for
the case in which one of the prices decreases:
Z p01
EV (p0 ; p1 ; w) = h1 (p1 ; p 1; u
1
)dp1
p11
Z p01
0 1 0
CV (p ; p ; w) = h1 (p1 ; p 1; u )dp1
p11