Manual of Process Economic Evaluation
Manual of Process Economic Evaluation
Alain CHAUVEL
Senior Director, Scientific Division, IFP
Deputy Director, Strategy & Corporate Planning Division, IFP
Professor a t the IFP School
Gilles FOURNIER
Engineer, Strategy & Corporate Planning Division, IFP
Claude RAIMBAULT
Senior Engineer, Strategy & Corporate Planning Division, IFP
Manual of
Process
Economic
Evaluation
New, revised and expanded edition
Translated by BGS
J.V. Guy Bray, M.A., M.Sc, Ph.D., P.Eng., ATA
Santa Barbara, California
2003
Among our most broadly accepted clichks, one that is particularly fixed in the public’s mind
aims to give credence to the idea that “forecasters, and more generally all those who claim to
anticipate the future, are always wrong”. Instead of interpreting this sentence as an inelucta-
ble error, perhaps it would be better to take it as a compliment, like the recognition that is
implicit in the growing role granted to this kind of activity. Indeed, to foresee an event by
endeavoring to deduce it from a set of accessible information and rational hypotheses about
change, will usually produce reactions among the group concerned, whose consequences
automatically lead to the event’s failing to occur. In other words, setting aside chance events,
a forecaster that people pay attention to is unlikely to be right, especially when his reasoning
leads him to envisage crises or tense situations.
In the case of economics the area of forecasts, and more broadly of futurology, is one that
offers favorable conditions for working out the application of its theories and methods. The
particular object of the operation is to present interlocutors with development scenarios that
are designed to identify the most difficult situations, and to prevent their occurrence by sug-
gesting appropriate measures-also to identify the most favorable situations, the ones to be
aimed for, while knowing perfectly well that they represent an unattainable ideal. In other
words, in this kind of activity the economist’s very function, like the forecaster’s, is bound to
lead to a contrary outcome. In practice, his role is not so much to picture a special situation
that he knows a priori will not occur, except under extraordinary circumstances, but rather to
define a space within which the most probable outcomes will be found. The aim is to replace
the irrationality of prediction, which in most cases is doomed to failure, by the deductive logic
of case studies based on various sets of development theories. Here economics comes fully
into play as a decision-making aid, especially when its objective is the regular, systematic
evaluation of Research and Development (R&D) projects, and the quantification of potential
innovations and their consequences.
For this purpose, economics uses some or all of the following procedures:
0 Study of the overall economic situation into which the project under examination will be
inserted, and consideration of the foreseeable evolution of the major indicators.
0 Analysis of the market and the status of competition, so as to learn one of the essential vari-
ables for all subsequent calculations, in other words the unit production capacities that char-
acterize given geographic contexts. Such results are usually derived from an examination of
the price-volume relationships for products or raw materials, and their extrapolation over the
X Foreword
medium or long term. Studies of competitors and industrial projects, both operating and
planned, are also very important for this purpose.
0 Techno-economic comparisons, measured against a criterion represented by a given stan-
dard of profitability, between the results for the technology under consideration-whether
developed in the laboratory, in a pilot plant, or as a prototype-and the results offered by the
existing or potential competing approaches. The procedure utilized in this type of operation
is based on principles similar to those employed by engineering companies or services, by
setting up a construction plan together with assessments of material and energy requirements,
and by sizing and costing equipment. The only major differences are the lack of detailed,
credible information, and also the very short time allowed for completing it. On the other
hand, it is not a matter of producing an absolute opinion, but only of reaching a relative judg-
ment.
0 Sensitivity analysis for technical parameters, so as to identify the essential variables and
thereby to provide a performance framework to guide research towards the achievement of a
successful project, i.e., industrial or commercial production. By establishing an economic
ranking of factors affecting the operation in a given situation, it also enables the necessary
efforts and means to be brought to bear preferentially on improving the most important
parameters4ither to achieve this goal as rapidly as possible, or to abandon the work more
quickly if the levels required for competition prove to be unrealistic.
0 Examining the overall impact, especially the positive or negative consequences of insert-
ing a new technique or equipment into an existing industrial context. In this case it is a matter
of crediting the innovation under consideration with the resulting savings or additional costs
generated by its presence. This type of procedure is widely used in the field of petroleum
refining, and linear programming is an invaluable tool in applying it. Its special interest lies
in enabling the definition of the techno-economic conditions, i.e., the external constraints,
under which the project being studied would turn out to be fully workable.
0 Considering the economic consequences of environmental measures and regulations that
the technology being evaluated must comply with, or that it may give rise to. Generally
speaking, the current trend is to consider all the different kinds of nuisance that may accom-
pany an innovation, including the effects on jobs (creation or loss), on the locality, on trans-
port, etc. In order for an analysis to be as comprehensive as possible and include all the
parameters that may ensure the success or failure of an undertaking (opportunity, acceptabil-
ity, etc.) it is necessary, in the time-honored phrase, to “internalize the externalities” for each
project. The major pitfall that this kind of evaluation runs into is the difficulty of having to
work entirely with forecasts, and to make simultaneous predictions of the evolution of all the
economic elements, both internal and external. Under these circumstances, even if several
scenarios are devised, it is practically impossible on the basis of existing knowledge to
attempt to pick out what may eventually become “strong signals” from among the “weak”
ones. Looked at in this way, evaluation falls back into the error of forecasting.
The present volume represents an updating, combined with a reorganized layout, of the
Manuel d ’dvaluationbconomique des procddds published by Editions Technip in 1976, and
later by McGraw-Hill in 1981. It does not attempt to cover all the various topicsjust mentioned.
Foreword XI
Firstly, it aims to discuss in somewhat greater depth the subject of market analysis, in
terms of volumes and prices. It thereby enables a better understanding of the modalities of
selecting a unit production capacity, an essential parameter for developing balance sheet cal-
culations, sizing and costing of equipment, and ultimately the definition of investment costs,
operating costs, and the costs required for plant profitability.
Secondly, it also takes up the three-part methodology expounded in the previous editions.
However, their order has been reversed, so as to provide a closer correspondence with the
method that proceeds from market data towards the technical characteristics of the systems
under consideration. Consequently the first section of this methodological triptych concerns
incomes, beginning with profits and the notion of taxation, then the main profitability criteria,
whether empirical or based on the concept of present value, and finally minimum profitable
sales prices. The second section deals with expenses, i.e., cost of price and operating cost,
examining variable and fixed operating costs as well as the cost of capital. The last section
takes a closer look at the structure of these fixed assets and the effects of changing production
capacities, dates, and local circumstances, assuming that the battery limits investments of
production unit or processing system size are known.
Along the same line, the third stage focuses on an examination of procedures for estimat-
ing the amount of these costs, in the reference capital. Next comes a fairly complete synopsis
of the so-called exponential and factorial methods. For this, it is necessary to know at least
the expense involved in acquiring the main items of equipment, which form the core of the
physico-chemical operating units involved in the system being studied.
In these circumstances, when this kind of information is not directly accessible, it can be
useful to have at one’s disposal procedures that enable it to be obtained. As in the earlier edi-
tions, this approach, which is based on the use of graphical representations of CEF (Cost Esti-
mation Formulas), makes up most of the appendices, where it is broken down by major
category of equipment. However, here it differs from preceding editions.
Indeed, to the extent that the considerable progress achieved in computing during recent
years has greatly improved the accessibility and dissemination of equipment size modeling,
the rapid calculation methods previously offered for the more common items of equipment
have not been repeated here. However, other kinds of infomation have been added, notably
for plate exchangers.
It is equally important to point out that the present publication concerns only those indus-
trial plants that operate continuously. Thus, pilot plants and prototypes are excluded, along
with consideration of batch or limited operations. In this last case the procedure for sizing and
costing of equipment is not so very different from the one suggested here. On the other hand,
the way in which modem facilities of this kind are managed is very specific to the conditions
selected: multi-usage or multi-product, employing teams in two or three eight-hour shifts,
five or seven days out of seven, etc.
Finally, contrary to the position taken in previous editions, no examples are given to illus-
trate the suggested methodology.
Table of Contents 1
Foreword ....................................................................................................................... IX
Chapter 1
MARKET ANALYSIS
1.3 Specific Application Methods for Forecasting Prices and Volumes ................ 39
1.3.1 Price Applications ........................................................................................... 39
1.3.1.1 Current Currency. Constant Currency. Deflation Index ........................... 39
1.3.1.2 Relationships Between Product Prices and their Raw Materials. Line of
Equivalence ........................................................................................ 41
1.3.1.3 Product Price Structure. Evolution Curves ............................................. 48
1.3.2 Sales Volume Applications ............................................................................... 58
1.3.2.1 Normalization of Evolution Curves ....................................................... 58
1.3.2.2 The Concept of Penetration as a Tool for Determining the Level of Market
Saturation ........................................................................................... 60
1.3.2.3 Real and Average Growth Rate. Application to the Long Term ............... 63
Chapter 2
THE ELEMENTS OF ECONOMIC CALCULATION
Chapter 3
THE DETERMINATION OF BATTERY
LIMITS INVESTMENTS
Appendix 1
FUNCTIONAL MODULES METHOD (FMM)
Appendix 2
PRk-ESTIME METHOD
When contemplating a new plant, a manufacturer’s first concern must be to confirm that the
raw materials that are needed are in fact available, and under what economic conditions. In
addition, it is essential to estimate the capacity of potential users to purchase the products that
it is intended to manufacture, both in volume and in price terms, and then-by comparing the
situation before and after plant installation-to evaluate to what extent it may be possible not
only to run the plant successfully, but also to make a profit. Consequently, whether they refer
to raw materials or to products, price/volume relationships are a permanent feature of this
type of analysis.
Moreover, the connection between these external constraints, which are a characteristic
feature of the inputs and markets for a given manufacturing process, is what leads the manu-
facturer to:
The decision whether or not to actually construct the corresponding plants.
6 1 . Market Analysis
a The definition of the most suitable unit production or processing capacity. Possession of
this information is in fact essential, because not only the equipment sizing calculations
but also the whole economic procedure of assessing the intrinsic worth of the project
depends upon it.
Before considering the influence of price/volume relations on unit capacity size, it would
seem essential to begin by emphasizing the relative nature of the raw materials/products dual-
ity, and then to define the element that makes it possible to measure the degree of dependence
between these variables: in this case it is the concept of market elasticity.
The distinction between the two makes sense only in the context of a conversion or process-
ing unit that on the one hand utilizes them, and on the other manufactures them: something
that is a raw material in a given situation may become a product in other circumstances, and
vice versa. Looked at in this way, the general study of the evolution of prices or volumes does
not require different procedures depending on whether we are looking at what goes into or
what comes out of a particular plant.
In terms of products, the size of the installations that are to be put to work depends essen-
tially on the quantities that may be accepted or asked for by the users, i.e., on the size of the
market. It follows that if it is not a seller’s market, competitors will have to be displaced; the
volume of sales will be larger in proportion to whether the prices offered, all other things
being equal, are attractive-which means low. If, on the other hand, it is a monopoly situa-
tion, with growing needs, it will be possible to keep prices high and even to raise them all the
more easily as the scarcity of the products increases and demand rises as a result.
For raw materials, the approach is much the same. If availabilities are adequate, the greater
the quantities sought, the better the suppliers’ prices will be, so as to retain the customer, pref-
erably the one who gives them the biggest orders. On the other hand, if there is a shortage
situation, manifesting itself in substitute raw materials or by a need to manufacture the
required inputs, the acquisition costs will obviously rise with the demand.
In any event, a manufacturer who wants to construct a profitable plant must have in mind
a sufficient price difference between the products and the raw materials. If at first certain ele-
ments, such as unit capacity figures, are not available for precise calculations of the minimum
difference, at least there will be some material balance sheets, even energy consumption or
production costs, which will provide reference points or limits that must not be exceeded.
This concept, whose origin may be attributed to the French economist Augustin Coumot
(180 1- 1877), is based on the following observation:
‘<Formanufactured goods, demand should vary more than price, whilefor the most essen-
tial things, as for the most superfluous, demand varies little in comparison to price”.
1. Market Analysis 7
Generally speaking, elasticity is defined as the ratio between the absolute, or preferably
the relative variations over time of two phenomena, i.e.,
AyIAx or AY Ax
--I-
Y X
Depending on the classification employed, several kinds of elasticity may be distinguished.
1.1.2.1 Mathematical
From a purely mathematical viewpoint, there are:
(a) Empirical or casual elasticity, obtained by calculation for each moment, using two
series of observations x(t) and y(t). This has only very limited interest.
(b) Theoretical elasticity, derived from the parameters of a model, or a combination of
these parameters: y = f(x), and from the corresponding smoothing of the observations (a log-
log model, for example). This type of elasticity is useful for forecasting.
(c) Anticipation elasticity, which includes:
Short-term elasticity, which measures the influence of the rate of change of one vari-
able on the rate of change of another variable, during a certain future period and with
the help of a model that correlates x and y ,
0 Long-term elasticity, which, for a future period, takes into account the cumulative
1.1.2.2 Economic
Employing an economic point of view, we may introduce the distinction between simple,
two-variable relationships: quantities (q) and price (P), and more complex relationships that
involve a greater number of parameters.
In the first case, we may consider particularly:
(a) Price-demand elasticity for a given product, also called “direct” or “self‘ elasticity,
to strongly emphasize that the price and quantity refer to the same product.
It is expressed by the relation:
3
q=- 4
AP
P
where
q: coefficient of elasticity
q : quantity
P: price.
8 1. Market Analysis
Although the mathematical formulation relating q and P has the form q = f(P), by conven-
tion, or rather out of habit, graphical representations of it always show the independent vari-
able, i.e., the price, on they-axis, and the quantities on thex-axis. Also by convention,elasticity
is negative, since experience shows that price and quantity usually move in opposite directions.
When it is positive, a minus sign therefore has to be inserted. Such a situation may arise in
two ways:
0 When the increase in the price of an essential product results, in spite of everything, in
an increase in consumption; the most disadvantaged social classes transfer their demand
onto this product to the detriment of the consumption of other, less indispensable prod-
ucts (the Giffen effect or paradox),
0 When the rise in a product’s price only heightens its snob or fashionable value, and
thereby causes certain purchasers, usually well-off ones, to buy it for themselves (the
Veblen effect).
Theoretically, the absolute value of price elasticity may vary from 0 to infinity. It is low
for essential and luxury products; in contrast it is higher for everyday or semi-luxury goods.
When it is nil, demand is said to be “inelastic”; when less than 1 , the market is called “tight”;
it becomes “elastic” if it is greater than 1.
If the relation between q and P is linear, the coefficient q decreases in proportion as the
price decreases. In an “isoelastic” graph, q has the same value at all points on the curve; such
a situation is described by the following equation:
k
q = - where k and a are constants
P“
In this case:
where: q = -a
and : q = k P
If q = -a = -1, we obtain the expression for an equilateral hyperbola. In logarithmic
coordinates the elasticity is equal to the slope of the straight line representing the fbnction
log q = f(l0g P).
(b) Cross elasticity of demand for a given product. In this case we are no longer taking
into account only the direct influence of this product’s own price on the demand, but also,
assuming that this latter parameter remains constant, considering the effects of the evolution
of the prices of other goods in the same market. In this case, for two products (1) and (2) for
example, we can measure the elasticity of the consumption of (1) according to the evolution
of the price for (2), when the price for (1) is held constant, by the relation:
dq1 4
%1)/(2) = y
dp2
According to whether these two goods are complementary or substitutable, the cross elas-
ticity will be negative or positive. In fact, when there is complementarity, as a general rule an
1. Market Analysis 9
increase in P2 also leads to a decrease in q1 (q < 0). For substitutable products, the rise in P2
leads to a fall in 42 but leaves (1) the possibility of increasing its share of the market q1
’
(rl 0).
(c) Substitution price elasticity. This enables the measurement of the relative effects on
their respective markets of a change in the price structure of several given products. If we
limit this analysis to only two of them, (1) and (2), such an elasticity will have the following
form:
COMMENT
Generalization of the concept of demand elasticity in relation to price.
0 This concept may first of all be applied by permuting the role of the variables; in
this case we are trying to determine the elasticity of prices as a function of the amount
available, i.e., the supply; it is expressed as:
e is a function of the existing stocks, the possibilities for increasing production, and
the length of time considered, but it is always positive. Indeed, any increase in the
demand increases the pressures on manufacturing and the problems of supply, and
thus leads to a rise in price.
0 Next, one of the two variables may be changed, the price for example, which is
sometimes replaced by purchasing capacity, i.e., income in the case of the consumer,
or the level of activity. In this case, we may define income elasticity by means of the
following relation:
q R is usually positive, but varies significantly according to the products, the services,
or the goods concerned. However, it follows certain empirical natural laws,
expressed in particular by Engel and Schwabe. Such a concept has practically no
application in the field of economic evaluation of projects.
The development of more complex models enables consideration of more numerous
relationships, by increasing the number of variables. The concept of elasticity finds
possible extensions here. Thus, for example, the numerous energy models developed
in the 1970s are based on statistical analyses where, as a first approximation, the
10 1. Market Analysis
overall demand for energy (E) may be deduced from the activity levels (A) or from
the yield and prices (P) of this energy, according to an equation having the form:
E = A ~ p%
A
where qAand qp are the coefficients of “product” and “price” elasticity respectively.
With this introduction, and based on these various considerations, how are we in practice to
determine the unit conversion or processing capacity? Several situations may be envisaged.
1.1.3.1 Raw Materials and Products are Freely Available on the Market
In this case, the acquisition costs for feedstocks are the same as those applied elsewhere; this
is also true for products. In contrast, in order to maintain competitiveness one must keep up
with the leading prices, i.e., the prices of the most efficient current manufactures. It is there-
fore necessary to do as well as the most economic processes, and the plants that make the
most of the effects of scale. So the size level to be considered emerges from a study of the
markets, particularly their development and existing capacities.
These leading prices may also come from plants of more modest size, but old enough to
have been paid off, and thus able to take advantage of special economic circumstances. If this
is the case, the unit capacity to be selected should be bigger than the existing ones, by a factor
such that the economy of scale obtained will compensate for the capital costs. It is often dif-
ficult to do this if the size of the operating plants is already large. Again, the answer will come
from a study of the evolution of prices and tonnages, and from the projections to be made
from them.
COMMENT
In this connection, we should also take into account the aging of operating units.
Depending on the particular case, contradictory results may be produced: either addi-
tional outlets and a replacement market if there is a halt in operations, or conversely
a reduction in the share of available tonnages if there is a modernization and debot-
tlenecking, leading to an increase in the unit manufacturing capacity.
Situations of this type are mostly found in intermediate chemical products, both organic
and inorganic. Thus, the production of styrene, a two-stage process:
0 Alkylation of benzene by ethylene to form ethylbenzene,
operates in a market where the raw materials, benzene and ethylene, are freely available at
prices set by market quotations, that is, by procedures external to the project under consider-
ation. The same applies to the styrene, whose prices and tonnages must be brought into line
with the competition. So if outlets do exist, unless a process can be found that is very different
1. Market Analysis 11
from the operating ones, the unit capacity to be considered must be in line with those already
in place, particularly the most modern ones, for example, at least 300000 t/yr in Western
Europe.
The concept of elasticity discussed above has nothing to offer here, in the short term.
Although it is indeed helpfbl in terms of predicting the overall market, in practice it is not
used to determine the desired minimum unit production size.
1.1.3.2
r
limited Availabilit of Raw Materials,
Very Big Markets or Products
In situations of this type, the manufacturer operates under two kinds of constraint:
0 The price of the product(s), which must be aligned with the market price, and which may
therefore be considered as fixed, at any given time.
The price of the raw material, which, because of limited availability, may have various
sources, or may even require major processing if it is not directly accessible. In this case,
as scarcity increases, the processing applied becomes more and more complicated and
the cost of the raw material rises in step with the needs.
0 In these circumstances the proposed plant’s unit capacity will depend on a minimal dif-
ference between the costs of the product and the feedstock, corresponding to the operat-
ing expenses and the capital costs for the production envisaged. There will therefore be
a maximum permissible raw material price. An illustration of such a situation is pro-
vided, for example, by the production of MTBE (Methyl Tertio Butyl Ether).
Let us suppose that, in the context of commercial development of lead-free gasoline in
Western Europe, a French, or more generally a southern European refiner wishes to know the
volume of high-octane gasoline conforming to the new specifications that he will be able to
put on the market at an economically acceptable price. For this purpose, considering his refin-
ery’s current structure, he thinks that by 1992 he will be able to fill his needs for additional
octane, half by modifying his refinery flow sheets, and the rest by including 10% of ether as
an additive.
The MTBE may have various origins, and in particular may be produced by the refiner
himself, as follows:
From isobutylene in a C4 steam cracking cut. The relevant unit is already set up in the
neighboring petrochemical area, which includes plants for pyrolysis of naphtha with a
total ethylene production capacity in excess of 500000 t/yr, i.e., sufficient to provide the
isobutylene supply for the manufacture of 100000 t/yr of MTBE, using a standard pro-
cess.
From isobutylene in a C4 catalytic cracking cut. The unit, set up within the refinery
itself, has a 50000 t/yr capacity and employs a reactive distillation technology with a
lower investment cost. In fact, the whole C4 cut is charged to etherification. Now, the
by-products from catalytic cracking have an average isobutylene content much lower
than those from steam cracking, especially after extraction of butadiene. The amount of
diluents directly influences the size of the facilities and consequently the investment
costs: this can lead to a search for less capital-intensive technologies, especially for C4
catalytic cracking cuts.
12 1. Market Analysis
MTBE can also be purchased on the market. In this case, let us suppose that it may have
the following origins:
0 C4 catalytic cracking cut located on another site, supplying an etherification unit in its
cost and suitable for supplying, in the same area, a large-scale industrial complex
consisting of a deisobutanizer, an isomerization of n-butane into isobutane, a dehydro-
genation of isobutane into isobutylene, and finally an etherification operating on an isob-
utane-isobutylene cut. Installation of an ether production capacity of 500000 t/yr would
enable delivery of products into the southern European market.
0 Isobutane alone or a mixture of n-butane-isobutane produced locally in Western Europe
(Scotland, for example) which, under conditions similar to or better than those just
described for the Middle East, could supply the same market, as long as the construction
of 500000 t/yr capacity etherification plants appears to be profitable under European
conditions for the sale of the initial C4 and payback of capital.
Each of these MTBE sources has its particular price, as shown graphically in Figs. l.la
and 1.1b. These prices include:
0 The cost of the initial raw material, after deduction of the revenues from by-products, C4
0 The cost of transporting the MTBE from its production site to the plant where it will be
used (ocean freight charges, for example). Based on linear depreciationover ten years, and
remuneration of capital at an internal rate of return of 15% (see Chapter 2, 9 2.1.2.3.D),
the situation in terms of the quantity of MTBE available and the transfer price is summa-
rized in Table 1.1.
Using these numbers, it then becomes possible to define a curve for the average price:
I Origin I I
Quantity Price ($/t) I Raw material source
I
1 100000 22 1 ex steam cracking of naphtha
2 50 000 237 ex catalytic cracking (reactive distillation)
3 30 000 262 ex catalytic cracking (conventional etherification)
4 80 000 268 ex n-butanelisobutane (Middle East)
5 50000 273 ex isobutane (Western Europe)
6 90 000 290 ex n-butanelisobutane (Western Europe)
1. Market Analysis 15
5 70075
q=-- z0.1
245.5 13650
In addition, the low value obtained emphasizes the tightness of the supply.
COMMENT
The example selected is a very petroleum-oriented one, but the terms would be much
the same in other areas of activity. Thus, the increased development experienced by
linear low-density polyethylene (LLDPE) leads to a strong demand for ethylene
comonomer, and particularly for n-butene- 1. Now, this product has various possible
sources: extraction (adsorption) from C4 cuts from naphtha steam cracking, dimer-
ization of ethylene, dehydrogenation of n-butane, etc. The average acquisition cost
for comonomer may have a significant influence on the selection of unit production
capacity for LLDPE.
for the product(s). Under these conditions its chances of success vis-a-vis the competition are
strongly affected. It can only look for new outlets, and in particular consider whether the qual-
ities of its own product(s) might enable it to displace various items from their markets: these
might be less sophisticated items, and thus a priori less expensive ones, but the demand for
them should, by significantly raising the unit capacity, lead to a reduction in the cost of pro-
duction. Of course, this will be possible only above a certain threshold, represented by the
minimum operating expenses for the plant. This usually means the costs that are directly
related to the material and energy balance sheets, and the costs of overhead, labor, and main-
tenance (capital costs, provision for depreciation, and financial costs are not taken into
account). These operating expenses are often confused with the marginal cost l . Such consid-
erations must be addressed as soon as the markets for a known product prove to be too lim-
ited, but they are also important when studying the possibilities of penetrating various
markets with a new product, whose qualities could lead to possible substitutions.
In this connection, the case of polymethyl-4 pentene-1, better known as TPX, is illuminat-
ing. TPX’s monomer, obtained by dimerization of propylene, is currently used in the produc-
tion of linear low-density polyethylene, in competition with other a-olefins. At the time when
the marketing of this polymer was under consideration, its special qualities, and in particular
its transparency, presented an opportunity for use as a substitute for a number of more tradi-
tional materials, such as:
0 Glass for laboratory vessels
A preliminary market study had moreover shown that for these four markets, and within a
particular geographical area, the annual sales volumes and average prices were as shown in
Table 1.2.
Market
Sales volume (4)
(t/Yr)
20 000
I Average price (P)
(local monetary units)
50
10 000 100
15 000 70
50 000 30
(Source: IFP)
1. Generally speaking, when the quantities produced are proportional to the operating costs, the
short-term marginal cost is effectively equal to these costs. This is not always so, especially at low lev-
els of production. Nor is it true for the long-term marginal cost. These concepts, which deserve a more
detailed analysis, will be considered later. They turn out to be very useful in selecting the optimal unit
capacity for a plant.
1. Market Analysis 17
These elements, although they were quite scanty, were enough to define the curve q = f(P),
giving the variation in total tonnage of annual sales (q)as a function of price (P). A graph of
this kind (Fig. 1.3) is very useful in making an estimate of the size of a plant to be constructed
and in very quickly deciding whether or not it is worth going ahead. In fact, when this kind
of information is available it is possible, right at the outset and based on a simplified eco-
nomic selection tool, to investigate the configuration that will ensure the most profitable
project. In this case the cashflow (CF, see Chapter 2, 0 2.2.2) is well suited to answer the
question. The object is to maximize the following function:
CF=q(P-D)
an equation in which q represents the potential market, P the product's sales price, and D the
operating expenses of the production plants (see Section 1.1.2).
The maximum value of the function CF is obtained by setting the first derivative to zero,
and confirming that the second derivative is negative, i.e.,
dCF dq
-=q +(P-D)-=O
dP dP
d2CF = 2 -
- dq + ( P - D)-d2q < 0
dp2 dP dP2
20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Now, the relation q = f(P) allows us to calculate the coefficient of elasticity q and thus,
knowing D, to determine the optimum price.
In the selected example (Fig. 1.3) we have:
q = A e-BP (or: q = 2.3.105e4.O3l59
or: P = 31.7 + D
At its maximum the price must therefore equal the operating expenses plus 31.7 units.
Such a result, which we obtained without knowing the size of the unit, but only from having
some idea of the operating costs, enables us to reach some conclusions about the market that
can be very interesting. Thus, in the present example, we see straightaway that market num-
ber 4, which is moreover the biggest one, is out of reach because the corresponding permis-
sible price is only 30. So the unit capacity of the plant cannot exceed 45000 tlyr. A hrther
calculation would show that D is greater than 20, which also eliminates market number 1, and
brings the maximum size of the unit down to 25 000 tlyr. We can thus see why it was neces-
sary, at the time when such a study was undertaken, to abandon the plan to market TPX.
One of the essential tasks of an evaluation is to make it possible to judge the economic attrac-
tiveness of projects. To do this we must therefore be able to visualize future situations, and
especially to define their characteristics. For this purpose we have to rely on the available
means, in particular the various known methods of forecasting-to the extent that they
answer our specific needs.
In this connection, it is desirable to emphasize at the outset that evaluations look three,
five, or even ten years ahead, and that they are also expected to make comparisons, on a con-
sistent basis, between several situations that could arise at those periods.
1. Market Analysis 19
Many fields of activity use forecasting techniques; they can handle demographic develop-
ments just as well as energy and raw material availability and demand, or possible variations
in financing capacity, manufacturing prices and costs, sales volumes for more or less sophis-
ticated products, even changes in the behavior of consumers, government policies, societies,
etc.
Market analysis, or more generally technological forecasting, which is all that concerns
evaluation, addresses the narrower field of prices and quantities. However, the methods uti-
lized for forecasting in all these cases are based on the general procedures that have developed
over time, such that their manner of application does not differ from one case to another. The
only thing that changes is the nature of the dependent variable; time remains the common
parameter, whether it appears directly or not.
If they are carelessly applied these methods often give rise to certain disappointments,
when the reality turns out to be different from the anticipated results. It is therefore essential
to define their basic character, and especially their limitations, before going on to examine
them in greater detail.
In the first place, the great number and complexity of the parameters that must be consid-
ered in assessing a situation are such that it proves to be impossible to develop a procedure
capable of yielding completely reliable information, especially as some of these variables
cannot be quantified. It is more a matter of obtaining orders of magnitude, or trends, than
definitive values.
Consequently, it is always desirable to maintain a critical attitude towards forecasting tech-
niques, and to bear in mind the possibility of intervening by including a certain measure of
subjectivity: this can provide elements of judgment, especially about economic matters, that
are hard to quantify or express formally. The level of uncertainty that characterizes forecast-
ing has also had the effect, over time, of multiplying the number of procedures and increasing
their level of sophistication, so that there is now a whole arsenal of methods, each one as
imperfect as the next, but all more or less specific and easy to apply. In this case, as in similar
situations throughout the process, the role of the evaluator consists in selecting the proce-
dure(s) according to the problem being faced, the credibility of the available information, the
degree of accuracy required, and above all the time allowed for providing an answer.
Forecasting methods may be classified according to various criteria, particularly by the time
period envisaged: the intervals are related to the frequency of acquiring or analyzing the data
or parameters concerned. From this standpoint four type frequencies are usually distin-
guished:
0 Daily
0 Monthly
20 1. Market Analysis
0 Quarterly
0 Annual.
The first types are quite obviously better suited to the near term than the latter ones.
Looked at in this way, forecasting methods can theoretically be grouped as follows:
0 Very short-term forecasts, for periods under three months: these rely heavily on descrip-
tive methods such as breakdown into time series, exponential smoothing, stochastic pro-
cesses (especially Box-Jenluns), distribution models (e.g., Gompertz), etc.
0 Short-term forecasts covering periods of from three months to a year: the usual approach
is to extrapolate from the previous forecasts, but simplified regression models are pre-
ferred for use here.
0 Medium-term forecasts, covering one to three years: the preferred procedures in this
case are multiple regressions, econometric models, the Box-Jenkins method with trans-
fer, i.e., with loop or feedback.
0 Long-term forecasts, covering periods of three to five years: the most suitable tech-
niques in this case are econometric models, distribution models, qualitative methods
based on decision theory, for example, scenario methods such as Zwisky’s morpholog-
ical techniques, the Delphi survey, etc.
0 Very long-term forecasts, for periods greater than five years: the procedures concerned
their extrapolation: these have the advantage of being quantitative and thus making it
easier to apply formulas or modeling. Morphological analysis, whose object is to exam-
ine all the possible solutions for a given problem, one by one, also falls under this
approach.
0 Intuitive procedures that look essentially towards the future: these bring qualitative and
quantitative matters together and thus involve taking subjective factors into consider-
ation. The Delphi survey and scenario theory are prominent examples.
This type of procedure finds its justification in the application of the following principles, in
whole or in part:
0 Observed changes occur by means of progressive modification only, without disconti-
0 Similar changes occur when the agents of change are the same: several independentvari-
ables thus have to be considered.
In these circumstances, the resulting methods may be divided into two groups:
0 Those that have only one endogenous variable (time or an equivalent parameter), which
are called “internal”,
0 Those that have this endogenous variable, and also exogenous variables, which are
called “external”.
However, they both have the same three-stage manner of application:
0 Data analysis
Obviously the last step is the trickiest to achieve, especially as the period under consider-
ation is far-off. In practice, this procedure cannot be used except for short-term or very short-
term forecasts. It loses all meaning for the most distant outlooks, since even if there is no dis-
continuity, profound changes may occur over such a period, making it necessary to consider
subjective factors.
These require the availability of chronological (or chronicled) data and observations. For
this reason, in theory they can be applied only to existing products, whether tonnages or
price are concerned. In practice, they also apply, by extension, to substitute products.
Depending on the frequency of the observations, it is possible to distinguish various kinds
of phenomena:
0 A general trend
0 Seasonal variations
0 Cyclical variations
Evaluation is in general little concerned with seasonal or isolated effects, as long as they
can easily be recognized as such. More specifically, it is recommended that evaluations
ignore them completely. On the other hand it is essential to identify trends. In this connection,
we may mention the various procedures that follow.
does not qualify as a real cause (moving average methods, least squares, various statistical
smoothings or adjustments, etc.).
Yi being the observation at time i, and then obtaining the “moving average” from the relation:
in practice, n varies by discrete amounts; in this case, if n is an odd number, we take the value
of the median observation to be the sum of the two observed values that surround time t, and
for n/2 the smaller integer. For example, if n is expressed in months, for n + 1 = 13 the moving
average is obtained by considering the month corresponding to the time t, the six preceding
it and the six following it, and dividing the total by 13. For n + 1 = 12, it is calculated from
the sum of the two consecutive months surrounding t, the five preceding and the five follow-
ing, and dividing the whole by 12.
When the data cover a relatively short period of time, the graphs of moving averages fall
on a “quasi straight trend line”. Over a longer period regular fluctuations appear, defining a
cyclical phenomenon, whose amplitude and period may be calculated and used to determine
cyclic coefficients that can be used for future projections.
It is also possible to smooth out this effect by taking the moving average of several moving
averages and so on, so that at the end of the process we see only a straight trend line, to the
extent that this sort of thing retains any meaning.
atory, or descriptive (time, for example). The graphic expression: j7 = f(xl, x2,x3, ...) defines
a regression 2 curve or surface.
In the case of two variables Xand Y, the dependence gives rise to a set of points M having
the coordinates (x, j ) ,representing the average of they values corresponding to a single value
ofx. The broken line joining these points constitutes the line of regression of Y onX, to which
a regression curve may to be fitted. If this curve is a straight line of the form:
y(x) = ax + b or y(x) - J =a (x - J )
we speak of linear regression, a being the regression coefficient, where:
The operating principle of the least squares method for finding straight lines of regression
is to minimize the sum of the squares of the distances from each point M to this straight line,
measured parallel to the y-axis. Thus for two points Mj(xi, yi) and h$(xi, y(xj)), having the
same x-value, and located on the plane (x, y ) and on the straight line y (x) respectively:
COMMENTS
1. If y is linked to several variables (xl, x2, x3, etc.), we can use the least squares
method to find a multiple linear regression having the form:y(xl, ~ 2 , ~..3. x,)
, = a1x1
+~ 2 x +2 ~ 3 x+
3 ... + a,x, + b, in which al, a2, a3, ..., a, are partial coefficients of
regression that express the separate influence of each of the variables on y. In an
(n + 1)-dimensional space, this equation corresponds to the regression plane, such
that the sum of the squares of the distances to this plane from the points represented,
measured parallel to the y-axis, is a minimum.
2. If the adjustment is made by using a non-linear function, we speak of a curvilinear
regression.
0 In some cases (logarithmic, exponential, hyperbolic, parabolic, etc.) forms, a
change of variable may allow us to get back to a linear correlation, which will be
much easier to project into the future (anamorphosis).
In other cases, the adjustment may be made on curves representing polynomial func-
tions such as y = a + bx + ex2. The constants a, b, c are defined such that the sum of
the squares of the distances of the experimental points to the curve (measured paral-
lel to the axis of the dependent variable y ) is a minimum.
2. This term, which is very widely employed, especially in statistical data processing, was first
used by Sir F. Galton in 1886. A. Chupov in 1925 preferred the term stochastic relationshipwhich,
however, has been less popular since that time-to better express the random nature of the dependence
being studied.
24 1. Market Analysis
In effect, to minimize:
y = abcf or y = ea--bc‘
where a, b, c are constants and b and c lie between 0 and 1, allows adjustments to be
made using a type of curve that is very often encountered in practice, and which is
particularly useful for describing the variation over time of a given product’s sales.
These are so-called S-shaped curves which, by using the FERT method, bring
out four stages in the life of a product: a first, uncertain or inductive, and called
“funny” (F); a second, exponential development, called “exciting” (E); a third, linear
growth, called “reliable” (R); and finally a fourth, decline, called “trivial” (T).
Figure 1.4 shows various forms of curvilinear regressions (parabolic and cubic), by way
of illustration.
D. Exponential Smoothing
In contrast with the preceding methods, which assign the same weight to all observations
regardless of their age, and give more importance to numbers than to quality, this type of
operation has the advantage of favoring the more recent data over those of more distant date,
by giving them a greater weight. Doing this enables us to better express the continuing effects
of certain parameters, and to limit those belonging to factors that are now inactive-and
thereby to provide a better picture of recent changes in a trend.
The observations are weighted by using an inverse geometrical progression, such that the
further back the observation lies in the past, the weaker its influence becomes. If a represents
the weight of the present as compared with the past, we find:
Y Y
9, = a + b x + c x2
Y Y
log ?,= a + b x + c x2
Y Y
It must also be emphasized that this method can be just as well applied to monthly or quar-
terly data as it can to annual ones. In this way, seasonal or cyclic-type variations may be
brought out. Giving more importance to recent observations does introduce major possibili-
ties for error in making projections. In this case, it is necessary to employ exponential
smoothing only on information from which seasonal effects have been removed.
“Deseasonalization” can be applied to historical data by considering:
0 Either mean monthly differences, for example (Buys-Ballot method), calculated by sub-
tracting from the overall monthly mean a series of observations covering several years,
the averages for this period of time being determined for each of the year’s twelve
months,
26 1. Market Analysis
0 Or coefficients obtained by dividing the various preceding monthly means by the overall
monthly mean.
This is done before processing the data by one of the procedures already described, espe-
cially by exponential smoothing, and then by reversing it after the future projection is made,
to restore the seasonal effects.
COMMENTS
In this type of calculation, it is essential to distinguish cyclic variations from random
fluctuations, which may in particular arise from economic phenomena such as
strikes, breakdowns in supply, temporary incentives or constraints, etc. The corre-
sponding observations have to be eliminated or if possible corrected. The Box-Jen-
kins model, published in the United States in 1970, is a generalized, sophisticated
version of exponential smoothing. It is relatively complex, but on the other hand
more accurate, and like other internal forecasting methods is especially applicable to
the short or very short term. However, the drawback of the complexity is that it finds
few applications in evaluation, which is why we will not consider it at length here.
We will simply take note of its principle: it distinguishes between seasonal and non-
seasonal data, handles a variable number of parameters grouped under three head-
ings (differential or stationary parameters, moving average parameters, auto-regres-
sion parameters) and includes methods for confirmation and diagnosis (in particular,
autocorrelation).
Figure 1.5 Variation of the Industrial Production Index (IPI) for Western
Europe (OECD Europe). (Source: OECD)
3 . As a first approximation, for a given country these indicators correspond to the following defi-
nitions:
Gross National Product (GNP) = Gross Domestic Product (GDP) + Balance of Exchange with the
rest of the world.
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) = Gross Domestic Production (GDP) + Non-commercial Services
(1976 SECN Agreement or 1970 SEC equivalent, i.e., SystPme Elargi de Comptabilite Nationale, or
SystPme EuropCen des Comptes 6conomiques integrb: Expanded European System of National
Accounting, or Integrated European Economic Accounts System).
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) = total of the added values for all goods + total of added values of
commercial services (UN Convention referred to as the SCN =Systtme des Comptes NormalisPs:
Standardized Accounts System).
28 1. Market Analysis
The external variable may also be selected from among various statistical reference series,
particularly demographic ones (marriages, births, education, etc., so as to obtain, for example,
some ideas about consumption of food, clothing, items of equipment, etc.), socio-demo-
graphic ones (distribution of socio-professional categories, etc.), administrative ones (permits
for construction, driving, etc., telephone, broadcasting, and insurance fees, etc.), economic
ones (incomes, purchasing power, etc.), and manufacturing ones (various kinds of packaging,
depending on variations in the demand for the contents, etc.).
COMMENTS
1. In some cases, it may be useful to define relationships with several indices at the
same time, with a view to reducing some of the inertia and thereby, using a single
mathematical formula, to improve the overall correlation, i.e., the accuracy of the
eventual forecasts. The increase in the number of variables considered is accompa-
nied by a much greater complexity in the sophistication and use of the formula, and
in fact makes it necessary to develop true econometric models (see Q 1.2.3.2B).
2. So as to at least partially correct the shortcomings, for evaluation purposes, of
exogenous methods that employ precursor indices, it is often desirable to accompany
this type of procedure by what are called “scenarios”. This is done by assigning a
number of different values to the external variable: values, both higher and lower,
that the variable could have at some future time in various economic situations. The
principal characteristics of these future situations must first be imagined and
described in detail, in order to justify the particular values selected.
The probability of reaching or falling short of a minimum threshold for carrying out
a project, according to the more or less optimistic or pessimistic hypotheses consid-
ered (rosy, neutral, or gloomy scenarios), thus becomes a determining element in
deciding the fate of the project studied.
3. The precursor index method, along with the so-called “analogous” or “historical
comparison” procedures, is particularly applicable to new products, to the extent that
they may be directly substituted for existing materials. It also applies to products
already on sale, but whose development and behavior resemble, with a certain delay,
those of materials that have been available on the market for a longer time. An exam-
ple is offered by the evaluation of markets for household appliances, photographic
equipment (instant cameras, disposables, etc.), televisions, videotape recorders
(whose market is related to the preceding ones, and their replacement, etc.). Both an
example and a counter-example may be found in a comparison of the variation of
demand for polyamides (nylons), acrylics, and polyolefins in the United States
(Fig. 1.7). Until about 1970 the developments observed were essentiallyparallel, with
delays between the first product type and each of the two others, over a very long
period, of around eight years and 14-16 years respectively. Knowing the growth in
demand for nylons, it was thus possible to make very long-term growth forecasts for
the other two fibers. Although this empirical rule later held fairly true for the polyole-
fins, it turned out to be completely wrong for the acrylics, whose decline resulted from
their inabilitj-unlike their competitor products-to adapt to modem application
techniques, which were particularly designed to eliminate certain conversion steps.
30 1. Market Analysis
10 000
1 000
B. Econometric Models
These are significantly more complex than simple mathematical correlations with a single
index; but they offer the advantage of taking better account, by quantifying them, of the reac-
tions of the markets when confronted by various economic changes, especially variations in
the prices of raw materials and energy. Although they are better suited to longer term fore-
casting, they are not greatly employed in evaluation, owing to their relative complexity. Con-
sequently, the description given here is deliberately brief. Among the principal models of this
type we may distinguish:
0 Models with several explanatory variables, i.e., correlation and multiple regression
models. These parameters have already been mentioned above: in practice, it is a matter of
extending the so-called precursor index procedure to accommodate the simultaneous use of
several indices. But in this case, the work of the economic analyst is a lot more complicated,
since he first has to identify the exogenous (also termed independent or explanatory) vari-
ables, then compare the time series that he wants to correlate with the ones corresponding to
each of the parameters selected, determine the levels and the coefficients of correlation for
each variable treated separately, and finally define a single regression by adjusting the weight
of each component.
1. Market Analysis 31
In practice, there are plenty of programs for facilitating statistical data analysis, choosing the
most significant indicators, and finding the best-fitting regression, particularly by seeking to
minimize the sum of the squares of the remainders (squares of the distances, measured paral-
lel to the axis of the dependent variable, between the various observations and their equiva-
lents on the representative curve).
0 Behavioral models. These have a double advantage over the preceding methods.
Firstly, they allow for unusual parameters: ones therefore not included in the list of explana-
tory variables regularly considered, but which may be suggested by an examination of the
context in which the study is being conducted. These are usually phenomena of an economic,
decision-based-even unilateral and arbitrary-nature, but nevertheless capable of operating
over relatively long periods or even of having a decisive effect. This is particularly true of
“heavy” fashion trends, or political or administrative decision-making that could have major
impacts on the demands or prices for various products. By way of example, in some market
analyses conducted for actual evaluations concerning medium-term prospects for refining
and petrochemistry, it is essential to consider the effects of a possible limit on the benzene
content cf gasoline, even though the measure might still be far from being approved, and even
though alternative solutions would immediately be proposed.
Secondly, they make it easier to identify the truly exogenous variables, by integrating the
probable correlations between various parameters that, at first blush, appear to be indepen-
dent. This applies to the volume-price relations examined previously, which, when inserted
into models, remove price as an explanatory factor.
0 Economic analysis models. These deal more specifically with short-term forecasts and are
particularly well suited to defining the prospects for equipment purchases. In fact, in this case
they take into account not only general market trends and corresponding parameters, but also
current economic conditions (inflation, credit terms, household funds, loosening or tightening
of fiscal measures, levels of saving, etc.). However, they may have some uses in evaluation,
particularly in forecasts of the demand for various kinds of equipment (rotating machines,
machine-tools, etc.) or products (catalysts, pharmaceutical products, etc.)--to the extent that
the models distinguish between the initial markets, which depend essentially on techno-eco-
nomic performance, and the repeat markets, which reflect the existing stocks, the probable
lifetimes, and the functional reliabilities of the equipment or the quality of the products.
The first of these has trouble with accommodating external factors, especially over the
long term; the second yields insufficient detail about products.
Input-output methods derive from the work of Wassily Leontieff, who showed in the early
1930s that a country’s total production could be broken down according to its kinds and allo-
cations. The resulting tables, which are processed mathematically by using matrix calcula-
tions, enable us both to have a clear picture of the economic structure at a given moment, and
to make forecasts. They usually have n + k columns and n + m rows, corresponding to a
nation’s various sectors of activity, and contain zeros or positive numbers representing mon-
etary values.
The elements aii such that 1 I i I n and 1 I j I n express in monetary terms the total goods
supplied by sector i to sectorj.
The elements aii such that 1 I i I n and n + 1 IjI k express correspond to the values added
by sectorj (wages, taxes, profits, etc.).
The elements aii such that n + 1 I i I m and 1 Ij I n express the final demand (private and
public outlays, and commercial transactions).
In summary, the output of a particular sector has two components:
One corresponding to the inputs of the other sectors: this is the intermediate demand or
consumption,
The other brings together all the utilizations as such: this is the final demand or con-
sumption.
As an example, we may suppose that a particular date and for a given country the electric-
ity sector is divided up in the following manner:
Agriculture 238 MF
Fisheries 2
Industries 4 905
Families 1898
Public services 478
Total 7521
In most of these sectors electricity is utilized as such, but in the industry sector it enables
transformations, such that its total production may be expressed as follows:
Total production = Intermediate demand + Final demand
7521 4 905 2616
When such an operation is performed for the sectors considered, vectors are obtained for
the total production and the final demand, and a square matrix for the intermediate demand.
The main problem that is encountered when applying such a procedure to a particular sector
lies in the distribution and grouping of the data (breakdown and aggregation).
When applied to chemistry, for example, an inputloutput matrix for a given date appears
as a double-entry table:
0 The columns correspond to the principal sectors of economic activity for a region, a
country, or a group of countries (automotive sector, building, paper products, food, etc.):
they contain the various products whose markets we wish to study.
The rows correspond to the chemical products selected (polyvinyl chloride, polyethyl-
ene, polyester fibers, etc.).
1. Market Analysis 33
The figures appearing in this table may be expressed in volumes (tons), and represent the
quantities of each product used in each sector.
For their part, the national accounts provide the results in monetary terms (local curren-
cies) for the various sectors under consideration. They also allow us to define the correspond-
ing vector, so that we can determine a “coefficient of penetration” for each product at a given
point in time in each of the sectors under consideration, by calculating, for example, ratios
such as polyethylene (tons)/automotive sector (dollars).
If we now define a new matrix, comprising:
Columns representing industrial activity sectors, and
0 Rows representing chemical products,
and showing the penetration coefficients, multiplying this table by the vectors of the indus-
trial sectors in monetary terms will return us to the tonnages previously considered. But when
presented in this form the input/output matrix allows us to perform market studies and
medium- to long-term forecasts. In fact, we can use it on two levels:
0 The sectoral analysis level, i.e., using the value vector, whose structure is based:
+
Added
value
vi
IF/tl
-
In fact, each product is manufactured from certain “upstream” components, and contrib-
utes to obtaining various other ones “downstream”. Assuming that losses are negligible, we
can deduce a matrix based on the average outputs of the transformations employed, consisting
of columns and rows for the products considered, and dimensionless (tonnagekonnage) coef-
ficients bij in the table itself.
The demand for each product is the sum of the intermediate demands (transactions) and
the “final” demand for the product itself, utilized as such. It is written:
Xi = CbijXj + Yi
(overall demand) (exchanges) (final demand)
Solving this matrix system enables determination of the vector Xof the demands Xi.
We obtain a similar formula for prices. The price Pi of a given product depends both on
the material cost, Pj (purchase of raw materials), and on the production costs, vi (added
value), such that we may write the resulting relationship:
Pi - C bij Pj + Vi
(product price) (cost of materials) (added value)
The solution of this matrix system enables the determination of the vector P for the prices
Pi. Any forecast based on the matrix of coefficients bij may be expressed in concrete terms
by projections concerning price variations.
In contrast with methods based on the processing and extrapolation of historical data, which
we may describe as premised on the absence of discontinuity, procedures that place more
importance on direct analysis of the future consider that there can be breaks in development.
These may be caused by sudden changes in conditions, whether economic, political, or tech-
nical. As opposed to the analytical, logical, and somewhat static nature of the first methods,
the latter ones thus offer a more dynamic approach, and the potential to include irrational and
novel factors. They reconcile both qualitative and quantitative aspects, in contrast to methods
that look to the past and consist essentially of modeling, formalizing, and quantifying. Their
very principle makes them especially suitable for forecasting the markets for new products.
A. Representatives
We refer here to vendors. In this case it is a matter of short- or very short-term forecasts,
which are not really of interest for evaluation purposes, because the future they address is too
1. Market Analysis 35
close, and/or because they are designed for producer companies that have well-developed
marketing departments.
B. Customers
Forecasts based on customer opinions address the short and even the medium term. For this
reason they are closer to the concerns of evaluators and in fact are derived from market stud-
ies, performed either in a purely quantitative manner or semi-qualitatively.
In the first case, a representative group of customers are selected and a formal investigation
is conducted among them; periodic repetitions may provide necessary corrective or moderat-
ing factors, so that by looking at previous results it becomes possible to ensure a better cor-
respondence in the future between the forecast and the reality.
In the second case, more specific for industrial equipment items and new products, several
members of each of the entities included in the sampling are questioned: they are chosen on
the basis of their various functions. The investigations address not only the proposed product
but also its competition. The bulk of the study is devoted to the rationalization, homogeniza-
tion, and interpretation of the results: the latitude of the procedure makes it to some extent
qualitative.
In the case of renewable goods, many models have been developed in an attempt to simu-
late customer behavior, most of them complex and requiring preliminary investigations. In
particular they include the ones proposed by Urban, A.D. Anstutz, and others, and the
“Trade-off’ software based on the analysis of consumer choice criteria.
In addition to these, we must mention the so-called experimental technique, which consists
of conducting full-scale tests, or tests in specific markets, of certain customer reactions to var-
ious changes (price, packaging, advertising effects, etc.).
Procedures that rely on expert consultation are specifically technological forecasts, for the
medium and long term. For this reason, they are perfectly suited to the needs of evaluation.
On the other hand, they are usually onerous to apply and require considerable time to yield
results. This inertia reduces their effectiveness and discourages their use.
They were originally developed from the work of 0. Helmer, N.C. Dalkey, and T.J. Gor-
don of the Rand Corporation, published in the 1960s, who perfected the so-called Delphi or
Delphic method. In this technique, the opinions of a group of experts, selected for their qual-
ifications in a particular area of activity or in a given subject, are compared. It is based on the
following two principles:
0 Maintenance of the anonymity of the persons selected, so as to avoid mutual influences
first applied), combined with a recirculation of the information to all the experts being
consulted between each round: the objective being to eliminate the extreme opinions at
each repetition, or at least to require a justification, so as to progressively reduce the
spread of results until they become significant for forecasting purposes.
36 1. Market Analysis
In the most recent applications, special emphasis has been placed on improving speed and
efficiency, first by limiting the number of rounds (one or two at most), then by carefully draw-
ing up the questionnaires. These are “quali-quantitative” in nature and allow the experts to
reply very easily and very quickly by simply checking boxes; in addition, this way of doing
things lends itself readily to collecting and processing the information by computer.
By way of example, we may cite the investigation undertaken in the early 1980s by Saga
Petrokjemi AS&Co. (Norway) on the possible potential for using methanol as a fuel for auto-
mobiles in the United States and Western Europe. The goal in this case was to measure the
effects on the exploration and development of gas deposits in the North Sea, which would
then be a preferred source of raw material. The initial questionnaire provided for 35 replies,
some of a quantitative nature (time periods or values considered to be most probable), others
more qualitative in kind (level of agreement with a given statement, for example).
A. Internal Audit
The first step consists of assembling in-house as much information as possible on the “prod-
uct” (in the broadest sense of the term). Although it would be nice to have economic or mar-
keting data about it at the outset (markets tested to date, actors, competition, price, volumes
or quantities), the first priority at this stage should be the collection of technical information,
so as to properly identify the performances and especially the preferred area for intervention.
For this purpose, the framework of the main section of the questionnaires that will support
the subsequent steps must be drawn up. This stage may be the time to initiate parallel analyses
of the legal, financial, and other aspects, or of patent rights, whose results sometimes result
in halting any further investigation. This part of the study is in any case no more than an infor-
mal inquiry among the experts of the company that created the product in question.
B. External Audit
The second step consists of undertaking a similar task externally, but in a much more formal
and structured fashion, so as to produce a definitive questionnaire. In this case, it is a matter
of drafting a guide for interviews, whose contents must be validated by a small number of
1. Market Analysis 37
actors (10- 1 9 , through direct contacts with the persons selected, who will have recognized
skills in the field. The objective of these interviews 4, which should not take longer than an
hour and use advanced draft documents, completedjointly by both parties, which confirm the
seriousness of the operation, is three-fold:
0 To validate the content of the questions already selected and their formulation,
0 To complete the questionnaire, if need be, by adding items addressing the new concerns
applies to everything that concerns the technical characteristics of the product or its com-
petitors.
The content of the interview guide now remains to be defined. It must already exist in
semi-final form, i.e., it should be as “quali-quantitative” as possible, so as to reduce the time
for obtaining replies to a minimum. In practice, each question should give rise to a matrix (a
table) with a small number of rows (fewer than ten) of pre-selected identification criteria, in
other words the ones considered to be relevant and significant. The quantification is per-
formed in columns with pre-determined variation intervals. The object should be to make the
maximum use of the principle of checking boxes. However, it is also possible to envisage
grading scales (1 to 4 or I to 10 for example). In this case, it is best to choose an even number
of possibilities, so as to avoid a median, neutral grade, and to make the person take a position.
One may also ask for a preferential ranking of the criteria from 1 to n, and, as a last resort, an
evaluation, but it should be quantitative. And the person consulted should always be left some
degree of freedom, by providing a “Miscellaneous” or “Other” heading, while of course ask-
ing for the additions to be specified, i.e., numbered.
At this point, we can see the importance of consulting internal experts, who are the only
ones who can help to define these matrices. We can also see how desirable it may be to offer
a broad range for quantification at the beginning, so that when the interviews are completed
we can be certain of being able to properly re-center the questionnaire on the intervalsjudged
by the external audit panel to be the most promising.
When all is said and done, the compilation of these tables amounts to a genuine multi-cri-
terion analysis which, as far as the interview guides is concerned, actually consists of three
parts:
The first has to do with the company, represented by one or more parameters (labor force,
sales, activities, installations, export figures, level of facilities, preferred suppliers, etc.).
The second is essentially technical and concerns the product studied or, more precisely,
the general characteristics of competitor products on the market. In fact, it is important
not to disclose the level of performance attained, but instead to refer to the ones most
commonly encountered or sought after.
The last concerns marketing. It aims to measure people’s levels of satisfaction, and their
expectations. It also enables an assessment of the person’s view of the market: identifi-
cation and relative weighting of the actors, current price levels, acceptable additional
costs for better performance or to provide supplementary services.
4. In its simplified form, and to gain significant time, the investigation may be halted at this inter-
view stage, which moreover can be conducted partly on the telephone.
Next Page
38 1. Market Analysis
Upon completion of the external audit, the interview guide should lead to a relatively short,
clear, precise questionnaire, concise but nevertheless easy to read, which should not take
more than 10to 15 minutes to fill out. A personalized letter should accompany this document,
stating the purpose of the investigation, and motivating the addressee by assuring him that his
answers are confidential and that he will receive the overall results if he agrees to participate.
A technical brochure may possibly be attached. The number of addressees should preferably
be limited to 100 (maximum 200).
In this type of procedure, it is essential to avoid vertical filing, i.e., direct transfer to the
wastepaper basket. To do this, it therefore becomes important to carefully identify beforehand
the persons and not the companies to which it is mailed. It is better to have a limited list of
this type than to have a bigger but anonymous sampling. An effective solution consists of
making an introductory phone call before the mailing, and if no reply is received within a cer-
tain time (one to two months), to send it out again. But the bottom line is that the operation
may prove to be both arduous and costly. Thus, while waiting for a better solution, another
attractive method of communication to be considered is e-mail, or fax, which conceals the
banality of the questionnaire by including it among a shower of announcements and miscel-
laneous advertising. Here again the procedure may prove onerous and difficult, particularly
when the geographic coverage is a large one: finding the right addresses and numbers is not
always easy.
results of an investigation,
Construction of a model for forecasting purposes,
0 Checking the forecasts.
The reality is very different, especially in evaluation. In fact, experience shows that the
third stage is almost never reached. It is rare for any follow-up to be scheduled for a market
study. Because they are generally one-time events, such studies are only very seldom
repeated at regular intervals or sufficiently close together in time for it to be considered
worthwhile-all other things being equal-to confirm the level of agreement between the
initial forecasts and the reality. The checks performed are always too partial or too general.
In the evaluator’s defense, it must be remembered that he wields an extraordinarily change-
able weapon, both in its design and as concerns its possibilities and its credibility, and that
what is asked of him is first of all to define a frame for further work. In that same defense, we
should mention the general disillusion displayed in recent years by all forecasters and all
kinds of user vis-a-vis models, particularly towards the most complex and sophisticated ones,
most of which have failed miserably to live up to their claims. Finally the information is not
always available, at least when it is needed: the compilation and upkeep of data-banks, or
even the mere subscription required to have access to one, let alone the conduct of meaningful
Previous Page
1. Market Analysis 39
studies and the correct interpretation of their results, often appear too burdensome and too
lengthy to undertake.
In conclusion, in the area of market analysis, as well as in the areas that come within its
field of application, the only course for evaluation is to make the most of some of the panoply
of forecasting methods available, while continuously adapting to the reliability of the infor-
mation available and to the time constraints imposed. From this point of view, methods based
on the extrapolation of historical data, combined with the use of several scenarios, are an
evaluator’s most suitable choice and, relatively speaking, the most efficient one. This is in
spite of their mediocre record for the medium and long term, and their even worse one in the
very long term.
Although the same procedure may in theory be applied to processing both price and volume
data, experience shows that the specificities of each of these two fields should be considered
before making a choice among the many methods available. In fact, in practice there is some
segregation, and a preferential use of certain ways of performing regressions and extrapola-
tions rather than others, depending on the kind of information concerned.
Here, we will not be dealing with the various kinds of price usually encountered in the area
of marketing, nor with the mechanisms that govern their setting. This matter is discussed in
detail in Chapter 2, 5 2.2.1.2. The main emphasis here is on forecasting and methodological
aspects.
Concerning price, the attitude taken and thus the choice of a forecasting method are essen-
tially a function of the type of calculation envisaged. Particularly in the case of evaluation,
the method is characterized by a priori reasoning from a real industrial situation, both in eco-
nomic and technical terms, and trying thereby to limit additional uncertainties by reducing
the number of exogenous variables and their associated lack of precision. Consequently, it is
often useful, if not indispensable, to begin by omitting the effects of inflation. One way of
doing this is to operate in “constant currency.”
values for this reference. To do this, it is necessary to have a correction factor, or preferably
a ratio of indices, for a given country, that takes into account the depreciation of the national
economy. This may be a variation in the purchasing power, the gross national product, the
average price, etc.
This so-called “deflation index” is premised on the fact that the “standard of value” usually
undergoes a deterioration that it is useful to correct, so as to make realistic comparisons at
different dates.
For a manufacturer, this depreciation roughly corresponds to the general rise in product
prices and shows up in its sales figures, i.e., in the price-volume relationships.
In the simplistic theoretical case where only one product is being considered, the sales fig-
ure Vat a given moment is such that:
V = q P where q = quantity produced
P = unit price
0 for t = to, we have VO = qo Po
0 fort=t vt = 4, pt
V, - Vo represents the variation of production in nominal values, when q and P vary simulta-
neously.
To compensate for the price variations and find the real changes in production, we must
determine:
vto = 4t Po
Vp - Vo then represents the variation in real terms.
Now:
vp=v‘ mP o lPmt
or:
example, the GNP Deflator is used; in Western Europe, and more specifically in France, the
index of consumer price development is utilized, or the implicit index of the GDP.
By way of indication, Table 1.3 presents the information concerning this latter method of
calculation since 1970. Figure 1.9 shows an application of deflation to the price of crude
petroleum since 1970, under this same procedure. Graph 1.9a shows US$ per barrel and
Graph 1.9b French francs per ton. Both of them clearly portray the effects of the two energy
crises of 1974 and 1980. However, the first one brings out the decrease in real value of a bar-
rel of petroleum in US$ after this date, while the second, because of the increase in the
exchange rate of the dollar against the French franc between 1980 and 1985, shows the con-
stant value of the cost of a ton of petroleum in local currency during this period.
Among the indices that are best suited to an industrial sector or a particular kind of product,
we may mention, for example:
0 For France: the monthly and annual indices of wholesale energy prices, motor vehicles,
pharmaceutical specialties, processed and non-processed foods, and indices related to pro-
duction sales prices (before tax) for refractories, glasses, etc., inorganic chemicals (excluding
fertilizers), fertilizers, organic chemicals 6 , etc.
For the United States: The Nelson indices published in The Oil and Gas Journal, partic-
ularly for inorganic (code 613) and organic (code 614) products, and for various items of
equipment, the Chemical Engineering and Chemical Week indices, etc.
Their specific application is discussed in more detail in the section on methods of calcu-
lating operating and cost prices (see Chapter 2, 6 2.2). Generally speaking, any index of the
variation in product price, equipment cost, value of a particular good, etc. may be used to cal-
culate deflation.
The coefficients a l , a2,a3,etc., represent the weights (or volumes) of outputs from the pro-
cess that converts the starting materials into the product studied; a priori, they are constant,
at least for a certain level of unit production capacity; bo is a term that includes all the other
manufacturing costs, and as a first approximation it too may be taken as constant.
5. This is a matter of a weighting among 295 categories of expense, performed by working house-
holds or employees residing in towns of all sizes; the analysis is based on about 160000monthly state-
ments, conducted at 30000 points of sale in a hundred urban areas.
6. These indices are calculated and published by the INSEE, particularly in the Annuaire Statis-
tique de la France (French Statistical Yearbook).
42 1. Market Analysis
France USA
80 -
70.
cc
60.
50 .
-2
i 40-
30 . h
20 .
10 ..
01
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
400
350
300
250
-g!
$ 200
LL
150
100
50
0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Figure 1.9b Variation in the crude petroleum price in FFIt. (Source: IFP)
44 1. Market Analysis
If one of the raw materials involved has a dominant economic weight, and if the prices of
the others are held constant, the preceding expression is simplified:
Pproduct = a P m +b where b = Cte
If, in addition, b is small, we find:
---
‘produc t
= Cte
R
‘M
Situations of this kind are found in many areas of industrial activity, particularly in sophis-
ticated chemical products (as long as we exclude the costs of packaging, advertising, invest-
ment in research, etc., i.e., marketing costs), and also in refining, where as shown in Fig. 1.10
we have relationships of the form:
1.2
‘naphtha
-- = 1.2 or
‘diesel
-- ~
crude crude
In practice, these are average values, around which we find fluctuations of ilO% ?. Corre-
lations of this type prove to be less evident in other areas, such as petrochemistry for example,
so that b may no longer be ignored. However, certain trends that result from smoothing, and
consequently certain extrapolations, may be obtained from a study of the variation of such
ratios over time. Figure 1.11 is an illustration of this for the prices of the major intermediate
petrochemical products ethylene, propylene, and benzene, which are mainly obtained from
naphtha, at least in Western Europe. In spite of some major fluctuations, mostly due to eco-
nomic phenomena linked to production incidents that led to appreciable imbalances between
supply and demand, there is an obvious relationship between the prices of these products and
that of the raw material from which they come, and this can be used to make short- or even
medium-term forecasts.
Relations linking the prices of products and their raw materials may help to make techno-
logical forecasting much easier. Two examples based on the concept of the equivalence rela-
tion and the division of areas will provide illustrations.
7. Figure 1.10 is presented as an example to show the roughly parallel variations of diesel fuel and
naphtha, except for the period covering the first half of 1986. This apparently erratic variation is
explained by the fact that at that time the British coal producers were on strike, and the fuel then pref-
erentially consumed in the United Kingdom for residential or community heating was coal. There was
a transfer of the corresponding demand onto domestic fuel oil (which is an almost identical product of
the diesel fuel production process). The pressure on supplies led to a very sharp rise in the price of
middle distillates.
In conclusion, it should be remembered that before defining a relationship it is important to elimi-
nate aberrant situations (remove accidents, remove seasonal effects, etc.) by endeavoring to identify
the events that produced them.
1. Market Analysis 45
1.8
1.ti
0
U
5
c
0
$
I
5-
V
1.4
1
I
1985 1986 1987 1988
Figure 1.10 Variation in the ratios of the Rotterdam spot prices of naphtha
and diesel to the price of Brent crude. (Sources: ECN, Platt 's,etc.)
V .
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
First example
This deals with two ways of synthesizing methanol, using either coal or natural gas as the
starting material. We thus obtain, depending on the case:
Prnethanol = Pcoal +
The price equivalence according to one or the other of these two possibilities also leads to
a linear relation:
b'-b
Coal = a
U'
f'natural gas + a
represented graphically (Fig. 1.12) by a straight line whose slope is unchanged over time as
long as there is no improvement in the yields, but whose intercept on the y-axis is valid only
for a given date, because it depends heavily on the investment costs of the plants. This straight
line delimits two areas, one favoring the use of coal (on the side of the natural gas price axis),
the other favoring the use of natural gas (on the side of the axis graduated in coal prices).
Depending on the relative variation of prices of the two raw materials (expressed in constant
200
150
s
e loo
al
0
.-
-hm
0
50
0
0 2 4 6 8 10
CIF price of natural gas ($rrmMBTU)
*
currency at the time of the study so as to be free of the constraint imposed by changes in the
y-intercept of the equivalence line) we can immediately decide, for a particular location
(Western Europe), not only on the economic potential of one technology versus the other, but
also on the probability of a change in conditions occurring in the long run. In the example
given, it would be difficult to imagine that coal, delivered in Northwest Europe, could ever
compete with methane in the synthesis of methanol, at least without the occurrence of major
upheavals.
Second example
The second illustration deals with a single technology capable of being applied, as before,
to two different raw materials (benzene and toluene), but leading to two products that are also
different: one established, styrene, the other a new one, p-methylstyrene. Insofar as the cor-
responding polymers have properties that are at least comparable, if not better for the second
one, here again we may look for the equivalence line for installations, either new, i.e., not yet
depreciated ones, or revamped ones (Fig. 1.13). In this case, it is a matter of adapting the sty-
5 000
4000
st
.-0
h 3000
Q)
w
:
2 000
1000
1000 2000 3000 4000 5000
Toluene price (FF/t)
8. Deflation performed using either the GNP Deflator Index (United States) or the consumer price
index (France).
48 1. Market Analysis
rene-producing units, which operate either in the liquid phase (oldest units) or in the vapor
phase (newest units), to obtain p-methylstyrene. The investment costs, which vary from one
case to the other, appear as three different straight lines of equivalence, each of which divide
the diagram into two areas, one favoring the production of styrene (on the side of the toluene
price axis), the other favoring p-methylstyrene (on the side of the axis graduated in benzene
prices). In addition, Fig. 1.13 shows the simultaneous variation in the prices of benzene and
toluene in Western Europe and the United States, in constant currency for the end of the
period. The result provides little encouragement for the construction of p-methylstyrene
plants, unless the resulting polymer offers distinctly better performances than polystyrene,
which would justify a price increase. It is not favorable to the revamping of liquid-phase sty-
rene units either; on the other hand, however, it does favor Mobil-type plants that operate in
the vapor phase. Unfortunately platforms of this kind are still uncommon and of recent date,
and thus far from having been completely paid off; in addition, the demand for toluene fuels
(lead-free gasolines) is not trending in the direction of a decrease in its price relative to that
of benzene.
Generally speaking, the price of a product at any given moment may be regarded as consisting
Time
Figure 1.14 Variation of the margin and floor price over time.
(Source: IFP)
1. Market Analysis 49
0 The floor price (or minimum profitable sales price) whose method of calculation is given
in Chapter 2, represents the lowest price that the market’s best-established producer would
ask. In a particular geographic area, this leader would thus be the one that currently had the
most efficient plants, both in terms of unit production capacity, giving it the greatest econo-
mies of scale, and of applied technology. These installations, which would necessarily be
recent, would therefore not have been amortized, requiring capital charges to be included in
the cost of manufacture.
The floor price also corresponds to the price that this same producer would ask for the con-
struction of a new plant having the same characteristics. So it is a reference price, which the
competition must try to meet if it wants to hold onto its share of the market.
The margin represents the difference between a product’s actual price at a given moment,
and its floor price. It depends on the demandsupply situation and may be very high, espe-
cially where new products are concerned. But, because they are attractive these high margins
are unstable: in fact, they encourage other producers to invest, which results in temporary pro-
duction overcapacities compared with needs, and thus leads to a general fall in sales prices.
In this regard, in fact, we must distinguish strong trends from short-term movements, over
the life of a product.
A. Strong Trends
Chronologically, there are three periods to consider.
a. Disappearing Margins
A reduction in the initial price first affects the margin, although its variation is only very grad-
ual: in order to maintain or increase its influence, each producer will seek to sell a little more
cheaply than its competitors, while still making maximum profits; usually, it is in no-one’s
interest to “break” the market. The fall in sales price is also partly due to a reduction in the
floor price: the opening of markets results in the construction of unit capacities of greater size,
and a better optimization of the techniques employed. Experience shows, however, that the
decline in the margin is by far the more significant: for new products it operates at an expo-
nential rate of 15 to 20% during the early years. In the past, this situation was even set up as
a principle by certain economists who extrapolated this downward trend, maintaining for
example: “If the sales volume grows two- or three-fold, the price will be approximately equal
to two thirds of the starting price”. Moreover, until the 197Os, i.e., before the first global
energy crisis, the reality did conform to this principle, as particularly shown in Fig. 1.15, for
six intermediate and 16 final products of the United States organic chemistry industry. This
graph, which normalizes the observed phenomena by making the origin of the time axis the
year in which the price began to fall, and assigning an index of 100 to the initial value, imme-
diately brings out the existence of a correlation. It also shows a regular, exponential decrease
that leads to an average reduction of about 50% in current currency after ten years.
The diminution in the margin continues until its complete disappearance, i.e., until the
moment when the sales price reaches the floor price. After that, we see fluctuations around
this value (Fig. 1.14). However, a manufacturer cannot maintain a price level below the the-
50 1. Market Analysis
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
Years since prices began to fall
oretical minimum for very long, without shortly having to shut down its plant. The recent
history of the steel, coal, refinery, and petrochemical industries shows what happens: the
disappearance of the least efficient plants is found to be necessary for the re-establishment
of a price scale that will not only allow the remaining units to function in an economically
satisfactory manner, but also enable a level of profitability that will encourage new
investments. This first takes the form of improvements in the utilization rate at existing facil-
ities.
0 Variable or proportional costs (cost of materials, expenses for catalyst, solvent, chemi-
cal products, energy and other utilities, etc.), resulting directly from the operation’s
material and energy balance sheets,
0 Marketing costs (packaging, advertising, distribution, etc.) and the costs of research.
As Fig. 1.16 shows, fixed operating and capital costs have a tendency, if not actually to
decrease as a result of the economies of scale, at least to stabilize because of the effects of
inflation on the investments; marketing costs tend to remain approximately constant. On the
other hand the variable costs, which are directly proportional to the cost of raw material, are
very sensitive to any change in its price. This explains why the rise in the price of petroleum,
and more generally in the cost of energy, from 1974to 1985,was directly reflected in the floor
prices of products, pulling them higher. During this same period, the high rates of inflation
and of return on capital that were encountered and pursued in many countries only served to
accentuate the phenomenon, by erasing what economies of scale were still possible. Ulti-
mately, the variation of the floor price for most products over time presented a U-shaped
Marketing, administrative,
\ Variable costs
-5 0 5 10 15 20
.
25
Years
curve. For a while, this observation too was set up as a principle, just for the purpose of mak-
ing forecasting easier. In fact, such a representation could be expressed mathematically by an
equation of the form:
P=ao+al t + a 2 t 2 + a 3 t 3
P being the floor price and t the time.
The coefficients ag, al, a2, a3, are derived by solving the set of equations obtained by con-
sidering four values of P at different periods in the past, i.e., by assuming that a large part of
the U-shaped curve is known, in particular the coordinates of four points on it, and that they
correspond to the prices calculated for the most efficient plants at each of the dates consid-
ered.
This eventuality, which appeared impossible to forecasters in the 1975-1985 period, has
become a reality in recent years in various industrial sectors, particularly in organic chemis-
try. Several things have helped to create a favorable situation: some have enabled the floor
price to be lowered significantly and then held steady, others have made it possible to follow
this by raising product sales prices.
For the first group the determining factor has been the fall in the real value of crude petro-
leum, which began to appear in the United States after 1980, but was in fill swing from 1986
onwards and accelerated in 1998-1999, reaching levels similar to those seen after the first oil
crash. In spite of some subsequent fluctuations and a marked recovery in producer country
prices (more than US$30/bbl in the third quarter of 2000), it appears that we may expect a
measure of stabilization at around US$17-20/bbl over the medium term. Another major factor
for most of the industrialized countries has been control of inflation, accompanied by a low-
ering, albeit moderate, in the interest rates set by the central banks. An exception is Germany,
where this option has been delayed as long as possible. However, the current economic recov-
ery should eventually result in some revival of inflation. Of course, the crises that have in
recent years successively affected Eastern Europe, then Southeast Asia, and finally Latin
America are evidence to the contrary. For all that, since they are essentially financial in ori-
gin, they can probably do little more than slow down a steady trend towards a growth in
demand signs of reflation are already visible in certain countries.
For the second group, we must especially bear in mind the recovery in demand and then
the scarcity of supply: by restoring the utilization rate of the production facilities these factors
first enabled the plants to benefit from near-maximum economies of scale, and then to bring
pressure to bear on availability, i.e., to drive up prices.
The resulting reconstruction of margins is also facilitated by certain governmental mea-
sures aimed at reducing taxes on company profits. To the extent that manufacturers are
increasingly encouraged to reinvest, in spite of the caution that past events must induce, the
main question concerns the duration of the phenomenon. The construction of new units that
could relieve pressure on available supplies, and thus on prices, cannot have its fill impact in
less than two or even three years from the date of the decision. From this viewpoint, for exam-
ple, projects announced in 1988-1989 implied that there would be little to fear before 1991-
1992: until that time both the sales prices and the margins should therefore remain high.
1. Market Analysis 53
Afterwards, the possible proliferation of new facilities could only reduce the average utiliza-
tion rate for all facilities, pushing the floor price up and leading to a diminution of the mar-
gins. We must nevertheless point out that other factors also contributed to this situation
(maintenance of a high level of price for raw material, erratic behavior of intermediates, etc.).
When all is said and done, although fluctuations may appear in short- and medium-term
forecasts of the variation of sales prices over time for most products, if we look at the longer
term and smooth out the historical data, it appears that the U-shape described above may still
apply. A polynomial equation is therefore sufficient to describe the phenomenon mathemat-
ically.
Such an approach is supported by the illustration presented in Fig. 1.17, which shows the
variations in the posted prices of various major intermediate petrochemical products in the
United States. Some of these, relatively new ones like acrylonitrile, show a more or less steep
fall at the start of the period examined; other older ones such as ethylene have an almost flat
profile. The results for major mineral or energy products would be similar. Obviously it
would be necessary in this case to go back to an earlier time period to observe the phenome-
non. It can also be brought out by applying a deflation index so as to work in constant cur-
rency for the end of the period (constant US dollars), instead of in current currency (current
US dollars). Figure 1.18 presents the result of doing this, for the major intermediate petro-
chemical products already mentioned. In addition, eliminating the effects of inflation has the
advantage of moderating the fluctuations and consequently making modeling and extrapola-
tion easier.
Figure 1.17 U.S. price variation for various chemical products, in current
currency. (Source: Chem. Marketing Reporter)
54 1. Market Analysis
Figure 1.18 U.S. price variation for chemical products, in constant currency
(1986 US$). (Source: ZFP)
B. Short-Term Variations
Fluctuations in the posted prices of high-tonnage products, which may be considerable even
in a period of relative economic stability, usually seem to be unpredictable. In fact, they
depend on too many parameters to permit any general interpretation that could lead to a suf-
ficiently reliable forecasting method. However, some of them are more significant than oth-
ers, and all by themselves may bring out subtler, i.e., shorter-term trends than the ones
mentioned previously. In this way, without undertaking a detailed analysis of the economic
events that produce these periodic saw-tooth variations, which are described as “volatility”,
it is nevertheless possible to use them to explain the overall past course of events, and conse-
quently to derive succinct rules for extrapolation.
Thus, for products that are already mature, and have modest profit margins, we find that
slight variations in demand sometimes lead to significant changes in price. It can be the same,
too, when unexpected plant stoppages follow incidents or accidents, and then if more of these
chance events occur there is a veritable surge in prices. In other words, variations of a few
percent (no more than &5%) in needs or availabilities at the world level, or within a given
geographic region, often have significant effects on price variations.
These temporary phenomena, whose magnitude we try to predict in spite of everything,
must be separated from longer-term ones that are the reflection and the consequence of so-
called strong trends, such as the opening of markets due to demographic expansion or
1. Market Analysis 55
improvement in living standards, and inversely by major economic recessions. These large-
scale variations result in the construction of new plants or conversely the permanent closure
of less efficient ones. The fluctuations, which are a priori more erratic in the very short term,
indicate a more or less complete matching of the market’s immediate supply potential to the
demand. In a way, they serve to recognize the existing mechanism’s lack of operational flex-
ibility at a given moment, and its inability to respond or adapt to additional disturbances.
Such a shortcoming is felt even more strongly as the production required approaches its
theoretical limit. In other words, as the utilization rate of the facilities increases, their sensi-
tivity to manufacturing incidents, to interruptions in output, etc., and generally to “marginal”
effects, grows exponentially. This is why various authors have come to define a “tightness
index”, expressed as follows:
capacity
tightness index = loglo
capacity - production
When extended to continental or even global scale, or even just to the scale of a single
country, depending on its level of industrialization, this concept requires some adjustments,
especially when it deals with widely sold products. In fact, a unit in continuous production is
generally calculated as actually working for a period of less than a full year, so as to take
account of scheduled stoppages for essential maintenance; it is sized according to a particular
work factor (see Chapter 2, Section 2.2. I. 1). Experience shows that when the number of facil-
ities considered is large enough, it is impossible to reach the maximum cumulative manufac-
turing potential: there are always one or more sites that are idle because of servicing.
Furthermore, owing to previous major accidents, some workplaces undergo prolonged shut-
downs. When it is possible to draw up a balance sheet for the facilities that are really in oper-
ating condition at a given moment, it is preferable to use the term “capability” instead of
“capacity”.
Except for this nuance, the tightness index proves to be a relatively efficient tool for short-
term forecasting. In fact, historical analysis shows that the level of correlation between this
index and some economic criterion, such as the ROI, the cumulative discounted cash flow, or
the IRR (see Chapter 2, Section 2. I), designed to measure the profitability of a manufacturing
process, is usually high. To illustrate this we have only to look at Figs. 1.19a and l.l9b, for
example, which show the United States market for p-xylene. The first displays the variation
over time of the gross profit in % together with the tightness index: the two curves are essen-
tially parallel. The second shows that a linear correlation may be obtained from them:
profitability = a x tightness + b
a and b being constants, in the present case respectively 39 and -28, so that: gross profit (“!)
= 39 TI - 28.
We will show later that for any value of a profitability criterion, a corresponding sales price
PV may be calculated, as long as certain economic data are available (investments Z,produc-
tion expenses D, etc.). Thus, for example, for the ROI we have the following equation:
ROIxZ+D
PV =
capacity
56 1. Market Analysis
Figure 1.19b U.S. market for p-xylene. Correlation of gross profits and
tightness index. (Sources: IFP, Chem-Systems, etc.)
1. Market Analysis 57
In conclusion, any prediction about how flexible the functioning of a group of installations
will be, must allow us to make predictions about prices 9.
900
800
700
-
*
600
Other
kinds of
Naphtha
with limited
Naphtha
and/or liquid
500 eedstock flexibility & integration feedstock
.-s
L1
ij 400
a
‘0
& 300
200
100
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18
Ethylene capacity (Mt/yr)
Figure 1.20 Variation ofthe minimum profitable sales price with cumulative
production capacity (for ethylene in Western Europe, 1991).N.B.: in that year,
the economics of steam cracking using ethane feedstock were better than for
naphtha. (Sources: IFP, SM, etc.)
9. This method must however be applied cautiously, since the concept of tightness is much more
complex than indicated here, and is linked not only to the balance between supply and demand, but
also, in particular, to the composition of the “pool” of suppliers and/or customers. As an illustration,
simply imagine a global market (demand) of 1000000 tlyr, fed (supply) either by 20 installations of
50000 t/yr each, or by 2 units each one by itself producing 500000 t/yr. The risks of an imbalance
occurring are much higher in the second case than in the first.
58 1. Market Analysis
a price, when all is said and done, that leads to plant shut-downs. It is usually a reflection in
economic terms of market conditions affecting those production units that may be character-
ized, whether wholly or in part, as having too small an output, insufficiently modern technol-
ogy, or a physical plant that is too old. However, in this connection we should note one
positive feature: the possible lack of capital costs, resulting from full amortization of equip-
ment after a certain period (generally 10 years); these may compensate for competitors’ tech-
nological advances or economies of scale.
If one constructs a graph whose x-axis shows the cumulative production capacities of the
various production units for a given product within a selected geographic region, and whose
y-axis shows, in ascending order, the corresponding minimum profitable sales prices for each
production unit, given its specific features, one generally finds a very flattened, S-shaped
curve, displaying a very wide “plateau” (Fig. 1.20). The first decile of production capacities
serves to identify the most favored plants, and the last decile the most threatened ones. In this
way it is possible, for example, to assess the size of a potential replacement market, or alter-
natively the limits of fluctuation of a product’s price with respect to an average level, identi-
fied by the y-value of the curve’s inflection point.
Just as for price variation, variations over time in the size of the demand, i.e., the quantities
sold, have certain specific characteristics. In addition, they are accompanied by some partic-
ular concepts, notably the penetration rate and the growth rate.
Time
QR =-
Qt and TR =- r,
Q 00 Tl 00
where Q = volume or quantity and T = time, and then to establish the degree of progress or
maturity of the various products, we must find a way to determine the characteristics, even
approximates ones, of the maximum for each one, especially for the ones that have not yet
reached or passed that stage. For this purpose, it is of the greatest importance to correctly
identify the most appropriate parameters, preferring the ones that can be of assistance in mak-
ing extrapolations. It would therefore appear that the concept of penetration is well suited to
normalization as regards quantity (y-axis), while time (x-axis) should no longer be expressed
as dates but as relative durations, by adopting as the origin (reference date) the moment when
the product began to be industrially manufactured and sold.
By definition, the meaning of this expression is “the level of presence of a product or a brand
in a market for goods or services”, and the rate of penetration is “the ratio between the number
of customers using a product from a given manufacturer, and the total number of potential
customers in the market for this product”. By extension, it is also defined as being the ratio
between the quantities actually sold and those potentially saleable; in this case, it represents
the market share taken up. According to different writers, the concept has been more or less
1. Market Analysis 61
broadened and misused. From this viewpoint, the mathematical correlation of the demand
with a precursor index such as the number of inhabitants or the industrial production index
(IPI) permits a kind of generalization. Thus, the consumption per capita or per index point
constitutes an indication of the market penetration and may be taken as a measure of the sat-
isfaction of the potential needs of the customer base or of an industrial sector:If the latter are
expressed in the same units the ratio between the two is equivalent to the penetration rate as
originally defined, because the element of correlation is then eliminated.
In its general form, however, this parameter offers the advantage of immediately introduc-
ing the concept of reduced coordinates. It is based on the maximum possible market, and
thereby justifies its selection for the construction of normalized graphs.
The additional interest of utilizing it in a derived form, especially when correlated with a
precursor index, arises from the possibilities offered for extrapolation and the rapid identifi-
cation of “critical” conditions.
In this connection, various writers, including D. Stevenson, have demonstrated, first, the
effectiveness of using the industrial production index (see 0 1.2.3.2.A) as a forecasting tool,
by testing it on a large number of chemical intermediates. They showed that although the rela-
tionships might be linear for considerable periods, overall they displayed an S-shape, like the
demand curves over time, differing only in that the slope of the tangent at each point provides
a measure of the speed of market penetration, in the broad sense of the term. Figure 1.23,por-
traying the consumption of styrene-butadiene rubber in Western Europe since 1960,provides
an illustration of this. It should moreover be noted that the graph of the variation of consump-
tion against index points has an S-shape too.
0.8
3
Y
I
0
E 0.6
8
a
m
.
v)
0
0.4
0
0.2
40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Industrial Production index (base 100 In 1980)
D. Stevenson also suggested a simplified method for determining the limits beyond which
extrapolation should not be pushed, i.e., the approximate position of the demand ceiling. The
approach consists of using logarithmic coordinates so as to obtain a linear representation of
the graph illustrating the relationship between the penetration for a particular year, and that
for the previous year. In these circumstances the first bisector is the place where the penetra-
tion values are the same from one year to the next, indicating zero growth. The intersection
of the representative straight line with this first bisector will therefore correspond to a station-
ary demand, i.e., to the desired ceiling; its coordinates will enable the identification of both
the timing and the size of the saturation threshold.
This method is illustrated in Figs. 1.24 and 1.25, showing the variation in demand for sty-
rene-butadiene rubber in Western Europe. The first shows the linear relationship obtained
using data from the period 1961- 1973; the intersection with the first bisector indicates a the-
oretical maximum penetration of 11 (thousands of tons per IPI point). The second enables
comparison of this result with the reality, by looking at all the information available for the
1960-1983 period. The difference for penetration is about 10%; as for the date of 1975 pre-
dicted by the theory, it actually occurred in 1971-1972. This procedure is of interest not so
much for its accuracy, which is all the more uncertain because the slope of the representative
straight line is near 45”, but rather for the possibility that it offers for placing limits on the
extrapolation and for estimating the characteristics of the “critical point”, whose identifica-
tion is essential for normalizing the variation curves for needs, and for determining levels of
maturity.
5 10
Log (penetration rate for the previous year)
Experience shows that application of this method to products that are already in decline
leads to estimates that exceed the reality by around 10 to 15%, which is explained by the
impossibility of actually saturating the potential markets. In these circumstances, so as not to
cause disparities with products in the expansion phase, normalized graphs should be con-
structed from the calculated critical parameters, and reduced by 10% even when actual fig-
ures are available.
1.3.2.3 Real and Average Growth Rate. Application to the Long Term
For products that are known, for example by using the above procedure, to be developing in
an exponential or linear manner, either growing or shnking, it may be of interest for extrap-
olation purposes to employ a parameter that is often mentioned in economic publications: the
growth rate. This concept is based on the following approach.
Let Do be the initial demand for a particular product. After one year, it will have increased
or decreased in a certain proportion rlDO, such that it is equal to:
D1 = Do(1 + Y1)
where rl represents the rate of growth between 0 and 1.
At the end of the second year, it becomes:
0 2 = Dl(1 + ~ 2 =) Do( 1 + ~ 1 ) (1 + 72)
64 1. Market Analysis
COMMENT
This expression is mathematically similar to the one for the continuous compound
interest rate i; in fact, i is such that, if a sum So is borrowed at this rate in year 0, a
sum S,,:
s,,= so (1 + i)”
must be repaid in year n.
D,,= D, em
'' (1.4)
where rm= average growth rate, linked to t by Eq. (1.1).
Note that the expression (1.3) may be written:
4 -- rmt
log -
DO
The corresponding curve as a function o f t is a straight line of slope rm,which agrees with
the above conclusions.
The extrapolation of needs by the exponential method expressed in Eq. (1.3) does not con-
sider the effect of market saturation, and very quickly leads to conclusions that are badly
wrong.
To accommodate this slowing down phenomenon, W.W. Taddle and J.B. Malloy, for
example, suggested a modification of the above model, first of all by introducing an element
that would provide a progressive correction, and then by setting a threshold below which the
growth in demand is highly unlikely to fall, during the extrapolation period considered. This
limiting growth rate r , in fact corresponds to a balance between the consumption of the prod-
uct under consideration, and a value characteristic of the economy, for example the GNP, the
IPI, etc.
So in the worst case, we may suppose-as before, of course, during the expansion phase-
that after an infinite time the growth of the sales volume will coincide with the value that the
institutional forecasters envisage for such an indicator. Under these circumstances, we find
that the growth rate at a given date is composed of two terms, one representing the limiting
growth rate r,, and the other decreasing exponentially over time from the initial value ro to
r,, i.e., with a time constant k such that:
Putting this new definition of r into the Eqs. (1.2) and (1.3) for the exponential variation
of demand, we obtain:
t f
0 0
or, by integration:
66 1. Market Analysis
'0 (I - ,+)
and: D=Doek
The use of this model assumes that the available data are sufficient to calibrate it to begin
with, i.e., to enable the value of k to be determined. To do this we must first divide the historic
data into two groups: older ones leading up to a definition of ro in the not too distant past, and
more recent ones, for example covering the last two or three years, providing the value of Y
for that period. We then calculate k using Eq. (1S),and retain the result for use in the same
equation when it is used for forecasting, r then becoming the unknown. However, applying
such a procedure demands certain precautions: it is desirable to avoid the use of statistical
information resulting from exogenous events (war, economic crisis, sudden inflation, deval-
uation, etc.). The curve in Fig. 1.19a illustrates this, with the 1942-1944period corresponding
to the Second World War, during which the demand for acetylene in the United States
reflected not only the traditional markets but also temporary ones related to the massive man-
ufacture of explosives.
CHAPTER 2
The Elements of
Economic Calculation
Whatever the kind, the purpose, or the degree of sophistication of a project, an industrialist’s
primary concern is to know whether it can be done profitably, or in other words, whether it
will generate profits once it has been carried out. This type of question first presents itself in
absolute terms. It can also be looked at in a relative way, in the sense that, on the one hand,
several projects may be competing with each other within a single company, and it is a matter
of pushing the ones that will generate the most income. The need for comparison also arises
when it becomes necessary to decide whether it is worthwhile to enter a given market, in com-
petition with other actual or potential alternatives, or to make a ranking of the various possi-
bilities, including that of not undertaking the project.
In practice, there are many ways of obtaining an answer, i.e., of assessing the intrinsic or
relative economics of a project. This statement alone shows that in this matter the recom-
mended procedures include neither a universal solution, nor interchangeable ones. In fact,
their applicability mainly depends on the kind, the volume, and the reliability of the informa-
tion available. Thus, some of them may require prior collection of a large volume of accurate
data: for example, carrying out a medium- or even long-term market study involving raw
materials and products, from three points of view-quantitative, qualitative, and price. In
contrast, other, shorter procedures are used when information about market situations, sup-
plies, geographic location, or operating conditions is lacking. These approaches find applica-
tions that relate their level of sophistication to the stage reached by the project: the more basic
ones are best suited to the preliminary study phase, the more complex ones to phases whose
outcome is the decision to begin construction or not. Beyond that point, there is no further
need to assess the operation’s economic attractiveness, unless particular events fundamen-
tally change the calculation’s original conditions.
For these reasons, profitability analyses are in practice most often applied in the area of
evaluation than in the studies carried out in a related discipline, estimating, which is more the
specialty of engineering companies. In their more sophisticated applications, on the other
hand, they are closer to the methods developed and utilized by economists and accountants.
But at the outset we must note an essential difference: some of them operate in an a priori
68 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
manner, on the basis of prospective data alone, the others can base their calculations on actual
balances, and thus are able to perform analyses a posteriori. In addition, for evaluators, who
must always look towards a distant future, the important thing is always to choose the simple
approach. Consequently, they usually resort to “light-weight’’economic or accounting proce-
dures and to simplified working hypotheses that allow these to be applied, even though they
may often be incorrect in principle-as long as they remain valid in terms of their credibility
and their objective.
This concept is applied to companies on every added value. It particularly applies to so-called
taxable profits, which represent the difference (assumed to be positive) between the products
or the revenues, and the charges that the tax authorities allow as deductions. It has signifi-
cance only where the existence of a private business sector is acknowledged by the state. Its
thus reaches its full importance in market economy countries, where the financing of projects
and the management of operations are left to the citizens’ own initiatives. Countries belong-
ing to planned economy (statist or socialist) systems are able to ignore it. In this case, indeed,
a given company cannot operate exclusively on public funds and at the same time give back
part of the money to these very financing institutions, calling it a tax: on the contrary, the prof-
its are entirely turned over to the community, which acts simultaneously as shareholder,
investor, and administrator.
In market economy countries, the taxation of companies, or more precisely the tax rate,
varies widely from one state to another. It also varies over time, depending on economic con-
ditions. By its nature, its purpose is to furnish part of the national budget, and thereby to con-
tribute, along with other sources of taxes, to the maintenance and improvement of public
services. In addition, depending on its level, it constitutes a direct intervention by the State in
the management of companies, to the extent that high tax deductions reduce by that much the
distribution of dividends or discourage reinvestment; conversely, low ones may encourage
reinvestment, innovation, and job creation.
Generally speaking, taxation is applied to companies as it is to individuals, at different lev-
els. Although we are discussing its effect on profits here, it must not be forgotten that com-
panies must also pay other kinds of tax: local taxes, training levies, sales taxes, customs
duties, ... value added tax (VAT). In this case, the company does the Government’s work,
collecting the tax for it, i.e., returning the difference between the deductions it takes from its
customers and those made by its suppliers, which are “recoverable”. When the difference is
negative (revenues less than investment expenses during the first years of a plant’s operation,
for example), the fiscal legislation usually grants a tax credit.
COMMENT
The usual unit of time for accounting purposes is a year: balance sheets and their results
are compiled only at the end of the period. This leads to discrepancies, particularly in
the tax area, that are hard to take into account when considering the future, which is
what evaluation does. In addition, the fiscal year does not necessarily coincide with the
calendar year, depending on the country (e.g., Japan and the United Kingdom).
2. The Elements o f Economic Calculation 69
In theory, there is a profit or loss as soon as there is an added value or a minus value, i.e.,
a difference between a good’s sale or resale price and its net book value. Here the tax situation
sometimes differs depending on the delay between the good’s acquisition and its transfer,
whether it is altered or not. In fact, the longer this delay becomes, the greater is the gap
between its apparent and real values, owing to the general rise in prices, which justifies a
reduction in the tax rate. Thus, a distinction is often drawn between:
0 Short-term added values-these are the ones that apply when a good is sold again within
two years of its acquisition, or upon the transfer of depreciable assets for no more than
the amount of depreciation already taken. They are like regular profits and are conse-
quently taxed in the same way.
0 Long-term added values-these correspond to transfers of goods, whether depreciable
or not, that have been held for more than two years, as long as (for depreciable ones)
there is a positive difference between the sale and purchase prices. This kind of added
value may be taxed at lower rates.
By way of illustration, Table 2.1 provides information on the 1997 rates of taxation
applied to company profits by various states.
Table 2.1 Tax rates on company profits (P) in various countries during 1997
Table 2.1 (continued) Tax rates on company profits (P) in various countries during 1997
For some of these countries, the variations recorded during recent years indicate an overall
reduction in taxation, intended to foster reinvestment and job creation. This policy is very
markedly displayed by some countries such as France, where profits distributed to sharehold-
ers are more heavily taxed; in Germany, the opposite is the case, no doubt to encourage the
acquisition of goods from beyond its frontiers.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 71
There are many economic criteria that can be employed to assess the attractiveness of a
project. Most of them are based on knowing the revenues or the sales prices, and take into
account the concepts of gross or real profits, i.e., that they apply before or after tax, depending
on the case. However, some of them, such as cost of price or operating cost, do not have this
alternative meaning, since their very definition excludes the revenue from sales.
The annual allocation to provide for depreciation. This concept deserves further explana-
tion: however, roughly speaking, it is a notional expense intended to compensate for the
economic disadvantages due to the ageing of pieces of equipment, and the eventual need
to replace them or to substitute an equivalent or better system (see Section 2.2.4.2.A),
0 The financial costs from possible loans obtained for the construction of the production
units.
CF=B(l -a)+A (2.3)
The cashflow or annual income, also called cash from operations, represents the effective
earnings. It thus covers:
0 The real profits, i.e., profits after taxes, which are obtained from the gross profits by sub-
constitutes the allocation to provide for depreciation, and that under this procedure-
which, moreover, is allowed under the fiscal legislation of most market economy coun-
tries-is deducted from the tax.
The Payout Time method thus applies under the following assumptions:
0 Revenues and expenses are constant from one year to another: prices and quantities of
products, raw materials, reagents, by-products, catalysts, various energy or other require-
ments, and labor needs are consequently supposed to remain fixed over time.
0 The provision for depreciation, which is itself regarded as constant, is derived from a nec-
essarily straight-line calculation procedure, and assumes a complete recovery of the original
investment, i.e., that the equipment has no salvage value (see Section 2.1.2.3.B.a(5)).
0 By using operating cost and its mathematical expression (2.2),the POT accepts the exist-
ence of financial or equivalent costs on all of the initial capital. It thus assumes that this cap-
ital outlay comes from a real or notional loan subject to repayment at a real or pseudo rate of
interest.
Taxation is taken into account; consequently the POT constitutes a assessment criterion
essentially confined to market economy countries.
The POT is measured in years. Actually, the investment Z is expressed in local or reference
currency, and the cash flow CF in annual value. The ratio between the two is thus denomi-
nated in years.
The shorter the recovery period thus expressed, the higher the earnings-represented by
the cash flow-must be, since the initial investment is fixed; and so, a priori, the better the
economics of the project being considered must be. When comparing two projects or alterna-
tives, the one with the smaller POT is regarded as having the better economics.
74 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
The expression (2.5) shows that the POT is less than the depreciation period n = I/A-
unless the operation loses money and thus has negative profits, a situation that would
condemn the project at once, since it would not even recover the initial investment. By way
of indication, for a large proportion of industrial units n is of the order of ten years (see Sec-
tion 2.2.4.2.A.b). Experience shows that an investment should not be considered in such cases
unless the POT falls below seven years, and preferably below five l. This limit is of course a
function of the economic situation: it is higher when economic conditions are favorable. In
difficult times, such as those experienced during the recent energy crises, the threshold is
around two years. This observation merely indicates the gap between revenues and expendi-
tures, i.e., between a product's sales price and its cost of price; the size of this difference
reflects the extent to which demand exceeds supply, which requires the economy to be
expanding.
In this regard, it should be noted that the expression for the POT can be written using unit
costs, i.e., per ton produced or that could be produced, or more generally per unit or per piece.
To do this, we have only to divide the elements used in its formulation either by the actual
production or by the production capacity. We thus obtain, in the latter case:
I'
POT =
(VI- c')(l- a ) + A'
where
I' : Ilcapacity = unit investment
V': Vlcapacity = sales price
C': Clcapacity = cost of price
A' : Alcapacity = unit provision for depreciation.
Such a presentation has the advantage of showing that, for a given POT, it is possible to
deduce a sales price, assuming that the other parameters are known.
1. Comment. In many cases, the life of the facilities is relatively short, or assumed to be for calcu-
lation purposes: usually less than or equal to ten years. This leads to even shorter payback periods, and
a need for rapid recovery of the initial investments. In practice, it is too difficult or even impossible to
obtain major loans from specialized institutions for such short periods. The financing for a given
project is usually obtained from the company's cash flow, which can take advantage of broader and
more favorable situations. In this case, the source of capital for a project under examination is
unknown, and from a strictly economic viewpoint we should employ the concept of present value. This
leads to an apparent contradiction, which may be brought up, inasmuch as the company treasury acts
as a lending organization at a notional interest rate that actually represents a present value calculation.
Consequently, we must take care to see that the interest rates used in the POT calculation are fully con-
sistent with the discount rates that are normally applied (see Section 2.1.2.3.A.d).
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 75
capital within a certain time. It should therefore be near the actual market prices, particularly
when substitutable products are concerned.
The simplified Payback Period method represented by the POT has the advantage of
enabling a quick analysis of a project’s economics: for this reason, it is well suited to the aims
of a preliminary evaluation. On the other hand, it displays all the drawbacks that generally
result just from utilizing this kind of criterion (see Section 2.1.2.3.E). In particular, the least
capital-intensive projects, the ones that require the smallest initial contribution, are the high-
est rated, and there is no consideration of the period after the recovery of the invested capital.
The POT constitutes a measure of the risk incurred by the investors, not by the producers.
V‘-D’
ROI=--. 100 (2.9)
I’
where
V’: Vlproduction capacity = sales price
D‘: Dlcapacity = unit operating cost
I ’ : Ilcapacity = unit investment.
For a given ROI, expression (2.9) allows a sales price to be calculated. If we consider the
value thus selected to be a minimum, V’ then constitutes a “minimum profitable sales price”:
(2.10)
76 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
By extension, some users have modified Eq. (2.8), which applies to planned systems, in
order to make it easier to compare projects from countries with different structures, on a pre-
tax basis and using the same kind of measures. For application in a market economy, this rela-
tion then becomes:
v-c
ROI = -.lo0
I
Again by extension, the concept of after-tax return on investment has been introduced. In
this case. the formulation is as follows:
(V - C)(1- a ) + A
after tax ROI = .loo (2.1 1)
I
where: C=D+A+F
Combining Eqs. (2.5) and (2.1 1) gives:
There are several other more or less empirical criteria of profitability, designed to correct cer-
tain defects in earlier methods, or to emphasize certain particular aspects. As a rough guide,
we will mention:
Turnover ratio
This expresses the ratio between annual sales (V)and invested capital (Z) and is well suited
to the ranking of projects of completely different kinds, involving construction plans that are
far apart in their design, and consequently have markedly distinct initial investments. It con-
stitutes a measurement of the rapidity of the renewal or reconstitution of the amount of the
sums tied up.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 77
Break-even point
In practice, this concept appears in various forms; for this reason its significance and its
content are usually explained differently by different authors and users. In its original defini-
tion, the break-even point is the effective production threshold below which the operations of
a plant designed to provide a certain level of manufacture, i.e., having a certain production
capacity, should be halted.
To determine the minimum utilization rate of the equipment (the ratio between the actual
and potential quantities coming from the units), a graph (Fig. 2.1) is constructed to show the
simultaneous variations of sales and operating cost in terms of this parameter. By sales we
mean the total turnover, after deducting possible related expenses (packaging, sales and
advertising costs, repayment of research and development costs, etc.). The break-even point
corresponds to the intersection of the two curves (usually straight lines). Its x-value represents
the rate of utilization for which the revenues and the expenses directly related to the units
under consideration balance each other. Experience shows that for facilities that consist for
the most part of pressure tanks, whose costs vary roughly according to the power 0.6 of the
quantities processed in the equipment (see Section 2.3.2.l), the threshold of economic utili-
zation corresponding to the break-even point is itself around 60%, for widely used products.
Generally speaking, the lower the value obtained in this way, the better are the project eco-
nomics, since they are less sensitive to fluctuations in demand. The advantage of this criterion
is that it introduces an upper limit to the production capacity derived from a market analysis:
in particular when, in seeking to improve the situation by economies of scale, a proposed
development is brought forward in time.
Total sales
Income after
deduction of taxes
m
e
W
s
Fixed charges
J
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 60 90 H)
Utlltzatlon or load rate (YO)
a. Background
Project financing involves locking up sums whose final total is equal to the overall invest-
ment. The disbursements are of course made progressively, throughout the planning and con-
struction stages, but they have to be provided without any expectation of short-term benefit,
since no income is likely to be generated by the operation of the facilities. Without special
incentives or other compensations, the act of investing thus leads to a definite loss. This sim-
ple observation doubtless explains why some return is expected from any sum that is locked
in, whatever its nature or origin.
Theoretically, all or part of the required project investments may be obtained via loans
contracted with banking organizations, or from the managing company’s equity funds. Now,
although we all know that loans require the payment of interest, there is no reason why other
sources of financing should not make similar arrangements. In fact, they have a right to
expect at least the same level of return, to make up for the losses or damages involved in pos-
sibly having to make their own loans to third parties, or to make acquisitions for more imme-
diate future profits or benefits. The concept of present value has no other purpose than to
provide economic guarantees of proper returns from all the sums invested.
In practice, distinguishing between capital sums on the basis of their source can be a tricky
business in the case of larger industrial companies: several projects may be under way at
once, their financing handled by a single central treasury. The treasury obtains its funds both
from the company’s own varied operations, and from various shorter- and longer-term loans.
In such a situation, it is impossible to define the real financing terms of a particular project.
Effectively, it is as if all the sums required for the project were borrowed from the central trea-
sury and repaid at a pseudo interest rate.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 79
In some cases, however, for example with companies that are smaller in scope or specially
created for the purpose, it is sometimes possible to differentiate the various capital sums by
origin, and to treat them accordingly.
Generally speaking, we may distinguish three types of financing:
0 Regular loans obtained directly from everyday lending organizations,
b. Borrowed Capital
The payment of interest in return for sums that are borrowed or loaned may be calculated in
various ways.
Simple Interest
In this case, the interest rate, defined as the amount that the unit of capital costs or returns
in the given unit of time (year), is held constant. At the end of k years, the sum Sk that must
be paid back or recovered from the loan or investment of the initial capital So, at simple inter-
est rate i, is:
Sk = SO (1 + ki)
where So x ki represents the total interest.
When the operating period is less than one year, the interest due or recoverable is prorated
to the actual number of days that the loan or investment was in effect, as a fraction of either
360 days (ordinary interest) or 365 days (exact simple interest).
Compound Interest
Simple interest, whether in the form of partial payments at the end of each period of time,
or as a lump sum at the end of the operation, yields exactly the same amount of money. In the
second of these cases the lending organization experiences a loss of earnings, because it could
have made other profitable investments during that time, using the money from the partial
payments. To compensate for this disadvantage, compound interest is utilized: here, any
interest left unpaid at the end of each basic time period (for example, a year) is itself treated
as an integral part of the loaned or borrowed capital during succeeding years.
Under this arrangement, investing or obtaining a sum So in year 0 leads to a return, or the
obligation to repay:
in year 1: SI = So (1 + i )
in year 2: S, = S1 (1 + i) = So (1 + i)2
80 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
s k represents the capitalized value at year k of the initial amount SO,and i represents the
interest rate applicable to the fractional unit of time considered.
One year is usually selected as the unit of time for calculations, but in the case of short-
term loans or borrowings it is often necessary to employ shorter periods-a month, or even a
day-and to set interest rates in consequence.
Because it is essential to make comparisons on a uniform basis, even though the interest
rates may have been determined under differing conditions, it is customary to reduce them all
to a common period of time: the year.
This method then leads to the definition of:
0 An effective interest rate (ir): the value of the interest rate i applied to the period of time
i = ”1
P
Generally speaking: i, 2 i, where the equality represents a period of one year. In practice,
the effective rate of interest i, is used for calculation.
To determine it, since i, is known we employ the expression:
(2.12)
This may be calculated by taking the limiting case of the following expression, where p
tends to infinity:
i,=
(1+“
a)” -1
k
and consequently: eiak = (1 + ir)
becomes: s k = soeiak
or:
Which returns us to the general expression for the capitalized annual value of an initial sum
SO.
When a company invests capital to finance a project, it must be compensated for the lost earn-
ings or the “psychological” constraints and losses that ensue. In particular at least a partial, if
not a full equivalent should be provided for disadvantages such as:
0 Depreciation of the currency,
Or to increase its working capital, distribute higher dividends, engage in stock exchange
operations, etc.
The bottom line is that having a certain sum now and having the same amount at the end
of k years is not the same thing. Let C
A be a coefficient representing all the inconveniences
mentioned above, some of which cannot be directly expressed in figures, such that it shall be
equivalent to have, on an annual basis:
0 F1 in a year’s time
0 Or C; F1 today.
82 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
In this case, C‘; F1represents the current or at least the discounted value of the sum F1 Ci
then constitutes a present value coefficient, also called a “psychological discount coefficient”
for the next year versus the current year.
k
In the same way, we may accept that it is possible to define coefficients Cf , C; , ... ck-1,
etc., such that it is the same thing to have a sum Fk in the year k, or an amount Fk in the year
k-1.
This, then is the same as having Fk in the year k, or in year 0 having A , available, such that:
Fk
A,=
In addition, when:
we obtain:
k - k E k
ck-l - Dk-l k-1
84 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
Now: ct-I
1.e.:
or:
If moreover we assume, as is the case in evaluation, that the coefficients are constant from
one year to another, the equation becomes:
C,k = ( C ) k = ( D ) k ( E ) k
c=-1 1 1
, D=- and E = -
1 +i' l+d l+i
i and i' being defined as above and d being the rate of depreciation of purchasing power, we
obtain:
--
1 - 1
1+ i' (1 + d ) ( l + i)
Looked at in this way, the minimum discount rate employed should therefore be equal to
the arithmetic mean of the various funds involved, each one associated with its own particular
interest or discount rate.
The result of this calculation actually represents only a threshold, or a point below which
it is unreasonable to fall, on pain of early bankruptcy. It is also necessary to consider how the
overall management of the funds available to the company is to be handled. As already noted
in the discussion of empirical criteria, and as we shall also see when we turn to those based
on present value, the purpose of these economic indicators is to enable projects to be ranked,
particularly in decreasing order of attractiveness, independent of any measure of their intrin-
sic profitability. Obviously, a company will only make new investments that fall within its
budgetary envelope. Preferably, it will get involved in the operations that appear most attrac-
tive, specifically the least risky and most lucrative ones. The economic criteria are there to
make its choice easier. This does not prevent a company with available cash from deciding,
in spite of everything, not to invest, or if it does nevertheless propose to go ahead, from decid-
ing to set a minimum profitability level for doing so. Below this threshold it will prefer to use
its funds for other purposes, in particular to reward its shareholders by giving them dividends.
Studies of the internal rate of return (see Section 2.1.2.3.D) illustrate how to put such an
approach into practice.
In fact, investing comes down to taking on risks, to accepting low discount rates: in par-
ticular, ones that are close to the values that emerge from analyses of financing modalities. In
short, the lower this rate, the more projects will appear worthy of interest. To generalize, a
conservative company will make few new commitments, and will favor payments to its share-
holders: consequently it will use high discount rates. Conversely, a dynamic company will
want to invest and to embark on new projects: it will tend to lower its discount rates. Actually,
it will do so only so far as it is able, depending especially on its size and its financial guaran-
tors. Thus, the most solid establishments use the lowest rates, but they cannot be lower than
the ones used by the most financially credible organizations of all, i.e., the ones belonging to
the State where the industrial facilities are located. Indeed, state institutions are usually the
most credit-worthy, inasmuch as they always have the resources to give back to the taxpayers,
to erase their debts. Of course, this is not necessarily the case, since some countries, particu-
larly developing ones, may be forced to suspend payments. Except for this kind of situation,
where international organizations must make up the deficiency, when States-particularly
the most heavily industrialized ones-need to finance major public-sector projects, they are
obliged to invest and recover their money over the long term. To ensure a minimal return on
the capital tied up in this way, they set a discount rate by reference to the one used for long-
term loans (= 5%), to which they add management charges and a little danger money (= 2%).
In the past, certain countries periodically published outlines of their major national economic
trends, specifying the value of the discount rate at which they intended to repay their invest-
ments in future years. The worldwide liberalizing trend that is currently under way, with the
privatizing of major State corporations and the growth in personal shareholdings, is down-
grading public financing and emphasizing financing by international banking organizations
and private institutions. Consequently, even if the concept of planning sometimes persists, it
now represents no more than a guideline. Table 2.2 provides examples of the constant money
levels advocated by various countries. They show a variation over time that reflects the eco-
nomic conditions and, possibly, the sector concerned (e.g., USA). These variations have no
86 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
other purpose than to encourage manufacturers to get involved to a greater or lesser extent in
new operations or the modernization of existing facilities.
The discount rates recommended by states are an indication of their political will to pro-
mote a more or less aggressive industrialization.
B. Calculation of the Discounted Cash Flow and the Net Present Value
The application of methods based on the concept of present value first of all requires us to
determine the annual income, then to reduce it to its present value, and finally to examine its
variation over time, i.e., in the absence of any simplifying assumptions, to draw up a schedule.
From an accounting viewpoint, we can look at the revenues and expenses for each year
that are actually credited or obligated.
In the a priori, or evaluation approach, we can estimate these data only by looking at the
future, so as to define a production program and to predict the probable variation of the prices
of various products, power sources, etc. involved in the project under consideration. Conse-
quently, although the construction of a schedule may be justified in one case, it may be unnec-
essary in another, particularly when the available information is insufficient or unreliable.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 87
a. Calculation Methods
Nevertheless, before undertaking an approach of this kind certain details must first be speci-
fied, e.g.:
(1) The type of procedure selected: current money or constant money. So as not to intro-
duce too many assumptions and uncertainties, constant money is generally preferred for eval-
uations; this requires working with a constant discount rate.
(2) The date, actually the year, for which the work is being done, since under this approach
there has to be a reference. Usually the choice for the base year 0, in whose money all the cash
flows are expressed, is the one when the facilities are actually put into operation.
(3) The duration of the study: n (in years). For the sake of convenience, or a desire to keep
it simple, n is generally made equal to the depreciation period. Sometimes a different number
is selected, particularly when the profitabilities of two competing projects are to be compared.
This possibility can best be illustrated by an example: the comparison of two alternative
versions of the same facility for producing ammonia. The first proposes the construction of a
single, high-capacity unit (300000 t/yr), with start-up in year 0 and a ten-year depreciation
period. The second proposes a two-stage construction, to match the growth in demand: a first
facility of smaller size (1 50000 t/yr), starting up in year 0 and depreciated over ten years, and
a second one, identical in its operation, starting up in year 5 and also depreciated over ten
years. The comparison will be valid only if it has a uniform basis; consequently there are two
possible solutions for the duration of the study:
0 Ten years, in which case only the 300000 t/yr and the first 150000 t/yr units will be
depreciated by the end of the period. The unrecovered portion of the second smaller unit
still has to be accounted for, for example by applying the concept of salvage value.
0 Fifteen years, where from the tenth year onwards no depreciation provisions for the
300000 dyr and the first 150000 t/yr units need be deducted from profits.
In both cases, the schedule must include, at year 5, an intermediate investment correspond-
ing to the second 150000 t/yr facility. In spite of the additional uncertainties that may result
from it, the preferred solution should be the one with the longest duration, so as to take better
account of effects related to the prospects for market growth.
(4) The terms of taxation, i.e., the possibility of making calculations before or after their
deduction from profits, which amounts to deciding whether or not to consider fiscal impacts.
(5) The salvage value of the facilities. At any time, the equipment at an industrial site may
be employed for other purposes or sold, even if only at scrap metal prices.
The price of these materials is essentially tied to their proposed usage. At that time, it rep-
resents their “salvage value”.
This approach can be applied during or after the depreciation period, and may have a real
or notional character.
From an accounting viewpoint, which reflects the actual cash flows on the actual dates
they took place, the calculation of the salvage value of a facility is possible only when it is
sold, if a sale takes place, or if not, when the units are dismantled. In this case, it is desirable
to consider the possible added values and their related taxes.
88 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
For evaluation purposes, the economic tool can be much more rudimentary, since it is
employed to analyze facilities that are usually notional. In addition, it is intended to make the
choice between several alternatives easier, and constitutes a handy means of comparison. So
the principal concern is to define identical study conditions for the various alternatives con-
sidered, and, particularly, to adopt the same reference date and duration. Although it is a priori
a tricky matter, even impossible, to foresee the end of the project, and thus to know the value
of the equipment at the end of its life or of its utilization in a given facility, it is possible that
at the end of the selected period it may not yet have been completely depreciated. To express
these possibilities the salvage value may, unless otherwise indicated, be taken to be zero, or
equal to the fraction of the invested capital that is unrecovered at the end of the study period.
b. General Expression
Although the chosen formulation permits a broader generalization, it seems preferable to
limit it to the more common circumstances encountered in project evaluation. Thus, calcula-
tions are usually conducted in constant money, and the reference year 0 is the year when the
units are put into industrial production. Finally, the facility is assumed to be in a market econ-
omy country, where profits are subject to taxation, and certain charges, in particular the
depreciation provision and financial costs for contracted loans, are deductible from the tax.
The recommended approach for determining the annual income then consists of calculat-
ing the result of the revenues and expenses that are produced by the operation of the facilities,
i.e., the corresponding cash flows (the differences between the annual revenues and
expenses). This exercise is made easier by setting up a schedule showing the variations from
one year to another of the various constituents of the flows of funds. Thus, for each year of
operationp, the cash flow (CF), is expressed as follows:
(CF), = V, - Dp - F, - ‘p - (Vp - D, - F, - A,) u
or: (2.14)
in which, as noted in Section 2.1.2.1, V, represents the operating revenues for the yearp, D,
the corresponding expenses, A, the provision for depreciation, F, the financial costs for pos-
sible loans, a the tax rate, assumed constant for the period of the study, and 1, the total invest-
ments made in year p .
Introducing the operating cost:
C, = D, i-A, + F,
allows us to simplify Eq. (2.14) above, which may then be written:
(CF), = (V, - C,) (1 - a ) + Ap -,Z (2.15)
Following the procedure mentioned in Section 2.1.2.3.A.q determining the current value
of the cash flow for yearp amounts to dividing by (1 + i)p, i being the discount rate for con-
stant money under the assumptions of this calculation, i.e.:
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 89
Depending on the value p , lying between the reference year 0 and the final year of the
study, n, they have varying significances, as follows:
0 In year p = 0, revenues and operating expenses are nil, depreciation has not yet taken
effect, and ZO is equal to the initial investment, i.e., the sum of the investments in depreciable
capital (Z) and working capital v), i.e.:
Z,=Z+f
which leads to:
0 At some year p , lying between the years 1 and n - 1 (1 5 p 5 n - l), there are usually no
new investments, hence I, = 0. This is not always the case. Sometimes, we need to consider
additions of capital andor working capital for process improvements, clearing bottlenecks,
etc.: in the previous example concerning the staging over time of the construction of two iden-
tical ammonia-producing facilities, so as to match the growth in demand, it would be neces-
sary at the year p = 5 to take account of the depreciable and working capital for the second
facility, put into operation at that time. The revenues and operating expenses vary according
to the quantities produced and the average prices charged from one year to another. The allo-
cation for depreciation A, is generally assumed to be constant over time, unless a declining-
balance system is used, or of course if new investments are made, which amounts to propor-
90 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
tionally increasing the allocation from the moment when the units become operational. The
expression for the present value of the incomes then becomes:
0 At yearp = n, i.e., at the end of the study period or the presumed life of the facilities, -I,,
represents an income that is the value of the recoverable capital. It covers the working capital
J; if it has not changed in the interim, and the salvage value I,, corresponding to the total of
the undepreciated portion of the facilities, if there is any at that time, and the revenue from
their sale or re-use. During this operation, there would be added values that must be consid-
ered. In evaluation, where the calculation concerns the comparison of projects that are usually
imaginary, and is conducted without any consideration for accounting principles,f is assumed
to be constant and I, either zero or equal to the portion of the capital not yet recovered. This
procedure avoids the problem raised in accounting by the tax on added values. Note that over
time the working capital becomes progressively smaller in real value by an amount equal to
the discount: this explains why it is legal to increase it proportionally, without it necessarily
constituting a concealment of profits. The total I, corresponds to the income -(I, +A; the rev-
enues and expenses are the ones for the year n: V,, and C,. The allocation for depreciation A,,
corresponds to the last annual payment. In these circumstances, the discounted income
becomes:
First Possibility
The first possibility is that the financial costs Fp are not zero, they represent the interest at
yearp on the sums initially borrowed, or, if need be, when additional investments are made.
Consequently the value of the discount rate employed, which reflects the average state of the
company's treasury based on its sources of capital, the amounts of the respective contribu-
tions, and their repayment terms, must exclude everything that relates to the loans and involve
only the company's equity funds. In this calculation:
At year p = 0, I0 must include the sums actually laid out by the company responsible for
the project. If the initial depreciable capital I consists partly of a loan E, and partly of equity
funds P, i.e., if
I=E+P
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 91
we obtain:
I o = I +f - E = P + f
E in fact represents an income received at time t = 0. For the purpose of simplification, the
working capital is assumed to come exclusively from equity capital. In practice this might not
be the case: it might be partly financed using loans. If so, the financial costs Fp must be mod-
ified appropriately. The total discounted revenues may be written as follows:
The allocation to provide for depreciation A p still refers to all the capital initially required for
the construction of the facilities. If there is strict proportionality, i.e., use of the straight line
depreciation method, Ap and R p are constant, so that:
with: D p = D, +R,
We recognize the initial expression, but with the advantage of considering only the equity
funds, and thus being, in theory, more consistent.
At yearp = n, -In represents on one hand the value of the recoverable sums, or (I, +A,
and
on the other the last repayment of principal R,. Then:
-In = (Z, +f)- R ,
92 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
and:
Second possibility
In the second possibility, which attempts to consider the best utilization of all the capital
laid out, even though its origins as loans or equity funds may be known we must return to the
initial concept in which Fp = 0 and the discounting is the result of a representative weighting
of the complete average basket of funds. To illustrate this, it is best to work with an example.
If the initial depreciable capital then consists of 20% of equity funds, for which the discount
rate is 15%, and 80%of loans that pay an average of 5%, the approach is as follows:
0 Either we look only at the equity funds, in which case for I = 100, E = 80 and P = 20,
No taxation
When calculations are made for countries with planned economies, the concepts of fiscal
debits and deductions, particularly provisions for depreciation, do not exist. In expression
(2.16), Fp and Ap become zero.
In the case where financing is provided by funds fiom the company treasury or the state
concerned, the discounted income is expressed as follows:
since, as we do not know where the funds come from, Fp is also zero.
In the case where the financing structure is known, since Fp # 0, the income becomes:
where Ip includes the repayments Rp. This can happen when a State contracts loans from
international banking institutions.
Using expression (2.16) to determine the discounted annual income makes it easier to define
and to apply various criteria of profitability, notably the following:
Capitalized discounted cash flow
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 93
a. Capitalized discounted cash flow, or Cumulative net annual discounted cash flow,
or Cumulative net present value 2
By definition a project’s capitalized discounted cash flow, or its total discounted income, is
equal to the sum of the present values of the annual cash flows from its operations:
p=n
(Vp - C,)(l- a ) + A, - zp
or: B = C (2.17)
p=o (1 +i)P
This criterion allows us to look at a project over the entire life of the facilities that it puts
to work, or at least over the depreciation or study period, i.e., for a sufficiently representative
length of time for the principal parameters to be considered. When it is a question of whether
or not to go ahead, the method first determines whether the operation is economically attrac-
tive, or if the capitalized discounted cash flow obtained is positive. In other words, the dis-
counted cumulative value of the revenues should exceed that of the overall expenses.
Consequently, when this is so, then the higher this criterion--expressed as a value-
becomes, the better the profitability of the project concerned is said to be. When two or more
projects have to be compared, the ones with the highest capitalized discounted cash flows are
considered to be the most profitable.
2. In these expressions, the word “cumulative” or “capitalized” is often omitted, which may lead
to confusion with the simple annual income (see Section 2.1.2.3.B).
94 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
or:
when Fp = 0.
In practice, in order to calculate a capitalized discounted cash flow we must proceed in
stages, since most of the parameters vary from one year to another: income, expenses, possi-
ble provision for depreciation, even discount and tax rates, working capital, etc. In these cir-
cumstances, it is best to set up a schedule like the one in Table 2.3, for determining the annual
incomes. To obtain the present values, we must also have the value of the following coeffi-
cient, which depends on the values of i and p :
a=- 1
(1+i)P
Table 2.4 shows how to do this. The accumulated value of the discounted cash flows, on
the bottom line of the schedule, is the desired capitalized discounted cash flow.
These calculations may at first appear tedious, especially when they become repetitive:
commercial software is now widely available to help out.
Special cases
(vP- cP)(1- a ) + A, - R,
+E p=l (1 + i)'
where Fp f 0.
Calculation
Comments
Years 0 1 2
.
i
Investments In general Ip = 0 -11 -12
for 0 < p < n and I, = 0
Sales volume V1 v2
Operating DP Variable charges, labor, DI D2
expenses(') maintenance, tax
and insurance, overhead,
and head office
Depreciation(') AP A1 A2
Financial costs(') FP These costs are zero: F, =0 0 0
Operating cost CP Cp = Dp +Ap + Fp Cl c
2
with F, = 0
Net profits
(for given a)
Depreciation AP
Cash Flow (CF)p
p=o
(CF)p
( 1 +i)P
Very important note: Be sure that the financial costs are zero in this operating cost calculation.
(Source: IFP)
96 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
1
Table 2.4 Determination of the coefficient a:a = -
(1 +i)"
or:
depending on whether the source of capital is not known or is taken into account.
When income and expenses are assumed to be constantfrom one year to another,
along with the allocationfor depreciation
This artificial situation, which is rarely encountered in the real world of economics or
accounting, has a special advantage in the evaluation of projects, where it is sometimes diffi-
cult, even absurd, to introduce arbitrary market fluctuations, given the lack of precision in the
available information. Its attraction is therefore to allow use of a simplifying procedure,
which replaces the schedule with a single equation. For example, in expression (2.18):
when Fp = 0.
Vp, Cp, and Ap are constant, and respectively equal to V, C, and A , such that:
p=n
+[(V-C)(l-a)+A] ~ 1 (2.19)
p=l ( I +i)'
when Fp = 0.
p=n 1 (1 + i)" - 1
The factor ~ can be calculated; it is equal to: p=
p=l (1 +i)' i( 1 + i)"
Depending on the values of i and n, it can be obtained by reference to Table 2.5.
In the case where the method of financing is known, this simplification can be applied only
if the repayments Rp and the financial costs Fp are also identical every year. It then becomes
necessary to resort to a calculating trick by defining an average interest rate, as shown in
Section 2.2.4.2.B.
Since, in addition to these simplifying assumptions, the salvage value of the facilities is
often assumed to be zero in an evaluation, at the end of the depreciation period the expression
(2.19) reduces to the following equation:
(2.20)
i( 1 + i)"
when Fp = 0.
98 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
Although the search for a less complex and more easily applied formulation may be justi-
fied by its ability to provide a quick approximation to an answer that is in any case based on
unreliable data, it nevertheless represents an invalid approach in terms of accounting and eco-
nomic theory. In fact, it is not so much using it that is the problem, as not fully understanding
the level of error being committed. Indeed, not only revenues and expenses, but also provi-
sions for depreciation, behave in different ways, depending on whether the calculations are
made in constant money or current money, i.e., in discounted values or not.
A straight-line depreciation gives the same amount each year only in current money. So to
assume that in constant money, the depreciation provision is the same from one year to another
implies that there has been a revaluation (which is legal, as long as it is also applied to the invest-
ments, and the possible added values are considered). Conversely, to use similar revenues and
expenses over time in current money actually amounts to accepting that the productivity of the
facilities diminishes over the assumed life of the project. Thus, strictly speaking, we cannot log-
ically assume that all the parameters used in the calculation remain constant at the same time.
This method arises directly from the preceding one, since by definition a project’s internal
rate of return i, is equal to the value of the discount rate i, which cancels out the capitalized
discounted cash flow calculated over n years.
We must therefore find i, such that:
i.e., such that the expression (2.17), or the expressions derived from it for particular cases,
becomes zero.
To do this, we need to draw the graph of the capitalized discounted cash flows against the
discount rate (Fig. 2.2a). The required value of i (i,) is the one for which the curve intersects
the x-axis. This is then the maximum discount that will allow repayment of the capital used
to finance the project, without making a loss.
When using capitalized discounted cash flow, for an operation to be considered profitable
by a company the outcome resulting from the application of the discount rate must be posi-
tive; similarly, for the internal rate of return, the value has to be greater than the discount rate.
If it is not, the project must be rejected.
In theory, a project is said to be more attractive, in economic terms, in proportion as its
internal rate of return, expressed in percent, is high; when the comparison concerns several
of them, the one with the highest IRR is considered to be the most attractive. This criterion
has the advantage of being an assessment method that is independent of the more psycholog-
ical and arbitrary concept represented by the discount rate; moreover, it is just as concrete and
evocative, since it also has the character of an interest rate.
In practice, certain restrictions have to be placed on its application, and it is sometimes
necessary to confirm the results obtained by resorting to other decision criteria. In particular,
when several projects are being compared, it is useful to examine:
100 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
0 The relative slopes of the variation curves of the capitalized discounted cash flow
against the discount rate. In fact, the most attractive project is often the one with the lowest
slope. Because of this, it is most sensitive to possible fluctuations in income, and most depen-
dent on the reliability of the information on which it is based, i.e., on the accuracy of the data
initially available or on the validity of the assumptions used in the calculation, which often
come from market analyses (Fig. 2.2b).
The relative position of the curves. When they intersect, the comparative profitability of the
projects can be measured only in terms of the value of the discount rate corresponding to the
intersection (Fig. 2.2~).In fact, depending on the case-that is, on the i concerned-the project
with the highest internal rate of return is not necessarily the one that also has the highest capital-
ized discounted cash flow. This assumes of course that the DCF is positive, which automatically
implies IRRs higher than the chosen value of i. Thus project (2), whose internal rate of return is
larger than the rate of project (l), does not yield a higher capitalized discounted cash flow, and
with it an economically equivalent conclusion, unless the company’s discount rate i is greater
than iA, the x-value of A: the intersection point of the two curves (1) and (2). In other terms:
iA<i<i <i
1‘ ‘2
Alternative (2) is more attractive than (1) whatever criterion is applied. The capitalized dis-
counted cash flow obtained is lower if i < iA; in this case the conclusion reached is the oppo-
site of the one obtained by comparing the IRRs, since i < i .
‘I ‘2
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 101
R
Discount rate ( I )
'r1
However, there is a case for preferring the results given by the capitalized discounted cash
flow. In fact, applying expression (2.17) and the others derived from it shows that i, increases
as the depreciable capital I decreases. Consequently, projects that are less capital-intensive,
and thus require lower initial investments, show to greater advantage. This type of analysis is
therefore disastrous for major construction projects, whose profitability may be among the
best over the long term. This situation is often encountered when projects with very different
investment costs are compared, or the study period is too short.
As pointed out in Section 2.1.2.3.A, the concept of the internal rate of return allows us to
get a practical grasp on one of the essential factors in determining the value of a company's
discount rate: how its capital is managed. The lower the value of i, the greater the number of
projects with i, values that are higher, and vice versa. A ranking can be set up on the basis of
decreasing internal rates of return, so as to identify the most favorable projects, and in parallel
the cumulative total of the corresponding initial investments can be shown. Setting a value
for i then amounts to establishing a minimum threshold of interest, but it also defines the lim-
its of the budgetary envelope required for projects considered to be profitable. In practice the
opposite procedure is generally employed: the amount of available capital is known or deter-
mined, and the value of i is deduced. Obviously, the larger are the sums for investment, the
lower the discount rate hurdle can be set, and the more numerous and more ambitious the
projects are likely to be.
The internal rates of return that are acceptable to the major industries, while they may not
be as low as those of State organizations, which a r e - o r are said to be-the most securely
based, nevertheless have minimum values around 12 to 15%. These figures are roughly
equivalentto a POT of 5 years and an ROI of 30 to 35% (before tax). In addition, if we employ
an approach similar to that described during the discussion of these two criteria, we can set a
minimum IRR and calculate a corresponding sales price, which we will again call the mini-
mum profitable sales price. Following the notation for unit costs used above, i.e., per ton of
production, the simplified Eq. (2.20) gives us:
a=- 1
with:
(1 + ir)"
(l+ir)n-l
P=
ir(l + ir)"
and F' = 0.
COMMENTS
0 The internal rate of return can be confused with the ROI. The minimal values
assigned to these two measures may perhaps enable them to be distinguished.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 103
the “relative” internal rate of return for this operation alone. This then concerns only
the additional income generated by the extra production, and is obtained by reducing
an expression comparable to the ones above, so that only the additional investment
required for the changes or additions is considered.
In practice, it is not so much a matter of setting out to determine a duration, but of first setting
a date. Thus, by definition, the recovery or repayment date of a project is the date k when the
total discounted cash flows become positive. Therefore, it is such that:
It corresponds to the moment when the incomes generated by the construction and opera-
tion of the facilities are sufficient to balance the initial investments, these investments being
repaid on the basis of a discount rate set by the manufacturer who sponsors and operates the
plant.
By extension, the payback period is defined as the period separating this date k from the
one selected for the start of the economic calculation, generally the time 0 when production
starts. This discounted equivalent of the POT is also expressed in years. For a given project,
the shorter it is, the better the profitability is said to be. When several competing alternatives
are compared, the one with the shortest discounted recovery period is considered the most
attractive.
From a mathematical viewpoint, applying this measure consists of finding the lowest value
of k, between 0 and n, such that:
p=k
(vp- cp)(1 - u ) + A, - z,
c
p=o (1 + i)’
20 with F p = 0 (2.21)
General case
Financing is provided from the company treasury if k < n, which is desirable and the most
common; from expression (2.21) we obtain:
The salvage value Zrand the working capital are not recovered, in terms of their present val-
ues, until year n, and thus cannot be considered during the study period.
On a graph, the curve representing the growth in cumulative discounted cash flows over time
(Fig. 2.3a) cuts the x-axis at a point that gives the value of k for the date of full recovery.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
Special cases
0 The financing method is known and only the repayment terms for the company’s equity
funds P matter. In this case, the expression (2.21) becomes:
-( P + f)+ gp=l
(VP - CP)(1- a ) + A,
(l+i)P
- R,
20 with Fp#O
0 Taxation is ignored; in other words, a = 0. The expression (2.21) can then be written:
20
p=l
(1 + i ) P
0 Revenues, expenses, and the depreciation provision are assumed to be constant from one
year to another, with financing provided from the company’s treasury. In this case, Eq. (2.21 )
takes the following form:
k
(1 + i ) - 1
-(I + f)+[(v - c)(1- a ) + A ] 20 with F = O
i ( l + ilk
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 105
Like the POT method, the minimum discounted payback period method leads to neglect-
ing the economic elements for the period later than a certain date, in this case time k.
For this reason, it may produce different results from those obtained, for example, by rank-
ing projects in order of decreasing capitalized discounted cash flows, since that criteriontakes
into account the income and expenses from the use of the facilities over their entire lifetime,
or at least their depreciation period.
Hence, as shown in Fig. 2.3b, for two projects (1) and (2) requiring different initial invest-
ments Zland Z2 (Zl> Z2 for example), the growth curves for the cumulative discounted cash
flows over time show that the payback dates are such that:
(POT)1 > ( P W 2
Consequently, alternative (2) appears more profitable than (1). In fact, in the example
selected, the slope of curve (2) (which actually consists of successive straight line segments) is
on average less steep than the slope of curve (1). After n years the incomes for project (1) become
greater than those for the competing alternative (2): the previous conclusions are then reversed.
Such a situation is rare when two projects from the same industrial sector have to be com-
pared. However it is much more frequent when it is a matter of deciding between proposals
of widely differing types, for example concerning activities as sharply contrasted as refining
and nuclear energy. For this reason, the payback period criterion is most valuable for inves-
tigating variants of a single project, whose competitive situations are essentially equivalent,
the technologies compared often related, and the investments of the same general size.
Generally speaking, if market forecasts were perfect (the “assured future” hypothesis) the
use of the payback period as an evaluation criterion would probably give incorrect results. On
the other hand this way of working can be very useful for shedding light on the investment
burden and its impact on incomes in a project’s later years. This favors projects whose pay-
back date is compatible with the risks that they may run. In other words, the payback period
is an effective method for assessing the hazards incurred, especially when competition is
intense; in this case there is every reason to evaluate the profitability by using this criterion,
particularly in its simplified form: the payout time.
This criterion is defined as the ratio of a project’s overall capitalized discounted cash flow to
its investment cost. If n is the presumed lifetime of the facilities in years, then using the above
notation we have:
(CF)P
/1 P
p=o (1 +i)
RCE = . ~ O(in
O %)
Z
The higher this rate, the more profitable is the situation. When two are compared, the one
with the higher RCE is considered to be the most attractive from an economic viewpoint.
Like the preceding ones, this method has its limits. It may prove to be inadequate, or even
faulty, when the objective is to determine the optimum dimensions of a facility. For example,
this is the case when a curve illustrating the variation of capitalized discounted cash flow
against investment has a sigmoid form (S-shaped curve, Fig. 2.4).The RCE is represented
graphically by the slope of the straight line joining the origin to the point on the curve that
represents the selected capital, i.e., the defined production capacity. It reaches a maximum
when this straight line coincides with the tangent drawn from the origin. However, this invest-
ment and consequently the size of the unit that it defines are smaller than the ones that would
be obtained from the optimum capitalized discounted cash flow, which corresponds to the top
of the curve.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 107
investment
corresponding
to maximum
capitalized
discounted
cash flow
investments
With its two terms, one describing the operating expenses, the other capital costs, this is
simply an “accounting production cost” for the yearp just elapsed.
We can imagine an analogous calculation being made for a long period in the future, but
based on a reference year, i.e., employing the concept of present value. In these circumstances
we would speak of a “discounted” or “economic” annual production cost, to distinguish it
from its accounting equivalent. But its nature must be such that whether the total is obtained
by cumulatively entering the figure for each year of operation, over the period of the study,
108 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
or by doing the same thing for its components, i.e., the actual stream of similar expenses
(operating costs and capital costs in particular), the result is the same.
The criteria considered so far involve the concept of discounted incomes, which assumes
the existence of revenues linked to the sale of products at market prices. Conversely, for each
particular value that may be assigned to them, there are annual returns that, when divided by
the actual quantity produced during the period, define an average unit sales price. We can call
this the “minimum profitable” price if the level of return selected is itself considered to be
minimal. In this case, calculating on a zero profitability basis signifies that the revenues are
equivalent to the operating expenses. Considered in terms of production units, these expenses
define an “economic unit production cost”, which is just the minimum sales price, as shown
previously, above which the discounted cash flow is positive, and below which it is negative.
As such it amounts to a new economic criterion or a special application of the use of cash
flows, which may prove very effective for a rough analysis.
Indeed, a simple comparison of prices quickly shows whether or not .projectis making a loss.
However, in this case it is often convenient to make a constant money comparison with a
sales price that is itself stable: this assumes, independent of any technological improvements,
that the performance or the productivity of the facilities, i.e., the annual or unit economic pro-
duction cost, is held constant. Here, two situations may arise.
i.e.:
or:
Note that the annual decreasing depreciation provision thus applied is higher than the lin-
ear depreciation of the accounting equivalent (see Section 2.2.4.2.A), since it includes not
only the depreciation itself but a repayment of capital at a rate equal to the discount rate i.
In contrast to accounting depreciation whose duration follows the legislative provisions,
economic depreciation is normally calculated over the effective or presumed duration of the
facilities’ operations.
This way of working answers an earlier concern due to an apparent logical inconsistency
in assuming that the incomes, expenses, and depreciation provisions could all be held con-
stant at once.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 109
Now:
so:
Next we have to find a constant annual equivalent for Co, i.e., a fixed annual economic cost
price P:
p = c o = c o i(l+i)”
P +
(1 i)” - 1
The economic depreciation for any yearp is found by calculating the difference: P - Dp.
As with the other criteria considered so far, for each annual concept there is a correspond-
ing way of working in production units, for example: per ton. This leads to the definition of
a “constant unit economic production cost”, also called the “average discounted cost”. Its
value is such that, if the entire production is sold at this price level, there is neither profit nor
loss. In other words, it is equivalent to a constant sales price for which the discounted income
is zero. This condition obtains if the total discounted revenues are equal to the total dis-
counted expenses. If Q represents the quantities produced in yearp, and P the constant price
at which they are sold, then:
p= n p=n
VPepJ cP
p=l
(1 + i ) p
or: (2.23)
The unit economic production cost is therefore equal to the ratio of the total discounted
expenses to the total discounted quantities produced.
Next Page
COMMENTS
By making Cp = Dp + Ap, we obtain:
p=n
p=l
P= (2.24)
p=n
0 In this simplified form (2.25) the economic production cost is equivalent to a min-
imum pre-tax profitable sales price, like that defined earlier when discussing the
internal rate of return. The equation obtained then:
V'=[
I' + f ' ( 1-a)- A'J 1+ c'
1-a
can in fact be written (as long asf' is assumed to be zero or included in I t , and a = 0):
I' + D'
V' = -
or:
P
I
-+D
so: p = -P
Q
since, by definition, V', I' and D' represent unit quantities.
Previous Page
T I ,
Growth
Gross profit Net available
- cash flow -c
cash flow cash flow
(undistributedprofits, etc.)
A A
Direct operating Capital repayment
Financial
+ costs - costs
- + cash flow
(wages, costs of benefits. etc.) (distributed profits. etc.)
The additional withdrawals for capital expenses such as financial costs and taxes on profits
lead to: the net available cashflow.
These flows can then be divided into three main categories:
Maintenance cashflow: this is for possible renewal of existing plant, so as to maintain
productivity, and to make the corresponding provisions (allocation for depreciation,A).
Growth cashflow: part of the net profits, distinct from the allocation for depreciation, is
invested in new projects.
Capital remuneration cashflow: another portion of the net profits is distributed to share-
holders as dividends.
Only the first two are likely to bring about investments: together they represent thefinanc-
ing capacity cash flow, corresponding to the deployment of concrete means of production,
both to hold on to existing market shares and to win new ones by the marketing of innovative
112 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
products, and also by creating new jobs. After all is said and done they are the source of
potential sales growth and, consequently, of possible profits.
Conversely, the dividends paid out to shareholders appear unproductive when looked at in
this way. This may enable a better understanding of the “psychological” character of the discount
rate selected by a company or a state. In fact, it appears to be the reflection of the desire either to
repay the shareholders(high rate), or to enable investment and risk-taking (low rate). So, it is an
indirect measure of the distribution of the net profits and the dynamism of the company.
In the previous section, these two concepts were frequently evoked in the nomenclature
employed. On the one hand, they are linked by the unit capacity, on the other the operating
cost ( C ) appeared as the resultant of two principal terms: the operating expenses (0) and the
capital charges (A and F).
Here, we need to explain them, to provide more detailed definitions, and to see what they
cover in practice.
Actually, evaluating a project’s profitability consists of drawing up a balance sheet of rev-
enue versus expenses for a production facility. The revenue side, arising from the sale of man-
ufactured products or from services provided, can be estimated from forecasts based on
market studies, which give both the probable volume of transactions and their expected price
levels. However, the expense side still has to be grasped, and its overall scope expressed in
terms of operating cost or cost of price.
firms and, more generally, of the engineering companies responsible for sizing the facil-
ities.
We will retain the first two of these three approaches, which respectively address the con-
cepts of “operating cost” and “cost of price”. The question then becomes one of how best to
manage the passage from one to the other: they are roughly subsumed in the unit production
capacity, but in reality are more complex.
In this context, in fact, there are several factors to consider.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 113
A. TheoreticalStream Factor
This corresponds to the duration of operation of the production facilities over the year, with
allowance for anticipated routine maintenance shutdowns. In this regard, we may distinguish
between sites that run continuously, 24 hours a day, including Sundays and holidays, and
ones that operate semi-continuouslyor discontinuously, whose schedules can be very diverse
(five or seven days per week, one, two, or three eight-hour shifts, etc.). For the sake of con-
venience in this discussion, we have limited it to plants whose size is sufficient to justify con-
tinuous operation. In this case, the stream factor may be expressed in various ways: for
example, 8 000 hours or 340 daydyear, instead of 8 760 hours or 365 days maximum for a
regular year. This is also why it is sometimes formulated in terms of a ratio or a percentage,
such as 0.9 or 90% (ratio of the operating time or stream days to the length of the year or cal-
endar days). The figure of 8 000 dayslyear is commonly employed: although it has the disad-
vantage of not yielding a whole number of days per year (333.33 dayslyear), it is very
convenient for consulting firms. For them, in fact, the basic unit of time is the hour. It is used
as much for material and energy balances as for the sizing parameters representing equip-
ment, and thus their costs. This approach simply aims to base the conclusions of market stud-
ies on a theoretical nominal capacity, allowing for a reasonable number of hours or days of
downtime over the year to permit maintenance and periodic inspections of equipment, possi-
ble overhauls, replacement of catalysts, adsorbents, solvents, etc. It reflects optimal usage of
the equipment, at its best possible production capacity.
(qi)and the corresponding sized hourly capacity. Expressed in annual terms, such an indicator
can be used in an equation like the following one:
Q (real annual production) =
t=O
CiTi
c
t =I year
t=O
ci
t=lyear
where: C = effective stream factor
t=O
t=lyear
and:
ct=O
t=lyear
CiTi
t=O
This approach assumes a knowledge of the results from operation of the facility under con-
sideration for a period of a year, and thus reflects an accounting viewpoint. In evaluation
work, where the studies naturally have a very pronounced predictive character, it is not pos-
sible to have access to such detailed information. Consequently, in these cases it is customary
to adopt an effective stream factor whose value is equal to the theoretical stream factor (pref-
erably 8 000 hourdyear), and a load rate that is equally arbitrary-although based on the fore-
cast of market growth-but assumed to be constant for relatively long periods: a year at least.
In this case, the concept of utilization rate vanishes and is merged with that of the load rate,
giving only one coefficient, comparable to an average value. It represents the ratio between
the forecast production and the calculated capacity, and may equally well be called the load
rate or the utilization rate.
Labor
Fixed charges or fixed costs.
The “variable charges” are so called because they are directly proportional to the actual
production of the existing facilities, not to their nominal manufacturing capacities. These
expenses reflect the results of the material and energy balance sheets that go with the opera-
tions concerned, i.e., with the yields.
~ ~~ ~~
Expressed in annual sums (euros per year), as recommended when utilizing operating cost
and accounting rules, they obviously reflect the demand, and track its variation.
In the commonest application, however, they are related to the unit quantity physically
manufactured, especially to the ton of raw material processed, or of product. In this case, as
long as the effect of scale does not lead to changes in the balance sheet, there is no difference
in energy or raw material content from one ton of product to another. In other words, the so-
called variable costs, when reckoned by the year, i.e., in terms of operating cost, become con-
stant costs if they are expressed as cost of price, In this case, the French often use the expres-
sion “mise au mille” (per thousand) to indicate that the costs, or the elements used in
determining them, are in per ton figures, i.e., per thousand kilograms of product.
The “fixed charges” are the expression of the operating costs that follow directly from the
costs of investment (see Section 2.3). They are so called because they are drectly tied to the
116 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
processing capacity of the facilities, and are consequently defined the moment this parameter
is known. In particular, they do not depend on the quantity actually produced. For example,
if there is a fortuitous but lengthy shutdown of the facilities, the fixed charges do not stop, but
continue to appear on the financial balance sheet. In these circumstances:
0 In terms of operating cost, i.e., annual expenses, they appear quite constant,
0 In terms of cost of price, i.e., per unit quantity manufactured, they become dependent on
the actual annual production, and therefore variable. They rise as the load rate falls, and
vice versa.
“Labor”, particularly the operating personnel, gives rise to costs that are difficult to assign
to either of the two previous categories of expense. The maintenance, general service, admin-
istrative, and marketing personnel, who do not do shift work, are accounted for under various
entries covered by the fixed charges. The others, however, who are obliged to work in shifts
to ensure the continuous operation and supervision of the facilities, must be accounted for
separately. Their numbers increase with both the capacity and the actual production. They do
not grow proportionally, but in discrete amounts; they generate costs that are roughly constant
over the year, continuing during short shutdowns, but they can fall off quickly if the situation
lasts a little longer, since the onsite personnel cannot remain idle too long: they will be trans-
ferred temporarily to other activities, and charged to other projects.
0 Utilities.
To these must be added related costs, often grouped under the label “miscellaneous”: they
are generally of secondary importance, even negligible. To determine the amount of the costs
generated by the first two items we must return to the concept of the quantity-price relation-
ship, discussed in Chapter 1. Both of the constituent parameters must be defined and ana-
lyzed, because the ultimate objective is to calculate their product.
With this in mind, the main headings to consider are the following:
0 Raw materials
Co-products
0 By-products
0 Heterogeneous phase catalysts, molecular sieves, alumina, contact masses, etc., and
agents, etc., and overall, any liquid additive in the processing stream
Cartridges, filters, electrodes, lamps, etc, and other items of equipment that are fairly
quickly worn out and frequently replaced, and which are directly related to the operation
of the facilities.
a. Raw Materials
The expression “raw materials” describes the essential starting items that go towards defining
the operation’s weight material balance. They are an integral part of the products and co-
products that result, and consequently they have the same nature, i.e., organic or inorganic
depending on whether they belong to one or the other of these two classes. In hybrid or com-
posite materials the two categories are represented in proportion to their contributions. Their
amounts provide a measure of the order of magnitude of the substances to be produced, and
they must conform to strict commercial specifications.
b. Co-Products
The term “co-product” covers all the products that are jointly produced from the same man-
ufacturing line, as long as they come from the same raw materials and can be directly sold in
their respective markets, i.e., as long as they have properties or specifications at least equiv-
alent to their commercial counterparts. They must also be able to take advantage of similar
economic conditions, in particular the same effects of scale, which means that each of the
substances thus manufactured must be available in volumes of similar size.
From this standpoint, steam cracking of naphtha, which simultaneouslyproduces ethylene,
propylene, isobutene, butadiene, and benzene, is a type example in which tonnage is the unit
for accounting purposes. In such a case, it may be difficult to draw up an economic balance
sheet in terms of cost price, i.e., per ton of products. There are two possible approaches:
Choose one of the substances produced as a reference (e.g., ethylene). It constitutes a
“key product”. The other co-products, expressed in quantities per ton of key product, are
entered as credits.
0 Define a notional ton of product, whose composition reflects the respective proportions
of the various co-products manufactured. The calculations are then conducted by refer-
ence to an “average ton” of this notional product.
The production of composite molded objects of various shapes (bottles, toys, etc.) provides
another example, in which the accounting unit is the piece. It requires the simultaneous use
of several thermoplastic materials. In this case, a balance sheet based on cost of price can be
drawn up only for a particular type of object, with the others appearing as credits.
118 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
c. By-Products
“By-products” have two different origins. They arise from secondary, undesirable transfor-
mations, linked either to the conversion of the raw materials itself, or to the use of reagents
or accompanying chemical products, even solvents, additives, or other additions. For this rea-
son they may or may not appear in the operation’s weight material balance, depending on
whether they come wholly or partly from the initial feedstock, or, on the other hand, entirely
from the use of reagents. As with co-products, their nature is strongly dependent on that of
their parent materials, but generally speaking they are much more numerous, and so their
compositions are even more varied. Their two principal characteristics are, first, that they are
produced in small amounts, the smaller the better, and, second, that most of the time they do
not meet commercial specifications. In the economic balance sheet, they appear as credits or
debits according to whether they can actually be sold, or whether, in order to get rid of them,
specific additional transformations must be carried out or a provision made for disposal costs.
However, even if it is possible to sell them, they have two considerable drawbacks: on the
one hand their presence in regular products is heavily penalized; on the other, with few excep-
tions, bringing them up to specifications demands additional processing, which is charged
directly to them. The bottom line is that even in the best circumstances the potential market
value of by-products has to be marked down by an amount that represents their cost as prod-
ucts in their own right. Unless otherwise indicated, this minus-value is roughly of the order
of 50%.
d. Reagents
In theory, “reagents and chemical products” do not appear as major items in the material bal-
ance. They have an accessory role, to the extent that they are designed to facilitate the oper-
ations of certain units, or to supplement them by eliminating by-products or surplus reagents
and catalysts, etc. They are often different in kind from the raw materials and co-products,
e.g., inorganic when the conversion involves organic substances. They must meet strict com-
mercial specifications, more exacting than the ones required for manufactured products or
their direct precursors, so as not to contaminate the main transformation. However, they are
generally used in smaller quantities. For this reason, since they do not benefit from economies
of scale, they also do not become more affordable in better economic times.
Their essential characteristic is that they are involved right from the start, in significant
amounts, and that the full complement must be in the facility from the moment it begins pro-
duction. This is true for all the solid contact masses such as catalysts, molecular sieves, alu-
mina, activated charcoal, diatomaceous earths, etc., and also for the quantities of liquids,
especially solvents used in extraction or absorption, various oils, coolants, mineral salts, and
liquid metals (e.g., mercury amalgams). The corresponding expenses, called first load or ini-
tial load expenses, which must be incurred even before the equipment starts operating, are
treated as investments (see Section 2.3). However, as time goes by the reserves of these prod-
ucts are used up, so that on one hand they have to be regenerated, whether continuously or
not, and on the other partly or wholly replaced, so as to make up the losses that are an inevi-
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 119
table consequence of processing. The bottom line is that there is a consumption that must be
treated as a variable charge, since it rises in proportion to the production.
However, each situation constitutes a special case deserving detailed analysis, so as to
make clear what has actually been spent. In this regard, it would seem more useful to study
some specific examples. One of the most complete is for catalysts operating in the heteroge-
neous phase, and is therefore worth spending a little time on.
There are various kinds of solid catalysts: in particular, they are described as mass or sup-
ported, depending on whether the active phases are mixed with binding agents before being
formed, or are deposited on a pre-formed carrier. In both cases, the result is a porous structure
onto which compounds are adsorbed, under controlled pressure and temperature conditions,
before being activated, converted, and desorbed. Certain parasitic transformations lead to
products that are hard to strip, and which, when heated, eventually form gums or carbon
deposits. This leads to a partial blocking of the pores and a masking of the active components.
It is accompanied by a similar phenomenon that is due to attrition, i.e., mechanical wear from
liquid and gaseous reagents circulating through the catalytic beds. The resulting fines seal off
the pores little by little, and lead to an overall reduction in activity. Another cause of deacti-
vation, especially for mass catalysts, may arise from the volatilization of certain active
phases: the temperature is far from uniform throughout the reactive mass, and local hot spots
may affect the stability of the existing systems.
This progressive aging of the catalysts over time can be monitored in various ways, in par-
ticular by measuring the loss of charge from the bed, which increases steadily, or the rise in
temperature that is needed to maintain their performance. This latter parameter has moreover
proven to be a particularly useful tool for control. In fact, every catalytic reaction has a par-
ticular initiation temperature, i.e., a heat level sufficient to obtain significant production.
Deactivation leads to progressively raising this temperature, until it reaches a level above
which the danger of destroying the active phases becomes too great. At this point, it is con-
sidered necessary to halt operations and restore the catalyst’s properties: we then say that we
have completed a run. Regeneration is usually performed in situ by careful combustion of the
carbon and gum deposits, either by using steam, or by controlled burning in air with reduced
oxygen. In some cases the catalyst may also be sieved, to eliminate fines, and made up to vol-
ume.
COMMENT
This operation is sometimes done offsite, by specialized companies with their own,
specially equipped facilities. To avoid a prolonged shutdown the system is immedi-
ately replaced by a preactivated one. This approach, which consists of keeping inter-
ruptions to a minimum by using two identical loads, is being more and more widely
adopted: it also frees operators from the technical and economic constraints involved
in catalyst management, by using service companies who thus act as rental agents.
In fact, after such reactivation treatments it is very uncommon to get back to the original
operating conditions: the initiation temperature is a little higher, such that the second run is
shorter than the first. Since the length of each succeeding run diminishes with each regener-
ation, there comes a time when it is preferable to stop the procedure and completely replace
the catalyst, which is said to have reached the end of its life. We then have to purchase a new
120 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
load, and it is as if the first one had been completely consumed during the preceding period,
in two years for example. The corresponding expense, expressed in terms of cost of price,
consists of dividing the cost of this load of catalyst by the actual production of the facility
during this lifetime.
When the active phases consist of precious metals such as platinum and iridium, or semi-
precious ones such as cobalt and nickel, the calculation becomes a little more complicated. In
fact, it is possible to re-process used catalysts to recover these elements, and then recycle
them.
The resulting savings are far from negligible, considering the prices of these metals and
the recovery rates, which may be as high as 99% in the case of platinum. Under these circum-
stances, when considering production expenses during the catalyst’s period of utilization it is
appropriate to charge only for the cost of the support, the impregnation, and lastly the supple-
ment of active phase needed to return it to its original operating condition.
The other kinds of solid contact masses, such as molecular sieves, alumina, activated char-
coal, etc., behave like catalysts from an economic viewpoint, at least in a general way. How-
ever, they typically create expenses that are low enough to be ignored, or included with a
larger group of miscellaneous consumables, depending on the level of accuracy required and
the information available.
of availability, shipping delays, ease of application, etc., which may for example impact on
various investment items such as the stock of spare parts, working capital, etc., or lead to spe-
cific labor or maintenance costs, etc.
development of regulatory methods for each case, and these very actions have created a mul-
tiplicity of reference price systems.
Spot Prices
These are prices connected to day-by-day transactions, as they occur, usually concerning
limited quantities and referring to specific locations where the shipment is assumed to be
available. For example, for petroleum products the most important spot markets are Rotter-
dam, also called ARA (Amsterdam, Rotterdam, Antwerp), for Northwest Europe, Genoa for
the Mediterranean, Caribbean or Gulf Coast for America, Singapore for Southeast Asia, and
so on. The best-known locations for grains are particularly Chicago, London, New York,
Paris, etc.; for metals, New York, London, Paris, etc.
These are also called ‘‘free” or “cash” markets: they effectively constitute exchanges
whose quotations are regularly published in the more specialized periodicals: dailies such as
Les kchos, the BIP, etc., weeklies such as the European Chemical News, Chemical Marketing
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 123
Reporter, L ’Usine nouvelle, Chimie Actualitis, etc., monthlies such as Informations chimie,
Petroleum Press Service, MatiBres plastiques, etc.
Certain organizations or associations such as Reuters, ICIS-LOR, Platt’s, Petroleum
Argus, Telesate, London Oil Report, Petroflash, etc. make a specialty of this kind of informa-
tion, which they collect, process, and publish, either on a daily basis or on request, via banks,
servers, and data transmission networks.
Spot prices are the product of transactions conducted either by independent traders 3, or by
the trading subsidiaries of producer or user companies. These private companies, which are
independent of government, are merchants responsible for buying and selling on the spot
markets real or notional shipments that they neither utilize nor distribute. They have no indus-
trial restrictions, but face strong constraints on the financial level. Traders must be distin-
guished from brokers, who are paid on commission and who have no negotiating power,
being charged simply with bringing their co-contractor and a customer together.
A single shipment may change hands several times (two or three times on average) before
being used, which gives this type of exchange a manifestly speculative character, even
though, when all is said and done, this aspect appears to be the necessary counterpart of cov-
ering price-risk.
Generally speaking, the spot price is a good indicator of the supply and demand situation.
However, in theory it only takes into account exchanges representing a very small fraction of
actual business or industrial activity: it does not reflect either mutually agreed swaps or cap-
tive uses. In practice, its influence is far greater, particularly during periods of over-produc-
tion, and to the extent that the liberalization of trade, combined with growing industrialization
in the developing countries, is drawing more and more actors into the free markets and aug-
menting the number and volume of transactions.
Contract Price
Mutual agreement transactions for the great volume of raw materials and products take
place in the context of contracts, arranged to cover all or part of the needs for a given period.
These agreements are likely to cover several years, or to be “evergreen”, i.e., renewable for
an indefinite duration, but liable to termination without notice by one or other of the co-con-
tractors. The aim of companies, depending on their purchasing policy, their level of integra-
tion, and their market access logistics, etc., is to assure their regular or principal supplies or
shipments as far as possible; the remainder to be covered by day-to-day trades on the spot
market. Such an approach is made even more necessary by the increasing trend among man-
ufacturers to limit the size of their stocks for economic and safety reasons, applying just-in-
time operation.
3. As a rough guide, some traders are multi-product (petroleum, metals, grains, etc.) and have
major financial scope and worldwide influence, such as Phibro (short for Philips Brothers), Marc Rich,
Tradax, etc. Others prefer to specialize in certain markets and rely on their long history or their reputa-
tion for reliability or aggressiveness, etc. Examples include, for petroleum products: Coastal States,
Intemorth, Mobanoft, Scantrade, Stinnes, Tampinex, Vitol, etc.; for the major petrochemical inteme-
diates: BMS (Belgium Marketing Services), Helm, Lucky Gold Star, MG Metal (Metallgesellschaft),
Tolson, Trammochem, etc.; for agricultural products: ADM, Bunge and Bom, Cargill, Dreyfus,
Fermzzi, etc.
124 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
the limited number of transactions on the spot market, when the unit quantities for
contracts are much more important. In this case, the two reference prices are not
directly comparable, since the exchanges do not concern related tonnages that are
likely to have similar coefficients for economy of scale.
In addition, spot prices are very “volatile”. An accidental stoppage in a major pro-
duction unit, in a just-in-time market, can lead to an explosion in prices that will be
reflected in the contract price, as long as it lasts for a certain period.
However, generally speaking, contract prices ultimately have greater stability,
usually being based on the spot prices for the preceding period, with the extreme
variations suppressed. By way of example, Fig. 2.7 illustrates this feature in the case
of ethylene. Another evident effect is a certain time-lag (of the order of three months)
between the maxima and minima, which clearly brings out the indicator or precursor
role of the spot market.
0 The US.dollar is very often utilized in inter-continental exchanges, for both spot
and contract prices. Within Western Europe they are generally drawn up in the cur-
rency of the price-setting country, i.e., the one that is the net importer of the product,
for example Germany for propylene, France for butadiene, etc.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 125
0 For captive products such as ethylbenzene, almost all of which is locally converted
into styrene, or for cyclohexanone, transformed successively into oxime, caprolac-
tam, and finally a nylon salt before being marketed, the spot prices, once published,
are generally disproportionate to what one might expect from the corresponding or
equivalent contract prices (average transaction or internal transfer price). This dis-
parity actually expresses a one-time, exceptional customer need: to fill it, the pro-
ducer had to make temporary or special arrangements that interfered with the normal
operation of its facilities and generated additional costs, which then had to be
charged entirely to the marginal quantities extracted. Such quotations are in no way
representative of the state of a product’s market or its regular commercial value.
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Figure 2.7 Comparative variations of the spot and contract prices for
ethylene ($/t: Northwest Europe). (Sources: IFe ECN, Plattk, etc.)
Forward Pricing
Forward markets are above all financial markets, also called “paper” or notional markets,
where contracts are exchanged: these are undertakings to buy or sell a certain quantity of a
product, having a particular quality and deliverable at a particular place. To simplify and
rationalize matters, these various criteria are standardized, given that in such a context phys-
ical deliveries are always numerically negligible in comparison with the volume of transac-
tions that they create.
The appearance of forward markets is a consequence of the very great price disruptions
that characterized the last three decades of the 20th century. Indeed, in stable times there is
no need to guarantee oneself against price fluctuations; when instability does appear, major
companies are relatively undisturbed, in that they are able to spread the risks over the various
126 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
items in their product range and still maintain their financial cover. It is different for smaller
companies, which are financially more vulnerable and whose activities are more concen-
trated.
The principle behind forward markets consists of limiting losses (and possible gains) via
a systematic cover provided by notional commercial exchanges, coming from a succession of
sales followed by purchases-of paper, not product. It involves making contractual commit-
ments that ultimately result in the payment (or recovery) of the simple difference between the
anticipated price at a given date (the forward price) and the actual spot price on that date (the
cash price), when the physical transaction actually takes place, or on the assumption that it
takes place at that time. In the terminology used by brokers, if the difference between the
actual cash price and the forward price is positive (difference > 0), we have a backwardation;
if on the other hand the difference is negative we have a contango (from continue and go).
Differences between two “forward” positions (three and six months for example) are handled
in the same way. Note that, although cash prices may vary dramatically, forward prices do
not: they fluctuate in a much more gradual manner because they are, in a way, the resultant
of the underlying market trends perceived by the professionals, with possible allowances for
economic events (Fig. 2.8).
The principal existing forward markets are, in the petroleum area: the Nymex (New York
Mercantile Exchange), the IPE (International Petroleum Exchange) in London, and also the
exchanges in Singapore, Chicago, Rotterdam, etc.; for grains and oleaginates: Chicago, etc.;
for sugar: London, New York, Paris, etc.; for cocoa and coffee: London, New York, etc.; for
potatoes: Lille, etc.; for rubber: Kuala Lumpur, etc.
11/98 12/98 01/99 02/99 03/99 04/99 05/99 06/99 07/99 08/99 09/99 10/99 11/99 12/99
27
25
23
21
19
17
15
13
11
9
-1.5.-’
-2.5
Contango
11/98 12/98 01/99 02/99 03/99 04/99 05/99 06/99 07/99 08/99 09/99 10/99 11/99 12/99
Calculated Prices
In a market exposed to economic hazards and major fluctuations, both buyers and sellers
have felt the need for more stable and realistic reference systems, capable of taking into
account the expenses involved in manufacturing and marketing a product.
In the petroleum field, the best-known mechanism of this type is the "netback". This arises
from a theoretical calculation that allows a refiner to determine the maximum price for which
it can buy a barrel of crude on the spot market, at the shipping port (FOB). The procedure
relies on knowing four components:
0 The real prices of products sold on the market, in the various geographic regions,
0 The yields for these various products, resulting from the refinery equipment available
0 Internal transfer price, particularly for captive products, with or without inclusion of a
margin,
Average transaction prices, comparable to actual minimum profitable sales prices, like
those obtained from calculation procedures similar to those discussed in this book.
The purpose of doing this is to have lists of prices that are uniform or consistent among
themselves, readily updated, and that can be used as techno-economic references in market-
ing discussions. As a rough guide, Table 2.6 gives some idea of the results produced by such
methods.
Threshold Price
In the context of national policies designed to protect certain sectors of activity from for-
eign competition that is considered unfair, in that it receives special advantages, other price
systems are often employed. This happens, for example, with agricultural products, which,
both in the USA and in Europe under the Economic Community, are directly or indirectly
subsidized. Examples include:
Intervention price or guaranteed price, at which a State or group of States undertakes to
buy a product from its own farmers. The value chosen is generally distinctly higher than
the world price; sometimes limits (quotas) are imposed, specifying the maximum quan-
tities to be sold in this way ( e g , milk, beetroots, etc.),
0 Minimum import price, providing a basis for determining the amount of deductions lev-
Table 2.6 Transaction prices for selected chemical products in the USA
($ per metric ton), January 1999
Regardless of the reference price selected, in order to obtain a proper understanding of a prod-
uct’s price it is also necessary to state just how the seller will make it available to the buyer,
so that the latter may take into account the additional costs of transferring it to the place where
it will be used. To avoid any ambiguity concerning the allocation of costs and risks assigned
to each of the parties, rules have been enacted which are expressed in the standardized lan-
guage drawn up by the International Chamber of Commerce. The vocabulary, called “Inco-
terms” describes particular situations, illustrated by diagrams in French and English. Their
manner of application is shown in Fig. 2.9a.
Between the factory that manufactures the product and the one that transforms it, several
steps must be distinguished:
Transport by truck, railroad, waterway, etc. to the production site
Customs control (customs clearance for export)
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 129
0 Unloading and possible loading onto a ship, a plane, a train, another vehicle, or contin-
uation by the same mode of transport
0 Transfer from one frontier to another
0 Unloading and possible loading onto a train, a truck, a barge, etc., or continuation in the
same vehicle
0 Customs control (customs clearance for import)
0 Transfer by truck, railroad, etc. to the place where it is used.
Each of these stages involves specific expenses: costs for transport, insurance, taxes, and
handling fees, whose payment by one or other of the parties must be clearly stipulated.
Among the numerous situations considered, we can only look at three principal ones:
0 “Factory” or “ex works”, when the price of the goods is identified as coming from the
manufacturing plant. In this case the buyer must take delivery at that point: all the costs
and risks connected with transfer to the utilization site are its responsibility.
0 FOB (Free On Board), when the goods are delivered under customs seal for export by
the selected mode of transport (ship, for example) to travel from one country to another.
The costs and risks to the buyer must cover the shipment to the unloading point, the bor-
der crossing, the customs clearance for import, and delivery to the factory where it is
used.
0 CIF (Cost-Insurance-Freight),when the goods are delivered under import customs seal
by the seller to the arrival point of the selected mode of transport (ship, for example).
The seller then bears all the corresponding costs and risks, except for those for insuring
the cargo, which are the buyer’s responsibility. The buyer also pays for loading onto
another mode of transport for delivery, customs clearance for import, and shipping to the
place of utilization.
To simplify matters, we often speak of prices that refer to the port of embarkation (FOB
Gulf Coast, for example), or of unloading (for example, CIF A M ) . Note that all these oper-
ations are accompanied by formalities (obtaining export licenses, buying insurance policies,
various invoicing, legal waivers, issuing certificates of origin, etc.) for which each party is
responsible, according to the stages falling under its control.
Figs. 2.9b and 2 . 9 ~
are diagrams of the FOB and CIF price situations, which themselves
give rise to several variants, in particular when it is a question of who is responsible for the
handling and border-crossing costs.
Wd
FOB
FOB means "Free On Board. The merchandise h)
W
is placed on board a ship by the seller, at the
FOB
FOB means "Free On Board. The merchandise h)
port
is of embarkation
placed on board named
a shipinbythe
thesales contract
seller, at the
Theport
riskofofembarkation
loss or damagenamedto the merchandise
in the is
sales contract
transferred
The risk from the
of loss orseller
damageto the buyer
to the when the is
merchandise
FREE ON BOARD merchandise crosses the shio's rail.
transferred from the seller to the buyer when the
FREE ON BOARD merchandise crosses the shio's rail.
CIF
---
COST, INSURANCE, FREIGHT
the seller must provide maritime insurance against the risk of loss or damage during
transport. The seller contracts with the insurer and pays the insurance premium.
The- buver
--,- will note that in this case. in contrast to the exDression ‘FreiohVCarriaae
& Insurance paid to ”, the seller is solely responsible for providing the minimum
insurance coverage (called FPA terms)
If the starting raw material is energy-related or strategic in nature, such as natural gas,
petroleum or derived petroleum cuts, coal, etc., or biomass, it may be difficult to obtain more
than a price range. It is best either to select several scenarios, with clear definitions and
descriptions, or to conduct a price sensitivity study. This approach may be extended, if need
be, to first generation chemical intermediates, to minerals, precious and semi-precious met-
als, basic agricultural products, etc., whose prices are subject to very large fluctuations
depending on the economic situation.
As for by-products, which are usually produced in small tonnages, their price reference is
the spot market. However, the costs of purification to meet commercial specifications must
be deducted, or failing this, a discount of around 50% should be adopted.
In some situations, to be studied on a case-by-case basis, by-products may have to bear the
costs of removal or disposal, or worse still, the expense of eliminating them. Sometimes, it
involves accessory production from the regeneration of startingmaterials (the major petrochem-
ical intermediates, for example); the reference price is then the one used initially for this type of
product, with a deduction for the possible costs of returning it to the original specifications.
Reagents, which are also used in relatively limited quantities, are like by-products, best rep-
resented in terms of price by the spot markets than by floor prices. However, in certain cases
it may be difficult to find the quotation in the usual market price lists. They may instead be
found in producer catalogs, designed primarily for chemical laboratory supplies, or industries
such as pharmacies, photography, etc., where purity is essential. As a result, the prices shown
are very largely over-valued for the applications intended for reagents. In this situation, two
approaches are possible: either apply a discount of at least 30%, or calculate by taking the unit
quantities to the power 0.8, or determine a floor price and increase it by about 30%, as long as
it is possible to find the way back through the manufacturing chain to a raw material with a
published spot price. In such an approach it is not necessary to know all the elements, partic-
ularly the energy costs or the investment costs. Simple rules show that the more sophisticated
the reagent, the smaller is the contributionof these two items to the floor price. Roughly speak-
ing, particularly for solvents, the cost of materials accounts for 70 to 80%. In other words, the
important thing is to carehlly identify the successive reactions and the corresponding yields,
so as to make a quick calculation. As a guide, in the absence of more specific information, an
approximate solution is the following: on the basis of an assumed standard unit production
capacity of 100000 Uyr, assess the average share of the cost of raw materials in the product
price, as a function of the output and the degree of complexity of the transformation to be per-
formed, starting with major organic or inorganic chemical intermediates (Table 2.7). The
capacity adjustment can then be made by applying the following expression:
Y
with
x : % of raw material cost in the floor price for unit capacity C1
y : % of raw material cost in the floor price for unit capacity C2
f:extrapolation exponent.
When x is obtained from Table 2.7, C1 = 100000 andf= 0.7.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 135
Table 2.7 Amount of raw material cost in a product’s floor price. Unit capacity: 100 000 t/yr
Yields (%)
Complexity
>90 70-80 50-60
Low (hydrogenation, alkylation, oligomerization, straight fertilizer, etc.) 75-80 80-85 85-90
Moderately low (polymerization, simple oxidation, nitration, chlorination, 45-60 50-65 60-75
phosphoric acid etc.)
Moderately high (complex oxidation, sulfuric acid, etc.) 30-40 35-50 40-55
High (steam cracking, co-production, chlorine, electrolytic soda, etc.) <20 10-30 15-35
(Source: IFP)
influence on investment matters is very strong (see Section 2.3.2.3), have only a negligible
impact here. Consequently, the situation is made simpler, since the kinds of index that we can
call on are international in nature. As a rough guide, among the regularly published ones we
may mention Nelson-Farrar’s: Table 2.8 shows the main values it provides in the area of
organic and inorganic compounds, in general terms.
COMMENT
The approach suggested for catalysts can be extended to reagents, when the compo-
sition of the corresponding item is unknown, but only if we can identify the overall
or dominant nature of the inputs (organic or inorganic).
0 Distribution costs, via the appropriate networks for each kind of utility,
0 If necessary, expenses for recycling effluents that are still valuable after being used, such
as condensed steam reinserted into the boiler circuit, and cooling water that, after warm-
ing, is returned to its initial condition by being passed through air-cooled towers,
0 Make-up amounts of starting materials, for replacing losses (water, liquid coolants, con-
densates, etc.).
These prices thus include:
0 Variable charges, which primarily cover the costs of “raw materials”. Actually, these are usu-
ally the utilities used as precursors to the one concerned, which in this case has a role analo-
gous to the products that are wholly manufactured elsewhere among the various units that
coexist in a complex industrial installation. For example, it could be the natural gas required
for the cogenerationof steam and electricity.This item also coversthe costs of chemicalprod-
ucts (particularlyfor obtaining the various categories of water and for their possible treatment
before recycling), and, of course, utilities (electricity for refrigeration, for example),
Labor costs,
0 Fixed charges covering the costs of investment for the construction and operation of the
0 Some provision for making a profit on the invested capital, via a minimum value for an
economic criterion, or following accounting rules used for a given site or manufacturing
company.
All in all, they are comparable to actual internal transaction prices, or minimum profitable
sales prices as defined in Section 2.1. This approach offers the advantage of affording a mea-
sure of autonomy to the utility production units, whose role in the management plan is in
every way similar to that of the facilities providing products that must meet precise specifi-
cations. It also enables the centralization and rationalization of the energy and other needs
arising from the whole assemblage of units that make up the industrial platform. It is just as
if each one of them were to charge its own utility costs at their real prices, like its raw material
and chemical product requirements.
However, since each entity has a specific function, which leads to operating conditions that
vary from one unit to another, it may prove necessary to make certain adjustments to the cen-
tralized distribution system. For example, there may be a request to regulate the saturated
steam supply by partial flashing, or it may have to be superheated or its pressure raised. The
resulting investments costs must then be charged entirely to the facility that uses the steam,
without changing the initial access costs for these utilities.
In the particular case of the provision of refrigerants at a certain thermal level, the corre-
sponding investments are usually charged to the consuming unit alone, since such facilities
are not very versatile or flexible, and are generally compelled to operate under very exacting
conditions. In this case, only the energy necessary for their operation is included in the eco-
nomic calculation, also possible expenses for replacements and additions of coolant liquid.
The same procedure is applied when a given unit has such large utility requirements that
they cannot be handled by a central entity that services other plants.
B. U f X f yPrices
These are very variable from one site to another, and in particular very dependent on the ease
of access to the basic energy materials required to produce them, or to natural water resources
(rivers, groundwater, seas, etc.). They are also closely linked to the existing regional or local
infrastructures where the particular manufacturing center is set up, and even to national deci-
sions in the area of energy policy.
Thus the Scandinaviancountries and mountainousregions are known for their low electricity
prices, and in Asian and African countries the scarcity of water is often compensated for by the
low cost of fuel. Governmentchoices, in terms of energy, also have the consequenceof favoring
cheaper sources: petroleum (Saudi Arabia, the Emiraks, etc.) natural gas (Great Britain,New
Zealand, etc.); coal (South Africa, Eastern Europe, etc.); nuclear electricity (France); and so on.
In sum, each project has its own specific utility prices. However, within the same geo-
graphic zone, we see that the fluctuations that affect it remain within certain limits. In the
absence of contrary indications reflecting local conditions, this observation enables the use
of average values, or reference to internal transaction price calculations, similar to those dis-
cussed for raw materials and chemical products; alternatively, prices that are periodically
published may provide the reference.
As a rough guide, the following information may be kept in mind.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 139
a. Fuels
These are usually directly available on the market. For this reason, they follow the same rules
and procedures that were discussed for raw materials. Sometimes they may be liquid or gas-
eous by-products from the various manufacturing operations at the consumer’s site. In this
case, if they can be used as is, close to their point of production, they are inserted into the
existing systems and charged in proportion to their calorific power. In such circumstances, if
they substitute for commercial products they may at best be credited for their useful value. If
it proves necessary to process them to required specifications before they can be used, their
price-as with any by-product that is marketed-must be reduced by the amount of the cost
of purification.
For late 1998-early 1999, the prevailing prices on the fuel markets were as shown in
Table 2.9a-d.
Table 2.9a Average fuel oil prices in various countries (late 1998-early 1999)
Uses Exchange
*ate&)for local
Industrial ElectricitJ Domestic currency
Country
1SC Heay ,SC Heavy Light Heavy Light
1997 1998
(US$lt) (US$/t) ~ ~ $ / m 3 )(US$/t) (us$/m3)
Australia nd nd nd nd nd 1.30 1.31
Austria 91.3 170.1 201.3 C 276.7 13.51 13.50
Belgium 116.7 111.0 161.5 116.7 195.5 36.66 36.80
Canada 105.8 nd 150.9 nd nd 1.17 1.16
Denmark nd 124.3 220.0 nd 503.7 8.32 8.38
Finland nd 146.3 207.8 96.9 253.6 5.91 6.04
France 95.7 109.7 207.8 nd 303.7 6.52 6.5 1
Germany nd 98.0 174.1 100.5 201.5 2.00 2.01
Ireland 159.4 nd 235.6 119.1 ( l ) 352.6 0.68 0.69
Italy 160.6 146.0 693.8 nd 832.6 1595 1621
Japan 123.6 186.1 175.4 154.2 (l) 274.5 163.52 163.00
Netherlands nd 156.2 nd nd 360.9 2.05 2.07
Norway nd 253.1 299.7 - 387.8 9.20 8.99
Portugal 207.1 225.0 770.3 99.4 808.8 122.60 125.00
Spain 150.5 178.5 290.1 178.2 336.5 123.89 126.00
Sweden - 162.1 ( l ) 176.4 nd 418.8 9.62 9.63
United Kingdom 122.1 nd 164.5 105.6 190.1 0.65 0.66
USA 84.9 nd 11 1.6 86.7 241.5 1.oo 1.oo
OECD Europe 137.1 nd 272.4 55.5 296.5 - -
(1)
. , 1997. nd: not available
(2) versus the dollar. C : confidential
- : not applicable
(Sources: AIE, Energy Prices and Taxes, 2nd Qtr. 1999)
140 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
Table 2.9a (continued) Average fuel oil prices in various countries (late 1998-early 1999)
Table 2 . 9 ~Average natural gas prices in various countries (late 1998-early 1999; US$/106 kcal)(I)
~~
Table 2.9d Average coal prices in various countries (late 1998-early 1999; US$/t)
Table 2.9d (continued) Average coal prices in various countries (late 1998-early 1999; US$/t)
b. Steam
This can be generated specifically to meet exact needs, in special boilers. It is also often co-
generated during electricity production.
In the first case, every expense connected to its production is chargeable. Its internal trans-
action price is then directly dependent on the price of the fuel employed; it is also a function
of the size of the plant, the pressure at which it must be delivered, and the scale of the distri-
bution system (see Appendix A.2.8).
As an example, Table 2.10 shows representative values for different fuel prices.
When steam and electricity are co-generated, the costs, whatever their source (variable or
fixed charges), must be charged in proportion to the amounts of the utilities that are jointly
produced.
c. Electricity
A distinction must be made between the average price tariffs offered by the major national
distributors such as EDF in France, ENEL in Italy, etc., and those found at heavily industri-
alized sites, for example refineries or chemical complexes, which provide for their own elec-
trical energy needs internally, usually, moreover, by using combustible by-products.
For the major distributors, the average prices offered to customers are not only a function
of the nature and structure of all the power stations in operation, i.e., in fact, a function of the
country concerned, but also of the sectors of activity being serviced and the scale of consump-
tion. In this regard, Table 2.1 1a gives a comparative idea of the price levels in operation in
1998-early 1999, among various members and non-members of the OECD.
For an average load rate of 8 000 hourslyear, for example, Table 2.1 1b shows the prices in
France for various power requirements.
At the producing sites, the calculations can only be made in term of costs, or of internal
transaction prices, which are very dependent on the kind of fuel used and the technology
employed. They also depend greatly on the unit capacity of the plant.
144 2 . The Elements of Economic Calculation
Table 2.1 l a Average electricity prices in various countries (late 1998-early 1999; US$kWh)
Table 2.1 1a (continued) Average electricityprices in various countries (late 1998early 1999; US$kWh)
Country
Uses I Exchange rates(2)for local currency
Industrial 1 Domestic 1997 1998
Argentina 0.079 0.139 1.o 1.o
Brazil 0.058 0.133 - -
d. Refrigeration
The internal transaction price for cooling depends on three main parameters:
0 The thermal level
C. Miscellaneous Costs
Among the expenses that may be included in the variable charges, and which have not been
considered under the headings listed so far, the royalties described as “running” are particu-
larly conspicuous. Their essential characteristic is to be proportional to the actual plant pro-
duction, i.e., to continue over several years, in contrast to the overall initial “paid up”
royalties, which are linked to the unit size capacity and are charged as investment costs, to be
examined in detail in Section 2.3.
Generally speaking, “royalties” are intended to at least partially repay the R&D work that
leads to the industrial implementation of innovations in equipment, processing, products, cat-
alysts, etc. Their main effect is to remunerate the research organizations, which do not market
their discoveries themselves, but grant licenses to third parties to exploit them commercially.
In return, the owner of the innovation is obliged either to give the operator certain exclusive
rights, or to undertake to protect the original aspects through patents.
Running royalties, according to the provisions of the agreement signed between the two
parties, are payable by annuities over the plant’s depreciation period, or according to the
period (or semi-period, sometimes) of the validity of the patents (18-20 years). These pay-
ments may be adjusted over time, to take account of the level of competition, but they remain
linked to the actual production, not the installed capacity, so that they are subjected to the
fluctuations of market demand, and all the hazards of operating the units. Roughly speaking,
we may say that for calculation purposes ten years of running royalty payments are equivalent
to a single initial payment. Intermediate solutions are sometimes applied, including both a
cash payment, and subsequent “running” payments over a pre-determined period and accord-
ing to a schedule established by contract.
2.2.3 LABOR
As mentioned earlier, this item covers only the expenses for the manufacturing personnel,
working in shifts on the facilities, which they operate continuously, semi-continuously, or
intermittently. It concerns only the labor responsible for the actual operations, as well as the
permanent and current maintenance of the equipment. It particularly does not include the
costs of general and special maintenance personnel, workshops, warehouses, control and ana-
lytical laboratories, or services of an administrative nature (accounting, management, market-
ing, food services, on-the-job medical, works council, etc.).
charges, as a given percentage of the investment for the production units. The other kinds of
expense are included in the overhead and head office costs, which are themselves calculated
as a certain fraction of the costs of the plant.
The maximum length for an effective period of work without a break is generally eight
hours (sometimes twelve hours). In theory then, continuous 24-hour operation demands no
more than working with three identical shift teams. In reality, a number of factors have led to
a gradual increase in the number of teams necessary to ensure continuous operation through-
out a normal year (8000 hours on average): legal measures enacted over time, such as those
regulating weekly and yearly holidays; temporary unavailability due to illness or authorized
absences; reduction in the length of the work week (39 hours or less per week, for example);
part-time employment, and so on.
Originally four, then five, the figure is now 6.5, at least for large-scale units such as refining,
metalworking, and basic or major intermediate chemistry. It is less for smaller continuous-
operation facilities, and obviously for those where the operation is semi-continuous or inter-
mittent: three eight-hour shifts, two eight-hour shifts, seven days a week, or five out of seven.
Technical publications quote numerous examples of labor requirements, usually expressed
in numbers of shift operators, according to the type of manufacturing unit concerned
(Table 2.13). This approach amounts to giving the overall number of workers in the team. The
broad growth in unit manufacturing capacities, combined with increasingly strict safety con-
trols, as well as ever more advanced methods of automation, is leading to greater centralization
of plant operation in control rooms. In these constructions, the visual display of the various
operations being supervised has introduced the concept of the control panel and made it a stan-
dard. Today, a single system operator can manage the operation of not just several sections of
the same unit, but also of several units, thereby reducing the overall need for personnel.
On the other hand, such a development is only possible when there is an improvement in
the operators’ qualification standards, and consequently their pay. However, their numbers
can grow by only a few at a time, as a function of the scale and also the complexity of the
facilities. There are no exact rules here, but certain quick rules of thumb have been suggested,
enabling approximate solutions for a new manufacturing facility. As a rough guide, we
present the following expression, which allows the number of operator hours to be calculated:
Also worth noting is the increasingly widespread trend towards using sub-contractors, partic-
ularly for maintenance or more generally for non-shift operations.
We should also note that, roughly speaking, the number of shift operators varies on aver-
age in proportion to the power 0.2-0.25 of the unit production capacity.
Table 2.1 3 Typical examples of numbers of operators per team, by industrial sector concerned
Table 2.14 Typical examples ofpayments and wage costs (early 1999)
for shift personnel in the French petroleum industry
number of operators per team and the number of work shifts, often incorrectly expressed as
“operators per shift”. As a rough guide, such a cost, which amounts to 0.35 lo6 € per shift on
average (mid-2000, EU conditions), results from a consideration of the following data:
average monthly gross reference wage (€) 1750.0
seniority bonus (%) 10.0
vacation and productivity bonuses (“YO) 13.5
wage basket and shift bonuses (“YO) 30.0
employer costs (“A) 60.0
supervision (%) 20.0
number of teams 6.5
average annual cost of a work shift (lo6 €) 0.35
In order to be able to make a similar calculation for countries other than France, it may be
useful to work either by using indices, which allow local specificities to be expressed by
means of a ratio, or by reference to the average hourly costs used (employer costs included)
in the different countries. By assuming that the number of hours actually worked is equal to
the theoretical load factor for the most widely used plants in continuous operation, i.e.,
8 000 hourdyear, we can then find the annual labor cost per work shift, which incorporates
local, and in this case national, disparities. For a certain number of countries, Table 2.15 pro-
vides information that will assist in this kind of calculation.
Table 2.1 5 Comparison of hourly labor costs(’) in various countries (November 1999)
Local currency
Country Index US%
Name Hourly cost
Austria 104.7 26.9 Schilling 348.69
Belgium 111.1 28.5 Franc 1085.10
Denmark 106.9 27.4 Krone 192.38
Finland 92.2 23.6 Markka 132.65
France 100.0 25.7 Franc 158.79
Germany 121.8 31.3 Mark 57.73
Greece 40.8 10.6 Drachme 3 245.00
Ireland 66.5 17.1 Pound 12.68
Italy 80.3 20.6 Lire 37630.00
Netherlands 99.8 25.6 Guilder 53.25
Norway 109.3 27.8 Krone 2 16.79
Portugal 30.1 7.7 Escudo 1460.00
Spain 67.9 17.4 Peseta 2737.00
Sweden 91.4 23.1 Krona 191.04
Switzerland 104.7 27.0 Franc 40.68
United Kingdom 86.7 21.5 Pound 13.37
I
I
Japan
USA
I
114.7
96.0
I
29.4
24.6
Yen
Dollar
3 338.00
24.63
(1) Including employer costs.
(Source: Rexecode)
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 151
COMMENT
Some treatments have a special line for expenses relating to laboratory and manufac-
turing control personnel, showing them alongside the expense for shift labor, and
reckoning them at about 20% of the latter cost.
This item covers two major expense categories, whose treatment depends on the nature of the
fiscal regime of the country in which the plants are located:
0 Fixed operating charges such as maintenance, taxes, and insurance, and overhead and
head office costs, whose essential characteristic is that they always form part of the oper-
ating cost or cost of price, regardless of any fiscal consideration.
0 Fixed capital charges, such as the allocation for the depreciation allowance and financial
costs, related to any loans that have been made, or more generally to the locking up of
the sums required for the investments. They are recorded as expenses or pseudo
expenses only in market-economy countries, where the concept of taxation of profits
exists, and where special provisions aimed at encouraging manufacturers to invest grant
them tax exemptions.
As their name suggests, these are connected to the operation of the plants, i.e., to the utiliza-
tion of the equipment that constitutes the unit proper, and to the partial use of the storage and
general services that support the related administrative operations. They are therefore usually
calculated as a hnction of the investments that these plants represent, and not in comparison
to the total investment burden represented by the depreciable capital and the working capital
(see Section 2.3). These concepts take into account all the essential expenses that must be
incurred before manufacturing can begin, but they do not all necessarily generate operating
costs: their main interest is to meet fiscal concerns rather than manufacturing ones.
A. Maintenance
The other two, which require adjustments, even replacements of all or part of one or more
pieces of equipment, generate both personnel costs and additional investment costs. As far as
the labor requirements are concerned, the skills required are in no way comparable to those
of the operators, since they generally call for the use of equipment manufacturers, construc-
tion firms, or workshops. For this reason, specialized crews, different from the ones that oper-
ate the units, perform such work. Usually, the scheduled services are assigned to outside
companies or to contract personnel. However, although urgent repairs are also performed by
specialists, in this case they work for the manufacturing company responsible for the produc-
tion. For all that, here too there is a trend towards increased use of sub-contractors, such that
only the most urgent or safety-related work is done in-house, and that outsiders are very
quickly brought in to get the apparatus itself running again.
All things considered, the correspondingexpenses, whose practical effect is the revamping
or alteration of various components of a facility, are comparable to the costs allowed for the
original construction, whether they are the costs of materials or of construction labor. Conse-
quently, it is just as if, in the course of operations, a portion of the investment was renewed.
It would therefore seem reasonable, in this case, to roughly value the maintenance costs as
being a fixed percentage of the initial cost of both the production units themselves, and the
units that directly support their operations (storage and general services).
In the so-called heavy industry sectors (refining, petrochemical, major intermediates, inor-
ganic chemistry, metalworking, etc.), it is customary to reckon maintenance expenses at an
average Of 4% per year of the cost of the plant, i.e., of the battery limits investments, as well
as for general services and storage (see Section 2.3). In fact, this percentage is very dependent
on the kind of products that are processed, being higher when they are considered corrosive
or likely to foul the equipment; it also depends on the type of equipment installed, being
higher here too when the moving parts cause wear on the static ones. Slight differences may
also be produced by differences in the characteristics of the materials employed: the higher
their quality, the better suited they are to their purpose, and thus the more resistant they are.
Ultimately, concrete constructions, which are both static and corrosion-resistant,require only
minimal maintenance. This is why some people recommend using only 3% for general ser-
vices and storage, while still using 4% for the production units. When the products are so
aggressive that special equipment has to be used (internal coatings, traps, etc.) maintenance
costs may reach as much as 10% per year of the battery limits investments. The same applies
to the processing of solid products, particularly minerals, which mainly affect the operation
of rotating machinery, which can be very sensitive to wear and to the fatigue caused espe-
cially by vibration.
However, we must make some minor modifications to this approach to the problem of
maintenance costs:
0 Firstly, technological advances have a tendency to progressively reduce differences in
maintenance of units consists of, on the one hand, providing at the outset for emergency
equipment (particularly pumps) in case of unexpected shutdowns, and including them in
the facilities part of the investments, and on the other hand of adding an item for spare
parts in the calculation of depreciable capital. This is mainly to cover rotating equip-
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 153
ment, and its importance appears only when considering anticipated delays in the deliv-
ery of replacement parts.
0 Finally, from a strictly logical point of view, treating maintenance costs as a fixed per-
centage of investments is also not very satisfying. For example, if the units are shut down
for a lengthy period, these expenses may diminish substantially, even if they do not
entirely disappear.
equipment itself, i.e., essentially the production units, general services, storage, etc., but
also for the loads of catalysts and other consumable goods, products, and raw materials
tied up and stored in this equipment, and also for damages caused to third parties, to the
environment, and so on. These costs are periodic in nature, and have to be paid at about
the same amount every year, unless significant changes have been made to the manufac-
turing complex being insured.
It is hardly possible to put a number on the respective contributions of each one of these
items to the total amount of these expenses without consulting specialists, looking at a
detailed list of the goods to be used, and considering the particular site. In fact, both taxes and
insurance premiums are extremely variable. They depend not only on the nature and scale of
the facilities, but also on how they are set up and on local tax procedures, which, moreover,
tend to evolve in the course of time. Thus, local, regional, and even national authorities or
governments may grant companies certain tax advantages, and various exemptions and
incentives, with a view to encouraging job-creating industrial developments in areas devel-
oped for this purpose. In other circumstances, however, deterrent measures may be taken, to
thwart developments that are inappropriate, polluting, that produce an increase in nuisances,
or that threaten a site.
Roughly speaking, and in the absence of exact information, we may estimate that the cost
of taxes and insurance is proportional to the industrial importance. In other words, the cost
will rise as the surface area taken up increases, or as the unit manufacturing capacity, which
also controls the scope of the related installations, grows. For this reason, it is customary to
use the investment cost of the facilities (production units, general services, and storage) as a
reference when calculating the annual expense for taxes and insurance, using a fixed percent-
age of around 2% per year.
Sometimes a distinction is made between:
Taxes and general insurance (1 to 2% of the investment cost of the production units)
Obligations of an environmental nature, which at the local level means specific contri-
butions to the existing or proposed and extended processing and purification system
(0.5% of the investment cost of the production units).
154 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
of shift labor (40 to 50%) and often repeated under the labor heading,
0 Related management expenses, calculated in proportion to both:
COMMENTS
0 Maintenance, taxes and insurance, overheads, and head office costs represent a
total of about 7% annually of the amount of the investment for equipment. This cal-
culation does not include the cost of the production facilities for the utilities. This
approach makes sense, because these utilities are included in the operating cost and
cost of price, being considered as actual products and billed at their internal transac-
tion prices, i.e., they are assumed to include the fixed operating costs, determined
according to the above procedure. In this case, the reference is composed of the
investment cost of the production unit for the utility concerned, and the cost of the
share of general services allocated to it.
0 The total of the variable costs, labor, and fixed operating costs constitutes the oper-
a. Background
chase price, the values of plants and equipment of an industrial nature diminish considerably
in the course of time.
The deterioration and the gradual wearing out of equipment during its operation leads to a
reduction in its efficiency, which is expressed as an increase in manufacturing costs, by
higher expenses for maintenance, and by unexpected technical stoppages that are more and
more frequent. In this way, its value as a production tool diminishes.
The most recent plants, based on more efficient or more economical processes and tech-
nologies, create difficulties for older ones in terms of their profitability and product quality.
New constructions also benefit from having higher unit manufacturing capacities, the result
both of technological improvements and of the progressive opening of markets. This further
penalizes the existing plants, which are generally of more modest size, through economies of
scale.
0 The products themselves, manufactured under older procedures, are liable to see their mar-
ket shares dwindling away or disappearing, to the benefit of new products that are better
suited to the demand; thus they may face certain problems of distribution and sale. This kind
of situation often appears at the finished product stage: rubber, plastics, synthetic fibers,
detergents, etc.
When we look at these considerations, only the one concerning the wear and deterioration
of equipment seems susceptible of being assessed with any precision. The others, particularly
technological aging and product substitution, appear very hard to quantify. Nevertheless,
when all is said and done, when facing these problems a manufacturer will not be inclined to
invest in building new facilities unless he is encouraged to do so, in particular by compensa-
tory measures. As a response to this concern, in market economy countries the provisions of
the tax code offer the possibility of exempting a portion of profits from taxation, by treating
as an expense a provision for depreciation that is intended to restore the initial capital invest-
ment, over the operating life of the units.
156 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
However, it should be emphasized that the fiscal legislation imposes certain limitations:
not all investments are necessarily eligible for depreciation, only the ones that fall under the
definition of “depreciable capital” (see Section 2.3). In particular, the following are excluded:
0 Working capital, which has a much shorter rate of repayment than the other investment
costs,
0 The cost of the property on which the plant is constructed,
0 And, generally speaking, all investments that can be recovered or sold at a value close
nance and repair that it requires, and the market restrictions, it may continue to operate. In
this case, we understand that the effective life of this facility may be longer than the legal
period of depreciation. Meanwhile, moreover, improvements may or may not be made
(changes in the equipment, re-sizing of the apparatus, additional pieces of equipment, etc.),
which may demand additional investments and, in consequence, the initiation of correspond-
ing depreciation procedures, which start when the new outlays take effect.
0 On the other hand, it may happen that the unit ceases to be operational even before it is
completely depreciated. In this case, at the end of the facility’s life a fraction of the initial
investment cost remains unrecovered: in economic calculations it is accounted for by using
the concept of salvage value (see Section 2.2.4.2.A.c).
In real-life industry, the period considered for an investment project depends on the antic-
ipated operating life of the equipment, not on the depreciation period used for accounting. For
evaluation purposes, it may be convenient to make the two coincide, and if need be to deter-
mine the salvage value of the facilities just at the end of this time. For all that, we must rec-
ognize a situation that lies between the ones described above, and which may appear
somewhat artificial, but much easier to handle in terms of calculations. In this one, the oper-
ating or project period selected corresponds to the depreciation practices in force in the coun-
try where the equipment is located. Of course, there are significant differences from one
country to another, but there are also variations in legal provisions, depending on the purpose
of the investments. Ultimately, certain variations occur over time, such that in this area it is
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 157
difficult to define rules that are applicable in every situation. However, roughly speaking, at
least for the heavily industrialized countries, we may refer to the information in Table 2.16.
COMMENT
The very reason for evaluating projects is to enable the comparison of several of
them, or of several variants of one of them. In some cases, it may happen that the
depreciation period is not the same as the project period. To illustrate this kind of
situation, it is best to choose an example similar to the one already discussed in
Section 2.1.2.3.B, namely, the production of methanol by two different procedures:
1. Startup in 1995 of one large-scale unit with a unit manufacturing capacity of
500 000 tlyr.
2. Startup in 1995 with a first facility of 250000 t/yr unit capacity, and five years
later, namely in the year 2000,startup of a second unit exactly the same as the pre-
vious one.
In the first case, it is possible to take advantage of a better economy of scale than in
the second; however, the second alternative permits a better response to market
growth, which takes place in a relatively gradual fashion. The economic comparison
of these two variants of a single project demands that the project period selected be
the same for both, so that we can work on a uniform basis. However, in this case there
are also two ways of looking at the matter:
Choose a period of ten years for the examination of the two possibilities under con-
sideration. In this case, in the year 2005,the 500000 tJyr unit will be completely
depreciated, and so will the first 250000 tJyr one. However, the second one, with the
158 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
same capacity, will be only partially depreciated, such that the unrecovered portion
of the corresponding investment must appear as a salvage value.
0 Choose a common project period long enough for the invested capital to be com-
d. Calculating Depreciation
Various methods are in use for determining the depreciation provision. The most widely
employed are the ones called straight-line, and declining balance. But some fiscal regulations,
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 159
particularly in the USA, permit the use of other methods, such as depreciation by linearly
decreasing annuities (Sum of the years’ digits method), or by depreciation funds or constant
economic depreciation (Sinking fund method).
Straight-Line Depreciation
This method, which was the one most commonly used before 1959, consists of recording,
each year, the same percentage of the initial “depreciable” capital, a term to be defined later (see
Section 2.3). Thus, if I represents the original outlay, and n (years) the duration of the depre-
ciation and assumed operation of the facilities, the annual depreciation cost is constant, and
equal to:
A = -I
n
Under the simplifying assumptions made, the salvage value of the equipment (I,) is
assumed to be zero at the end of the period concerned.
The depreciation rate in this case is equal to:
1
u1 =n
It has the same value each year, and enables the complete recovery of the nominal value
of the starting investment in the n-th year.
Since n is usually ten years, ul will be 10%. For accounting purposes, the depreciation
begins on the day the equipment is first used. To provide for the exact time elapsed between
the start of production, or of effective utilization of the facilities, and the end of the project,
the first and last annual amounts are calculated on aprorutu temporis basis.
The principle of this method assumes that the annual depreciation is a fixed percentage of
the value of the facilities at the start of the year. If ad is this constant factor, the fraction depre-
ciated during the first year is: ad (Z- Z,.),and the value of the equipment is:
at the end of the first year : (I- Zr)(1 - ad)
at the end of the second year : (Z- Zr)( 1 -
__________--_____________
at the end of the n-th year : (Z- Zr)( 1 - ad)n
At this point, the value of the unit corresponds to its salvage value Z,.(the capital not yet
depreciated, or the resale value, or the re-use value).
COMMENT
In practice, I,. is not cancelled out until the end of a time period that is infinite in com-
parison to the duration n of the project study or of the depreciation. In fact, if the
equipment stops operating at the end of this time, the items that are still functional may
be re-installed at other facilities, and so on until they can only be used for scrap metal.
From the expression: (I-Zr)(1 - ad)n= Z., we can deduce the declining balance depreciation
rate:
a,=1- [ -
Z q n
In this case, in any year p, such that 0 I p I n, the annual provision for depreciation may
be written:
A, = (I - I, 1)- ad)P-*
( ad
As shown in Fig. 2.10, the annual provision is higher under declining-balance than under
straight-line depreciation, during the first years of a comparison; on the other hand it is lower
later on. The recovery of the original outlays is incomplete, since the curve representing its
variation approaches the time axis asymptotically. In addition, this approach may lead man-
ufacturers to employ or call for a higher rate of decline, depending on their specific situations.
The usual trend is of course to “hold” rather than “run”, i.e., to depreciate as quickly as pos-
sible, as long as revenues permit it.
This shows that, here again, the regulatory provisionswere designedto restrict tax deductions.
Thus until 1954, in the United States, it was not possible to have a declining-balancerate
of more than 150% of the straight-line depreciation rate. After that date ad was allowed to
reach a value of double the straight-line rate (“double declining balance”).
In France, article 37 of the law of December 28 1959, and the accompanying regulations
of May 9 1960,provided for a declining balance system based on the lifetime of the facilities:
less than 3 years a d = 1 x a1
from 3 to 4 years ad= 1.5 X
from 5 to 6 years ad= 2 x
more than 6 years ad=2.5 X U ]
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 161
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Years
In other words, the largest part of the equipment of an industrial nature is likely to receive
the highest values. Moreover, in 1989 these provisions were strengthened by the addition of
accelerated declining-balance depreciation, which was authorized for investments for saving
energy and economizing raw materials. Beyond the three-year mark, all the figures shown
above were increased by 0.5: for industrial chemical and refining facilities, for example, this
method allowed a declining-balance depreciation rate of three times the straight-line one.
COMMENT
If ad is greater than the straight-line rate, at the end of the depreciation period I, is
theoretically not zero. In some cases, particularly in evaluation, it might be desirable
to apply a constant depreciation rate, which implies a declining-balancemethod, and
nevertheless recover all of the funds originally invested, even if additional income or
capital gains appear should the equipment be re-used or re-sold at the end of the
period. To answer this type of request, the government allows the use of combined
methods: declining-balance for the early years, and straight-line for the later ones.
Actually, from a legal viewpoint, when the annual amount of a declining-balance
depreciation falls below the straight-line amount for the remaining residual value,
162 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
i.e., when the slope of the tangent to the declining-balance curve is parallel to the line
representing the straight-line depreciation, it is possible to finish up by using the lat-
ter method. In practice, the delays involved in setting up the accounting for this
mixed system make it just as if the straight line that is followed were to join the curve
tangentially at yearn on the time axis.
2(n- p + 1)
A, = (z-zr)
n(n+1)
which amounts to calculating the annual amount for a given year by subtracting a constant
amount corresponding to A , from the previous year’s figure.
where A represents the desired economic depreciation constant for the period n, i being the
discount rate used by the company responsible for the project concerned, so that:
I-I,
A=
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 163
i( 1+ i)"
or: A = ( I - I,)
(1 + i)" - 1
A is the constant annual amount by means of which the initial investment could be repaid
over n years, if the investment had been borrowed at an interest rate equal to the discount
rate i.
The economic depreciation annuity is higher than that for an accounting depreciation
spread over the same number of years, since it contains both a portion covering the depreci-
ation of the facilities proper, and also another portion for the repayment of capital via the dis-
count rate i. In addition, since the annual payment A is constant throughout, and the share for
the financial costs necessarily decreases over time, this type of method leads to a slower
recovery of initial investments than does the straight-line method, during the early years. The
risks incurred by the investors are therefore greater, which to some extent justifies their reluc-
tance concerning such a procedure. On the other hand, it is just the reverse for the lending
organizations.
Financing a project means locking up sums equal in amount to the overall initial outlay, i.e.,
the so-called depreciable capital and the working capital (see Section 2.3).
As discussed in Section 2.1.2.3, in market economy countries these investment costs give
rise to repayments, via:
0 Either a real interest rate when they are obtained by loans from banks or lending agen-
cies,
0 Or a pseudo interest rate, also called a psychological interest rate or a discount rate, when
they concern the internal funds of the company running the project, or its shareholders,
or when the source of capital is unknown, or even assumed to be.
For empirical, after tax methods, such as the POT or the ROI, (see Section 2.1.2.2), it is
just as if the full amount of the initial sums required had been borrowed from the company's
treasury, which would then charge the project for real or notional financial costs calculated
on the basis of an interest rate peculiar to itself, and equivalent to its discount rate.
The procedure used for this is that of continuous compound interest, as discussed in
Section 2.1.2.3.A.a, which involves the concept of effective or declining interest i,, which
should apply only to the sums remaining to be repaid or recovered, i.e., in any given year par-
ticularly the portion of the investments not yet depreciated. Also, when a straight-line depre-
ciation is adopted for the purpose of simplifying the evaluation calculations, it leads to a
similar rule for the financial costs. But just as it is handy to have a constant depreciation rate
for the depreciable capital concerned, it may be useful to take a similar approach concerning
the effective or notional interests that must be considered, both for this same capital and for
the working capital. For this reason, rather than applying a constant interest rate to sums that
are declining in a straight-line manner, it is often preferable to apply, by means of a calculat-
ing device, a constant average interest rate to the clearly identified initial outlays. This aver-
age value ,i is derived from the effective value i, by means of the following equation:
164 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
.
1,
. n+l
= lr -
2n
n being the assumed length of time during which the sums concerned are locked in.
Thus, in the case of depreciable capital for which in general n = 10, if i, is taken to be 12%
per year, we obtain:
im = 6.6% i.e., = 7%
For working capital, for which the renewal period is usually of the order of two years:
im= 9%.
It must be remembered that this calculating trick has no accounting or economic justifica-
tion, and is accordingly rejected by the corresponding authorities. On the other hand, it is very
valuable when there is a need to obtain an order of magnitude by incorporating the component
that expresses the cost of tying up capital.
Examining the profitability of projects by applying economic criteria, as well as the determina-
tion of the amount of the fixed charges included in the operating cost or the cost of price,
requires that one first possess figures for the depreciable capital and also for the working capital.
In practice, moreover, this overall approach to the investments authorized for the construction
and operation of new plants or equipment is inadequate in itself. It appears necessary, in fact, to
look at the individual items, i.e., the various investment charges that addup to these investments.
The purpose of the present section is therefore to analyze them in detail, more particularly
by emphasizing the basic element of such a breakdown: the battery limits investments.
Depending on the company concerned, on whether it belongs to a productive sector or the ser-
vice and consulting side, and also according to the current fiscal provisions applicable to a cer-
tain project, the composition of the depreciable capital and working capital may be defined
differently. So it is not surprising that there may be differences both in the items presented and
in the partial groupings that are made of them. However, as a general rule, it seems that a con-
sensus can be reached about the major topics that are currently likely to be considered here.
The investment cost for the facilities proper (unit investments), comprising:
- The battery limits investments (on-site or on-plot investments)
- General services and storage (off sites or off plot),
0 Storage facilities
At workshops and smaller industrial platforms, these same entities may still be identified,
but they are usually well integrated into the manufacturing process itself. In such situations
we can justify limiting the investment cost of a plant to the outlays for the battery limits
investments, particularly if it produces only one product. In practice, this is another case
where it pays to look critically both at the information being processed and the application of
the suggested procedure to the particular situation.
erection, connection, and indirect workplace costs, whose definition and contents are given
in Chapter 3. Provisions for accidental or unforeseen expenses are often included.
Sometimes the costs of planning work are also included, particularly engineering studies.
To make calculation and presentation easier, it is preferable to separate them and, depending
on the approach suggested, to show them under fixed capital costs.
As shown in Fig. 2.12, at a given industrial site of a certain size there will generally be sev-
eral sub-units for manufacturing or conversion, arranged in series or in parallel, whose activ-
ities are complementary. This complementarity is technological in nature when each of them
constitutes an essential link in a chain of processing or a production line; it becomes eco-
nomic when their purpose is to supply several markets at once, with different natures and
characteristics, from the same raw materials. By identifying the battery limits investments,
we thus mean to isolate the sums that concern each one of these steps only. Looked at in this
way, their geographic limits or boundaries become the locus of:
“Imports”, shown at their respective access costs, i.e., as discussed in Section 2.2.2, at
their market or internal transaction prices, and meeting precise specifications, either
commercial or as required by the operation concerned:
- Raw material(s),
- Common utilities: electricity, steam, various waters (cooling, process, and boiler
water, etc.), fuels (gaseous, liquid, or solid), refrigerants, industrial gases (com-
pressed air, inert gases, etc.),
- Chemical products, catalysts, solvents, absorbents, sieves, etc., depending on require-
ments,
STORAGE
chemicals
4 i + by-products
I
,STORAGE
RODUCTION OF UTILITIES4
f PRODUCTION OF UTILITIES
~
0 “Exports”:
- Products manufactured or processed in the facilities, meeting particular marketing or
internal specifications,
- By-products, organic or inorganic, generated by the main transformation or ancillary
processes, possibly including combustible gases, tars, various residues and wastes,
residual waters, etc., which may possibly be sold or disposed of, but which first
require some additional treatment,
- Utilities described as “exhausted”, because their exit characteristics differ from their
entry ones (for example, cooling water, refrigerants, etc.); but here we must consider
the corresponding by-products, particularly condensates, fumes, and various resi-
dues. Each of them must be either recovered or rejected, but in both cases they require
additional treatment, which for reasons of economy of scale are generally performed
together on all the effluents of the same kind emanating from the various manufac-
turing or conversion stages.
The battery limits investments specifically do not cover the stocks of raw materials or fin-
ished products. However, it may happen that specific modifications have to be made to a
facility (particularly cyclic systems or semi-continuous operations) and that these lead to
intermediate or buffer stocks being established. In these circumstances it is customary to con-
sider such items as integral parts of the manufacturing or processing procedure, and to treat
the investments accordingly.
The different sub-units that make up the various conversion stages at a manufacturing site
cannot be viable as such, whether they are considered separately or even as a whole. To
become operational, they must be provided with accompanying “services”, whose primary
characteristic is to be as general as possible, i.e., to meet the requirements of the majority of
the units and to avoid being too specific. The most conspicuous examples of this kind of facil-
ity, because of their very applications, are the facilities for generating utilities and the corre-
sponding distribution circuits. In spite of their service functions, these entities have a special
role, which is expressed in a specific manner of treating them for economic purposes, partic-
ularly in terms of investment.
In fact, there are two ways of looking at them, which actually correspond to the three most
common situations:
0 The first, which is also the one usually encountered, concerns existing industrial sites,
already provided with services, where it is a matter of examining the effects of inserting
new sub-units or replacing such facilities with more efficient equivalents.
0 The second concerns industrial complexes that are totally new, where we must not only
consider the production facilities themselves, but also provide everything required for
their operation. This particularly happens in industrializing countries.
0 A third situation, which in its investment consequences is comparable to the preceding
one, and requires the same economic treatment, is the one where the insertion of new
components creates disturbances because of their size, so that it becomes essential to
construct service facilities that are wholly devoted to meeting their needs.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 169
To address the first situation as simply as possible as far as the utilities are concerned, it is
best to treat them like raw materials or chemical products. In this case, in fact, we regard them
as inputs from outside the system studied, available under particular conditions, both of a
technical (specifications) and an economic (market or internal transaction price) nature.
These prices, which are derived from a calculation method similar to the one presented in this
chapter, or determined by the laws of supply and demand discussed in Chapter 1, particularly
incorporate the investment charges that are required for the manufacture of the desired “prod-
ucts’’ to the required specifications. In other words, as long as the utilities are accounted for
at their market or transaction value, under the operating cost or cost of price, there is no need
to add in the investment cost for obtaining them. Otherwise, it would amount to counting the
same capital costs twice, by entering them at two different places in the operating cost:
0 As fixed costs, determined by the overall amount of the investment for the units (includ-
C. Storage
are shipped, either to other facilities in the manufacturing complex concerned, or to cus-
tomers, or are possibly removed to the appropriate treatment centers, which may func-
tion semi-continuously or in batch mode. Here again, the stocks act as buffers in the
event that the downstream units and the distribution system are temporarily unable to
function properly.
170 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
As a general rule, companies try to limit the size of their storage, for economic reasons.
Moreover, the trend is more and more to work on a just-in-time basis, and this includes high-
production facilities. The fact remains that, without pushing matters to such limits, manufac-
turers do attempt to reduce the number of drums and tanks allocated for such purposes, by
allowing them some flexibility in utilization. Thus, these items are not used for a single facil-
ity only, but, as long as the kind of content remains the same or changes very little, they are
made to serve several potential users in parallel. This approach explains why their investment
cost is usually separated from the costs of the various production units proper, and why in
practice only a portion of it is allocated to a particular facility.
The share that must thus be charged actually depends on the internal structure of each oper-
ating company. If it concerns the construction of a new industrial complex, it is easy to cal-
culate the amount of storage required, and to distribute it among the production platforms
according to a rule fixed ahead of time, for example by making the various products, whether
finished or not, carry the correspondingexpenses, either in proportion to their respective sales
or to the battery limits investments.
If it concerns the installation of a new facility on an existing industrial site, we must take
account of the equipment in place, their capacities, and the possibility of enlarging them or
the need to construct new ones.
For a specific industrial project, an exact calculation can be made, but in evaluation such
details are not specified: in particular, the place where the unit is to be set up is often
unknown. So we must fall back on empirical rules. Thus, roughly speaking, it is accepted that
the cost of the investment for storage is of the order of 25% of the cost of the battery limits
investments. Such a figure amounts to having a margin of eight days of raw materials or major
products.
Obviously, this figure must be raised if special legislations require longer durations: this
is the case for strategic products, such as those derived from petroleum.
- Site preparation
- Roads and access
- Railroad tracks
- Loading and unloading docks, ancillary handling equipment
- Fences and security
- Lighting
- Parking lots
- Landscaping, etc.
Buildings to house materials, when they are not included in the battery limits investment
envelope, sheds, warehouses, etc.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 171
0 General services proper (buildings and materials or furniture): workshops, stores, labo-
ratories, food services, community health services, safety, administration, management,
etc.
0 Centers for purification or waste treatment, particularly fumes, wastewaters, solid
wastes, etc.
0 Systems for sewage, blow-down, flaring, etc.
0 Holding tanks, retaining walls, etc., and other systems for safety, environmental protec-
tion, observance of prevailing regulations, etc.
This list, which is certainly far from complete, shows-in case there was any need to do
so-the inevitable nature of the additional investments that a manufacturer is obliged to con-
sider, over and above the cost of the actual production facilities themselves, and even before
this equipment becomes operational. Since they produce no revenues themselves, for finan-
cial purposes these ancillary investments have to be charged to the manufacturing units 4.
But, as with storage, the rules for allocating these costs are in practice very dependent on the
internal structure of each company.
However, here again it is possible to separate the case of a new facility being inserted into
an existing industrial complex, from that of the construction of a complete plant. Attention
must also be paid to whether or not it is necessary to modify or to add to what is already there,
when the disturbances produced by the introduction of production platforms completely dis-
organize the existing services. This type of situation is relatively rare, in fact, since from a
size point of view, general services facilities have much less influence than, for example, stor-
age buildings.
Nevertheless, the empirical approach to the investment cost of general services consists of
calculating it in proportion to that of the production units, at a rate of about 15%.
This approximate rule is based on the fact that the more costly a conversion or processing
facility is, the bigger it is, the more site space it takes up, the more employees it has, and so
on, and the greater the burden it places on outside services.
COMMENTS
0 General services and storage taken together represent about 40% of the battery
limits investments. Such an average figure reflects current practices in sectors such
as refining (not including strategic stockpiles), inorganic and organic chemistry, spe-
cialty chemistry (drugs, paint, ink, photography, etc.), food processing, metalwork-
ing, etc.
It is sometimes different in other areas of activity such as nuclear technology, auto-
mobile manufacturing,etc. Accordingly, arbitrary generalizations should be avoided.
0 General services and storage are often grouped together as “offsite” items, as
4. Note that the costs of operating these common services are charged against operating cost under
the item “factory overhead”.
172 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
estimate that may have been made by the engineering companies during the initial feasibility
studies (see Chapter 3). Thus, when compared to a theoretical estimate, the figures proposed
to potential clients may either be significantly lowered, or on the other hand raised. The
explanation for such fluctuations may be attributed to the very nature of service activities,
which depend on the vagaries of the economic situation, on very intense competition, and
often on pressures of a political nature. In such circumstances, various situations may arise,
among which two extreme cases are found:
The first applies to an engineering company whose order books are half-empty and whose
personnel are under-employed. Rather than lay off trained staff who may be desperately
needed later on, when better times come along, the company prefers to keep a minimum level
of operations going. For this purpose it will make every effort to secure the contract by cutting
its prices, i.e., by keeping its operating budget as low as possible, even by under pricing, and
of course by reducing its own fees correspondingly.
0 The second case concerns an engineering company whose order books are full, and whose
personnel are over-worked. In preliminary tenders, it will tend to quote the real price, even to
over-price. In fact, if its reputation acquired in previous dealings leads to its being selected in
spite of its rates and its conservative budget forecast, it will have to hire additional personnel
and quickly train them, or sub-contract, while still looking after the supervision of the work
and guaranteeing it to its client, using highly qualified experts. In both cases, there will be
additional costs that explain the higher fees that are demanded.
Regardless of these practical considerations, which show how dangerous it is to treat the
prices in contracts as if they represented the truth, as certain publications sometimes sug-
gest-and a similar caution must apply to figures obtained through personal contactsder-
tain empirical rules do nevertheless allow a more accurate estimate of engineering fees.
The first alternative consists of relating them to the costs of the equipment that is being
analyzed or monitored, i.e., to the pieces of equipment that require drawings, size calcula-
tions, quotes, etc., orders, receiving, assembly, and so on. In this case it is a matter of taking
a given percentage of the total of the battery limits investments and the investments for ancil-
lary infrastructure (general services and storage, perhaps production of utilities, depending on
the procedure adopted). An average figure, generally accepted and verified, is 12%.
In fact, the engineering fees are not directly proportional either to the unit manufacturing
capacity, or to its complexity. They become smaller as the scale increases and the facilities
become more complex, and vice versa. In practice, it may be best to choose a compromise
between values lying between 7 and 30%, depending on whether, for example, steam crack-
ing or selective hydrogenation is being considered, a rolling mill or a specific refining pro-
cess, an automobile assembly line or the production of replacement catalytic converters, etc.
A second alternative, which is more accurate and more realistic, requires that we first be
in possession of a schematic diagram of the production facilities, showing all the main items
of equipment (including pumps). Storage and general services are not involved in this
method, which consists firstly of counting the items in the manufacturing units only, and then
applying the product of an average number of hours worked (calculation, drafting, monitor-
ing, checking, supervision, etc.) and an average hourly labor cost for the consulting firm,for
each company concerned. As a first approximation the following values may be accepted:
174 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
In practice, at the end of the day it is up to the evaluator to make the best possible judgment
of the situation and to decide on the measures to be applied. This is where an evaluator’s
expert knowledge and professional skills come into play.
C. Contractor Fees
Generally speaking, the engineering company selected by the manufacturer to construct the
project under consideration is neither the designer nor, more broadly, the inventor, of the pro-
cesses, technologies, and equipment, etc. that its calculations are based on. In other words, the
R&D work that leads to the innovations, and the work of putting them into commercial practice
as industrial facilities,usually come from separate organizations.This leads to interface problems:
0 Firstly, economic ones, concerning the proper remuneration for research work,
0 And then technical ones, involving the adequacy of the formal expression of the labora-
tory or pilot development results, so that they can be conveyed to and properly applied
by the engineering company.
COMMENT
Until recently, many companies operated their own in-house R&D departments.
Even where this type of arrangement still exists, the implementation stage is taken
care of by an outside engineering firm, which in no way reduces the problem of trans-
mitting and processing the basic information. In addition, the laboratory and the
operation itself, even though they may belong to the same organization, represent
two different worlds, each one seeking recognition for its own contributions. To
answer such demands, it would seem essential, even in-house, to include a notional
payment for R&D in the accounting.
Paid-up Royalties
These are lump sums paid to the owner of the technologies, by the manufacturer wanting
to apply them, in order to acquire the operating license. They are usually linked to the size of
the facilities envisaged, and proportioned to the tons of unit capacity of production or pro-
cessing. Depending on the kind of technique concerned, they vary from a few Euros per ton
of installed capacity for mass-market products and for less complex applications (for exam-
ple, refining processes), to several hundreds of Euros for the most sophisticated manufactures
and for the most specialized markets (pharmaceutical products, for example).
Moreover, a declining tariff may be applied, with continuous or stepwise reductions,
which takes into account the effects both of scale (the rates diminishing as the nominal unit
176 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
capacity grows) and of the progressive aging of the invention (catching up by the competi-
tion). In some cases, especially when the first industrial use or a demonstration plant is con-
cerned, special terms may be granted, which may go as far as royalty-free operation.
The payment terms are set by contract. The general rule is not to make an overall payment,
but to proceed by installments. For example, a portion (1/4) is paid upon signature of the
agreement assigning the license, another (1/4) during construction of the facilities (at the
beginning or the end), and finally the remainder (1/2) is received after handover testing of the
unit, during which the attainment of the advertised performance is verified.
In this connection, it should be mentioned that the owner of the process or technology is
liable to penalties, deductible from the amounts owed, if the advertised results are not obtained.
However, the risks are reduced by having the contract stipulate guaranteed performances that
are generally less than those actually obtained. In practice, both the user and the licensor make
a joint effort to operate the facilities as far as possible in the manner originally intended, iden-
tifying possible causes of malfunctioning and making the necessary changes when the circum-
stances dictate. The resolution of financial disputes takes place only afterwards.
Running Royalties
Sometimes, by agreement with the holder of the process, or, more broadly, with the owner
of the invention, the payments are made in the form of annuities over a period related, for
example, to the depreciation period of the operating plant, or the life of the patents that protect
the original aspects of the innovation. These sums obviously incorporate financial, insurance,
and administrative costs, etc., connected to the way these arrangements are currently handled
by banking institutions.
Running royalties are so called because they relate to the actual production of the facilities
and not to their unit capacities, as in the payment method discussed previously. For this rea-
son, they are subject both to fluctuations in demand, and to accidental or other incidents that
may affect the normal operation of the manufacturing units. To some extent, this approach
amounts to making the inventor assume a share of the commercial risks. For the same reason,
the amount of the payment is, by way of compensation, usually calculated as a percentage of
the sales price of the final product, even if only to allow for depreciation of the currency.
Since the originality of the innovation fades over time, this payment rate is also periodically
revised downwards, unless additional improvements are made, justifying its remaining in
force for a longer period (for example, Ziegler catalysis). The details of how the royalty is
calculated and applied, or revised, are expressed in agreements between the parties.
The two ways of paying for R&D work discussed above are not completely independent.
Roughly speaking, they conform to the following empirical rule: a paid-up royalty is equiv-
alent to a ten-year running royalty. Intermediate or combined alternatives are sometimes con-
sidered: these include an initial cash payment, followed by a payment proportional to the
actual production over a particular period, and according to a scale fixed by contract.
economic data are provided to the end user by the inventor or holder of the process, technol-
ogy, etc. This information becomes more and more specific and detailed as the negotiations
proceed. The early information, provided at the outset of discussions, is usually for promo-
tional purposes, intended to attract the manufacturer or its representative and to get through
the pre-selection stage. Accordingly, its nature is sufficiently general that it does not lead to
specific studies, and can be presented free of charge.
For example, the interested party may set conditions of unit production capacity, and pos-
sibly of date and regional location, and request specific information on the following points:
The operating principle of the facilities, supported by a diagram showing the basic phys-
ico-chemical operations involved in the conversion or the processing, the volumes pro-
cessed, and the operating parameters (especially average pressures and temperatures),
The overall material balance sheet(s) for the operation, with specifications for the feed-
stocks and principal products, also in what form they are produced within the battery
limits,
General consumptions of utilities and chemical products, by the hour or by the ton (of
feedstock or product),
0 The quantity (the quality, even) of the labor needed to operate the units, often expressed
tial loads of catalysts, solvents, etc.; sometimes the royalty and startup costs, etc.
These data constitute the typical contents of a document that can take the form of a con-
tract, supplied free of charge, and often called a preliminary proposal. The subsequent stages
are rather different.
Thus in the final step of the discussions, when a choice has been made among the various
bidders, the owner of the process or technology selected must provide the client with suffi-
cient information to enable the engineering company contracted to do the actual construction
of the project to conduct its own calculations and studies. This information, which is far more
specific and detailed than what was originally provided, is brought together in a document
called a detailed proposal, or a Process Data Book. It normally carries a price fixed by con-
tract, to be paid by the manufacturer requesting it, in that its production represents a major
and specific contribution from the owner of the technology. In fact, it should provide:
0 More specific diagrams of the facility and of each of the main pieces of equipment that
comprise the outline being described, with their regular operating parameters, and the
transfer lines between these elements,
Material balance sheets, no longer generalized but line-by-line, allowing the composi-
tions and the kinds of constituents in the intermediate flows to be identified, as well as
their circulation parameters (average pressures and temperatures),
0 Utility requirements for each of the main pieces of equipment that consume them-and
ures for primary and secondary equipment, erection and connection, indirect construction
costs, etc., perhaps even accompanied by a list of the primary equipment broken down by
type of apparatus: reactors, columns, tanks,furnaces, exchangers, compressors, pumps,
etc., and sometimes for the secondary equipment and the two other major headings.
178 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
The owner of the process also creates another document: it too carries a price because it is
used in training the personnel to work on the facilities. This is the “Operating Manual”, which
sets out the equipment startup and shutdown procedures, with special attention to the precau-
tions for avoiding major incidents (explosion, breaks in circulation, etc., premature deterio-
ration of the catalytic or solvent systems, etc.).
The cost of the process data book and the operating manual, which usually go together,
obviously depends on the complexity of the technology concerned and the accounting meth-
ods employed by each company. However, it does not vary with the unit capacity, so as a
rough guide it will fall between 0.2 and 0.5 million € (mid-2000).
COMMENT
Among the owners of technology, it has become more and more common not to sep-
arate the costs of providing the contract documents (process data book and operating
manual) from the royalty cost, and to group them all under the heading of contractor
fees.
In this case, an approximate method for estimating their total cost is to calculate them
as a proportion of the cost of the production units plus general services and storage,
i.e., roughly 5%.
often take the form of a “turnkey” contract that includes an agreement to a specific price,
these supplementary expenses arise from specific negotiations with various parties and
may vary depending on the economic situation or current events.
0 Next, the location of these expenses in the statement depends on the government tax pro-
A. Initial Loads
When the various pieces of equipment are installed, the manufacturing facilities of which
they are a part are not necessarily ready to produce. Some of them, indeed, require that there
be a minimum amount of solid or liquid content inside the vessel: this represents an invest-
ment that must be made ahead of any startup, admittedly at the last minute, but an essential
one. This additional outlay constitutes the initial loads: depending on the particular case, after
a period that is generally shorter than the supposed life of the equipment it will either be used
up and therefore require replacement, or be recovered if the necessary regeneration proce-
dures are performed.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 179
The additions referred to are usually solid catalysts, adsorbents, molecular sieves, desic-
cating agents, etc., solvents, liquid coolants or refrigerants, etc., electrodes, lamps, and other
elements. To some extent, by analogy with the construction industry, they may be said to rep-
resent moveable property, as opposed to real estate.
Since, these initial loads must either be regularly replaced, or periodically reconditioned,
they may be compared to “consumables”. The corresponding expense should therefore
appear under “operations”, i.e., show up in the operating cost or the cost of price. They must
be provided for via the working capital, a temporary investment not subject to depreciation
(see Section 2.3.1.6). This is the procedure applied when the products concerned must be
replaced within a period of time less than or equal to the theoretical renewal period of the
working capital. If this is not the case, the tax regulations usually define it as an outlay that
may be deemed a regular investment.
The problem becomes more complicated when, as a safety precaution, the equivalent of
two initial loads of catalysts, adsorbents etc. are purchased at the outset. One is actually put
into the equipment, the other stored away, to be available for quick replacement in case of a
major operating incident or a sudden loss of activity. In such cases the relevant expenses may
be divided into a portion that is permanent, and thus depreciable, and a remainder that is
renewable, i.e., part of the working capital.
In the same way, it may also sometimes be useful to analyze the costs of the initial loads
in more detail. Thus, when a portion of the investments made for this purpose can be recov-
ered, in one way or another, after a period of time that is significantly shorter than the facili-
ties’ theoretical depreciation period, that sum may be considered to be similar to those spent
on the products in storage, which are treated as working capital. This particularly applies to
catalysts containing precious metals and deposited on a support (see Section 2.2.2.1.A.e). In
fact, at the end of a catalysts life, when the regeneration cycles are so short that it has become
uneconomic to keep repeating them, 99% of the precious metal fraction can be recovered,
while getting rid of the support. To take these economically distinct behaviors into account,
the costs of the metals may be treated as working capital, and only those for the support and
its impregnation as initial load costs. The same approach may also be considered for particu-
lar adsorbents or special, costly solvents that can be regenerated in batches.
The amount of the initial loads is generally determined on the basis of three specific
parameters:
0 Two are size-related:
catalytic cracking, blast fiunaces,rolling mills, power stations, etc.-and especially when grass-
roots sites have to be developed, it can be well in excess of two years, even as much as four.
During this period, which precedes the active production phase, the manufacturer has to
gradually release or borrow a significantportion of the investment, sometimes almost all of it.
The manufacturer must, in fact, successively finance the construction plans, the development
work and civil engineering, order the equipment, pay for it, set it up, assemble it, and so on.
These outlays may be partially or wholly covered either by direct loans obtained from the
appropriate organizations, or by the treasury of the company undertaking the project. As soon
as these capital sums are lent, there is an obligation to pay effective interest on them; when
equity funds are employed, or, generally speaking, when the company treasury acts as a lend-
ing organization, it is also desirable to earn a return on the sums invested by means of a
notional or psychological interest rate that reflects the company’s financial policy and its
management methods. This matter has already been extensively discussed in Section
2.1.2.3.A,which dealt with the concept of present value.
The amount of these effective or notional interests, called construction interests, obviously
depends on the current cost of money. A rough way to assess them consists of first assuming
that the outlays are made in a linear fashion throughout the construction period, and then fol-
lowing the procedure in Section 2.2.4.2.B.The final investment cost, in this case the fixed
capital, serves as a reference amount, on which an average interest rate (i,) is levied, as
defined by the equation:
.
1,
. n+l
= z, -
2n
where n is the assumed duration of construction and i, the effective interest rate applied by
the lending organizations (banks or government agencies).
Thus, if n = 2, and i, = 12%, we obtain im= 9%.
The highly empirical nature of this method of calculation must be emphasized: from a
strictly financial or economic point of view it has no validity.
This construction loan interest item is often ignored in preliminary evaluations. Indeed, the
amount it represents is sometimes smaller than the margin of error of the known or calculated
investments for the production or processing facilities proper.
C. Startup Expenses
The startup of a manufacturing facility is generally performed under the joint technical
responsibility of the representatives of the engineering company, which undertook the
planning and construction work, and of the owner(s) of the license(s) involved. This opera-
tion takes place in the presence of the employees of the operating company who have been
assigned to the regular running of the equipment. The corresponding costs cover two main
aspects: the services performed on this occasion, and the related expenses that they create.
a. Services
The first objective during startup is to get the unit up to operating speed, so as to confirm that
the equipment is capable of doing what it is supposed to, that the products obtained conform
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 181
properly to the required specifications, that the theoretical nominal capacity can be reached
without difficulty, that the performances advertised and guaranteed for the various systems
concerned (catalysts, solvents, adsorbents, electrolytes, etc.) meet the contract conditions,
that the shutdown and startup procedures are effective and agree with the descriptions in the
operating manual, and so on.
At first sight, it may appear surprising that the services provided by the engineering com-
pany and the license holders in carrying out or participating in these acceptance tests, which
are intended to confirm the proper functioning of the facilities, should be paid for by the cli-
ent. In fact, this operation is not only meant to produce an actual warranty certificate, but also
to obtain an idea of the possibilities actually offered, which often go beyond the undertakings.
In the contrary case, it also presents a means for identifying the causes of malfunctions and
of course for correcting them, the corresponding expenses then being charged to one or other
of the parties present, depending on the source of the problems, or shared.
In addition, the second objective may also serve to explain why these startup costs are
charged to the manufacturer. In fact, during the initial operating period there is a genuine
transfer of knowledge to the personnel responsible for managing the units, and this training
is performed as much by the engineering company’s representatives as by those from the
license holders. Moreover, a veritable after-sales service is often established, including peri-
odic visits to the facilities, assistance during certain shutdowns or restarts (for example,
change of catalyst), minor improvements and modifications in the equipment or its operating
parameters, etc.
b. Related Expenses
Although they may be significant, the cost of the above services is on an altogether different
scale from the related costs produced by starting up the facilities. During this period, in fact,
the equipment has to be operated, if only to tune it or make minor adjustments. The products
that emerge from the units are not necessarily up to marketable specifications, or acceptable
to downstream operations. There are consumptions of raw materials, chemicals and other
products, utilities, etc., personnel activities-so many kinds of expenses that are not balanced
by income from the sale of finished products.
The duration of this veritable breaking-in of the equipment, and its takeover by the opera-
tors, depends on how complex the facilities are. It may be relatively short when it concerns a
facility on a pre-existing industrial site, with a well-controlled environment and experienced
crews, and when the technique being applied is simple. In such cases a fortnight is generally
enough. On the other hand, it can extend over several months for more complex installations
(steam cracking and related operations, for example), when it concerns plants on grassroots
sites, or when the personnel have not had suitable training (particularly in industrializing
countries).
The loss of earnings represented by the starting up of these units, from their operation
alone, is substantial. It can be calculated in equivalent months of operating cost, excluding
charges for capital, i.e., in months of operating expenses, as long as this term does cover the
consumption of raw materials, various related products, utilities, and shift labor. In fact, there
are two ways of accounting for it, depending on whether the manufactures obtained during
the startup period are marketable or not.
182 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
0 If they are not, and cannot be sold later, the raw materials that produced them must be
treated as definitively lost. In this case, the startup costs are often taken as being equal
to 15 days of operating costs (cost of materials included).
0 #en the products obtained meet the required specifications, or can after all be sold
when a few matters have been taken care of or some minor adjustments made, these
starting expenses are in practice evaluated at three months of operating costs (cost of
materials excluded).
The purity standard provides a specific example of a situation in which a product, although
it does not immediately meet the required performance levels, is capable of being sold. If the
market requires a level above 99.5% by weight in this regard, and the average value for the
product obtained during startup operations is only 99.2%, it often happens that once the facil-
ities are operating properly they are capable of reaching 99.7% or more. The product that is
unfit for direct use only has to be stored long enough to use it up by gradual mixing with the
batches whose quality is greater than the required minimum.
f
(l+i)P
where i is the discount rate, generally falling between 0 and 1. This shows that the value of
the working capital falls year by year. This explains why government tax provisions permit
periodic re-evaluations, as long as they do not lead to capital gains, which would then be tax-
able.
Working capital essentially constitutes a current allowance that includes the following
main headings:
0 The value of the regular reserve stock of raw materials: loads, various chemical prod-
ucts, homogeneous phase catalysts, solvents, other consumable goods such as elec-
trodes, electrolytes, lamps, etc.,
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 183
0 The value of the fluids and solids in circulation, or present at a given moment, in the pro-
cessing units themselves, in the various stages of conversion,
0 The value of the normal stock of finished products and by-products,
0 The amount of the costs to be incurred by unexpected or other shutdowns of the facili-
ties, to allow for continued product shipments, and receiving and paying for raw mate-
rials, according to the terms of the contracts with suppliers and buyers, and also to pay
the regular equipment operating and maintenance personnel,
0 If necessary, the value of the current stocks of spare parts, wrapping, packaging, etc.,
0 Coverage for the delays experienced between the issuance of invoices and receipt of
payment. These delays result both from the regulatory provisions of each particular gov-
ernment, and from commercial practices that may vary over time, depending on the eco-
nomic situation. Thus, in France, payment of invoices is made 90 days after month end;
however, during the crises of the last twenty years this period has sometimes fallen to
30 days after month end. In the USA payment is generally made within two weeks, leav-
ing aside postal delays.
In practice, the current credit may be evaluated in various ways, the most important items
being those concerning supplies and the reserves of product; a handy method consists of
expressing them as the equivalent of months of operating cost, excluding capital costs, i.e., in
the habitual terminology, as months of operating expenses. Custom dictates that this shall be
roughly equal to double the amount of the startup costs for the facilities. In other words, the
current credit thus corresponds to:
0 Either one month of operating expenses, cost of materials included,
Depending on whether one is inclined to take a conservative view or not, the higher or
lower value is selected.
The working capital also sometimes includes investments for non-consumable goods that
can be compared to a real temporary stock of products (initial loads of precious and semi-pre-
cious metals, adsorbents, etc., and, more generally, certain recoverable pieces of equipment
or spare parts). Examples include platinum, iridium, palladium, cobalt, nickel, mercury, etc.,
and components of catalysts, electrodes, etc., which-allowing for various treatments and
certain losses+an be recovered and re-activated, once the system is shut down. This item,
which may account for a major portion of the working capital, represents a sum that can be
accurately defined on the basis of technical considerations. It thus differs from the current
allowance, whose amount is evaluated on the basis of an estimation of the risks incurred.
The determination of this kind of investment is relatively uncommon, since it demands a good
prior knowledge of the chosen construction location, as well as all the accompanying param-
eters (geographic, geologic, climatic, financial, fiscal, social, etc.).
In fact, to determine the amount it is best to add the two following costs to the total invest-
ment for an industrialized site: land costs, and yard improvements.
Next Page
A. Land Costs
The cost of the land on which the production or processing facilities are to be constructed is
sometimes included among the project investments that a manufacturer has to make.
Although such outlays are far from negligible, they are generally rarely mentioned, espe-
cially when smaller installations are concerned. On the other hand, the matter is sometimes
addressed in the case of significant extensions, or the creation of entirely new complexes on
as yet un-serviced sites. It must be remembered that in most cases, for projects of moderate
size, the land purchase procedure is usually disconnected from the procedures affecting the
manufacturing units proper, since the site acquisition process is not conducted separately for
each unit, but is part of a much larger development program.
Nevertheless,when the question arises, the value of a site is mainly dependent on its particular
interest. Now, the parameters that can be applied to measure this are extremely numerous and var-
ied. Among the most important are not only the required surface area, which is easy to quantify,
but also several other factors that are more difficult to assess, because they are more subjective.
In particular, these include the geographic location (industrial area, open countryside, seashore),
the relief, the existence of port or river shipping facilities,railroad or highway systems,proximity
of urban centers, facilities for obtaining constructionmaterials, energy, drinking and other water,
ecologicalrestrictions,local conditions in terms of housing, socio-culturalenvironment,and edu-
cation, the availability,skills, and attitudes of local labor, etc. and generally speaking the existing
infrastructure-so many elements that may require a specific study of the problem, since in this
regard each project constitutes a special case. Outside factors must also be added to this list: they
can further complicate the situation and may prove decisive. These include local, regional, or
national incentive measures aimed at promoting job creation by means of tax exemptions, and
various development assistance measures, even offers of property. These measures may on the
other hand be deterrents, reflecting environmental,population balance, over-industrialization,or
other concerns: they can make any project that goes against them uneconomic.
Thus, unless we are able to estimate the respective weights of these various factors-
which amounts to knowing in detail all about the transactions in the area-it would seem
impossible to make even an approximate estimate of the land costs.
B. Yard Improvements
Besides the outlays for obtaining access to the physical property, projects on new sites require
specific preparation work that is likely to lead to additional investments, which, moreover,
precede any installation of equipment.
Depending on the characteristics of the site, these include in particular provisions for lev-
eling the surface, possible stabilization of the ground or protection against wind erosion,
access works, connections with highway, railroad, and waterway systems, etc., also for clean-
ing up, fire fighting, environmental protection, etc., and for supplying energy (oil and gas
pipelines, power lines, etc.) and water (water mains, connections to rivers, groundwater, puri-
fication or sea-water desalination stations, etc.).
In some cases, all or part of these infrastructures are missing. If they are required just for
the construction of the project concerned, they must be charged to it, which often leads to the
inclusion of major public works activities (port and highway facilities in particular).
Previous Page
Here again, unless we are well informed about the geographic and structural contexts into
which a new manufacturing complex is to be inserted, it would seem difficult for an outside
observer to estimate the consequences in terms of investment costs. However, there is an
average empirical rule for the servicing of grassroots sites, which says that the amount of the
depreciable capital should be increased by 30%.
COMMENT
We must distinguish between the concept of construction on an as-yet unserviced
site, and that of the “first industrial plant”. The latter is a “prototype” unit, based on
new ideas, as yet untested over an extended period at full scale, and for which the
probability of incidents is higher than for proven technologies. To allow for such
possibilities, which can require improvements, hence additional investments, the
cost of the production or processing facilities proper is often increased by 20 to 30%,
depending on the degree of complexity.
Available information about investments costs generally refers to very specific conditions.
Now, in practice, the questions that have to be answered usually refer to the following two
main situations:
0 Determination of the economic or profitability aspects of a facility that is technically
similar to the “reference” unit, but that operates under different conditions: production
capacity, date, site, possibly the source of raw materials, kind of catalysts, market factor,
yields, operating variables (temperature, pressure, etc.) and more broadly any parameter
likely to require a sensitivity study,
0 Comparison, on the same or “consistent” basis, of several processes or projects that lead
to the same products, but for which the available economic data, called “reference” data,
are mixed, and sometimes of differing credibility.
In such cases, one approach is to embark on complex procedures aimed at repeating all the
calculations for each modification, particularly those concerning the investment costs. A sec-
ond approach, more realistic because it is quicker although less accurate, emphasizes limiting
the number of parameters to be considered, and the use of simplified methods, usually empir-
ical ones. In this regard, three variables turn out to be essential in terms of finding the amount
of the battery limits investments:
0 The unit capacity
0 The date
0 The location.
ical data, according to which the costs of two pieces of equipment-and more generally, of
two facilities-of the same kind but processing different volumes or quantities, are related by
an empirical expression having the following form:
1,and Zfl represent the erected costs of the equipment or units concerned, i.e., the battery
,
limits or comparable investments. Gland C’ are the processing or production capacities cor-
responding to these investments;f i s incorrectly called the scaling “factor”, even though it is
actually an exponent.
The use of such an expression was first advocated for calculating the costs of various kinds
of equipment by “similarity”. For example, Table 2.17 gives an idea of the values generally
recommended forf, according to the kind of equipment concerned: they are obviously only
rough guides, since it will always be possible to run into the exception that will invalidate the
rule. So, it is always worthwhile to confirm, before making any calculations, that the equip-
ment being considered has no special feature that would prevent any comparison with the
family to which, on the face of it, it is supposed to belong.
The use of the equation for the units themselves was considered only later on. But here
again, before applying it, it is desirable first to confirm that there is no difference between the
design of the facility whose investment cost is required, and the reference facility; in other
words that the sequence of equipment is indeed the same in both cases. Figure 2.13 is a graph
on which the y-axis is the logarithm of the ratio of the investment costs, and the x-axis is the
logarithm of the ratio of the production capacities: it has a straight-line segment of slopef
with the following properties:
0 The value off is generally around 0.7. In theory, a production unit composed only of shells,
i.e., tanks, columns, exchangers, tubes, etc., or similar apparatus (Table 2.17), should be
capable of extrapolation at the power of 0.6667. This figure is explained by the fact that the
price of this kind of equipment is proportional to its weight, and that for the same thickness
the price increases with the total surface area (shell and heads), and decreases in inverse pro-
portion to the volume or the flow that this area defines. In other words:
/ -
0.8 0.9
//
/ -
1I5 1 5
Below the range where the factor 0.7 applies, the battery limits investments are actually
found to be higher than those calculated according to the rule. To put it clearly, this means
that to obtain a credible result the value offmust be reduced, for example to 0.55-0.5. As will
be shown in Chapter 3, the explanation comes from the breaking down of the costs of facili-
ties into various categories, which, apart from the amount for the principal equipment itself,
include the amount for secondary equipment, the costs of erection and connection, indirect
construction costs, and contingencies. Now, it appears that when the production capacity is
significantly reduced, the relative weight of these additional categories in the unit limits
investments tends to grow in comparison to that of the apparatus, which forms the basis of
the calculation. By way of illustration, one can easily see that the use of a crane to position a
column on its base generates costs that are not proportional to the size of the shell thus
mounted, but are essentially a function of the period of utilization or rental of the crane, i.e.,
practically independent of the mass hoisted.
When all is said and done, it is just as if a certain portion of the curve in Fig. 2.13 were
likened to a straight-line segment of slopef= 0.7, the real value of the extrapolation factor at
each point of this diagram being represented by the slope of the tangent at that point.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 189
Practical confirmation of the proposed use off values for calculating the battery limits
investments, by overall extrapolation based on the production capacity, is provided by
Table 2.18, which shows type examples from the refining, petrochemical, and inorganic
chemical sectors. These figures are based on mid-sized facilities currently operating in the
heavily industrialized regions (North America, Western Europe, and Japan). The lowest val-
ues correspond to extrapolations for low capacities, and conversely for the highest ones.
Process Exponent
Refining industry
Atmospheric distillation 0.70-0.65
Vacuum distillation 0.70
Hydrodesulfurization
of naphtha 0.65-0.85
of residue 0.80
Catalytic reforming 0.70-0.85
Catalytic cracking 0.70
Steam cracking 0.75
Sulfur unit 0.60
Hydrogen unit 0.60-0.70
Petrochemical Industry
Steam cracking of naphtha 0.75-0.80
Acetic acid (carbonylation of methanol) 0.57-0.52
Methanol (steam reforming of natural gas) 0.75-0.93
Ethylene oxide (oxygen) 0.72-0.77
Phenol 0.58-0.66
Vinyl chloride (from dichlorethane) 0.60-0.70
Polyvinyl chloride (suspension) 0.66-0.68
Linear low-density polyethylene 0.70-0.75
Polypropylene (suspension) 0.66-0.74
Inorganic chemical industry
Nitric acid 0.77-0.85
Phosphoric acid 0.53-0.87
Sulfiuic Acid 0.75-0.80
Ammonia (steam reforming of natural gas) 0.76
Electrolysis (mercury amalgam) of sodium chloride 0.77-0.82
(Source: IFP)
190 2. The Nements of Economic Calculation
A. The Problem
In different ways, this kind of information processing resembles both the deflation procedure
described in Chapter 1 (see Section 2.3.1. l), and the present value procedure discussed in the
present chapter (Section 2.1.2.3.A).
Although, it is incorrectly called “discounting”, investment updating does not consist of
calculating the present value of a sum that is usually paid later on, or sometimes earlier, but
rather of taking into account the variation over time of the prices of materials and the costs of
making or assembling equipment, i.e., both the productivity and the costs of labor (skills,
wage scales, benefits, etc.). This approach incorporates the effects both of currency depreci-
ation and of variations in the real value of the cost of raw materials and of the total wage bill.
Generally speaking, since in practice the observed overall drift is usually positive, the current
cost of a piece of apparatus or a facility will appear higher than the cost of the same system a
few years earlier. Thus, although there are similarities with the concept of present value, they
concern only that part of the idea that deals with historical data and the use of current money
calculations. However, such a definition seems not to apply to the methods referred to as price
revision, which often accompany estimates that the bidder guarantees for a limited period
only; after that the adjustment procedure is applied.
In fact, in this case it is not a matter of using existing data but of anticipating future infor-
mation. For all that, when the method is actually applied, the values to be used will be avail-
able and considered to be “objective”, i.e., observed or real, whereas estimating a discount
rate will always have a subjective aspect, related to the uncertainty of the future.
As for the deflation method, its special feature is that while it too concerns past informa-
tion, it also ignores currency depreciation proper. Its only connection with updating is that it
does consider the variation of the true value of the prices of “products” in the broad sense. In
this way, it expresses either source variations in the real prices of raw materials, which rise
and fall with the evolution of supply and demand, or technological improvements, which,
although their impact is more modest, generate a downward drift.
Thus, when compared with the related concepts discussed earlier, updating has two prac-
tical consequences:
Any informationabout an investment should be accompanied by the correspondingdate.
For a complete facility, this means stating the year and sometimes the quarter to which
the information applies (e.g., 4th quarter 1994 or mid-1990). For a piece of equipment
the month can be given (e.g., October 1985).
To determine the value of an investment at another date, or to make a uniform compar-
ison of two investments having different dates, we need a procedure for transposing the
available information from one year or one month to the other.
To respond to these two requirements, the most convenient solution is to use a coefficient,
incorrectly called a “discount index” or, better, a “cost index”.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 191
By definition, an index is in fact a ratio, and therefore a dimensionless number, which mea-
sures the relative variation of a parameter between two different “states”, in time or space;
one of them may be arbitrarily taken as the reference (value 100) for the calculation. Eco-
nomic indices may concern flows (income, consumption, savings, sales, etc.), quantities
(products, consumables), activities (length of work, wage-earning employees, etc.), prices
(consumer, producer, wholesale, etc., deflated), or wages (hourly, monthly). Combining two
indices sometimes enables a third to be defined: for example, labor productivity from the pro-
duction and activity indices, or purchasing power from the income and price indices.
An index is said to be simple or elementary when it is based on the gross variation of a
single parameter, as compared to a given initial state. Thus, we speak of the elementary index
of the parameter Y, at time t, compared to the reference situation zero, given by:
V
It is obviously not necessary to refer to the zero state, and between two states t l and t2there
is a relation given by the number or coefficient:
i=n
- arithmetic: 410= Ccxi4io
i=l
where
n : number of parameters concerned
410 : elementary index of the parameter Yi at time t in comparison to reference state 0
ai : weight, expressed as a percentage of the parameter Yi.
The formulas most widely used for constructing price and quantity indices are those of
Laspeyres and de Paasche, which are the arithmetic means of simple indices, whose weight-
ing coefficients are proportional to the expenses or sales figures (quantity x price):
192 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
0 Laspeyres index:
i=l i=l
0 De Paasche index:
i=l i=l
where
pP: price of product i at the reference date 0
pf : price of product i at date t
9: : quantity of product i at the reference date 0
9: : quantity of product i at date t.
Note that in the Laspeyres formula the reference structure comes from the base date (a con-
stant year), whereas in de Paasche’s the ratio for the sample concerned refers to the time when
it is made (the current year). This recalls the two approaches already discussed for deflation
and present value.
Instead of considering price variations, we can look at quantities and calculate volume
indices. When attempting to weight quantities by the price in the base year, we calculate a
“Laspeyres volume”:
n
When weighting by the prices for the current year, we calculate a Paasche volume:
n
i=l
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 193
COMMENTS
0 For convenience, Laspeyres-type indices are the ones most frequently used. In
fact, it is easier to refer to a past year than to examine the structure of a sample during
the current year. These can always be criticized for being based on a breakdown and
weighting from the past, which, over time, progressively lose their credibility. This
problem becomes crucial, for example, for a calculation of a retail price index: it does
not make sense to choose the same “shopping basket” in 2000 as in 1985.
0 To compensate for this drawback, one method consists of regularly changing the
standard state, so as to update the reference structure itself. This procedure produces a
succession of indices that cover short periods of time, so that, to get to the required
year, they all have to be multiplied together. This procedure, called the Laspeyres
chain-index, is used, for example, particularly in France, to calculate retail price indi-
ces. As mentioned in Chapter 1 it is also used to calculate the IPI (industrial production
index). It has the advantage of avoiding the progressive aging of the updating method.
0 Price revision formulas, which are found in many contracts, particularly in those
concerning the supply of raw materials or products, shed additional light on index
calculations and the uses to which they can be put. As a rough guide, taking natural
gas as an example, an expression such as the following one may be considered for
the periodic (monthly, quarterly, etc.) re-estimation of the sales price:
where
C
+0.2 -+0.1
CO
-+0.1 -
Go
GOO “1
NO
PandPo : price per m3 of gas, as delivered by the vendor company, on the cal-
culation t and reference 0 dates respectively (0 = date of contract
signature, for example)
FO and FOo : price per ton of fuel oil
CandCo : price per barrel of petroleum
NandNo : price per ton of naphtha,
each of the products considered as meeting precise supply specifications (quality,
delivery date, etc.).
The bracket does indeed represent a Laspeyres-type formula with weighting coeffi-
cients fixed at the outset. However, it is worth noting that these factors are generally
not obtained from calculations of prices and quantities for each of the component
products, but usually represent the result of a statistical study of historical data.
It may also be desirable to measure the variation of the price-quantity pair, and in
this way calculate a global value index (GVI) according to the following formula:
i=n
GVI,,, = i=n
,‘=I 100
194 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
indices, whose variation may or may not also be monitored by the authors of the total
index.
As for manufacturing facilities, the updating of battery limits investments is based on three
types of index, depending on the kind of components it contains:
Those whose constybents depend only o n variations in wage costs and the prices of
materials,
Those based on a weighting of component indices concerning equipment (pressure ves-
sels, exchangers, furnaces, compressors, etc.),
Finally, those that combine the two previous concepts and are therefore described as
“mixed”.
COMMENTS
Whatever type of index is concerned, two major features must be emphasized:
0 The kind of parameters used in the initial formulation, and their respective
weights, usually derive from statistical analysis and processing of available data.
Consequently, on the one hand there may be significant differences between the dis-
tribution represented by the index and that of the facility to which it is applied; so it
is of the highest importance to choose the updating method whose constitution
appears to be the most appropriate. On the other hand, this weighting may vary over
time, leading either to progressive obsolescence for this tool, or to periodic adjust-
ments, with changes in the reference date and development of different time series.
0 An index can always be reduced to two components, one concerning wages, the
other, materials. Obviously, this operation entails a loss of accuracy of several per-
centage points. On the other hand, for a country where information is hard to come
by, it offers the advantage of greatly simplifying the design of a formulation that is
better suited to local conditions. It is easy to achieve for indices of the first type,
because it only requires the grouping together of the parameters concerning wages
and the ones dealing with materials. It would seem to be trickier for indices of the
second type, since, before the grouping can be done, it is necessary to separate the
different equipment components into the part for boilermaking or shaping labor, and
the part for the basic manufacturing materials. For indices of the third type, the pro-
cedure to be applied derives from the two preceding ones.
a. France
The description of each component is summarized below it, in standardized terms. The
values are published regularly, notably in L ’Usine nouvelle.
196 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
A comment must be made after considering these two examples, which belong to the first
type of index. It concerns the weight of the wage parameter, which exceeds 60%. Put another
way, too detailed a breakdown, depending on the kind of reference materials, may be
regarded as irrelevant, considering the precision with which the labor component is assessed.
Many other formulas could be given here, each representing a particular sector of activity
or even specific companies, if the related confidentiality problems could be ignored. When
localization is considered (see Section 2.3.2.3), there will be a more detailed analysis of one
of them, designed by AFITEP, a project management association.
b. USA
A lot of work has been done in this area, and several indices are publicly available, both in
mass-market publications and by subscription to consulting firms (for example SRI, the Stan-
ford Research Institute, which compiles an index called the PEP or Process Economics Pro-
gram index, for various countries). Among the better-known indices the following may be
mentioned
fields. One of them concerns the petroleum sector, another is broadly chemical, others
more specifically cover the rubber, cement, glass, paint, paper, refractory, electrical
equipment, mining, crushing and grinding, refrigeration, and steam generationindustries.
These indices are published twice a month in the journal Chemical Engineering; their ref-
erence year is 1926.
weighted average of the costs of fuel, labor, investments, and chemical products.
The most widely used is the inflation index. It belongs to the third, i.e., mixed, type, and
may be directly compared to various other total updating methods, compiled by various work-
ers, for adjusting battery limits investments by date. As its name indicates, it is intended for
the refining industry; it has three main components:
Various items of equipment (12%)
0 Materials (28%), including ferrous metals (20%) and non-metallic construction materi-
als (8%)
0 Labor (60%), including 39% for specialists and 21% for others.
Their variations in recent years, and the variation of the resulting composite inflation
index, are shown in Table 2.19. The item “equipment (various)” is itself the result of a
weighting of the costs of five particular types of apparatus: pumps and compressors, electrical
equipment (motors, transformers, welding machines, lighting, etc.), non-electric drives,
instruments, and heat exchangers.
The Nelson composite indices, especially the inflation index, are published in the first
issue of The Oil and Gas Journal for each month. A very detailed summary of the partial indi-
ces (Table 2.20) is given in the first issue for the months of January, April, July, and October:
the observed difference between the date of publication and the date the figures refer to is
about six months. These indices concern the costs of utilities, inorganic and organic products,
labor, and equipment and materials; each of them includes a reference, either a code number
from the U.S. Department of Labor’s Bureau of Statistics, or a description of origin such as
“manufacturer’s data” or “calculated”.
Table 2.20 shows examples of the variations of the cost indices for a certain number of
items of equipment that are widely used in the refining and chemical industries. The inflation
and true costs indices (the latter was dropped in 1976), as well as the labor, equipment, and
materials components, have 1946 as their reference date; the others have 1956 as their base
100 year.
198 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
0 Erection (22%)
0 Buildings (7%)
0 Engineering (10%).
The first component is itself composed of the following elements: assembled equipment
(37%), pumps and compressors (7%), other machines (14%), piping, valves, and fittings
(20%), instrumentation and control (7%), electrical equipment (5%), structures, insulation,
and painting (10%).
c. Other Countries
It would seem both difficult and tedious to embark on a bibliographic study of the various
indices published worldwide, especially as, to do justice to their local features, it would be
necessary to revisit some of them. In the present case, the aim is not to add to the list of exam-
ples presented, but rather to analyze the principles of their design, and to show the develop-
ment of the ideas on which they are based.
However, by way of illustration, we should also mention some additional examples:
0 For the United Kingdom, the index published each month in the journal Process Engineer-
ing. The purpose of mentioning this publication is not so much to show the approach
employed, as to draw attention to its evolution over time. Thus, originally, the journal, which
until 1972 was called Chemical and Process Engineering, presented the “plant construction
cost index”, calculated by using the following expression:
0.075N. (Io)*
P = 0.46M + 0.09E + 0.18C+
V
in which
M , E, and C are the price indices for equipment and energy employed by the mechanical
engineering, electrical engineering, and construction industries
I0 is the average wage index for the construction industry
V represents the investment costs of the food processing, tobacco, refining, chemical,
paint, and ink industries
N is the number of employees in the construction industry.
This information is available from these official British organizations: the Department of
Trade and Industry, and the Department of Employment and Productivity. First established
with a base of 100 in 1965, it was modified and adjusted to a new base 100 in 1970. This same
publication also publishes a “productivity” index (Productivity index, manufacturing). In
January 1973, the journal’s change of name was accompanied by the appearance of a new
index: the PE (Process Engineering) index, based on the following expression:
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 20 1
in which
ZM represents the index for the mechanical engineering sector
ZE the index for electrical engineering
Zc for civil engineering
Is describes yard improvement engineering
lo refers to general services engineering.
For Germany, the monthly publication by Messrs. Von Kolbel and Schulze, in Chemische
Zndustrie, of a cost index specifically for chemical facilities. It is of the second type, and is
based on the following average distribution of investments for assembled units: static equip-
ment (26.7%), rotating machinery (13.3%), piping (16%), metal structures (5%), electrical
equipment (7%), instrumentation (7%), industrial buildings (12%), and indirect site costs
(13%). The values for these components can be found in documents published by the Statis-
chen Bundesamtes zur Verfugung, for a base of 100 in 1962.
0 For the Netherlands, the compilation by WEBCI (Werkgroep Begrotingsproblemen in der
Chemische Industrie) of a weighted cost index, as follows:
0 Reference year: 1966
instrumentation (8%), civil engineering and metal structures (6%), erection (including
thermal insulation and painting), engineering, and overheads (42%)
0 Components: figures published by the Centraal Bureau Voor de Statistick.
ponents to which any updating procedure can be reduced, the one concerning labor tends to
rise more strongly than the one for materials. In the latter the prominence of plateaus and even
occasional drops should also be noted. However, it has to be remembered that the two ele-
ments do not have the same weight, since roughly speaking, and whatever the index con-
cerned, as long as it refers to industrial facilities the ratio of the labor to the materials item is
around 60140.
0 The second, shown in Figs. 2.15a, 2.15b, and Fig. 2.15c, is more difficult to bring out. It
assumes, in fact, that there has first been a certain normalization of values, in particular a
change in the reference year for the indices being compared. In addition, a comparison of this
nature has no significance unless it is restricted to updating formulas that relate to facilities
that are fairly similar in terms of their equipment.
202 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Four indices were selected for this study, which, in view of the availability of information
and especially its variety, concerned the United States:
Chemical Engineering Plant Cost Index
PEP Cost Index from the Stanford Research Institute (SRI)
Marshall & Swft Index
Nelson Refinery Construction Cost Index.
If we compare the variation over time of these indices, reduced to the same base year 1958,
we see that they all rise after that time, but at different rates (Fig. 2.15a). The Nelson index
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 203
shows the largest gains (averaging 5.3% per year over the whole period), versus 4.9% for the
SRI’s PEP, 4.2% for the Marshall & Swift, and 3.7% for the Chemical Engineering index.
Figure 2.15b, which shows the annual percentage variations, confirms this visual impression
of differentiated rates, but on the other hand it brings out an overall similarity in the trends:
moderate variations until the early 1970%a good ten years of stronger growth, return to a
more stable situation at the end. Table 2.21 provides the figures for these three periods. Also,
on Fig. 2.15b, note the very strong changes that followed the petroleum crises of 1973 and
1980, as well as the almost negligible variation during the counter-crisis of 1986.
Although it is somewhat reassuring to find a basic consistency among the observed varia-
tions, nevertheless a little explanation is required in order to interpret, or even to justify, the
different amplitudes reflected by the curves.
Figure 2.15a Comparative variation of cost indices in the USA (base 100
in 1958). (Sources: The Oil and Gas 1,Chem. Eng., Slu)
204 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
1970-1982 1982-2000
To do this, it would appear necessary to take a closer look, particularly at the composition of
the synthetic indices concerned, and the actual definitionsof their components. For example, the
breakdown given by SFU for the PEP cost index is very similar to the one used by Chemical Engi-
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 205
neering. But although all the components of the first index include labor contributions at about
the same levels as the second one (the CE cost index), the accompanying description states that
the contributionsare adjusted “for constant productivity”. In other words, SRI compiles its index
as if there were no productivity gains over time, whereas Chemical Engineering corrects the
labor percentage by a “work improvement” factor, set at 2.5%per year up to 1982, and reduced
to 1.75%thereafter. In these circumstances, in order to check the consistency of the two indices
it seems appropriate to use this information to calculate a corrected CE cost index, as follows:
1958 :i=O
1959-1981 : 1 I i I 2 3
CE,,,,’ = 0.433 x CE, x (1.025)’+ 0.567 x CEi
1982-1994 : 24 I i I 3 6
CE,,,,= 0.436 x CE, x (1.025)23x (1.0175)’-23+ 0.564 x CEi
> 1995 : extension of the preceding expression.
The coefficients 0.433 and 0.436 represent the labor contributions used by the authors.
Figure 2.1% shows that when this correction is made, the new variation curves for the CE
and PEP cost indices are very similar. Although an even more detailed analysis would no
doubt be required before such an investigation could be considered rigorous, the result
obtained nevertheless tends to prove that the two approaches are consistent.
The problem is a little different with the Marshall & Swift index. In fact, regardless of the
productivity gain aspect, it must be noted that a smaller figure is used for the labor contribution.
This is explained by the fact that the M&S cost index is concerned with the installed costs of
equipment, not with complete production units. For this reason, it only considers the costs of
installation on an already improved site. Using the same approach as before, the variations of
the Marshall & Swift index can be brought into line with those of the corrected CE cost index,
but using weight factors of 0.15 and 0.85 respectively, since the labor share in the overall M&S
formulation is only 15%. In spite of a noticeable (but never greater than 10%)difference for the
period 1980- 1985,we once again observe a strong similarity between the representative curves.
Finally, the Nelson curve shows similar variations to those of the PEP, but with a stronger
average growth. This is mostly explained by the more rapid rise in construction labor costs in
the refining than in the chemical and, more generally, in other sectors of activity. For exam-
ple, from 1972 to 1992 they went up by a factor of roughly 3, whereas in the chemical sector
the ratio was closer to 2.5. This is no doubt due to the fact that, in comparison with other
industries, refining has two specific differences: it involves large unit capacities, and pro-
cesses products that are regarded as dangerous and that are often under pressure. Conse-
quently it was very quickly obliged to move to units that operate continuously, to adopt very
strict safety standards (minimum thicknesses for pressure vessels, a high level of automation,
centralization of information and control, special equipment, etc.), to employ more skilled
and thus better-paid personnel, to supervise operations more closely, etc. Looking at the size
of the “wage” component in the composition of the total index (>60%), it is easy to see why,
in this respect, refining has opened up a significant gap between itself and the other industrial
sectors, and maintained it over time. Nevertheless, if we wish to judge the consistency of the
Nelson index against the other indices, there is no reason why its figures should not be cor-
rected for productivity gains, which were not considered in its design.
206 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
-c-
Q-
Chemical Engineering
Nelson
-+- Chemical Engineering
(corrected)
I
Figure 2.15~Comparative variations of the Chemical Engineering and
PEP indices (base 100 in 1958). (Source: Chem. Eng., SRI,)
A. Background
It is often necessary to compare the costs of facilities constructed in different countries or on
different sites. The matter sometimes takes the form of a question, as follows: what is the cost
of an industrial unit under the local conditions prevailing in another geographical region,
given that we know all the costs of a “reference” unit that is identical in every way-design,
technology, and size-at a known location?
Experience shows, in fact, that just applying the currency exchange rate for a given date,
when two different countries are involved, leads to incorrect results: the difference from the
true figure may reach or even exceed 25%, depending on the period concerned. Although they
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 207
are smaller, disparities often also appear in comparisons within the same country, especially
when it is a large one or the development and operating conditions are very different. This
phenomenon has many explanations, not only technical but economic, social, political, and
financial: variations in the costs of labor, supervision, materials, etc., norms and standards
peculiar to each region (equipment characteristics, construction and safety regulations, etc.),
calculation methods that may differ from one engineering company to another, tax codes, reg-
ulatory restrictions, assistance, various incentives, etc., existing infrastructure, availability
and quality of labor, local customs, and so on.
But when put this way, the question implicitly assumes that the comparison concerns
extreme situations, in which all of the actions required to complete the project, from its design
phase up to the construction of the facilities, are entirely performed on one site or the other,
and under the corresponding conditions. Now, the localization effect can take much more
subtle and complicated forms, for example if we consider the successive locations in which
the preliminary studies, the production of the various pieces of primary and secondary equip-
ment, and the erection of the manufacturing unit proper take place. In heavily industrialized
countries the equipment is often manufactured in the same place where it is assembled, and
the same applies to its design and application; at the very least, even if this is not the case,
these activities occur in areas where industrial practices are much the same. Moreover, so as
to avoid possible disputes and especially to provide reference points, they refer to a type
installation that is readily identifiable.
In industrializing regions, it is necessary to distinguish between these different stages in
the construction of a manufacturing complex. In fact, equipment made of high alloy steel or
employing a special technology is usually imported; similarly, the specialized personnel
required to erect and start it up are brought in. In this case, it is necessary to allow for the addi-
tional costs involved in transporting the equipment and waiting for its delivery, as well as for
the use of skilled foreign labor. Conversely, local conditions may favor the use of worksite
personnel at very attractive rates of pay.
B. First A ffempfs
The development of a relatively systematic approach occurred only recently. Until then, most
authors were content simply to acknowledge the situation, and, at best, when they had enough
information, to make a limited statistical analysis. However, companies have proved to be
very helpful, since their work has allowed a progressive development of more rational meth-
ods of correlation, having a certain predictive character.
At first, information on local disparities was confidential, with each company using its
own figures, even its own approach, in this regard. Without trying to compile a complete his-
tory, some stages in making this kind of information available for general use nevertheless
deserve to be mentioned.
Thus, in 1963, W.L. Nelson connected the ratio of costs for facilities constructed overseas
and in the United States to the wages paid in the same countries. He showed that where there
was cheap local labor (South America, Southeast Asia, Middle-East, etc.) there were gener-
ally, at that time, high construction costs. Exceptions included Japan and Belgium, with free-
enterprise systems and highly skilled but poorly paid personnel, and Sweden and Spain, with
many state companies and wages that were high in one case, low in the other.
208 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
In 1969, R.J. Johnson (using the Gulf Coast as a base) published comparative costs for
pieces of equipment and complete units in the principal industrialized countries (Tables 2.22
and 2.23).
Table 2.22 Relative costs of process equipment in 1969 (from R.J. Johnson)
United Germany
USA Vetherlands Belgium France Italy Japan
Kingdom (FRG)
Furnaces 1.oo 0.95 0.90 0.90 0.90 1.00 1.00 0.90
Tanks 1.oo 1.oo 1.10 1.oo 0.98 0.95 0.85 0.80
Exchangers 1.oo 1.10 1.oo 1.oo 0.90 1.10 0.85 1.15
MPS 1.oo 0.90 0.90 0.85 0.85 0.82 0.80 0.80
Compressors 1.oo 0.85 0.85 0.85 0.75 0.80 0.80 1.00
Piping 1.oo 0.91 1.oo 0.95 0.91 0.88 0.87 0.90
Structures 1.oo 0.90 0.95 0.95 0.90 0.90 0.85 0.85
Instruments 1.oo 1.05 1.05 1.05 1.10 1.05 1.00 1.00
Insulation 1.oo 0.95 1.oo 1.oo 0.90 0.90 0.90 0.95
Electricity 1.oo 0.95 0.95 0.93 0.93 0.90 0.88 0.85
Average 1.00 0.96 0.97 0.96 0.91 0.92 0.89 0.91
(Source: Chem. Eng.)
Table 2.23 Relative costs of process units in 1969 (from R.J. Johnson)
Equipment
Land
Engineering
USA
1.oo
1.OO
United
(Gulf Coast) Kingdom
1.oo 0.96
0.95
0.75
0.91
--l-rl
l 0.97
0.95
0.80
0.92
Wi-
Jetherlands Belgium
0.96
0.95
0.90
0.91
0.90
0.80
0.92
0.90
0.90
1 1 1
France Italy Japan
0.89
0.85
0.80
0.80
The relative figures given for the erected units (battery limits investments) indicated lower
costs than those used in Nelson’s correlation. These differences arise as much from the lack
of precision in the methods applied and the statistical information available, as from changes
in the situations analyzed between 1963 and 1969.
In 1973, J. Cran presented the first principles of a method for comparing costs from var-
ious industrialized countries, taking the United Kingdom as reference. For a certain number
of refining and, especially, petrochemical facilities, with identical production capacities and
for which he had the same kinds of data, he used distribution curves to determine the repre-
sentative average costs, and then the corresponding localization coefficients. These resulted
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 209
in overall coefficients for each country. For example, for the United States he obtained a ratio
of 1.2 to 1.3 versus the United Kingdom, for April 1973. This analysis led to a dynamic
approach, whose main elements are presented in Section 2.3.2.3.C.
Also at this same time, P. Terris suggested order of magnitude scales for the breakdown
of erected costs (Table 2.24), which enabled investments made in France in 1973 to be com-
pared with those made in industrializing regions. For this purpose, he distinguished three cat-
egories of country, according to their level of development, particularly their ability to
undertake civil engineering and erection works.
I France
Principal equipment 38 42 40 42
Secondary equipment 19 21 20 21
Erection (including supervision) 26 31 44 54
Civil engineering 17 18 19 30
(including supervision)
Total 100 112 123 1
I
147
say, 110 to 115 say, 120 to 125 say, 140 to 150
(Source:AFTP)
area, where the foreign contribution consists of providing supervisory and training per-
sonnel (type l),
0 Countries where the local labor has good experience in civil engineering and public
works, and uses modern equipment for this purpose (type 2),
0 Finally, countries where the labor is unskilled, and where civil engineering and erection
Table 2.26 Effect of location on the cost of refining units during 1971-1972 (from W.L. Nelson)
Among recent publications providing specific accounts of location problems, the work of
C.A. Miller and A.V. Bridgewater must also be mentioned.
The first suggests an actual calculation procedure in the form of a matrix with four columns
for the most important parameters, permitting an assessment of the effect of the site (direct
and indirect labor costs, direct cost of materials, engineering and management expenses). The
rows give the “reference” (Gulf Coast) values generally accepted for these items, and then the
values of the assumed corrective coefficients, depending on the local conditions, productivity
and material costs, travel and subsistence expenses, accommodation, overtime, etc.
The second publication, from 1979, provides the relative costs for the USA and the United
Kingdom of chemical facilities with the same functions, making it clear that they are only
orders of magnitude, and that in the same country it is possible to find major fluctuations with
respect to these average values (Table 2.27).
Table 2.27 Location factors for similar chemical facilities (from A.V Bridgewater)
Values Values
Location United Location United
USA
Kingdom Kingdom
Australia 1.40 1.20 1.10
Austria 1.10 1.oo Netherlands 1.10 1.oo
Belgium 1.10 1.oo New Zealand 1.40 1.30
Canada 1.25 1.15 North Africa ( ) 1.20 1.10
China(‘) 1.20 1.10 (2) 0.80 0.75
(2) 0.60 0.55 Norway 1.20 1.10
Central America 1.10 1.oo Portugal 0.80 0.75
Denmark 1.10 1.oo South Africa 1.25 1.15
Finland 1.30 1.20 South America (N.) 1S O 1.35
France 1.05 0.95 ~ South America (S.) 2.50 2.25
Germany 1.10 1.oo Spain 0.80 0.75
Greece 1.oo 0.90 Sweden 1.20 1.10
India (l) 2.00 1.80 ~ Switzerland 1.20 1.10
(2) 0.70 0.65 Turkey 1.10 1.oo
Ireland 0.90 0.80 United Kingdom 1.oo 0.90
Italy 1.oo 0.90 1.10 1.oo
Japan 1.oo 0.90 1.oo 0.90
Malaysia 0.90 0.80
I) Imported equipment.
!) Locally-made equipment.
(Source: Process Economics International)
countries and bring out their specific features, especially in terms of wages and materials.
Whether they had many components or only two, these indices offer the great attraction of
taking into account two of the principal parameters that explain the observed disparities
between one geographic region and another, and especially of presenting formulations of a
universal nature, at least in most cases. On the other hand, they have the drawback of covering
only a limited number of countries, most of them having a level of industrialization or devel-
opment sufficient to allow access to the local values of the selected components. They have
also all adopted a common reference date, for which, whatever site is concerned, the index
arbitrarily takes the value 100. In this respect, the approach has not been carried quite far
enough in terms of location factor and currency exchange as to enable an easy conversion
from one country to another.
In this regard, J. Cran must first be mentioned: beginning in 1976 and throughout the life
of the journal Engineering and Process Economics, i.e., until 1991, he regularly published a
two-component index, the EPE index, which could be calculated for various industrial coun-
tries and thereby show their relative variations with respect to a given date, on which, what-
ever the site, it had the same value: 100 in 1970 (Fig. 2.16).
This approach can certainly be grouped with the publication, in 1979, of the PEI Plant Cost
Index, in the first issue of the journal Process Economics International, published by
D.H. Allen and A.V. Bridgewater. With a value of 100 for the first quarter of 1975, it has
the advantage of covering a greater number of countries than Cran’s index, with varying lev-
els of industrialization, situated not only in Western but also in Eastern Europe, North and
South America, Africa, the Middle East, the Pacific, and Southeast Asia.
In the same vein, the changes progressively made in the PE Index, published by the journal
Process Engineering, must also be noted (see Section 2.3.2.2.D.c). The reference year has
been changed on various occasions; in addition, this index was also calculated from 1983
onwards for other countries besides the United Kingdom, in particular Australia, Canada,
Japan, South Africa, and the USA. A final change took place in September 1991, with the
adoption of a base 100 for 1990, and an extension of the approach to the United Kingdom’s
principal trading partners: Australia, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the
Netherlands, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, and the USA. In addition, the name was changed
to the “PREDICT” (Process Engineering Data and Information Cost/Time) Indices. The for-
mula remains the same for the United Kingdom, the components being drawn from the pub-
lications of H.M. Government’s Central Statistical Office. For the other countries, the indices
are reduced to two constituents, whose values are obtained from international publications,
or those of organizations such as the OECD; the calculation is effected monthly in the first
case, quarterly in the second.
It is always dangerous to make a claim to completeness when one is attempting to recon-
cile the chronology of the methods proposed and the successive advances to which they con-
tributed. Accordingly, we hope that the authors or publications that have not been mentioned
here will not be offended by the omission. Similarly, we trust that they will also not be upset
if the emphasis here is placed on two particular methods, one developed by N. Boyd, the other
by the IFP.
In both cases, the approach to location consists of first setting up a composite index, which
allows the relative variations for different countries to be tracked. Generally speaking, with
such methods the main problem lies in the choice of components, which have to be relatively
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 213
500
450
400
350
- 300
250
200
150
100
1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982
accessible for the largest possible number of different sites, while maintaining a certain level
of accuracy. This is why, when all is said and done, it is easiest to assign priority to indices
with two constituents: wages and materials.
D. N. Boyd’s Indices
The first merit of Boyd’s approach is that it provides a certain consistency with the observed
facts, beginning with the development of his updating formula, whose results were published
regularly in the journal Engineering Costs and Production Economics until a few years ago.
This periodical unfortunately ceased publication in 199 1.
214 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
In practice, while there are many parameters capable of explaining the differences in costs
from one site to another, and thereby providing a location factor that can be applied for a
given date at the current exchange rate, some appear to be more relevant than others, and par-
ticularly these three:
0 Productivity, i.e., the number of hours required to complete the same work,
0 The costs of benefits, which vary from one country to another, producing wages and
- 3Y0cement
- 3% steel bars
- 1% steel structures,
63% of mechanical and electrical materials and equipment (including engineering and
purchasing), divided into:
- 1% steel structures
- 22% sheet steel
- 30% industrial labor,
0 30% of site assembly costs (construction labor).
In a second step, Boyd displayed his originality by bringing together both the above break-
down and the three main explanatory measures from the location factor, in one and the same
formula, namely:
7 1
C = 10 4 + p2 + 3 p3 + 6 4 + 3 0 0 4 -
l+F
+ 230 L2 F
L.
where
P I: cost of a ton of Portland cement
P2:cost of a ton of steel rods
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 215
Australia
1976
0.89
1977
0.94
1978
0.85
1979
0.87
1980
0.84
1981
0.90
1982
0.89
7-
1983
0.86
1984
0.80
1985
0.76
1986 1987
0.67 0.68
1987
on July 1st
0.78
1988
0.77
1988
on July 1st
0.79
Belgium 1.oo 1.01 1.10 1.18 1.36 1.21 0.92 0.81 0.72 0.60 0.68 0.92 1.03 1.oo 1.05
Canada 0.95 1.05 0.98 0.87 0.90 0.90 0.92 0.92 0.86 0.81 0.76 0.80 0.85 0.84 0.89
Denmark 1.01 0.98 0.98 1.10 1.13 1.05 0.80 0.76 0.72 0.62 0.71 0.98 1.15 1.12 1.23
France 0.93 0.89 0.87 0.96 1.02 1.04 0.82 0.75 0.68 0.58 0.67 0.90 0.99 0.98 1.02
Germany 0.98 0.99 1.02 1.12 1.20 1.13 0.88 0.85 0.76 0.64 0.73 1.01 1.12 1.09 1.18
Italy 0.88 0.81 0.82 0.91 1.01 1.01 0.78 0.79 0.74 0.65 0.72 1.00 1.11 1.07 1.14
Japan 0.55 0.59 0.65 0.82 0.79 0.77 0.73 0.60 0.62 0.58 0.65 0.94 0.96 0.99 1.11
Netherlands 1.05 1.05 1.12 1.13 1.18 1.12 0.82 0.82 0.73 0.61 0.69 0.96 1.06 1.04 1.10
Norway 1.16 1.28 1.25 1.29 0.31 1.32 1.07 1.00 0.92 0.82 0.89 1.15 1.28 1.37 1.45
Sweden 1.18 1.24 1.13 1.19 1.26 1.29 0.99 0.90 0.76 0.70 0.79 1.03 1.14 1.16 1.26
United Kingdon 0.81 0.70 0.72 0.80 0.94 1.08 0.86 0.79 0.68 0.59 0.70 0.81R 0.90 0.92 1.03
USA 1.oo 1.00 1.00 I .oo 1.00 1.00 1.oo 1.00 1.00 1.oo 1.00 1.00 1.oo 1.oo 1.oo
-
(Source :Engineering Costs and Production Economics)
218 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
In fact, and this is Boyd’s third original idea, the author suggested that instead of working
with such a monetary ratio, one should take an approximate 60/40 weighting of this ratio’s
values, three months and six months before the date concerned. Indeed, in order to deliver a
piece of equipment in operating condition on January 1st of any year, the required materials
have to be ordered, and their prices agreed to, on about the previous July 1st, and, considering
the time needed for their delivery, the manufacturing crews must be put to work on October
1st, which sets the manufacturing costs. Given, as we saw for example with the Nelson index,
that in a two-component system the weight of labor is of the order of 60%, while materials
are around 40%, we can better appreciate the value of Boyd’s practical rule. This also
explains why each location factor that is published on a given date is accompanied by a cal-
culated exchange rate that is different from the published one for the same date. Actually, the
weighting selected may vary over time; moreover, it is not exactly the one stated, which was
chosen in order to simplify the presentation.
This concept was originally based on the simple observation that applying the published
exchange rate between a given currency and the dollar at a given moment did not provide a
realistic evaluation of the investment costs for the same type of facility in the two countries
concerned. To express this fact, we need to introduce a theoretical exchange rate that, by def-
inition, is given by the following expression:
Investment in country X
Technical parity in the yearn -
-
in year n, in local currency
between and currency and the US$ Corresponding investment in the USA
in year n, in US$
This equation applies to two exactly similar units, but in one case the planning, the mate-
rials, the manufacturing and site labor, etc. are assumed to be done or produced only in coun-
try X , and in the other situation these same services are supposed to come entirely from North
American raw materials and personnel.
It can be expressed in another way by noting that, if we want to use the current exchange
rate to find the investment in year n in country X , when we know the investment for the cor-
responding facility in the USA, we must correct the rate by means of a coefficient which is
actually the location factor for the year concerned, i.e.:
Investment investment Monetary parity Location
incountryX -
-
intheUSA currency XIUS$ factor
in year n , in year n, in US$ in year n in year n
in local currency
In other words, if we combine the two expressions, we obtain the general rule:
Technical parity -
- Monetary parity Location factor
X
in year n in year n in year n
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 219
0 Determination of the technical parity between these countries in the reference year
As before, the problem comes down to first establishing a composite updating index. The
proposal that was made for France by IFP in 1984 is given in the following formulation:
6 t of sheet steel
0 375 hours of industrial labor (300/0.8)
The difficulty that then arises is in applying this type of expression to other countries, par-
ticularly ones in geographic regions that are industrializing, where the required statistical
information is not always available. Bearing in mind Cran’s work, which tends to show that
a proper choice of the weighting between labor and basic materials can give a good idea of
the variation of a multi-component index, it appeared worthwhile to construct a two-compo-
nent index, called “BIEVAL”, which, for France, has the following form:
TM,
Sime + 0.33 -
I = 0.67 -
308.2 292.2
which thus includes 67% labor and 33% materials (steel).
COMMENT
0 By way of comparison, the index published by PEI (base 100: 1st quarter of 1980),
is given by the expression: I = 0.70s + 0.30M, where S = earnings in manufacturing,
and M = basic steel, obtained from the U ” s Monthly Statistical Bulletin.
0 Figure 2.17 displays the variation in monthly values of EVAL and BIEVAL, for
France since 1975. Generally speaking, we can see that over the whole period the
variations in the ratio between these two indices at the same moment very rarely
exceed 4% above and 2% below. The drift begins in 1983 and grows mainly until
1989; afterwards it stabilizes. To reduce the disparity and bring it down to less than
=k2.5%on average for the last fifteen years, while keeping the same components, the
weighting has to be changed, and brought back, in the case of BIEVAL, to a compo-
sition close to the following: 60% wages, 40% materials. Nevertheless, when all is
said and done this kind of analysis lends support to the idea that a two-component
index should be preferred only when getting hold of information sources proves to
be a problem. For all that, periodic readjustments of the original formulation are
found to be necessary if good consistency is to be maintained, in particular whenever
the period concerned exceeds ten years.
The second step is to determine the technical parity, on a particular date. If we take the case
of France vis-a-vis the United States as an example, the problem is the following, namely, to
determine the equivalent for France in July 1987 of US$1 000 in January 1984. With the tools
available at the current stage of the procedure, there are two possible routes for doing this
(Fig. 2.18):
The first consists of taking the exchange rate for January 1984,7.773 FF/US$, to go from
the USA to France, and then to apply the selected values of the updating index, namely 273
and 3 17, to obtain the equivalent of the original US$lOOO in France in July 1987, namely
9026 FF.
0 The second performs the updating right away, remaining in the USA from January 1984
until July 1987, using the corresponding values of the selected updating index, namely, in the
present case, 209 and 212, and then in July 1987 to go from the USA to France by applying
the average exchange rate for that date, namely 6.3 1 1 . The equivalent of the initial US$l 000
then comes to 6400 FF.
.
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 22 1
250 -
200.-
150.-
100.-
50
75
-
jan. jan.
n
jan.
79
jan.
81
jan.
83
jan.
85
jan.
a7
Ian.
89
jan.
91
jan.
93
jan.
95
jan.
97
jan.
99
jan.
01
Figure 2.1 7 Variation of the EVAL and BIEVAL cost indices (France,
base 100 on 1/1/1975). (Source: IFP)
Investments Investments
in the USA in France
x 7.773
January 1984 US$1000 b 7773 FF
x (212/209) x (317/273)
J. x 6.311
9026FF ?
July 1987 US$1014 b 6400FF
If we accept the figures adopted for the indices as realistic, the disparity of the results
obtained can come only from the exchange rates that were applied-which means that we
have to change them, so that the two possible routes are made to converge on final values that
222 2. The Elements of Economic Calculation
are sufficiently close to one another (Fig. 2.19). The values thus obtained represent the
desired technical parities. In fact, the operation come down to defining a relationship between
the two technical parities x and y at two different dates, which, in the example concerned, is:
x -317
- 209
-- X-
y 273 212
Investments Investments
in the USA in France
x 5.28
January 1984 US$1000 b 5280FF
July 1987
x (212/209)
$.
US$1014
x 6.04
b
Ix (3171273)
6131 FF
6125FF
2
As shown in Section 2.3 of the previous chapter, the battery limits investment is unquestion-
ably the one basic piece of information upon which all economic calculations are based. To
some extent, the same can be said of the complementary investments for general services and
storage facilities, the production of utilities being usually regarded as an independent matter.
The fundamental question that then arises is how to determine this cost.
Now, experience shows that in project development and management, economic and even
financial concerns have a tendency to show up at an increasingly early date, as a result of a nat-
ural and very creditable desire to avoid budgetary setbacks and slippages. It is therefore essential
to have a mechanism for finding this cost, as well as specialists capable of applying it correctly.
3.1.1 BACKGROUND
The main problem, which is readily apparent, lies in the methods for applying this kind of
procedure, which can only function if the calculations have something to work on, i.e., data.
Obviously, depending on how advanced the project is, the information itself may be more or
less available and reliable. In these circumstances, the method chosen must first of all be flex-
ible, and designed to accommodate both the accessibility and accuracy levels of the reference
data, and the time allowed for a response. We must avoid compromising the result by reduc-
ing its accuracy still further, while at the same time not resorting to a system that demands
too much in terms of procedures, time, and personnel.
All this suggests that it may be difficult to create a method applicable to all cases: instead
we are likely to find a whole array of procedures. In addition, when it comes to deciding
which one should be utilized and how well it fits the problems to be faced, it would seem that
only a qualified person with some prior experience in the matter could provide a satisfactory
answer. This, then, is a genuine profession, and depending on the circumstances it may take
on various aspects, generally being referred to as that of estimator, sometimes evaluator, and
224 3. The Determination of Battery Limits investments
found both in engineering companies and in consulting firms, or the relevant departments of
the major manufacturers, R&D centers, etc.
In practice, the profession operates at the interface between the technical aspects of a
project and company management, between engineers and technical experts on the one hand,
and accountants and financiers on the other. Its role is to express in cost terms the operating
principles and the process data, such as-depending on the level of sophistication of these
elements-the operating conditions, the results, the material and thermal balances, the flow
diagram, the size of the apparatus, and so on. In this regard, it is important to emphasize the
essential feature of estimation, which is that it works in an a priori manner, i.e., with facilities
or construction projects that are notional, because they lie in the future. In the same way, two
main and quite different types of situation are often identified, on the basis of the kind of ini-
tial technical or even economic information they involve:
0 The first type relates to “research” projects: they rely on preliminary or confirmed exper-
imental results from laboratory or pilot and prototype development work, or from more frag-
mentary information coming from publications, patents, etc., that may furnish an idea for
research. To make use of these data it is necessary to resort to calculation methods that are
comparable to the sizing and costing procedures used by engineering companies, but which
differ from them both in the low level of reliability and detail of the available information,
and in the very short response times allowed. This situation usually corresponds to what are
referred to as preliminary or pre-project studies, and requires estimating methods that are rel-
atively rudimentary and which are grouped together under the heading of evaluation-but
this is far from being a general rule.
0 The second type concerns projects that can be described as “industrial”, based on operating
conditions of production or processing plants that are either similar to ones already in opera-
tion, or that arise from advanced studies in pilot or demonstrationplants, which express actual
behavior and provide a basis for the engineering studies that are essential for full-scale con-
struction. Such studies are applied both for the construction of a new factory and for modify-
ing an existing installation, and must thus meet specific technical and economic requirements
for the manufacture of products whose quality and price correspond to market demands; con-
sequently, their application demands very sophisticated sizing procedures and the use of ser-
vice providers as consultants for costing. The time needed to complete such work is obviously
much longer than that required for analyzing research projects. This approach is what is gen-
erally meant when the term estimation is used.
For all that, although these two situations may appear to be very different, they belong to
the same class. They are no more than the expression of two particular steps in the life of a
single project, when it is followed from its first beginnings to its concrete expression at the
industrial stage, as we shall see by examining the full sequence of events.
Whatever its size, its degree of complexity, its location, or its purpose, the completion of a
project almost always involves utilizing the same approach. This means undertaking studies,
3. The Determination of Battery Limits lnvestments 225
2. The Elements of Economic Calculation 165
purchases, and transport, then the actual construction and startup of the units. All these oper-
The investment cost for the facilities proper (unit investments), comprising:
ations are inter-related, and demand a proper scheduling over time, not just to enable each one
- The battery limits investments (on-site or on-plot investments)
of them to be performed in a technically and economically optimum manner, or to facilitate
- General services and storage (off sites or off plot),
the involvements of the various actors concerned, but also to give the decision-makers an
Fixed capital, comprising:
opportunity-at each critical step in the project-to halt it or to carry on, or to undertake cer-
- Investments related to the units
tain checks or make certain changes.
- Consulting and engineering fees
With this in mind, the timetable of activities that the client must initiate, manage, and mon-
- Supply of spare parts
itor in order to ensure the proper development of its project right up to the scheduled start of
- Contractors’ costs or licensor’s fees,
manufacture and marketing, must be of the kind shown in Fig. 3.1, which is drawn broadly
0 Depreciable capital, whose main components are:
enough to be applicable to most of the situations encountered. This diagram covers the exe-
- Fixed capital
cution of a project that extends over seven years: three of them are devoted to studies, the
- Initial loads
other four to the construction proper.
- Interest on construction loans
- Startup costs,
A. Identification
In principle, this consists of conducting an overall analysis of the techno-economic context
in which the project is placed, so as to fix its objectives, particularly in terms of production.
In practice, the approach is to assess the unit capacity or capacities of the production facilities,
in order to establish an order of magnitude for the amount of the investments required, and to
measure their profitability in several possible situations. More specifically, this kind of study
involves successively performing:
A market study, both for supply and demand, and in terms of quantities as well as price. This
work includes an examination of the current situation, of past data, and of a projection five to
ten years into the future under various scenarios: this must be done not only for the country
concerned, but also for neighboring states or even for the entire geographic region, which
means considering trade and consequently distribution systems, existing infrastructure, local
supplies, tax measures, etc. The procedures for doing this were discussed in Chapter 1. How-
ever, the use of them here certainly provides a better basis for evaluating their usefulness and
the way they are employed in the conduct, or, more broadly, in the management of projects.
An industrialplanningpre-study,to identify, first, the possible production targets in light
of the preceding observations. The next step involves evaluating any problems related to the
location of the facilities, calculating the total budget envelope required, considering the finan-
cial setup, defining preliminary operating costs and cost prices, undertaking general or spe-
cific profitability studies of certain steps, examining possible foreign exchange savings, and
so on. Here again, the methodology likely to be employed for this kind of analysis was dis-
cussed in detail in Chapter 2. In terms of investments, the corresponding provision is intended
to give the interested party what is usually called an “order of magnitude” budget.
The ranking of various possible alternatives, including the one of not undertaking the
project. In this regard, consideration of possible overcapacities, in anticipation of market
growth, or on the other hand the need to postpone the plant’s startup date for several years
while waiting for probable new market outlets, are just two examples of the potential situa-
tions that need to be envisaged. This kind of study is in principle based on sensitivity analysis:
usually it addresses only the economic components of the project concerned; its impact is
greatly improved when it is based directly on the most important technical parameters.
B. Feasibility Studies
These represent a major step, since the decision whether to invest in the project or not depends
on their conclusions. Their main objectives are:
To make it easier for the client to reach a decision, through a detailed examination of five
essential factors: the availability of raw materials and energy, the market outlets, the applica-
ble processes and technologies, the anticipated investment cost, and the personnel require-
ments. At this point, efforts must be aimed at identifying items that must be obtained from
third parties (supplies, foreign markets, access to technologies, outside contributions of cap-
ital, personnel training, etc.). As for the investments in particular, in this case the manufac-
turer will expect to receive what is usually called a “preliminary budget”.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 227
To define the project’s technical and economicfeasibility. To this end, it is first of all nec-
essary to better define its technical aspects by developing manufacturing plans that fit the pro-
duction goals, while allowing a certain flexibility, particularly as regards raw materials; the
plans must also identify the essential processing stages (selection of the most suitable pro-
cesses or technologies) and constraints (accompanying services and treatments), and the
resources that the facilities must have in order to function. Next, it is desirable to consider the
infrastructure needed to begin the project, such as personnel requirements and their implica-
tions (accommodation, education, transport, etc.), both for the construction site and for oper-
ating the units, and also the arrangements for delivering equipment and materials via the
existing or planned highway, railroad, and port systems, etc. Finally a general development
timetable must be drawn up, and the project must be analyzed from an economic standpoint:
for this purpose more detailed estimates must be prepared, and annual budgets determined,
also operating costs, and probable financing arrangements and tax implications, so as to per-
form the profitability calculations. This work too may be accompanied by a sensitivity study.
about one month for management contracts, and three to five months for flat fee contracts;
their evaluation and the selection itself take about one month in the first case, and two or three
in the second.
following activities:
0 Drawing up timetables and plans, to define the scope of the project and establish the
design criteria,
0 Development of the project, the main goal being to approve and finalize the project
tracts, or the “contract budget” for the turnkey ones, which will be used for cost control
and to define deadlines,
0 Production of documents (drafting and checking of plans and timetables; drawing up
schedules for shipping and testing, etc.; preparation of the operating manual, etc.),
0 Purchase of equipment and the signing of contracts for follow-up, checks, and the supply
This latter period corresponds, in fact, to two notable changes in activity. First of all, it
marks the transition to the period when the budget envelope is roughly estimated, which
allows the project’s economic and financial status to be defined; it involves going from the
mere evaluation of investment costs to a more accurate estimation of them, so as to begin
making definite commitments. It then becomes the prelude to another form of business man-
agement, that of cost control, where it is no longer a matter of making forecasts, but of taking
steps to enforce them.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 229
B. Construction Proper
This covers all the work performed on the site, and also comprises three distinctive phases:
0 Start of operations and site preparation, which begins when the preceding study and supply
period has not yet been completed, and mainly includes everyhng related to the constructionof
a working base and the development of the site, as well as foundation work, roads, and the civil
engineering work preliminary to assembly. This is also when most of the main apparatus is
delivered. At the end of this stage about 25 to 30% of the construction work has been completed.
0 The active constructionphase, which covers the whole set of activities related to the deliv-
ery and receiving of all the equipment and materials, the completion of civil engineering works,
the signing of contracts for mechanical erection (equipment and piping), electricity,instrumen-
tation, painting and thermal insulation (the final task), before transfer of ownership from the
engineering company to the client. At the end of this period the construction is 90% complete.
The completion and backj?tting,which include mechanical testing and acceptance, pre-
startup, startup, and performance testing of the facilities.
one of them. For this purpose, it has to have a three-point methodology, which is essentially
what Chapter 2 was about, but which also has the special quality of being based on a simpli-
fied approach using the amount of the battery limits investments, and which ultimately leads
to judging the comparative economic attractiveness of the alternatives considered, i.e., the
profitability of the facilities concerned. By contrast, estimation confines itself to the determi-
nation of the investment cost.
0 Estimation is an absolute matter, providing opinions on figures alone, usually obtained by
direct consultation with service providers, and required to be as exact as possible. In fact, for
example in the case of a turnkey contract, it must commit to all of the engineering work on
the basis of a single, un-revisable figure: in these circumstances, a calculating error can have
devastating effects, such as the loss of a business, the creation of deficits, compromising the
reputation of a brand name, etc. Evaluation, on the other hand, has an orienting or preparatory
role, offering a choice from several alternatives, in other words it “compares”. It thus works
in a relative manner, employing information of a “bibliographic” nature (databases); for this
reason, it is not necessary to know the investment costs with great accuracy, as long as this
uncertainty does not affect the ranking of the situations examined.
0 The accuracy of the result is meaningless if the starting information itself is not sufficiently
reliable. Estimation thus demands a priori a certain level of credibility, and consequentlya level
230 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
of detail that is very markedly higher than that required for evaluation. Moreover, in the latter
case the methodology must be designed to require only a minimum of data, even to allow the use
of substitutesor approximations.Obviously,however, if the informationdoes exist the same pro-
cedure must be capable of incorporatingit, which will certainly improve the accuracy of the final
result. In other words, the techniques employed in evaluation must first of have great flexibility.
When all is said and done, the particular characteristics of evaluation and estimation are
such that in practice the pre-study period is based essentially on the concepts and procedures
of calculations arising from evaluation, especially for the definition of so-called “order of
magnitude” and “preliminary” budgets. In the construction phase, the methods used in esti-
mation become predominant, and progressively more detailed, complex, and accurate as the
date for the construction decision approaches, i.e., the time when the “target” and “contract”
budgets must be defined.
Client
b
Consultant CaDital fundinq
b
Funding parties L Manaqement of pre-financina L
Process licensors Select deliver Pgcess Assist studies Assist end of
Engineering process. Data Book constr e
Suppliers
Companies
Reply to RFP
F
Do.
- Do.
Manufacture
Worksite
h
r
v b
The suppliers of equipment and materials are solicited by the engineering company when
the tenders are called. They provide direct assistance during the supply phase. Their main
concerns are to meet both the specifications and deadlines required of them.
Finally, the service companies make their first contribution when they respond to the call
for tenders. Their participation becomes essential when work starts at the site, and is com-
pleted only when the factory is handed over. Their main constraints are similar to those of the
equipment manufacturers; however, it should be noted that these companies are exposed to
greater risks and proportionally more unforeseen events, particularly as regards weather,
stock shortages, strikes, etc.
As already mentioned, and as will be discussed in more detail later on, there are many meth-
ods of estimation and evaluation, whose very diversity proves that none of them is entirely
satisfactory. Nevertheless, some seem to be more effective than others, and in particular bet-
ter suited to the situation.
232 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
which previous results are retained, and extrapolation,namely how the data are expressed
as costs, etc.
These properties are analyzed in detail, for each method, in Section 3.1.3.2.
In addition, it is tempting to judge the reliability of an estimation procedure only on the
“accuracy” it permits. Now, this characteristic,which should rather be called closeness to the
true value, to the extent that that can actually be known on the basis of initial calculations,
and which is discussed at greater length in Section 3.1.3.3, mainly depends on the quality of
the available information. In this case, it includes the reference informationjust as much as
information about the product being estimated. The level of uncertainty thus appears to be an
extremely insecure potential selection criterion: for the same method, it fluctuates, depending
on the situation to which it is applied.
In practice, it seems much more relevant to consider the following three characteristics:
0 Sensitivity, which determines to what extent a small change at the data level is expressed
in the result,
0 Traceability, which describes how easy it is to make the connection between the result
what the decision maker should know about the connection between data and results.
This criterion, which is a subjective one, is very important, since there is no point in per-
forming estimations if the person making the decisions has no confidence in the chosen
method.
In view of these considerations,how is the most appropriate estimation method to be defin-
itively selected?
By assuming that each method can be positioned within a segment that goes from the
detailed approach to the overall approach, the choice can be made in the following manner:
at the moment when a decision is made to undertake an estimation, we try to minimize the
cost associated with that operation. This consists of the total of the expenses resulting from
the forecast itself, and from the shortcomings of this procedure, costs shown on Fig. 3.3 by
the curves (C,) and (C2).
This then identifies the procedure to be followed, or rather the level of detail at which it
seems appropriate to work.
It is easy to see that curve (C,) does not depend on time, since the use of a given method in
different situations takes roughly the same effort, whatever the conditions. On the other hand,
curve (C2)varies with the progress of the project, which in practice means that there is not just
a single curve, but a whole system. In the initial period (C23, when the project is just getting
under way, it is relatively flat and the minimum point rn lies closer to the overall approach.
Later on, when the project is better defined, it curves more and more steeply (C2,,): employing
a detailed procedure allows us, as it were, to make better use of the available information,
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 233
cost
Detailed m, ma Overall
approach approach
which is not usually the case with an overall approach, because by ignoring a portion of the
data it risks making a faulty prediction. The point m thus moves towards the detailed approach.
In other words, the choice of a method will therefore depend, in large part, on the phase in
which the project lies. When starting a study, the estimator must first settle the following
problem: given what is known about the project, and the assumptions that will have to be
made to arrive at a cost, which procedure is the best suited? Obviously, the answer will differ
from one project to another, but it will also change as the projects progress.
In conclusion, as concerns the quality of estimation methods, one is not better than another.
Each offers a certain number of features, and these determine which is the better tool at a
given moment.
However, many decision makers see little purpose in being able to apply an estimating pro-
cedure at the start of a project, though it seems self-evident that waiting until the last minute
to evaluate the cost of an operation is not a good way to operate, since in this case one might
end up evaluating a product whose cost price is greater than the average sales price the market
will accept. Even an inexact study would surely avoid such a situation, by drawing attention
at a much earlier date to problems, even to impossibilities, inherent in the project under con-
sideration.
In fact, it is best to make use of estimation as soon as possible, in particular before the
design phase, where 70% of the costs have already been settled. By way of example, although
the sums required for raw material purchases may not in fact be paid out until the moment
when the facilities actually begin working, the selection of this or that source of supply (and
consequently the commitment to possible additional costs resulting from the use of an expen-
sive starting product, as compared to another alternative), is decided well in advance.
234 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
This interval between the decision and the actual correspondingexpense may be illustrated
by means of Fig. 3.4, which shows perfectly that the longer one waits, the less room there is
for maneuver.
cost
costs
-
70%
of expenses
design phase .
In addition, at the end of the project, not only does it become difficult, if not impossible,
to change the costs, but even when it can be done any last-minute adjustment carries heavy
economic penalties, as shown graphically in Fig. 3.5.
Time
a. Principle
One way of looking at estimation is to view it from the following angle: “Doing something
is only a matter of repeating tasks, always the same ones, which differ only in their size”.
Based on this principle, it then becomes possible to undertake this kind of study if one has
both a description of the sequence of activities necessary for carrying out the action under
consideration, and a tool for quantifying each of the tasks in terms of cost.
In practice, this approach corresponds to the first way of beginning a cost estimate, i.e., by
asking the question: “What do you do to produce the product whose cost you want to deter-
mine?’.
In even more practical terms, it requires a two-stage process: first a list of the activities
must be drawn up; then a cost is assigned to each one of them, and the total gives the required
overall value. These costs are compiled in a database (catalog) and generally include a portion
for materials and another for labor, both of them derived from a size descriptor.
To completely describe one of the tasks concerning a product, it is necessary to know:
0 Its nature
For example, to quantify a linear welding operation, the labor portion is essential, and
depends on the number of hours devoted to this work; the length of the weld often serves as
the descriptor, in view of its close connection with the working time required.
b. Application
The analytic approach is based on the following premise: the impact of the size of an activity
on the cost is linear. In other words, if the size of an activity is multiplied by a factor k, the
resulting cost is also multiplied by k.
This type of procedure can be applied either more or less precisely. Several things contrib-
ute to deciding the level of detail ultimately selected for the work. In the first place, the needs
of the company must be considered. Its strategy may in fact require the estimator to evaluate
an alternative solution that differs only in certain details. As a consequence, the level of gen-
eralization of the process is the determining factor: the more comprehensive the desired
approach, the more precise it must be. This has repercussions in terms of cost, since both the
236 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
compilation and the maintenance of the catalog, and the estimation proper, take more and
more time. In practice, the lack of a certain number of data compels the estimators to accept
a less detailed approach than they might have wished.
The database itself constitutes a fundamental problem for the analytic approach. In the first
place, the amount of information to be compiled and stored is such that it leads to serious
management difficulties. Consequently, it is necessary to perfect a very precise nomencla-
ture. Moreover, it is essential to normalize the information contained, since it serves as refer-
ence for the estimations. To evaluate a new cost, two steps will be essential: to extract from
the database the data that correspond to the problem being studied, and to confirm that the
values selected are not contaminated by events of an exceptional nature. In the automobile
sector, for example, these “externalities” may be of various kinds, such as a strike at a pro-
duction center, an abnormally small production run, products made for unusual customers
with specific requirements, etc. This normalization leads immediately to a need’for an expert
capable of doing this kind of work. In practice, each specialist will establish a scale for his
own type of activity. For example, for welding an automobile chassis (for reinforcement), the
expert may fashion himself a rule such as: an operator makes 10 to 15 spot welds per minute;
the positioning of each of these with respect to the others largely determines the value to
employ (10 in a complex situation, 15 at most). Nevertheless, he always tends to think that
everything is a special case and he does not automatically try to establish general rules, even
if his approach seems to lead in that direction. This latter point is important, in fact it partly
explains why certain sectors, such as the automobile, have difficulty in getting away from
analytical methods. The second reason is linked to the number of items and activities
involved in a vehicle, and, consequently, the multitude of changes that are made during the
design phase. Whenever there is the slightest modification, the person in charge wants to
know what it costs: in this case an analytic approach seems desirable, if not necessary.
Generally speaking, applying such an approach takes time and therefore proves to be
costly; the complexity of the system prevents quick responses, and, in addition, traceability
is always poor: the very detailed breakdowns require a lot of work if the discrepancies
between forecasts and outcomes are to be explained.
Among the other characteristics of this kind of method the following favorable situations
for applying them must also be emphasized:
0 When the project is sufficiently advanced, their great sensitivity and the many points they
have in common with analytical accounting make them indispensable(possibility of allocating
charges by department,etc.); this feeling is strengthenedby the great credibility enjoyed by this
approach in such situations, since it fits in with what the decision maker expects, it has been
successfully tested over many years, and it leaves little room for the estimator’s subjectivity.
On the other hand, these tools may prove to be unsuited to certain situations. Firstly, at the
start of the project the data are generally insufficient for this approach to be used; later on,
analytical methods are poorly adapted to rapid technological development, which requires
frequent, expensive updating of the catalog and usually involves an incomplete definition of
the product, which is incompatible with this procedure.
Nevertheless, it must be noted that it is always possible to “imagine” a manufacturing
facility capable of making the product that one is trying to estimate, without ever intending
3. The Determination of Battery Limits investments 237
to put it into practice: the work then consists of predicting the number and kinds of apparatus,
the persons required for the work (both for the operations themselves and for supervision,
maintenance, etc.), the nature and amounts of energy and raw materials, etc., so as to deter-
mine the factory’s operating cost, and thereby even the cost of the product. However, if one
considers the significant expenses involved in such a task, without having a fairly complete
description of all the activities, it is certainly preferable to adopt another approach. In fact,
the “accuracy” of these procedures is always very dependent on the setting in which they are
applied (factory, crew, etc.) and a change in assumptions automatically leads to a blurring of
the result.
The approach no longer consists of an analysis of the activities, but of a study of the product
itself. One attitude has been succeeded by another in the course of time, thanks to the devel-
opment of calculating aids and statistical tools: direct analogy and modeling.
a. Direct Analogy
Principle
This is a purely statistical method, applied to a homogeneous family of products, i.e., ones
that perform the same function and have been made by the same technology. By reduction of
past data, the estimator finds a link between the cost and certain physical variables, and then
utilizes the relation thus defined to assign values to the different sizes within the family.
In general, we may distinguish several kinds of method according to the statistical treat-
ment employed. The simplest is to use averages and thus to define “price lists”. Although this
way of working is useful in certain areas of activity (for example, the construction and public
works industry uses this kind of tool when it costs trenches in linear meters), as a general rule
it is best to be careful with it. In fact it is very restrictive, and is only useful in the case of a
linear relation between cost and size. Now, the cost per unit of size usually decreases when
the size increases: for this reason, in practice the average values are calculated for ranges of
size units. Consequently, it may seem convenient to apply such a tool to rapidly obtain an
“order of magnitude”: nevertheless, it is recommended that other, more “reliable” methods
be given priority for confirming the results.
In these circumstances, it is usual to apply Cost Estimation Formulas (CEFs), established
by linear regression (for example, using the least squares method: see Chapter 1) and taking
one of the following forms:
cost = ao. (descriptorl)al ... (descriptor,)”. (3.1)
cost = a0 + a1 . (descriptor,) + ... + a, . (descriptor,,) (3.2)
The first, exponential expression can be turned into a linear one by taking the logarithms
of the variables (cost and descriptor). In fact, (3.1) can also be written:
1, cost = 1, a. + a , . 1, (descriptor,) + ... + a,, . 1, (descriptor,)
238 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
By way of example, the cost of a heat exchanger of a given type can be roughly calculated
by the following formula:
c=en. Sb
where
C : is the cost of the exchanger
S : the exchange area
a, b : are log-log regression coefficients.
COMMENT
In practice, the number of descriptors rarely exceeds five; for clarity of explanation,
only one descriptor is considered in what follows.
As already stated in Chapter 1, Section 1.2.3.1.c, the principle of the approach is to find
the best straight line fit for a number of known pairs on a cost-size graph, by minimizing the
sum of the square of the residuals, i.e., the sum of the squares of the distances, taken parallel
to they-axis, between each representative point and the straight line (Fig. 3.6). Then the con-
fidence limit (ymin; y,,) for a cost prediction is obtained by taking the value of y on the
regression line (D) for a given size x.
This confidence limit, which represents the area within which the cost has a probability p
of occurring (for example, p = 95%), is given by the two arms of a hyperbola. It is possible
to show that it is a function of three main factors:
0 The dispersion of data about the straight line, i.e., the spread of the residuals (which rep-
resents the information lost when the cloud of points is replaced by the CEF): the farther
the points are from the straight line, the greater the limit.
0 The spacing of the x-values of the reference sample about their average value (which is
given by the inverse of the variance of x in the confidence limit calculation): the bigger
it is, the closer the arms of the hyperbola are to each other.
0 The number of data points: as it increases, the limit tightens up.
It should be noted that these three factors are related: for example, increasing the number
of data points does not necessarily improve the regression. In fact, adding an aberrant point
also increases the dispersion. In practice, it is reasonable to consider that constructing a CEF
that is “credible” (having an acceptable confidence limit) requires about twenty points. In
view of the above considerations, it is evident that this is a minimum figure and that the het-
erogeneous character of the available information may demand a larger number.
Application
Given how quickly an estimation can be obtained from a CEF, it is often very desirable to
employ such tools, especially as they are generally very reliable if the family is properly
selected, which gives them a high credibility. On the other hand, it is essential to use them
with full understanding, particularly in areas of rapid technological development, where the
connection between current and earlier products is usually uncertain, in advance of the copi-
ous information required for the definition of a new “statistical model”. It should also be
noted that accuracy is not the best feature of this class of methods: in fact, unless there is a
very extensive database and the time allowed for a response is lengthy, it is best to limit the
number of parameters.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 239
cost
I
I X Descriptor
The so-called extrapolation factor method, discussed in Chapter 2, Section 2.3.2.1, which
is expressed in the following equation:
0 Its homogeneity appears highly doubtful, since in fact each construction is unique: for
example, depending on its structure, a refinery is capable of providing the various cuts
that it produces (liquefied petroleum gases, gasolines, diesel, etc.) in a range of given
proportions. Consequently, to simplify, the distribution of the demand for petroleum
products anticipated during the coming years largely controls the type and the relative
size of the facilities to be constructed.
There is, therefore, a double problem: lack of data, and inadequate homogeneity. To com-
pensate for these shortcomings, we “ ~ n l y ”need to descend to a more detailed level, specifi-
cally that of simple equipment. Their essential characteristic is that they are manufactured in
greater quantities, either because there are so many of them in the complex under consider-
ation, or because they are not specific to this complex, so that each item is itself a homoge-
neous family. In practice, we often calculate the investment cost required for the manufacture
of a product by using an analogous sub-unit (itself divisible into homogeneous components)
that is considered representative, and then using factors (which may be multipliers or not) to
arrive at the desired value (which in this case is the battery limits investment).
b. Modeling
History
Modeling applied to cost first appeared in the United States at the end of the 1960s, thanks
to the work of the American, Franck Freiman. Freiman was originally looking for an answer
for his superior, who wanted to have a tool that would allow him to quickly check the estima-
tions made by the relevant departments of his company, using traditional methods. The man-
ager, facing reports hundreds of pages in length, had no means at that time to confirm the
consistency of each study (was each one using the same assumptions?), their completeness
(was anything overlooked?), and so on. An overall approach was evidently needed.
Freiman engaged in a series of discussions with estimation experts from many different
sectors of activity. The observation that there were strong similarities between the approaches
gave him the idea that it might be possible to develop a model that would bring them all
together in a general theory of cost. In a certain way, then, it makes sense to speak of “mod-
eling how an expert thinks”.
A first prototype appeared in 1972 and, based on the good results obtained, it was marketed
in 1976 under the name: Price. The first generation of models dedicated to “equipment” was
born.
A number of drawbacks quickly appeared the need to know the mass, tricky estimation of
the complexity parameter owing to its eminently abstract nature, etc. In the face of these dif-
ficulties, Freiman took a fresh look at the original model, to eliminate its application prob-
lems. Although the core of the method remained unchanged, several basic improvements
were introduced and the Fast-E model (E for “equipment”), marketed in 1982, represented
the second generation, of which today’s Map-H is the direct descendant.
Since then, still following the same principle, estimating by using models has enlarged its
range of applications to include the development costs of software, construction and civil
engineering costs, etc., each one a variant on the basic theme of the “equipment” model.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 24 1
Thus Map-H belongs to a family of models that continues to evolve, in France under the
initiative of Pierre Foussier (the 3F company). For example, the list includes Map-C for con-
struction and civil engineering costs, Map-S for software development, and Map-0 for car-
rying costs.
It should be noted that the Price family still exists, but that it has retained the original, less
advanced techniques: in particular, it does not incorporate the very important contributions
that emerged from the work of Freiman between 1976 and 1982.
Principle
Although they are often incorrectly grouped with direct analogy under the generic term
“parametric methods”, mathematical cost models are based on fundamentally different con-
cepts. In fact, like all scientific software, they aim to represent the behavior of a “system” in
mathematical terms. They are generally made up of several expressions that relate certain
variables, which are the ones being investigated, to certain others whose variations have
effects on the evolution of the first ones.
Developing a CEF is therefore a fundamentally different thing from developing a model.
In the first case, one reaches a conclusion by compressing data: the statistics are used a priori.
In contrast, in the second case, one tries to explain the observed behaviors of systems; conse-
quently, the construction proceeds in two distinct stages:
0 Research based on abstract concepts (Maxwell fields, Newtonian forces, etc.),
0 Trials of mathematical expressions until reality confirms them: the statistics are thus
applied a posteriori.
As in all models, there is a sharp distinction between the laws that govern the evolution of
a system, on the one hand, and the initial (or reference) conditions on the other. The two
aspects are complementary and essential.
Cost estimation software is also bound by this initialization and reference rule. Because of
its all-purpose nature it does not explicitly single out families of products, but places the item
to be estimated within a general system of curves. On the other hand, the specificity of the
company cannot be completely ignored, because although competition requires that the price
be around the “normal” value (a company that remained inefficient too long would disappear
from the market, another that offered lower prices would force its rivals to catch up), never-
theless there are differences in working methods. The initial conditions, called adjustment
variables, take into account the way in which the company designs its products.
The whole process is shown schematically in Fig. 3.7: it includes two distinct stages. The
first, called calibration, consists of acquiring the initial conditions. To do this, it is necessary
to have one or more reference points, each comprising a description of the product and the
accompanying cost. The model, operating in reverse, then deduces the adjustment variables.
Using the initial conditions and a description of the product to be estimated, it then becomes
possible to move on to the second phase of the operation: the cost estimation. In fact, it
involves identifying the “forces” that have acted on the reference system (changes in size, in
materials, etc.) and describing them “in numerical terms” to the model, which uses them to
deduce the cost of the final object. This comes down to extracting the common feature of the
pieces of equipment (the initial conditions), and then determining the differences between
them.
242 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
The cost factors, which are used as much for the calibration as for the estimation itself, are
linked to the production context (quantity, degree of automation, economic conditions, etc.).
They are different from the description in that they do not directly refer to the product itself, but
they have a similar impact, since their variations also produce “forces” that act upon the cost.
The concept of calibration requires a special comment: it is central to the process of cost
estimation by mathematical modeling, so it is important not to make a mistake in understand-
ing concerning this step-a mistake that some persons, put off by the idea of having to calibrate
the procedure before each evaluation, commonly make. Now, it is not a matter of doing this on
the model proper, but on the processes and their environment. This approach is rendered essen-
tial by the following fundamental principle: a universal parametric method is not “absolute”:
by its nature, it is comparative. Estimations are made on the basis of previous experience, quan-
tified by various persons. The calibration thus improves the consistency of the description, but
not the accuracy of the model. It develops real measures of performance that serve as refer-
ences, so as to assure the link with the company’s capacities and to establish a credible base.
It also enables us to become familiar with the software’s parameters, and with the way in
which they can be used to describe the differences between the products, and between their
development possibilities. In this way, the estimator improves his ability to quantify the
assessments that are essential for comparing new products, processes, and environments with
existing ones.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 243
Application
In a way, the principle consists of looking at the problem in a more abstract fashion than
when using CEFs. Formulas of the type:
cost = a. x(descriptorl)al ...(descriptor,,)’”
are still used, but the coefficients ( a j )are themselves estimated by relations that employ the
product’s characteristics, which have to be described to the model. Looked at in this way, the
universality of the procedure requires that the product description be simple, but above all not
specific to it alone. Accordingly, the parameters are the same, whatever the study undertaken,
even if they are understood in different ways. This feature is very important, since it allows
the application of the model to be modified to fit the progress of the project.
The estimation’s validity still depends on the values of the parameters entered by the user,
which the software simply translates into economic data. Next comes an essential training
stage, whose purpose is to find correspondences between the situations to be described and
the numbers derived from the parameters, and especially to determine their rates of change,
so as to be able to express the observed differences between the products correctly. This expe-
rience can only be acquired by using the model; as a result, it is quickly passed on. In fact, all
that is needed is to have an up-to-date computer file that covers the company’s history, and
includes each product for which an estimation was made, with a list of the values of its param-
eters, and especially the steps that led to their determination. In practice, passing the baton is
a little more complicated than that, since two different estimators may have slightly divergent
perceptions of the approach. It is necessary, therefore, to explain to one’s successor just how
one has employed the tool, which essentially means describing the conventions that were
established to ensure the greatest possible consistency between estimations.
Once the calibration has been done, making a prediction is quick and consequently cheap.
Moreover, as already noted, the model’s flexibility allows for multiple choices, in particular
the level of detail at which to work. Because of this, although the preferred place to apply
them is at the beginning of a project, these procedures can also be useful later on, and may
even allow activities to be evaluated, as long as they can be described in physical quantities.
Two additional properties of models should be noted. First, by their nature they establish
a very clear link between design and cost, and thus serve as a tool for dialog between the var-
ious actors, particularly the designers and the estimators. Next, since the estimators need to
consider only a fairly limited number of parameters, an increase in productivity is often seen.
However, it must be admitted that because the mathematical expressions cannot be examined,
the models have a “black box” character that sometimes leaves the estimator puzzled. In addi-
tion, one cannot become expert in applying this approach overnight: the training period,
which is fairly long, has to be considered as an investment that will bring future benefits, aris-
ing from the use of modeling. Finally, the overall approach generally does not allow expenses
to be distributed by department, but this is a very minor drawback at the outset of a project.
The possibility of using mathematical cost models to estimate the time it takes to perform
operations should also be mentioned. For example, following a principle very similar to the
one used previously, when the initial conditions have been defined, manufacturing times can
be evaluated on the basis of a certain number of parameters that take into account the com-
pany’s specificity in this area. This can be very valuable, since making a piece of equipment
available quickly can make a decisive difference.
244 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
0 etc.
In practice, the unavailability of one procedure or another often simplifies the decision. If
not, the choice is governed primarily by how far the project has progressed, and secondly by
the product’s level of novelty.
At the start of a project, it is not well defined, which limits the level of detail attainable;
moreover several alternatives are generally competing. In fact, time and money are in short
supply, and a quick, cheap method is essential. This situation dooms the activity approach
because of its design principle. In this case, the technological stability of the field concerned
often influences the choice between the two options under the product approach. If develop-
ments seem to be gradual and not too rapid, direct analogy may appear to be the most suitable.
Indeed, nothing is simpler than a CEF, and there is enough time to accumulate the experience
and deduce robust rules from it. On the other hand, if the technology is constantly changing,
modeling is the only reliable solution. This is also the case when the number of known points
is too small to permit a linear regression to be performed.
When the project is well advanced, the activity approach is the.preferred one; in any event,
preparing for the construction phase requires detailed work and the objective is no longer to
make design decisions, most of them having already been made. Note that many companies
elect to develop their own methods, semi-detailed, for example, which attempt to reconcile
the advantages of the activity approach with those of direct analogy.
By way of illustration, Table 3.1 presents a summary of the various options, with their
respective principles, advantages, and shortcomings.
If we now draw a parallel between the various phases of project development, as shown in
Fig. 3.1, and the procedures to be applied to meet the various types of budget that a manufac-
turer must underwrite before making the decision to go ahead or not, and then to go on to the
construction stage, we are led to the choices recommended in Table 3.2.
The first two types of procedure belong to the product approach, the second explicitly
requiring CEFs; the fourth is purely analytic in nature and assumes prior consultation with
the equipment suppliers and service providers for all the apparatus and works that are likely
to be involved during the construction of the plant. As for the third, it is based on a mixture
of the two kinds of approach, consultation being involved in only a portion of the actions.
Modeling is not specifically mentioned in this presentation: it is mainly utilized in the prelim-
inary stages, when, as noted previously, reference to earlier constructions of the “same type”
is impossible, i.e., in situations whose elements make them virtually special cases, or when a
technological leap is achieved.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 245
Budget II 1
Order of magnitude
1
Preliminary
1
Target or initial
1
Contract
category
1 1 1
Estimation Modular or factor
Overall or similariq Semi-detailed Detailed
method method
1 1 1 1
Level of
+40/50% +25/30% k 15/20% k3/5%
precision
I
(Source: BF)
If we restrict ourselves to the so-called “evaluation” methods, in the sense defined earlier,
i.e., to the pre-study phases, the recommended procedures are likely to fall under direct analogy.
Nevertheless, a few words must be added concerning the degree of sophistication of these
approaches. Moreover, from this viewpoint the selection may be made partly on the basis of
chronological considerations, in that the accumulation of data over time, and the progressive
improvements in the methods of analyzing and interpreting information, have allowed them
to be perfected and given greater depth.
246 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
To begin with, we may consider the distinction made earlier between overall extrapolation
methods, which are exponential in nature, and those based on a prior breakdown into ele-
ments that are calculated by analogy with cataloged data of the same kind, followed by a rein-
tegration of the whole using sets of coefficients. Looking at them in more detail, the first
category comprises:
0 The “extrapolation factor” procedure, an incorrect term although widely utilized by the
profession to express the determination of a new cost from another, known one, under iden-
tical conditions of date and site, by multiplying it by the ratio between two values of the same
size variable, raised to a certain power. It works just as well for apparatus (exchangers, col-
umns, furnaces, compressors, etc.) as for assemblies or complete units (in this case the size
parameter is usually the unit production or processing capacity).
0 The block, or notional operating unit methods. Their principle consists of a “Prtvert”
inventory, in which each of the constituents is assigned the same weight-r different
weights, depending on the designers-and which leads to a notional average piece of equip-
ment, whose cost is obtained by analogy (for example, R.D. Hill, F.C. Zevnik and
R.L. Buchanan, G.T. Wilson).
0 Flow methods, which attempt a weighting of the value of the size variable represented by
the unit flow through the various pieces of equipment in a plant (for example, E.A. Stallwor-
thy, D.H. Allen and R.C. Page).
0 Approaches based on identifying “significant” steps and calculating their respective costs
by direct analogy (for example, J.H. Taylor).
0 Procedures employing a prior breakdown of a plant into hnctional modules, i.e., ones that
have a physico-chemical reality, each one’s cost then being determined by analogy, on the
basis of one or preferably several significant size parameters (for example, J. Bergman and
A. Chauvel).
Next, as concerns the multiplying or the factorial methods, we may distinguish between:
0 The ones that use constant factors (for example, A.J. Lang, N.G. Bach, W.E. Hand), which
date from the decade following the second world war: they are based on a rather limited
amount of information concerning traditional materials, and fairly small unit manufacturing
capacities in comparison to the tonnages handled today.
0 Ones that recognize the variability of these factors and instead offer a range of possible
values (for example, C.H. Chilton, or M.S. Peters and K.D. Timmerhaus).
0 Finally, ones that endeavor to quantify these variations, taking the specific nature of each
project into account by means of a limited number of explanatory parameters; here we can
differentiate between:
0 Relatively comprehensive procedures (for example, J.H. Hirsch and E.M. Glazier)
0 Modular methods using type units (for example, C.A.Miller, or the AACE {American
al., SRI).
3. The Determination of Battery Limits investments 247
As shown in Table 3.3, these various possibilities reflect an almost chronological, twenty-
year evolution in the means available for collecting and processing information. Moreover,
the most recent developments in the field are a result of the enormous progress achieved in
computing in recent years; they mainly concern the marketing of estimation software, based
on reference to very large databases and the use of CEFs, and having nothing in common with
the cost models discussed above.
In this section, we do not intend to make a detailed study of all the procedure that may or may
not have been published. The catalog would be far too tedious; and already some readers will
be complaining that it is long enough with just the ones selected so far. These two reasons
will suffice to explain why the analysis undertaken here is, on the contrary, far from being
exhaustive, and certainly partial as regards the authors who have not been mentioned. We
therefore trust that the persons who consider themselves to have been slighted will be kind
enough to believe that they have been omitted more out of ignorance of their contribution to
the development of these methods, than by any deliberate action.
In addition, so as to honor past descriptions of these procedures as far as possible, they are
mainly repeated in their initial form, in particular by retaining the original nomenclature and
notations. Sometimes this may lead to some confusion when going from one approach to
another, since the same acronyms may have completely different meanings; conversely, as
often happens, the same idea may be formulated in different ways.
248 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
The main advantage of these approaches is that they generally enable a very quick evaluation
of investment cost, based on a minimum of information.
This approach, which is valid only for chemical plants that operate with fluids as their prin-
cipal products, takes into account the following characteristics:
The factory's production capacity,
The number of functional units or blocks: each functional unit is defined as the apparatus
required to perform a given operation, such as a distillation, a stripping, or a compres-
sion,
A complexity factor based on the process's range of operating conditions: temperature
(factor FT),pressure (factor Fp),and the quality of the materials employed (carbon steel,
specialty steels, alloys, etc., factor Fa).This complexity factor is expressed as follows:
where
FT= 1.765.104 T -0.053 for T > 300 K
FT = -2. T + 0.6 for T < 300 K
Fp = 3 . lo4 (loglo PIP,, - 1)
Fa = 0 for cast iron, carbon steel, and wood
0.1 for aluminum, copper, and AISI type 400 stainless steels
0.2 for type 300 stainless steels, monel metal, nickel, and Inconel
0.3 for Hastelloy
0.4 for precious metals.
The cost of the average notional functional unit for the diagram concerned (the unit cost)
is a function of the plant's production capacity and the complexity factor (Fig. 3.8). The bat-
tery limits investment is obtained by multiplying the number of unit blocks by the unit cost.
The total grassroots investment is deduced by applying a constant factor (33% extra). If nec-
essary, an update may be performed by using the ENR cost index.
The following expression is then obtained:
Zg = N . (CPFU) . 1.33 -
(E"
300
where
Zg is the total investment
N number of functional units
(CPFU) cost per functional unit
(ENR) value of the ENR index on the date of the evaluation.
250 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
The advantages of this method are to be found in the rapid evaluation that it enables, even
in the absence of accurate information. However, it provides acceptable results only for fairly
complex processes: the authors applied it successfully to the production of cyanhydric acid,
ammonia, acetylene, phthalic anhydride, etc. If the factory’s process diagram is simple, i.e.,
having only one stage of synthesis with practically total conversion, high selectivity, and easy
purification (for example, the hydrogenation of benzene to form cyclohexane),we obtain much
higher investments than those found in practice. The error may reach, or even exceed, 100%.
In fact, the value of the method depends on:
0 An accurate evaluation of the number of functional units, whose cost is directly propor-
tional to the total investment. This work is very sensitive, and demands a lot of concentration
and experience. Available process diagrams are often found to be incomplete as regards the
load preparation stages, the product finishing operations, the catalyst handling, the equipment
required for plant startup, and the regeneration or recovery of catalysts.
0 A proper determination of the complexity factor, in particular the coefficient Fa, which
depends on the kind of materials employed. This assumes that we either know at the outset
the quality of steel being used, or that we undertake a meticulous analysis of the corrosion
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 25 1
problems likely to be encountered in the process concerned. If this analysis cannot be per-
formed, for example by comparison with existing situations, the accuracy of the method will
be significantly affected, and its value greatly diminished.
In addition, a major drawback, which relates to the very principle of this way of evaluating
investments, consists of taking the same basic cost no matter what the function and relative
scale of the functional units, and looking only at the total production capacity. Because of
this, the approach does not allow their actual fluid circulations to be assigned separately to
each of the units that are counted: these circulations control their real sizes and consequently
their costs (recycling, by-products, reflux system, etc.).
To a lesser extent, the use of a single complexity factor, representing the whole range of
conditions, is also a built-in drawback. Thus, it is easy to understand why several authors have
subsequently attempted to correct these failings.
(AUC) = 21
Table 3.4 Specific factors for types of material. Method of G.T. Wilson
Material FM Material FM
Carbon steel 1 .oo High-alloy steels 1S O
Bronze 1.05 Hastelloy C 1.54
Boiler steels 1.07 Monel metal 1.65
Aluminum 1.08 Nickel 1.71
Low-alloy steels 1.28 Titanium 2.00
Worthite (austenitic steel) 1.41
(Source:British Chern. Eng. and Process Tech.)
According to G.T. Wilson, the accuracy of the method is such that investments can be cal-
culated to *30%, as long as Vlies between l@ and lo6t/yr. In fact, it depends on how well
it is possible to know the plant diagram and the material balance, not just overall, but as far
as possible line by line, also the general operating characteristics of the principal equipment.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits lnvesfmenfs 253
_r .
5 10-2 lo-’ 10‘ 102 103 104
e!
b
0
Operating temperature (“C)
I = 0.00751 Az(
i= s
i=l
N . FM.Fp . FT .R)i
254 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
in which we have
s the total number of primary and secondary products i
R the ratio of the output of product i concerned, to that of the principal product
N the number of steps (or component units) involving a product i
FM a factor specific to the type of material used in the equipment through which the dis-
charge i travels
Fp a factor related to the pressure in this same equipment
FT a factor related to the temperature, also for the same equipment.
The coefficient A, expressed in 1967&, is a function of the production capacity for the prin-
cipal product of the plant concerned. If V is this capacity, in tlyr, A has the form:
A = 0.62 . 10-5 (0-0.65
i may represent a secondary product as well as the principal product.
The values for the factors FM, Fp, and FT result from a weighting based on the operating
conditions of the main equipment involving the discharge i, and the type of material
employed.
Apart from the difficulties caused by having to describe the stages, i.e., the functional units,
and by determining their number, the drawbacks of this method are in particular related to:
0 The very definition of the coefficient A, which is calculated from the theoretical output
The cost of the principal equipment available onsite is obtained from the following rela-
tionship:
(DEC) = N . (SF) . (BIC)
where
N is the number of principal items of apparatus (including pumps), obtained by exam-
ining the complete plant diagram
(SF) is a complexity factor (the State Factor), reflecting the operating conditions and the
kind of materials employed. Thus, we have:
(SF) = FTmax ‘ FPmax ’ FMaver.
FT, Fp,and FMare obtained from Figs. 3.10a and 3. lob, and Table 3.4, compiled
by G.T. Wilson. According to Allen, it is not necessary to calculate the average
weighted temperature and pressure factors
(BIC) is the actual cost of a “standard” item of principal equipment (Basic Item Cost). It
is a function of the product’s average circulating flow rate through the unit, the
Throughput variable (TP), calculated from the following expression:
with
(BIC) in June 1972 $
(TP) expressed in lb mol/year
(BIC), $7 000 (June 1972)
(TP), 2.5 . lo6 lb mol/year
(EXP) extrapolation exponent for the plant concerned.
If an update is required, the authors recommend the use of the Marshall and Stevens index.
The average throughput (TP) is given by the following relationship:
(TP) = (CAP) . (FF) . (PF)
where
(CAP) is the total load in Ib mol/year
(FF) is the Flow Factor, defined as follows:
(FF) =
%‘ number of lines entering and leaving
each item of principal equipment
N
from the liquid fraction alone. The authors emphasize that if even 2% or more by
weight of a hydrocarbon is in the gaseous state in a given piece of equipment, then
its size parameters should be determined on the basis of the gaseous volumes pro-
cessed. The constant 0.0075 is the value of the ratio of the vapor and liquid densi-
ties of a type hydrocarbon product under average conditions. Expressing the
average circulating throughput in lb moyyear, i.e., in terms of volume, makes it
easier to keep track of the capacity effect.
The exponent (EXP), which applies to all the principal equipment, is calculated as the
weighted average value of the extrapolation exponents for each category of apparatus, i.e.:
(EXP)= ‘=’
5i=l
ci
where
ci is the base cost of the item of principal equipment i
ei is the extrapolation exponent for the item of principal equipment i.
Between i = 1 and i = N, there are a number of pieces of apparatus belonging to the same cat-
egory, and therefore having the same base costs and the same partial extrapolation exponents.
To calculate (EXP), the authors recommend using the values of ci and eisuggested by
K.M. Guthrie (see Section 3.2.2.4.F) and partly shown in Table 3.5.
Although the level of accuracy provided by Allen and Page’s method for quickly deter-
mining the cost of principal equipment is attractive, its impact is limited by having to apply
a constant factor to obtain the total investment (the erected cost) from it. In fact, it possesses
all the drawbacks of the methods that rely on multiple constant factors (see Section 3.2.2.2),
such as Lang’s method and those derived from it.
Table 3.5 Extrapolation exponents and relative costs of various items of equipment, from K.M. Guthrie
Equipment I (;i:f 1
ExT:rt I
Base costs
I1
Equipment Exponent
(ei)
Base costs
( ~ 1968
i
$000)
Reactor furnace 0.85 135.0 11 Crusher:
Heating furnace 0.85 103.5 cone 0.85 12.0
Boiler: gyratory 1.20 3.0
15 psig 0.50 92.0 jaw 1.20 4.7
150 psig 0.50 101.2 pulverizer 0.35 23.4
300 psig 0.50 115.0 Mill:
600 psig 0.50 138.0 ball 0.65 4.4
“Packaged” boiler 0.70 60.0 rod 0.65 40.0
Tube-type exchanger 0.65 6.5 hammer 0.85 8.0
Reboiler 0.65 8.8 Evaporator:
U-tube heat exchanger 0.65 5.5 forced circulation 0.70 270.0
Cooler 0.66 6.8 vertical tube type 0.53 37.2
Cooling tower 0.60 9.9 horizontal tube type 0.53 30.4
Plate column 0.73 33.5 double shell 0.60 32.0
Packed column 0.65 35.2 Hopper:
Vertical drum 0.65 7.6 conical 0.68 0.1
Horizontal drum 0.60 5.0 silo 0.90 0.4
Storage vessel 0.30 6.0 Crystallizer:
Pressure storage: maturing 0.65 385.0
horizontal 0.65 4.8 forced circulation 0.55 276.5
spherical 0.70 8.0 batch 0.70 32.5
Centrifugal pump with: Filter:
motor 0.52 1.5 plate press 0.58 4.3
turbine 0.52 3.0 frame press:
Alternative pump: wet 0.58 5.3
with motor 0.70 6.0 dry 0.53 15.1
steam 0.70 1.1 rotating drum 0.63 17.5
Compressor: rotating disk 0.78 31.0
gas 1000 psig 0.82 85.0 Dryer
air 125 psig 0.28 36.5 drum 0.45 30.0
Blower and fan 0.68 9.5 tank 0.38 12.5
rotary vacuum 0.45 43.4
(Source: Chem. Eng.)
A 0.6 t . Reaction
B 0.6 t 1OO'C. 10 atm
S (recycling) 4 t
3.
Filtration Distillation
7
Wash water a-
ndzhing EO'C, ss
Filtrate 5 t
I I I
J.
Product C 1 t
The costliness indices generally lie between 10, for a plant designed to produce a relatively
simple chemical product (formol, for example), and 200, or even more, when it concerns a
more complex facility, for example one that produces a pesticide or a pharmaceutical constit-
uent.
The principle of the method is to make a direct correlation between the amount of the
investment for a production unit, and the chemical process employed, bypassing any consid-
eration of the engineering of the equipment involved. In this it differs fundamentally from the
other rapid cost calculation procedures. Another peculiarity is the fact that the complexity
score for each step is assessed separately for each of the determining factors (throughputs,
corrosion, operating conditions, etc.). Table 3.6 shows how such a calculation is performed.
The basic relation between the battery limits investment (C), expressed in k&,the costli-
ness index, and the size of the plant (S),expressed in kt/year and assumed to be built in the
United Kingdom, is therefore as follows:
c = 45 . I . 9 . 3 9
using an EPE (Engineering and Process Economics cost index) of 300 for that country. The
investment C includes the installation costs and engineering expenses.
The field of application claimed by the author covers a range of unit production capacities
going from 0.3 to 250 kt/yr, for traditional plants in continuous operation, processing both
organic and inorganic products. It can be extended to discontinuous operations with capaci-
ties up to 1 kt/yr, by using a modified equation similar to the previous one:
c = 45 . I . ~ 0 . 6
Table 3.6 Determination of the complexity level and the costliness index. Method of J.H. Taylor
The procedure reaches its limits when it comes to conducting optimization studies, to eval-
uating the costs of modifying or extending existing plants, or dealing with operations that are
too specialized (electrolysis, plastic extrusion, spinning fibers, etc.).
10
1
105 106 107
Battery limits investment ($)
Generally speaking, a significant step is one that enables the execution of a complete phys-
ico-chemical operation. It thus comprises not only the equipment essential for this operation,
but also all the peripheral apparatus required for it to function properly. In the absence of
exact information, N represents the total number of steps identified, each having a value of 1;
N is therefore usually a whole number. In some cases, knowledge of the plant diagram may
allow a judgment of the relative importance of the various treatments involved in this case,
we may assign a value of 1 to the more complex ones, and assess the others by comparison
(values < 1). As a result, the total may not be a whole number. This way of working offers
the advantage of getting closer to reality.
The value of the fimction may be obtained from Fig. 3.13, using the value of the ratio . The
ratio Z/O may be found directly by considering the input and output flows, and then simply
dividing by N.
S is obtained by using the set of curves in Fig. 3.14, which involve the pressure level,
expressed in psi, and the fraction Mfof equipment (in fact, the portion of significant steps)
that uses more sophisticated steels (actually, AISI type 304 stainless) than carbon steel. In
practice, S results from a weighting of the type:
N
S = x S i Ni I N
1
COMMENT
The 100 psi curve refers to carbon steel; the ones for higher pressures apply to 304
stainless; this set of curves must be changed or adapted when the kinds of steel
employed are different.
0.1 1 10' 1
VON,inputloutput ratio by number of significant steps
Figure 3.1 4 Determination of the correction factor for pressure and kind
of material employed. Method of J.L. Viola. (Source: Chem. Eng.)
f,is calculated from the number of significant steps in which solids appear, in comparison
to the total number of steps, under the assumption that they all have the same “weight”, or,
preferably, as a function of the total of “relative weights” assigned to them, compared to the
“total weight” of the whole, when such differences can be measured. It is limited to a maxi-
mum value of 0.45.
According to its author, the accuracy is f 15%. In practice, experience plays an important
role in assessing the kind, the number, and the respective weights of the various steps. N is in
fact the parameter that has the greatest influence on the final cost. In addition, as with
J.H. Taylor’s method, it is best to be cautious when the manufacturing diagrams include a lot
of specialized or modular processes involving electrolysis, membranes, crystallization,
adsorption, etc.
In 1984, T.J. Ward revisited the work of J.L. Viola, as well as that of other authors such as
F.C. Zevnik and R.L. Buchanan. In particular, he showed that the procedures suggested usu-
ally produced values that were too high, when compared to the reality. He therefore proposed
to change them, first of all by systematically calibrating them against known examples of
plants of similar design. He then recommended that, especially when applying J.L. Viola’s
method, all the ancillary operations should be left out of the equation: storage, packaging,
shipping, waste removal, solvent purification, heat recovery, etc. Moreover, he defined the
mathematical expressions for the curves in Figs. 3.12,3.13, and 3.14:
I =65 Co.6exp(Z/O. l/N)0.i067
Previous Page
where
Z is the battery limits investment (expressed in 1981 $)
C the production capacity (lying between 2 and 50 million lb/year)
= 1,0167 (Z/O. l/N)0.1067
S = (0.8 + 0.00045 P + 2.5 lod P2)(A4+0.8) + 0.6
where P: pressure (expressed in psi).
- Thermal insulation
- Instrumentation (if appropriate)
- Electrical system
- Setting up equipment
- Hookups and connections
- Temporary buildings
0 Contingencies:
- Special costs arising for example from unforeseen delays due to strikes, bad weather,
etc.
- Last-minute technical changes
In some accounts, the engineering costs are sometimes included and set out in full for each
category of equipment, instead of being grouped together as shown in the calculation of
investment costs presented in Section 2.3.1 of Chapter 2.
Contingencies
Erection
civil engineering, foundations, site preparation,
setting up equipment, connections, road work,
etc.
Secondary equipment
steel structures, structures, piping, valves, electricity,
insulation,buildings,control room, painting, regular
instrumentation,etc.
Principal equipment
columns, drums, tanks, storage, reactorsand similar items,
exchangers, evaporators, pumps, compressors, drives,
furnaces, specializedequipment (centrifuges, steam ejectors,
dryers, filters, mills, crushers, conveyor belts, etc.)
As far as the first attempts in the area of factorial procedures are concerned, the basic prin-
ciple obtained from the compilation and analysis of the data available at the time the work
was done consists of accepting that there is a constant relationship between the amount of the
principal equipment and its erected cost. In other words, if we refer to Fig. 3.15, and if we
accept that, given certain simplifying assumptions, the figures for the various headings are
valid for a large number of manufacturing units, we can see that as long as we know the cost
of the principal equipment, arbitrarily set to a normalized value of 100, then a multiplying
factor of 3.5 will give the erected value.
employed up to this point, is equivalent to the battery limits investment (II)and the general
services and storage (I2).Moreover, even at the time when he was doing the work, the author
evidently found that that this factor was not completely constant, since he was ultimately
forced to distinguish three major kinds of manufacturing units on the basis of their products,
as shown in Table 3.7.
Obviously, the results achieved are much more complex than might appear from the
summary figures in Table 3.7, and Lang evidently played a pioneer role in this area, since
this type of relationship is named after him. However, it must also be emphasized that at that
time, unlike today, the state of knowledge and of industrial development, especially con-
cerning unit production capacities, did not permit a differentiation of all the activities and
trades involved in constructing a commercial facility. For this reason, for processes that
involve fluids, the values suggested then seem too low when compared with the ones
employed today.
The analyses performed by Bach were similar to those of his predecessor, but he suggested a
different way of looking at the investments. For a particular application, he prefers to draw a
connection between the cost of only the principal equipment devoted to it, and the erected
cost of the corresponding facility. He thus separates the manufacturing unit proper from the
production of utilities and everything concerned with storage, by adopting specific erection
coefficients for each of these categories of facility. In fact, the author feels that these are inde-
pendent entities, whose cost calculation and management procedures are not connected. To
the extent that they are no longer being distinguished on the basis of the products being
processed, the result is not a single value for each, but a range of possibilities, as shown in
Table 3.8. These “constant” factors suggested by Bach do not include engineering costs.
In fact, the usual practice is to talk about one thing when meaning another, since, when the
Lang factor is involved, we actually imply the relationship between the battery limits
investment (I,)and the cost of the principal equipment, i.e., the Bach coefficient. For this
reason, when discussing the matter, it would be more correct to speak of the “modified Lang
factor”.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 267
I Type of equipment
I Hand’s facto
I
Distillation columns 4
Pressure drums 4
Exchangers 3.5
Furnaces 2
Pumps 4
Compressors 2.5
Instruments 4
Miscellaneous 2.5
As shown in Table 3.10, which contains some of the headings and sub-headings of
Fig. 3.15, these factors result from a much more sensitive and detailed analysis than might
appear from their overall values. Moreover, they allow us to anticipate certain characteristics,
which the methods that follow attempt to take account of by determining installation coeffi-
cients. Thus, we can see that the Hand factors for fixed equipment such as columns, tanks, and
Table 3.1 0 Method of W.E.Hand
1. Principal equipment
2. Secondary equipment
Column
100
Drum
100
Exchanger
100
Furnace
100
Pump
100 1- Compressor Instrument
Piping 60 65 50 10 30
Electricity 5 5 3 5 73
Instrumentation(1) - - - - -
Sub-total 65 70 53 15 103
Total 1 + 2 165 170 153 115 203
3. Equipment and materials
Concrete 10 5 5 10 5
Structures 15 20 25 - -
Insulation 25 12 14 7 7
Painting 3 3 3 3 3
Buildings - - - - 10
Sub-total 53 40 47 20 25
4. Construction labor
Hoisting & installation of 10 10 3 - 10 10 10
principal equipment
Other construction 72 80 62 15 60 20 50
Sub-total 82 90 65 15 70 30 60
Total 3 + 4 135 130 112 35 95 60 110
5. Transport, insurance, tax (1) - - - - - - -
Total 1 to 5 300 300 265 150 300 190 300
6. Engineering and indirect costs 100 100 85 50 100
Total 1 to 6 400 400 350 200 400
Modular factor 4.0 4.0 3.5 2.0 4.0
(1) To be considered on a case-by-case bas] but must not be overlooked in the calculation.
(Source :Petroleum Refiner)
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 269
exchangers are high; for the others, especially those involving rotating items, such as com-
pressors and others (i.e., specialized equipment: rotary filters, centrifuges, etc.), these factors
are fairly low, around 2. Furnaces and pumps appear to be exceptions. In the case of furnaces,
it should be noted that, at the time when Hand defined his correlations, the scale of the facil-
ities allowed pre-assembled units to be brought directly to the site, which is no longer possible
today. As for pumps, it must be observed that, in spite of their modest cost when compared
with other equipment, they represent a compulsoryjunction point, generally located at ground
level, which requires the installation of a significant system of piping and valves.
The author also anticipated what other methods have since introduced, by noting that the
employment of specialty steels and the use of high pressures (P > 12 bar) represent two situ-
ations where the principal equipment accounts for a larger share of the total cost of the unit;
in these circumstances he recommends a reduction in the value of the factors usually applied.
0 Instrumentation
0 Erection of instrumentation
0 Underground piping
0 Above-ground piping
0 Structures
0 Buildings
0 Site preparation
0 Foundations
270 3. The Determination of Battery Limits lnvestrnents
Electrical systems
0 Thermal insulation
Access ways, fences, etc.
So as to have a uniform basis for discussion, most authors evaluate the respective weights
of the various items as a proportion of the principal equipment, whose value is arbitrarily set
to 100. In other words, the observed variations, which mostly arise from technological differ-
ences between the plants being studied, are expressed as percentages of the cost of the prin-
cipal equipment. For example, the expenses assigned to piping can range from 52% to 125%
of the cost of the principal equipment, depending on whether the technology is simple, with
few fluid transfer lines, or involves a process with a lot of large-diameter pipes, or a unit oper-
ating at high pressure or having many small-diameter lines of specialty steel.
By 1949 C.H. Chilton had already published ranges of variations, measured as percentages
of the erected cost of principal equipment, for a number of classifications, such as valves and
piping (10 to 40%), instrumentation (5 to 15%), buildings (0 to 8%), ancillary services (0 to
75%), engineering (30 to 40%), contingencies (10 to 40%), etc. He based his figures on a few
simple characteristics representing the degree of technological advancement or the level of
complexity of the plant concerned.
Subsequently, N.G. Bach and W.E. Hand, and later J.E. Haselbarth and J.E. Berk,
H.E. Bauman, and M.S. Peters and K.D. Timmerhaus,published fluctuation ranges for the coef-
ficients of various elements of the investment; depending on the particular case, and following
the original nomenclature used in the present work, this may be an erected cost, a battery limits
investment, fixed capital, etc. By way of illustration, Tables 3.1 1 and 3.12 present some of the
results obtained by M.S. Peters and K.D. Timmerhaus:the first concernsthe average distribution
of investments directly connected to the production unit and its associated facilities, according
to the kind of product processed (direct costs); the second concerns the variations and average
values for all the various cash flow items that make up the fixed capital (direct and indirect costs).
Solids
by kind of material processed
1 Solids and fluids 1 Fluids
Principal equipment delivered onsite 100 100 100
Erection of principal equipment 45 39 47
Instrumentation and control (erected) 9 13 18
Piping (erected) 16 31 66
Electrical system (erected) 10 10 11
Buildings (including general services) 25 29 18
Site preparation 13 10 10
General services and provision of utilities 40 55 70
Cost of property (if required) 6 6 6
Total direct costs 264 293 346
(Source: McGmw-Hill)
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 27 1
Indirect costs
Engineering and supervision 4.0- 2 1.O 9.1 40
Construction costs 4.8-22.0 10.2 45
Contractor costs 1.5- 5.0 2.1 9
Contingencies 6.0- 18.0 9.3 41
Fixed capital 100.0 439
~~ ~
iource: McGraw-Hill)
From one author to another, there are obvious differences both in the title and in the con-
tent of the categories, and also in the respective weights assigned to them. However, once the
procedures have been edited and normalized, it is possible to see a certain convergence in the
results, and a good overlap in the ranges of variation suggested. This is particularly apparent
when a rearrangement is made on the basis of a distribution such as the one presented in
Fig. 3.15.
more significant than others, that is to say they have a greater influence on the final result. If
we accept a certain loss of precision, for example, to come no closer to the truth than some
predetermined level of correlation (>90%), we can considerably reduce the number of vari-
ables to be investigated. The problem then comes down to finding a way to identify the most
relevant criteria. The tools of modern mathematics and computing, such as principal compo-
nent analysis and factor analysis using a distance table, generally allow us to find answers to
such questions. Obviously, during the preceding decades, when the methods for calculating
production battery limits investments and erected costs were slowly being put together, these
tools were both difficult of access and largely unknown. The identification of the most sig-
nificant parameters thus resulted mainly from a heuristic approach, based on experience.
Among the most representative of these explanatory variables, we may mention the fol-
lowing:
The kind of material employed. The presence of corrosive products requires the use of
sophisticated materials or specialty steels, either for all or part of the equipment itself, or as
internal cladding (reactors, exchangers, etc.). Knowing, for example, that the cost for a unit
weight of AISI type 304 stainless steel is 2.5 to 3 times higher than for a carbon (285 C) steel,
then all other things being equal, we may measure the potential effect on the erected cost of
an apparatus of using the same value for the modified Lang coefficient in both situations. In
fact, by comparison with a standard state where the factor is directly applicable, the more the
kind of material used improves, the smaller the modified Lang factor should be. We can see,
in fact, that for hoisting a carbon steel reactor or a specialty steel equivalent of the same
weight, the hoisting expenses (rental and utilization) are exactly the same. The same is true
for erection: the costs of welding or brazing are similar, in that the expense depends essen-
tially on the time taken by the specialist worker who carries out the operation (working time
and wages practically the same in both cases). Turning this concept into a general rule, most
authors have concluded that the coefficient that relates the value of the principal equipment
to its erected cost should be applied only to the base price of the equipment in carbon steel,
or steel assumed to be so, as long as the equivalent sum for this material is recalculated (for
certain pieces of apparatus, centrifuges for example, the reference may be already be a high-
alloy steel).
The unitproduction capacity. As this increases, experience shows that the cost of second-
ary material, erection expenses, and indirect construction costs do not rise in proportion to the
cost of the principal equipment. In fact, certain items are changed little if at all (instrumenta-
tion, buildings, etc.), others vary somewhat (civil engineering, electrical systems, etc.), and
others do grow, but not proportionately (structures, piping, connections, etc.). By way of
example, if the size of a column is doubled, its price is multiplied by approximately 1.5: the
expense of renting a crane for positioning the two kinds of equipment is the same; handling
costs may be higher for the heavier apparatus, but are still negligible in comparison to the
rental cost. A similar reasoning applies to pipe welding: the larger diameters require more
welding and take longer, but in the long run what counts is the number of jobs that a welder
can complete in a day, and this is effectively the same in both cases. Altogether, when the unit
capacity grows, the modified Lang coefficient should diminish. This is another critical mea-
sure that the authors very quickly adopted in developing their methods.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 273
The severity of operating conditions. The most critical operating parameter is pressure. In
fact, all other things being equal, when it rises from 50 to 200 bars, the thickness of the vessel
concerned must be multiplied by approximately 4: the same applies to weight, and thus to
price. Keeping the same value for the modified Lang factor in both situations leads to an
erected cost four times as large, which is not in accord with reality. In other words, some
items do not vary in proportion to the amount of the principal equipment: this is particularly
true of hoisting charges or connecting expenses, for exactly the same reasons as those men-
tioned above for the other criteria. Consequently, an increase in the severity of operating con-
ditions should be accompanied by a relative reduction in the modified Lang factor. Only the
latest procedures incorporate this concept.
The cost structure ofprincipal equipment. As shown by W.E. Hand, the factors for calcu-
lating the erected costs of different categories of equipment are a function of their nature: gen-
erally speaking, high values for coefficients should be applied to static equipment, but low
ones to rotating machinery. In other words, first of all the data and the calculation itself should
be detailed enough to enable a specific average factor to be applied to each major family of
equipment; then, by comparison with a reference situation, where all the classes of equipment
have the same weight in terms of erected costs, a correction factor can be applied that takes
into account their respective actual contributions to the production battery limits investment.
Certain authors have developed methods that to some extent incorporate these two features.
The oldest approaches make do with only two or three different types of equipment, for exam-
ple by using a series of curves; the latest ones utilize appropriate coefficients and make sys-
tematic “relative size” corrections with respect to a standard situation covering all equipment.
The type of equipment. The influence of this criterion on variations in the modified Lang
factor is certainly much greater than that due to either of the two previous characteristics, on
the respective weights of the various categories of equipment. It arises from considerations
that are similar to those chosen to reflect the kind of material used. In fact, the same family
of equipment, for example, exchangers, may be composed of elements of different types
(condensers, reboilers, cross-flow exchangers with or without phase change, etc.). The mod-
ified Lang coefficient applicable to this group (which is actually a Hand coefficient), is cal-
culated in reference to a standard equipment item (for example, TEMA exchanger type AES).
In practice, the cost of secondary material, erection expenses, and indirect construction costs
are more or less independent of the type of apparatus concerned. In this situation, we must
calculate the equivalent amount for equipment in the same category, not just in the reference
steel (carbon steel), but also in the basic type, and apply the factor for obtaining the erected
cost only to the standardized equipment. The difference between the actual figure and the
total used for calculation is added at the end. If we apply the same procedure when consider-
ing the severity of use of the equipment, we can see that this difference represents a sort of
“complexity increment”. This approach is employed in the majority of current methods, par-
ticularly the ones used in commercial software.
The list of criteria to be considered could certainly be extended; nevertheless, a compro-
mise has to be found between improvement of the level of accuracy on one hand, and on the
other, the accessibility of information, which rapidly becomes pointless and devoid of inter-
est. In fact, the main qualities expected of a procedure are that it should be both easy to apply
274 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
and flexible. This latter characteristic is particularly popular with engineering companies,
who use analogy methods as a preliminary to consultations, which are often very time-con-
suming, and which also employ a very high level of detail. In line with the French saying: “he
who can do most, may do least”, they prefer to utilize the means at their disposal, rather than
waste them; in this case, when the corresponding data are not available, the procedure must
nevertheless be capable of application, using, by default, the standard values.
Apart from W.E. Hand, who had already raised the question, among those who paid particular
attention to this matter we must first of all mention J. Clerk. In the method he recommends,
he suggests that for each major category of apparatus comprising the principal equipment
(columns, exchangers, pumps, compressors, furnaces, instruments), a graph be constructed
with, on the y-axis, a factor for converting it to the corresponding erected cost (including indi-
rect costs, but excluding engineering), and, on the x-axis, the kind of material utilized. The
value of the independent variable is determined by comparing the price of a piece of equip-
ment constructed in a given stainless steel or some other specialty material, to the price of the
same apparatus if made from carbon steel. Accompanying tables provide examples of the rel-
ative costs of vessels, exchangers, and centrifugal pumps; in some cases, corrections are pre-
sented to take into account the effect of thickness.
J.T. Callagher should also be mentioned: he returned to this approach to enable a rapid
evaluation of the impact of using corrosive reagents on the economics of a system.
Furnaces and compressors among other items are not discussed. It is true that quoted
prices (or published information) for such equipment very often concerns erected costs,
To equipment made from carbon steel.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 275
tion and connection expenses are not included in the delivered price, and which are, conse-
quently, not explicitly known. This equipment includes items that, because of their relatively
small size, arrive onsite pre-assembled, but still need additional adjustments, as well as ones
that, because of their large size, require onsite assembly.
0 B concerns the equipment whose erection, positioning, and connection costs are included
in the onsite delivery price. At the time when the authors were developing their procedure,
these were mainly furnaces, sometimes compressors, and some intermediate storage; today,
when the unit capacity of plants has very greatly increased, this possibility has almost disap-
peared, which usually comes down to using B = 0.
0 C is the additional price that arises from the use of specialty steels in the manufacture of
certain equipment. It represents the difference between the actual cost of the equipment to be
assembled, and the cost, A, of this same equipment if it were made from carbon steel.
0 E is a coefficient, near 1.4, which reflects the “indirect costs”. J.P. O’Donnel suggested a
more accurate way to determine this factor. In the nomenclature used hitherto, the ratio I/E
corresponds to the definition given earlier for the production battery limits investment I1,
which explains the modifier “total” added to the description of I in the previous equation.
FL, Fp, and FM are obtained from empirical equations that contain, on the one hand, the
value of A itself, and on the other, the ratios to the cost A of the cost of exchangers in carbon
steel (e),the cost of vessels assembled onsite cf)l, the cost of pumps and motors (p), and the
cost of columns, or more precisely the tank shells alone (t).
1. Columns and reactors with diameters greater than 4 m, excepting very high pressure, multiple
bed reactors.
276 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
When the value of the equipment is expressed in thousands of dollars, we obtain the fol-
lowing equations:
logloFL= 0.635 - 0.154 logloA - 0.992 (e/A)+ 0.506 ( f / A )
logloFp= 4 . 2 6 6 - 0.014 logloA - 0.156 (e/A)+ 0.556 @ / A )
FM = 0.344 + 0.033 logloA + 1.194 ( t / A )
FL, F p , and FM may also be obtained directly by using the graphs in Figs. 3.16a, 3.16b,
and 3.16c, expressed in thousands of dollars for the year 1957.
The method of Hirsch and Glazier allows corrections to be made to the modified Lang fac-
tor for the effects of the kind of material used, by means of C, and of the unit manufacturing
capacity and the relative weight of certain categories of equipment, by means of FL, F p , and
FM, which depend on the value of A, and thus on the size of the plant.
0 Piping
0 Electrical systems
0 Instrumentation
0 Other buildings.
When the average cost of the representative component rises, i.e., when we go from the
lowest price brackets to the highest ones, the value of the percentages and consequently the
multiplying factors diminishes: this approach allows us to see the effect of capacity. In fact,
since the intervals that could be assigned to these factors were relatively wide, Miller endeav-
ored to improve the accuracy of his method by defining various possible cases for each item,
which allowed him to make a more detailed breakdown.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 277
exchangers
_t_ I vessels assembled onsite
basic principal equipment A , basic principal equipment
,- 0.2
- -- -- P
L
0.4 I
0.6
0
AL
0.2
0.4
0.6
FM 1.2
0.8
0.4
Table 3.13 illustrates this method for the calculation of the expenses attributable to foun-
dations and structures, an item offering four possibilities. The same approach is used for the
other items; certain slight differences are sometimes introduced, particularly for building
costs. In this way, by adding the results obtained for the various items, we can determine the
manufacturing battery limits investment.
The method also allows us to obtain the total expenses required for general services, and
the provision of utilities and storage. Here the basis for calculation is no longer the principal
equipment, but the production battery limits investment. A distinction must be made between
plants set up on pre-existing industrial sites and those constructed on new sites (“grassroots”
units), for which the “offsite” portion is necessarily higher.
It must be recalled that in practice Miller’s method presents only ranges of percentage, and
that, where it is not possible to make a choice, the calculation actually provides extreme val-
ues of the partial or total multiplying factors obtained by addition (the modified Lang factor).
The author therefore recommends immediately adding 10% to the lowest figure, and deduct-
ing 10% from the highest one. The Lang factor is thus situated within a smaller range, whose
most probable intermediate value is not-unless by a lucky chance-the arithmetic mean of
the upper and lower limits.
One of the main attractions of this procedure is that it immediately provides results
together with their confidence limits. But it is very demanding of the user’s industrial expe-
rience, which makes it harder to apply, and thereby reduces its impact.
Table 3.1 3 Multiplying factors (in %) for obtaining production battery limits investments.
Example: the item “foundations and structures”. Method of C.A. Miller.
which are generally established under the assumption that carbon steel is used.
The method described by Guthrie can equally well be applied to calculating manufacturing
battery limits investments, or those for general services and storage, or even to determining
the various supplementary expenses required for grassroots plants.
For this purpose, it comprises six “modules” within the total investment: five are related
to “direct costs”, the last to “indirect costs”. They are:
0 For “direct costs”:
0 Standard chemical equipment, i.e., for the principal equipment: furnaces, exchangers,
vertical vessels, pumps and their drives, compressors, built-in storage; for the secondary
material: piping, foundations, steel structures, instrumentation, electrical systems, ther-
mal insulation, and painting
0 Solids handling, i.e., for the principal equipment: mills, mixers, centrifuges, conveyors,
crushers, dryers, evaporators, filters, hydraulic presses, sieves, hoppers, equipment for
hoisting and transport; for the secondary material: piping, foundations, steel structures,
instrumentation, and electrical systems
Site development: the property purchase including the costs of topographic surveying
and fees, dewatering and drainage, clearing, excavations, earthmoving, sewers, fencing
and pilings, roadways, footbridges, parking lots, landscaping, walls, firefighting equip-
ment
0 Industrial buildings: offices, laboratories, community health services, shops, ware-
0 Ancillary services: steam and electricity generation and their distribution systems, cool-
ing towers and the circulation system for this water, distribution systems for liquid and
gaseous fuels, blow-downs and blow-offs, pollution control facilities, fire hydrants,
purification and settling tanks, lighting and telecommunication systems, storage for
receiving and shipping (trucks, railroad, boats: platforms and docks).
COMMENT
In contrast to the approach followed in the methods considered hitherto, where the
principal equipment constituted a non-dissociable whole for reference purposes,
Guthrie distinguishes two major types of equipment, which he treats separately.
The five modules of “direct costs” include not only the expenses for equipment (principal
and secondary), but also the erection and connection costs. They consequently give us the
erected costs.
0 For “indirect costs”:
0 Freight, tax, and insurance
0 Indirect construction costs (profit margins, welfare costs, site supervision, temporary
This allows us to determine, for a known exchange surface, the “price” of an exchanger:
0 With floating head
0 In carbon steel
Reboiler
Floating head
U-tube 0.85
Fixed tube sheet 0.80
(Sources: Crajsman, Chem. Eng.)
<I50 0.00
150-300 0.10
300- 400 0.25
400- 800 0.52
800- 1000 0.55
282 3. The Determination of Battery Limits lnvestments
Exchange
surface CSI CSI stainless1 CSI MoneY Ti/
CSITi
(sq ft) Mo stainless stainless Monel Monel Ti
400 1.60 1.54 2.50 2.00 3.20 4.10 10.28
100-500 1.75 1.78 3.10 2.30 3.50 5.20 10.60
500- 1000 1.82 2.25 3.26 2.50 3.65 6.15 10.75
1000-5 000 1.30 2.15 2.81 3.75 3.10 4.25 8.95 13.05
5 000- 10000 2.50 3.52 450.00 3.75 4.95 11.10 16.60
Erection
Set-up.
0 Indirect costs (freight, insurance, and tax; indirect construction costs; engineering).
Table 3.1 5 Method of K.M. Guthrie. Factors for determining the gross module cost
for tube-type heat exchangers, in % of principal equipment cost
I
Direct construction costs 61.2 60.1 59.4 59.0
erection 55.4 54.7 54.2 53.9 53.8
set-up 63.0 7.6 6.5 5.9 5.5 5.2
Direct costs of equipment and labor I 234.4 231.7 230.0 228.9 228.3
I
Indirect costs(') 86.8 83.9 83.5 81.0
freight, insurance, tax 8.0 8.0 8.0 8.0 8.0
other 94'7 86.7 78.8 75.9 75.5 73.0
Gross module cost I 329.1 318.5 I 313.9 I I 312.4 I 1 309.3 I
(1) Unlike other factors, which are the result of direct statistical compilation, the indirect cost coefficients are given by a particular formula that is shown under the cor-
responding module.
(Sources: Craftsman, Chem. Eng.)
284 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
The sum of the direct and indirect costs constitutes the “gross module cost”. If necessary,
by adding contingencies and contractor costs, we obtain the “total module cost”. The result
obtained from these tables assumes that only reference equipment is utilized. To allow for the
complexity of the equipment actually employed, and the kind of materials really used in their
manufacture, and also for updating, the author defined a “final module cost”, calculated as
follows:
final module cost = updated gross module cost, for carbon steel
+ standard base cost (corrected for type, operating conditions,
and materials) and updated
- uncorrected base cost, updated.
Table 3.1 6 Method of K.M. Guthrie. Determination of the gross module cost for special equipment
Factor for
Kind of cost Labor/
Extrapolation direct cost
Equipment unit of unit equipment
factor of equipment
Barameter 3arameter ($) ratio
and labor
Crushers:
cone ton/hr 750 0.85 1.57 0.23
gyratory tonnu 55 1.20 1.57 0.23
jaw ton/hr 85 1.20 1.57 0.25
pulverizers Ibh 520 0.35 1.59 0.25
Crystallizers:
maturing tonlday 5 500 0.65 1.75 0.38
forced circulation todday 7 900 0.55 1.75 0.38
batch gall 170 0.70 1.60 0.26
(Sources: Craffsman, Chem. Eng.)
In fact, the coefficients come either from direct consideration of the installation require-
ments for the unit concerned, or from formulas that involve the direct costs of the equipment
and the labor.
Thus, for the three main items that make up the module, the author suggests the following
approach:
The transport, tax, and insurance costs are strongly dependent on the place where the units
are installed; in particular, they are a function of the proximity of the factories manufacturing
the equipment, of existing tax provisions and incentives, and the risks incurred. It is conse-
quently impossible to give a precise rule for determining the expenses for this item. For facil-
ities in the United States, or more generally in industrialized countries, Guthrie reckons them
at 8% of the cost of principal equipment.
0 Indirect site costs are calculated from the following expression:
Indirect construction costs in mid-1968 $ = direct costs of equipment and labor
in mid-1968 $ x 0.178 x F,, x F,, x (update)
F,, is a correction factor based on the labodequipment ratio:
F,, reflects the size of the direct cost of equipment and labor:
Direct cost of equipment and labor 1 3 5 7 10
(mid-1968 $ million)
Fmo 1.07 1.02 1.0 0.97 0.95
286 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
Fptis a function of the type of unit concerned: 1.4 for chemical complexes; 1.O for com-
mon chemical facilities; 0.8 for mits processing solids and liquids; 0.6 for those processing
solids, and 0.4 for buildings.
The indirect site and engineering costs are then expressed in percentages of the cost of the
principal equipment.
The above analysis of the three modules of Guthrie’s method focuses on the increased
accuracy that it can offer. When it is fully applied, it more closely resembles estimation tech-
niques than those used in preliminary evaluation; in such a context it no doubt requires some
simplification, and this is what the approach developed by the IFP is intended to do, using
factorial procedures (see Section 3.3).
However, we should point out that the validity of the method essentially depends on the
reliability of the curves used to determine the base prices of equipment (CEFs). Now, it is
impossible to summarize on a single graph, using a few correction factors, all the costs that
are actually applied to a whole category of equipment. For this reason, it seems best to apply
this method either directly to prices obtained from discussions with manufacturers, or by
using a more detailed set of curves.
Roughly speaking, L, and L, cover both the erection and connection costs, as well as the
site costs.
The total costs (i)give the equipment battery limits investment for a complete installed
unit, which is equivalent to I1under the breakdown and nomenclature used earlier.
0 The purchase price E for the principal equipment is obtained from graphs, compiled for
each category of equipment and containing one or more curves, based on a representative size
parameter. Among the equipment included we find traditional items such as columns, tanks,
compressors, pumps, exchangers, etc., as well as components intended mainly for handling
solids, such as filters, cyclones, centrifuges, conveyors, dryers, etc. The independent vari-
ables, depending on the particular case, are power, surface area, throughput, sizes, volume,
etc. The mathematical expressions describing these curves are of the form:
The price M of the commodity material is deducted from the cost of the principal equip-
ment E, either by applying an overall coefficient C, or by adding up the results obtained in
the same way by applying the partial factors ci,in particular for foundations and civil engi-
neering, piping, steel structures, instrumentation, thermal insulation, electrical systems, and
painting, i.e.:
M = E C C=~E . C
As an illustration of this, Table 3.17 gives the values suggested by the authors for some items
of equipment.
Table 3.1 7 Method of 1.V Klumpar and S.T. Slavsky. Cost factors for secondary material
--
1 I
Zentrifuge Conveyoi :yclone hyer Wtei Cxchanger Column Zompressot
--
Foundations c1 9 12 2 9 13 9.0 11 6
Civil
engineering
Piping c2 25 - 9 10 59 49.0 55 20
Steel c3 10 25 22 10 15 7.0 9 7
structures
Instruments c4 10 7 4 6 5 6
Thermal c5 4 - 10 - - 3
insulation
Electricity c6 27 20 47 20 10 26
Painting c7 1 1 1 1 5 0.5 1
--
Total C 86 I 65 95 56
--
107 79.0 103 69
(Source: Chem. Eng.)
288 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
The cost L, of setting up the principal equipment is given by the following equation:
L , = E . H e . (pg/p). we
where L, and E are defined as before, and the other parameters are respectively:
He: the setting-up factor for the equipment concerned, expressed in hours of work per $100
of principal equipment
Pg:the relative productivity factor for the geographic area considered
p: the productivity factor for the reference area (Southern California, mid- 1984), arbi-
trarily set to 1
we:the hourly cost of setting up the principal equipment under the reference conditions,
expressed in dollars per hour worked.
0 The cost L, of installing the commodity material is obtained from the following expres-
sion:
L, = Me (pg/p) . C (h,j . w,j)
in which
L,, M, andp are defined as before
hMjrepresentsthe number of hours worked per $100 of commodity material, as required
by the involvement of a given trade i in installing the ancillary equipment necessary
for the operation of a component of the principal equipment
wCiis the average wage cost in the reference situation, expressed in dollars per hour
worked, for the trade i.
This expression can be simplified by employing the overall average values for all the dif-
ferent trades: it then takes the following form:
L , = M . H M . ( p g / p ) .W
where H M = ChMjand W = the average hourly cost of all the trades involved. If we now return
to the principal equipment, the preceding equations become:
and:
since on the one hand: M=E.C
and on the other we take: hMj= hEjlC
or: HM=HEIC
In this case, hEi represents the number of hours worked per $100 of principal equipment,
as required by the involvement of a given trade i in installing the ancillary equipment neces-
sary for the operation of a component of the principal equipment, and HE= ChEj. Table 3.18
gives an outline of the values of these factors for various pieces of equipment. Among the
problems that may arise in applying Klumpar and Slavsky's procedure is that of obtaining the
relative productivity values, and the hourly costs of services. To address this, the authors sug-
gest that the calculation may be simplified by using the following expressions:
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 289
L e = E . D e and L c = E . D ~
in which De and DEare factors, expressed directly in dollars per $100 of principal equipment,
relative on the one hand to the setting up of an apparatus, and on the other hand to the execu-
tion of ancillary civil engineering, erection, and connection work. Obviously, this simplifica-
tion takes a toll on the accuracy of the results, even though the coefficients in $/$ are not
affected by the effects of currency inflation, in contrast to those expressed in hours worked/$,
since in this case inflation does not act equally on both elements of the ratio. Table 3.18 also
provides examples of the values of these factors.
Table 3.1 8 Method of 1.V Klumpar and S.T. Slavsky. Cost factors for installing principal equipment
and secondary material. Southern California, mid- 1984
:
h v)
.
8e
I
W
.
a
M
e
I ie 2
E!
.n
$
8 .
I
h c)
k a
n
.I
> H
I e
.
u
I
8
4
- -
Factor hEl hE2 hE3 hE4 hE7 He DE De
- -
Centrifuge 0.4 0.9 0.4 0.4 0.2 1.0 0.0 3.3 0.5 50.5 10.1
Column 0.5 2.5 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.1 4.5 0.5 70.3 8.7
Compressor 0.2 0.8 0.3 0.4 0.1 1.0 0.0 2.8 0.2 44.1 3.6
Conveyor 0.9 0.0 1.5 0.3 0.0 1.3 0.1 4.1 0.8 61.0 15.1
Crystallizer 0.4 1.4 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.0 3.3 0.4 51.5 7.6
Cyclone 0.2 1.9 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 2.9 0.4 46.0 8.2
Exchanger(') 0.3 1.7 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.0 2.8 0.1 43.9 0.9
Evaporator(2) 0.8 7.8 0.1 1.2 0.2 0.0 0.0 10.1 0.5 160.0 9.0
Filted3) 0.5 2.9 0.4 0.4 0.0 0.3 0.1 4.6 0.4 73.0 7.4
Pump(4) 0.2 1.6 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.9 0.0 2.8 0.6 45.0 9.9
Dryer 1.1 0.9 0.9 0.5 0.0 1.7 0.1 5.2 0.7 79.6 13.0
Blower 0.4 0.0 0.7 0.2 0.1 0.7 0.0 2.1 0.2 31.6 3.0
Fan 0.4 0.0 0.5 0.2 0.0 0.9 0.0 2.0 0.5 29.6 9.6
(I): with tubular shell and bundle. (2): with long vertical shell and tubes. (3): rotary, with pump, larger than 10 m:
(4): centrifugal,rotary, or geared.
(Source: Chem. Eng.)
290 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
COMMENTS
0To remain consistent with the observations in Section 2.3.2.3 of Chapter 2, if the
location effect is the subject of an overall adjustment, there is no need to correct for
productivity when looking at the setting up of equipment, or at civil engineering,
erection, or connection.
0 However, the suggested method of calculation does allow for a better distinction
to be made, if intermediate situations should require it, between local labor and out-
side personnel.
where
fp is the initial piping coefficient
f IP the modified piping coefficient
A the cost of the equipment in carbon steel
X the actual cost of the equipment.
internally, to provide answers to very specific requests for the comparison of processes, or of
variants of the same technology.
Without claiming to be exhaustive, we can identify two kinds of commercial tools in the
area of evaluation:
0 Chemical engineering software. These programs have the common characteristic of pro-
viding a compact means for sizing the principal equipment. Some of them also enable the
costing of equipment, even a complete economic calculation. Examples of this are “Aspen
Plus” from Aspen Technology, and “Process” from Simulation Science Inc. (SIMSCI).
According to available information the new version of “Process”, called PROAI (with PROAI
Provision) only provides sizing for some equipment. Prosim SA’s “Prosim” goes as far as
providing quotes for principal equipment; Belsim SA, with its “Simu 11” and “Vali 11” stops
at sizing.
Cost calculation software. Some of these are specific to types of equipment, especially in
the United States. Among the ones that can handle the full range of principal equipment we
may single out PDQS and Icarus:
0 PDQS (Price and Delivery Quoting Service), marketed by PDQS Inc., is a relatively
low-cost software program that enables the cost of equipment to be evaluated, as long as
there is a rough and ready preliminary sizing, or a way to approximate the result of the
estimation calculation by specifying the program’s default parameters. In addition, in
this case, the source of the information is given.
0 Icarus (Investigating Costs and Reliability in Utility Systems), from Icarus Corporation,
is a relatively expensive software program that offers a complete range of options, from
sizing of equipment right up to the final economic calculation. However, the user is
expected to provide certain basic data.
3.3.1 BACKGROUND
In the course of their regular activities, evaluators will in future have to face two very differ-
ent kinds of situation:
Either they will work at their offices, and in this case will have access to all the computing
assistance they may need. The advances made in this area in recent years enable them to
employ very elaborate models and sophisticated methods, especially ones based on solid
databases and very detailed correlations (CEFs).
Or they will be located far from their usual working base, with no proper computing facil-
ities at their disposal, and nevertheless be obliged to provide an outline of a budget envelope.
In this case, a pocket calculator alone, a few graphs, or just their experience must suffice to
produce an answer.
292 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
In the first case, like most organizations currently engaged in evaluation, IFP usually
employs existing commercial software. It is necessary to observe, however, that these instru-
ments do not always give satisfaction, especially when it is a matter of considering equipment
that has only recently been industrialized, or that has been significantly improved in the last
few years in terms of productivity, size, design, etc. In addition, it must be admitted that the
early tools tend to be preferred, because they are easier to learn about and have a track record,
over the more popular, widely used pieces of equipment. Now, we are currently seeing a dou-
ble evolution, which first of all concerns mass-market products, whose standards are chang-
ing, with the aim of bringing new kinds of equipment to market (plate exchangers, turbines,
falling film evaporators, etc.); on the other hand there is a general tendency in the equipment
field that is directed more towards a greater degree of specialization and increased sophisti-
cation (multiphase reactors, multiphase pumps, simulated counter-current adsorption, etc.).
To address these two concerns, it is necessary, in the first place, to keep up the traditional
evaluating system (based on the use of CEFs), and to update it, if need be, as new generations
of standardized equipment appear. In addition, we must acquire the means to determine the
investments generated by the use of specialized equipment, in other words to employ mathe-
matical models of costs. While taking action on the first point, it may be possible to draw up
a list of the advances in the field, given that it is an instrument developed in-house, but it is
much more tricky to provide a detailed description of the procedures applied in the second
case, since that involves using commercial software.
In a field situation, without any support, only exponential methods can provide any relief.
In these circumstances we must endeavor to preserve the elements that give them their main
attraction and their special nature, i.e., their simplicity of application and especially their min-
imal requirements concerning data, namely:
A general diagram of the plant
0 An overall material balance
In this section, we will simply describe the principal operating rules on which this method is
based. All the information for actually applying it, in its current state of development, is laid
out in full detail in Appendix A1 .
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 293
The term module covers not just the basic equipment essential for the physico-chemical
operation concerned, but also all the peripheral equipment.Thus a distillationmodule includes:
the column itself, the reflw tank, the condenser, the re-boiler, the reflw and feed pumps, and,
if necessary, the exchangers for preheating the feed and the complementary cooling of the dis-
tillate and draw-off. A plant diagram may comprise several distillation modules in series. The
same principal applies to all the other parts of the unit.
The method developed by the IFP more specifically addresses the study of the following
modules: reaction, compression, distillation, crystallization, and evaporation, as well as ancil-
lary operations designed to make certain calculations easier (such as the conversion of a
weight material balance into its molar equivalent).
The approach used for finding the cost of the various kinds of modules is based, like most
other methods, on the collection and mathematical and statistical processing of information
of a historical nature. After confirmation against known examples, the correlations obtained
are applied to new cases. What is really different about the method used here has to do with
the vast possibilities now offered by computerization, which makes it easy to perform princi-
pal component analysis, factor analysis using a distance table, and multiple linear regression.
Under these circumstances it becomes possible in principle to consider all the variables that
may be involved in a cost determination, without even having to be concerned about their
interactions. The object of the exercise is then to rank them, and select only the most relevant
ones, i.e., the ones that have a decisive effect on the cost. In practice, this amounts to keeping
only a minimum number, as long as they allow an estimate of the true value that satisfies a
pre-selected correlation level, for example above 90%. Moreover, so that the method shall be
as simple to apply as possible, these parameters must be easily available or, if they are not,
they must be made easy to estimate by some calculating or graphic device.
To illustrate this approach, it is best to look at its application to a particular module: the
relatively complex distillation module seems the obvious choice. The first step consists of
assembling the largest possible sampling of unprocessed data, i.e., information in whatever
form it is available, and covering all the physical parameters involved in a “distillation”,
namely 25 variables including the cost. To ensure that the method is universally applicable,
a representative number of samples must be collected (more than 900 in this case), and they
must cover the various fields (straight-chain alkanes from C1 to (220, branched alkanes, ole-
fins from C2 to C,, diolefins, acetylene compounds, cycloparaffins and cyclo-olefins, alco-
hols, chloroparaffins, aromatics, carbon monoxide and dioxide, hydrogen, water, nitrogen,
acetic acid and acetates, hydrogen sulfide, acetone, ammonia).
Processing this raw information by principal component analysis, i.e., by orthogonal projec-
tion on a plane, did not at first bring out a principal axis, in other words a particular axis along
which the projected images of the points representing the samples in a 25-dimensional space
have a tendency to cluster. To achieve this, the data had to be modified. Experiments having
shown that the kind of material employed was the variable with the strongest influence on cost,
it was decided to homogenize the data set being processed by recalculating the ones correspond-
ing to alloy steel into their equivalent in carbon steel. This time, the analysis of this mixed sam-
ple group, composed of items that are either natural or artificial, led to the identificationof a first
principal axis, then a second one at right angles, in other words a principal plane defined by
these two axes. During this operation, it proved necessary to drop a certain number of samples
for lack of information: the total for the remaining group was reduced to about 600 samples.
294 3. The Determination of Batrery Limits Investments
The resulting factor analysis using a distance table enabled the most relevant ones to be
selected: the ends of the 25 unit vectors were projected along the line defined by the origin of
the 25-dimensional space and the origin of the two principal axes, into a circle of radius 1
(Fig. 3.17). In this case, the selection involved keeping only the ones whose unit vector pro-
jections fell closest to the first principal axis and, whether on the positive or negative side,
closest to the circumference of the circle. The pre-selected correlation level was achieved
with only four variables (pressure, content of lights in the feed, output, and relative volatility).
f Unitvectors
The last stage consisted of defining a linear regression, which had the following from:
In (cost) = 4.3588 + 0.5848 x In (DEDIST)
+ 0.7540 x In [In (VORM)] - 0.3477 x In (XLEC) - 0.1138 x In (PTE)
where
(DEDIST) is the molar output of distillate
(VORM) is the average relative volatility
(XLEC) is the proportion of light constituents in the feed
(PTE) is the pressure.
Such equations can also be expressed in graphic form (Fig. 3.18).
D
f- 50000.0
50000.0:
100.0- - -
-- -
- 20000.0- - 20000.0
-
50.0- C Separation
10000.0-
- -
- - 10000.0
20.0- very difficult 5000.01
-
- - 5000.0
10.0--
-
2000.0- IA-X-B 1
-
-
difficult
/C-Y-D I
-
5.0-
1ow.o=
-
-
-
- 2000.0 lx-2-Y I
m.0-
- 1.75 -
- Material factors
2.0-
-- 1000.0
- -
200.0 -
A - SA 203
1.o 1.0- 100.0 1 -500.0 304 stainless -1.57
--- - 316 stainless -1.99
Pressure
0.75
50.0 7 -
0.5 -
20.0-
-
-200.0
. 150.0
! Erection factor
ISBL -3.39
20.0
50.0 10.0 1
-
-
0.25 Relative
volatility 5.0 -
-
Distillate
' Basecost
(FF 000: Feb. '85)
0.1
Percentage
of lights
0.05 in the feed
(molar X)
Figure 3.1 8 Graphical presentation of the linear regression. Example: distillation module.
Method of functional modules. (Source: ZFP)
296 3. The Determination of Battery Limits hvestments
COMMENTS
In view of the results, one may doubt whether the values of the parameters can be
easily obtained. In practice some changes need to be made, if we are to answer the
initial desire for a simple tool that is easy to apply:
0 The conversion of an overall weight material balance, covering a plant, into more
detailed balances, confined to each module, can be performed in an approximate way
by first considering the assumed yield of a chemical conversion or an equivalent sep-
aration; we then only have to identify the light ends, and make the arbitrary assump-
tion that it is roughly equivalent to a separation into a binary mixture, with a 100%
yield, ignoring impurities. In this approach, an azeotrope is treated like a pure con-
stituent.
We can go from a weight material balance to its molar equivalent by using an aux-
iliary graphic, based on the molecular weights of the constituents of a stream, and its
approximate assumed composition.
0 The content (molar percentage) of light constituents in the feed can be obtained
graphic allows the actual value to be used when it is known, or to make an estimation
by indicating whether the distillation is more or less difficult to perform. To assist
the user in doing this, an auxiliary table provides some significant examples
(Table 3.19).
The graphic gives an un-erected cost for the module, assumed to be in carbon steel. To
obtain the final cost, it is necessary to apply a multiplying factor, which in the case of distil-
lation is 3.39, to which is added an increment that depends on the kind of steel actually used
(for example, 1.57 for 304 stainless).
There is a similar approach for each type of module, and an equivalent regression, so that
the production battery limits investment may be found by adding up the results thereby
obtained.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 297
The accuracy of the method, in comparison with more sophisticatedprocedures such as the
ones based on the systematic application of multiplying factors, is f 15%. Its interest to some
extent lies in providing a compromise between the extrapolation procedures, and those based
on defining cost estimation formulas (CEFs).
Its major drawback is that, in spite of everything, it demands a certain amount of practice
and knowledge in the field of industrial engineering.
Using a graph showing the cost of the equipment as a function of the value of its dimensional
parameter ((Fig. 3.19) for tube-type heat exchangers), and under very specific conditions:
0 European Union mid-2000 €, tax-free, ex-factory
0 Standard material: in the example selected, we specifically assume that the shell and the
tubes are of carbon steel, the apparatus is of TEMA type AES, the operating pressure is
no greater than 10 bar, etc.,
it is then possible to assign a so-called base price to each exchange surface:
and the corresponding real prices (PR)are obtained from the base prices (PB)by using a set
of correction factors cf;), such that:
PReal =PBase *fi‘k!... ’ f p
’ ’
1 000000
100000
i
L
w
10 000
;
I
E
I
c
0
I
h
1 000
1 10 100 lo00
Exchange surface (m2)
The values to be assigned to these factors are obtained from Tables 3.20a through 3.20g.
COMMENTS
Not all of the correction factors have the same weight: some have a much stronger
influence on the final result than others. In the case of tube-type heat exchangers, we
can see that three of them make a decisive contribution: the kind of material utilized,
and the type and pressure of operation.
This approach already allows us to judge one of the goals of the suggested method,
which is to be flexible and to be capable of dealing with the greatest possible variety
of situations. In the case of tube-type heat exchangers, when all the equipment is
specified and their characteristics are known (as with an engineering company), the
procedure may be applied in full, by giving each correction factor its corresponding
value. When a preliminary (evaluation) study is concerned, where it would be an illu-
sion to expect every detail to be available, it is sufficient to try to roughly estimate
only two or three of the coefficients, and to adopt a value of 1 for the others.
After making this preliminary calculation, we now have the total actual and base prices of
the exchangers. Obtaining the erected cost for the “exchanger” category is done by using a
reference assembly factor& exchangers, which can if necessary be corrected, using the proce-
dures to be described in Section 3.3.3.3. This applies to the total base prices. To this we add
the difference between the totals of the real and base prices, in other words a complexity
increment that is not affected by the erection.
300 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
Pressure
(bar) Tubes Tubes and shell
1.oo 1.oo
10 1.07 1.12
20 1.17 1.29
30 1.27 1.48
40 1.45 1.81
65 1.63 2.13
85 2.03 2.85
130 3.25 3.25
- ~~
(Source: IFP)
f. Effect of temperature
I Temperature ("C) I ft I
t < 350 1.oo
350 < t < 550 1.08
1.00 1.50 2.00 2.10 2.80 2.40 3.45 4.80 5.80 13.00
lOO<S< 1000 1.00 1.65 2.45 2.25 3.06 2.40 3.55 5.30 5.80 13.00
Cu:brass. Mo: molybdenum steel. Ti: titanium
(Source: IFP)
If:
-
C A exchangers - PRexchangers
-
'
PBexchangers
We obtain:
Since this calculation can be extended to every category of principal equipment, and as
long as we have the corresponding erection factors, we thus obtain:
corrected + C A
pBcol"ms . fgcolums
corrected + ...
0 A real price, calculated from the base price by using correction factors obtained from
Centrifugal
Pumps and
Pressure vessels Heat exchangers compressors(*) Furnaces
drives
Type of equipment
100
Tube-type
100
Air-cooler
100 100
and drives
100
reaction
100
heating
100
Secondary material vms) 103 63 78 50 56 48 43 42
piping and valves 60 40 45 14 23 17 19 17
civil engineering 10 6 5 2 3 10 11 11
steel structures 8 - 10 20 - - 7 7
instrumentation 11 6 10 4 2 7 4 5
electrical equipment 5 5 2 9 25 11 2 2
thermal insulation 8 5 5 - 2 2 - -
painting 1 1 1 1 1 1 - -
Erection 97 58 60 29 64 54 36 35
Indirect site costs v;) 105 77 84 62 77 70 62 62
Total 405 298 322 24 1 297 272 24 1 239
Multiplying factor v,) 4.05 !.98 3.22 2.41 2.97 2.72 2.41 2.39
(1) Plate assembly included.
(2) For reciprocating compressors the factor& is 2.95. The items to be increased are piping (reduction of vibration and hammering), civil engineering (more massive
foundations), and erection.
(Source: IFP)
w
s
304 3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments
Equipment Coefficient&
Agitators 1.85
Mills 2.00
Centrifuges 1.80
Conveyors 1.90
Crystallizers 2.00
Steam ejectors 1.20
Evaporators 2.25
Filters 2.00
Dryers 2.00
Vibrating screens 1.50
1.2
1.1
z
c
8
4.0
.2
0.9
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
COMMENTS
0 The family of curves is defined for a particular date, so that the real reference
prices-for which& takes the value 1 for every category of equipment, when they
have the same weight-vary over time as a function of the depreciation of the cur-
rency. This graph must therefore be updated periodically.
3. The Determination of Battery Limits Investments 305
The fact that f, is calculated from real prices and not from base prices must be
underlined.
0 The variation of the correction factor is represented by:
The procedure described here applies not only to the determination of battery limits invest-
ments for manufacturing or processing, but also to determining the costs of producing utilities
and constructing storage. The principle is the same: it is based on knowing the base and real
prices of the principal equipment for these two types of plant, which can be obtained from
curves and adjustment coefficients presented in an appendix. Then, we have only to apply the
erection factors& from Table 3.23 to the base prices, and if necessary correct them by usingf,,
taken from Fig. 3.19 as a function of the real prices of the categories of equipment concerned.
Table 3.23 Coefficients (f,) for converting the cost of complete equipment
to battery limits investments, for utility and storage production
Equipment Coefficient&
~~
Steam generation:
package boiler 1.50
erected boiler 1.60
Electricity generation 1.40
Cooling towers 1.50
Refrigeration 1.40
Storage tanks:
<I50 m3 1.65
>I50 m3 2.00
Pressurized storage:
horizontal 1.40
spherical 1.85
Source: IFP)
0 Most specialized equipment has moving parts: they tend to belong more to the rotating
system class than the static equipment one. Now, as W.E. Hand showed, the modified
Lang factor is smaller in this case.
0 The maximum unit processing capacities are relatively limited for methods involving
diffusion, hydrodynamics, etc. In other words, this kind of equipment can generally be
pre-erected in the workshops of the company that designed it. When it reaches the con-
struction site, it needs only to be positioned and connected.
0 In matters of wear, maintenance, reliability, etc., the standard of reference for special-
ized equipment represents to a more elaborate product than is the case for static devices.
The kind of material employed is often superior (stainless steel); the electrical systems
for operation, measurement, and control are more sophisticated.
Assigning a higher erection coefficient to static equipment only means that it has a greater
weight in the evaluation of site costs, and consequently, that more attention should be paid to
determining its contribution. This is the main reason why a much more detailed breakdown
of its constituent headings was given in Table 3.21, when describing this process. The sec-
ondary material, erection, and indirect construction costs are shown separately, and can be
adjusted by changing their respective sizes according to the conditions encountered: for
example, the principal equipment and the secondary material may in some cases be imported,
while the site labor is local. Going even further, the secondary material heading is broken up
into piping, civil engineering, steel structures, instrumentation,electrical equipment, thermal
insulation, and painting. Doing this makes it possible to work on each item by changing, if
need be, the value of the coefficient that was initially indicated, when it is known that it cor-
responds to a plant that was set up in typical average conditions. To illustrate this possibility,
two examples can be cited
The case of a plant constructed on marshy ground: instead of pouring a concrete slab at
ground level, which is the hypothesis selected for the suggested reference figures, it will
be necessary to place it on shell or ram piles. This requires a correction, which can be
performed by multiplying the standard value by the ratio of the cost of one m2 of slab
seated on such pilings to the cost of one m2 of regular slab.
0 The case of a food-processingplant: all the equipment is at least stainless steel, including
the piping and valves. The suggested reference assumes that, for economic reasons, the
use of superior materials is limited to only that equipment, or those portions of the equip-
ment, which actually require it. In other words, traps or similar devices are provided to
prevent corrosion products from spreading. In these circumstances, most of the piping is
of carbon steel. In the food business, the regulations do not permit such an approach. To
allow for this, the weight of the piping and valve item must be increased by multiplying
the corresponding reference value by the ratio of the cost of a kilogram of stainless steel
(304, for example) to that of a kilogram of carbon steel (235 C, for example).
Here too, the procedure described answers one of the initial concerns, which was to allow
for a certain flexibility, and to make it easy to extend it into situations where more precise
information is available, particularly about plant construction. In the opposite case, as stated
earlier, one only needs to go straight to the all-inclusive value for the factorfg.
Abbreviations and Acronyms
DEB Flow
DEC Delivered Equipment Cost
DEDIST Distillate or Molar distillate
DT Temperature differential
EAPF Plate joint exchanger
EbLMS Ebonite Lined Mild Steel
ECMRA European Chemical Marketing Research Association
(now European Chemical Marketing and Strategy Association)
ECN European Chemical News
ELMS Enamel Lined Mild Steel
EMIP Equivalent Maximum Investment Period
ENR Engineering News-Record
EO Ethylene Oxide
EPDM Ethylene-Propylene-Diene-Monomers
EPE Engineering and Process Economics
EVAL n (> 2)-component IFP index for updating investment evaluations
EXP Plant Exponent
FAS Free Alongside Ship
FAST-E Freiman Analysis Systems Technique-Equipment
FCC Fluid Catalytic Cracking
FF Flow Factor
FF French Francs
FOB Free On Board
FPA (shipping contract terms) Free of Particular Average
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GNP Gross National Product
GVI Global Value Index
HC Hydrocarbons
HD High density
HDS Hydrodesulfuration
HDT Hydrotreating
HDPE High Density Polyethylene
hr Hour
HTS High sulfur content
ICARUS Investigating Cost and Reliability in Utility Systems
IEA International Energy Agency
IFP Institut FranGais du Pitrole
IME Institute for Market Economics
INSEE Institut national de la statistique et des itudes bconomiques
I/O Input/Output ratio
IPA Isopropyl Alcohol
IPE International Product Exchange
IPI Industrial Production Index
IRP Interest Recovery Period
IRR Internal Rate of Return
Abbreviations and Acronyms 3
sc Steam Cracking
SCN S y s t h e des comptes normalisb (Standardized accounting system)
SEC Syst2me europten des comptes kconomiques normalists (Standardized European
economic accounting system)
SECN SystGme klargi de comptabiliti nationale (Expanded national accounting system)
SF State Factor
SIMSCI Simulation Science, Inc.
SMI Small- and Medium-sized industries
sq. ft. Square feet
SRI Stanford Research Institute
ss Stainless Steel
TEFC Total Enclosed Fan Cooled
TEMA Standards of Tubular Exchanger Manufacturers Association
TI Tightness Index
TML Logarithmic Mean Temperature
TP Throughput
TPX Commercial acronym: Polymethyl-4 pentene- 1
TS Residence time
tlyr tons per year
VAT Value Added Tax
VI Volume Items
VORM Mean relative volatility
WEBCI Werkgroep Begrotingsproblem in der Chemische Industrie
XLEC Amount of light constituents in the feedstock
Bibliography
Chilton CH (1960) Cost Engineering in the Process Industries. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Page JS (1963) Estimator’s Manual of Equipment and Installation Costs. Gulf Publishing Co,
Houston.
Bauman HC (1963) Fundamentals of Cost Engineering in the Chemical Industry. Reinhold
Publishing Corp., New York.
Grant EL, Ireson WG (1964) Principles of Engineering Economy. The Ronald Press Co,
New York.
Aries RS, Newton RD (1965) Chemical Engineering Cost Estimation. McGraw-Hill, New
York.
Rase HF, Barrow MH (1966) Project Engineering of Process Plants. John Wiley and Sons,
New York.
Jelen FC (1970) Cost and Optimization Engineering. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Popper H (1970) Modern Cost Engineering Techniques. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Stallworthy EA (1973) The Control of Investment in New Manufacturing Facilities. Gower
Press Ltd., Epping, England.
Park W R (1973) Cost Engineering Analysis. John Wiley and Sons, New York.
Wright MG (1973) Discounted Cash Flow. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Guthrie KM (1974) Process Plant Estimating Evaluation and Control. Craftsman Book Co of
America, Solana Beach, Cal.
Ludwig EE (1974) Applied Project Engineering and Management. Gulf Publishing Co,
Houston.
Bussey LE (1975) The Economic Analysis of Industrial Projects. Prentice-Hall Inc., Engle-
wood Cliffs, N.J.
Happel J, Jordan DG (1975) Chemical Process Economics. Marcel Dekker Inc., New York.
436 Bibliography
Wilson RMS (1975) Cost Control Handbook. Gower Press Ltd., Farnborough, England.
Baasel WD (1976) Preliminary Chemical Engineering Plant Design. American Elsevier Pub-
lishing Co, New York.
Nelson WL (1976) Guide to Refinery Operating Costs. The Petroleum Publishing Co, Tulsa,
Okla.
Guthrie KM (1977) Managing Capital Expenditures for Construction Projects. Craftsman
Book Co of America, Solana Beach, Cal.
Clark FD, Lorenzoni AB (1978) Applied Cost Engineering. Marcel Dekker Inc., New York.
Wilson RMS (1978) Cost Control Handbook. Gower Press Ltd., London.
Jelen FC (1979) Project and Cost Engineers' Handbook. American Association of Cost Engi-
neers, AACE, Morgantown, W. Va.
Kharbanda OP (1979) Process Plant and Equipment Cost Estimation. Craftsman Book Co,
Solana Beach, Cal.
Chemical -Engineering Magazine (1979) Modern Cost Engineering: Methods and Data.
McGraw-Hill, New York.
Peters MS, Timmerhaus KD (1980) Plant Design and Economics for Chemical Engineers.
McGraw-Hill, New York.
Humphreys KK, Kate11 S (198 1) Basic Cost Engineering. Marcel Dekker Inc., New York.
Stewart RD (1982) Cost Estimating. John Wiley and Sons, New York.
American Association of Cost Engineers, AACE (1984) Project and Cost Engineers' Hand-
book. Marcel Dekker Inc., New York.
Humphreys KK (1984) Project and Cost Engineers' Handbook. Marcel Dekker Inc.,
New York.
Page JS (1984) Conceptual Cost Estimating Manual. Gulf Publishing Co, Houston.
Ulrich GD (1984) Economic Analysis. A Guide to Chemical Engineering Process Design and
Economics. John Wiley and Sons, New York.
Gutman N (1985) How to Keep Product Costs in Line. Marcel Dekker Inc., New York.
Westney RE (1985) Managing the Engineering and Construction of Small Projects. Marcel
Dekker Inc., New York.
Axel1 0, Robertson JM (1986) Economic Evaluation in the Chemical Process Industries.
John Wiley and Sons, New York.
Kerridge AE ( 1986) Evaluate Project Cost Factors. Engineering Construction Project Man-
agement. Gulf Publishing Co, pp 217-238, Houston.
Humphreys KK, Wellman P (1987) Basic Cost Engineering (revised and expanded). Marcel
Dekker Inc., New York.
Spear M (1991) Defining home office engineering costs. Process Engng.
Part 1 (Apr.) p 17.
Part 2 (May) p 19.
Part 3 (June) p 2 1.
Part 4 (July) p 17.
Part 5 (Oct.) p 16.
Bibliography 437
2. Market data
Methodology
Duchesnes D (1964) Le r6le de l’ttude de march6 dans l’entreprise chimique. Annales de la
Socittt belge de l’industrie du pttrole 14, p 27.
Twaddle WW, Malloy JB (1966) Evaluating and sizing new chemical plants in a dynamic
economy. American Association of Cost Engineers, AACE, 10th National meeting,
Philadelphie, Penn., June 20-22.
Comgan TE, Dean MJ (1967) Determining optimum plant size. Chem. Engng. 74, 17, p 152.
Amstutz AD (1967) Computer Simulation of Competitive Market Response. The MIT Press,
Cambridge, Mass.
Bright JR (1968) Technological Forecasting for Industry and Government. Prentice Hall,
Englewood Cliffs, N.J.
Box GEP, Jenkins GM (1 970) Time Series Analysis. Forecasting and Control, Holden-Day,
San Francisco.
Infor. Chimie (1970) Les matrices Input-Output europtennes. 80, janv., pp 3 1-38.
Saglin I (1970) How to Price New Products. Modern Cost Engineering Techniques. McGraw-
Hill, New York.
Stobaugh RB (1970) Chemical Marketing Research. Modem Cost Engineering Techniques.
McGraw-Hill, New York.
Jolson MA, Rossow GL (197 1) The Delphi process in marketing decision making. Journal of
Marketing Research VII, Nov., pp 443-448.
Azoulay P, Ponthus P (1974) Les moddes de dtcision dans l’entreprise. Presses Universi-
taires de France, pp 318-335, Paris.
Malloy JB (1974) Projecting chemical product prices. Chem. Engng. Progr. 70,9, pp 77-83.
Selden RA (1978) How forecasters forecast, Chemtech., Apr., pp 204-208.
43 8 Bibliography
De la Mare RF (1978) Long term forecasting. A novel time-trend analysis technique. Engi-
neering and Process Economics 3,2, pp 129-140.
Guyot F (1979) Elkments de macro-kconomie. Editions Technip, Paris.
Stevenson D (1984) Analysing marketing information: a macro view of consumption. Pro-
ceedings of the International Conference of the ECMRA, Amsterdam, 15-17 Oct., pp 189-
215.
Dayan A, Blon J, Cadix A, de Maricourt R, Michon C, Ollivier A (1985) Marketing. Presses
Universitaires de France, Paris.
Chauvel A (1987) Apport de l’evaluation a l’orientation des projets de recherche. Rev. Inst.
FranG. du Pktrole 42, 1, pp 121-134.
Schmeder G (1988) Prkvision technologique: rktrospective critique. Problkmes
Economiques, 2103,14 dkc., pp 2-8.
Sedriks W, Carmichael LA (1993) Predict petrochemicals’ price behavior simply. Chem.
Engng Progr. 89, 10, pp 61-67.
3. Indices
Localization (miscellaneous)
Yen-chen Yen (1972) Estimating plant costs in the developing countries. Chem. Engng. 79,
15, pp 89-92.
Bauman HC (1962) Costs for chemical process plants abroad. Industrial & Engineering
Chemistry 54,9, pp 40-43.
Johnson RJ (1969) Costs of oversea plants. Chem. Engng. 76,5, p 146.
Callagher JT (1969) Efficient estimating of world wide plant costs. Chem. Engng. 76, 12,
p 196.
Alonso JRF (1971) Estimating the cost of gas cleaning plants. Chem. Engng. 78,28, pp 86-
96.
Tems Ph (1973) R61e des pays producteurs de petrole dans l’industrie pktrochimique. Revue
de 1’AssociationFranCaise des Techniciens du PCtrole, nov.-dCc., pp 186-189.
Catry JP (1975) La localisation industrielle (confkrence presentee au stminaire: Evaluation
des avants-projets, au Centre de perfectionnement des industries chimiques de Nancy,
30/05/75).
Miller CA (1979) Converting construction costs from one country to another. Chem. Engng.
86, 14, pp 89-93.
Massa RV (1983) International composite cost location factors. Cost Engng. 25,5, pp 15-21.
Wagialla Kh4 (1984) The use of location factors in estimating the total fixed investment of
chemical plants. Process Economics International 5, 1, pp 37-41.
Inflation
Hirschmann WB (1971) Has the cost of building new refineries really gone up? Chem.
Engng. Progr. 67,8, pp 39-47.
Burford CL, Liles DH, Dryden RD (1977) Effects of inflation on capital investments.
Chemtech, Feb., pp 129-134.
Jones BW (1982) Inflation in Engineering Economic Analysis. John Wiley and Sons,
New York.
Bibliography 443
General
Zwingelstein G (1984) Panorama des mkthodes d’identification de processus. Le Nouvel
Automatisme, Oct., pp 65-71.
Foussier P (1988) Pourquoi? ou les besoins en matiere d’estimation. Les methodes d’estima-
tion de coQt.Conference AFITEP, Paris, pp 5- 16.
Foussier P (1988) Comment? Les methodes d’estimation de coQt.Conference AFITEP, Paris,
pp 17-40.
Kharbanda OP, Stallworthy EA (1988) Capital cost estimating for the process industries. But-
terworths, London.
Perrin JL, Chauvel A (1994) Projets de R&D: methodes de pre-estimation des cotits.
lre partie, La Cible 53, pp 18-23. 2e partie, La Cible 54, pp 9-13.
Extrapolating investments
Williams R, Jr. (1947) Six tenths factor aids in approximating costs. Chem. Engng. 54, 12,
pp 124-125.
Nelson WL (1 949) Overall plant costs cracking. The Oil and Gas J. 48,29, p 9 1.
Nelson WL (1964) How to scale plant costs to other sizes. The Oil and Gas J. 62, 39, pp 84-
85.
Woodier AB, Voolcock J W (1965) The ABC of the 0.6 scale up factor. European Chem.
News, large plant supplement, Sept. 10, pp 7-9.
Chase JD (1970) Plant cost vs capacity, new way to use exponents. Chem. Engng. 77, 7,
pp 113-118.
Guthrie KM (1970) Capital and operating costs for 54 chemical processes. Chem. Engng. 77,
10, pp 140-156.
Earl PH (1977) Specifying escalation indexes to aid in process plant cost forecasting. Engng.
and Process Economics 2,2, pp 119-126.
Miller CA (1965) New cost factors give quick accurate estimates. Chem. Engng. 72, 19,
pp 226-236.
Guthrie KM (1969) “Rapid calc.” chart. Chem. Engng. 76, 1, pp 138-144.
Montfoort AG, Meijer FA (1983) Improved Lang factor appoach to capital cost estimating.
Process Economics International 4, 1, pp 20-2 1.
Ward TJ (1984) Predesign estimating of plant capital costs. Chem. Engng. 91, 19, pp 121-
124.
Blecker HG, Smithson D (1985) Detailed cost estimating during the process engineering
phase of a project. Process Economics International 5,2, pp 17-28.
Klumpar IV, Slavsky ST (1985) Updated cost factors:
Part 1. Process equipment. Chem. Engng. 92, 15, pp 73-75.
Part 2. Commodity Materials. Chem. Engng. 92, 17, p 76-77.
Part 3. Installation Labor. Chem. Engng. 92, 19, pp 85-87.
Klumpar IV ( 1986) Updated capital cost estimation factors. Process Economics International
6 , 3 and 4, pp 40-53.
Klumpar IV, Brown RF, Fromme JW (1988) Rapid capital estimation based on process mod-
ules. Process Economics International 7, 1, pp 5- 10.
Meisl CJ (1988) Techniques for cost estimating in early program phases. Engng. Costs and
Production Economics 14,2, pp 95-106.
Park RE, Korda PB (1989) Making estimates credible or why should I believe what you are
telling me? Journal of Parametrics, 9,2, pp 9-37.
Gottardi G, Coppola L (1990) Elaboration des modeles parametriques d’estimation de coQt.
Actes du 1le congres AFITEP, Paris, pp F.3.1-F.3.5.
XPAR (1992) ExposCs de la journCe d’etude ESCP-XPAR. Le Journal des Paramttriciens,
Janv., pp 1-16.
Melin JB, Jr. (1994) Parametric estimation. Cost Engng., Janv., pp 19-24.
Fournier G (1997) Application des modbles mathtmatiques de coQt a la determination des
investissements dans l’industrie pttrolikre. These, UniversitB de Bourgogne, Dijon - Insti-
tut franCais du petrole, Rueil-Malmaison (soutenue le 20 mai 1997).
Modeling
Enyedy G, Jr. (1979) PDQ$ (Price and Delivery Quoting Service for CPI Equipment). A
computer-based cost estimation service. Transactions of American Association of Cost
Engineers, AACE, Gates Mills, Ohio, July, pp 139-143.
Koehret B, Joulia X, Le Lann MV (1985) Developpement des programmes de simulation des
prockdts chimiques. Le simulateur PROSIM. L’actualitC chimique, juin-juillet, pp 63-70.
Lui A, Branch J. (1985) Costing and economic evaluation using ASPEN PLUS. Process Eco-
nomics International 6, 1, pp 30-37.
5. Project profitability
(1 960) Petrokhem. Engineers, Aug., C8-C44:
Happel J - Economic evaluation.
Newton RD - Selection of plant capacity.
Martin JC - How to measure project profitability.
Clark RW - Consider these factors affecting plant costs.
Schraishuhn EA, Kellett J - How to obtain speed and accuracy in preliminary appraisals.
Happel J, Kapfer WH - Evaluate plant design with this simple index.
Sniffen TJ - The right cost can reduce pumping costs.
Hackney J W (1961) How to appraise capital investments. Chem. Engng. 67, 11, pp 145-164.
McLean JG (1963) Techniques for the appraisal of new investments, 6e Congres mondial du
petrole, Francfort, section VIII, juin, pp 47-63.
Early WE (1964) How process companies evaluate capital investments. Chem. Engng. 7 1,6,
pp 111-116.
Weinberger AJ (1964) Improving R&D’s batting average; How to estimate required invest-
ment; Calculating manufacturing costs; Estimating sales and markets; Methods for esti-
mating profitability; Post audits and qualitative factors. Chem. Engng. 71, 9, pp 123-168.
Urban WJ, Holland FA (1966) How to determine optimum plant size. Chem. Engng. 73, 6,
pp 103-108.
Sinclair CG (1966) Measurement of investment worth. Chem. Process Engng. 47, pp 137-
139.
Bibliography 447
Walton PR (1966) Cost estimating at the research level. American Association of Cost Engi-
neers, AACE, 10th National Meeting, June 20,21 and 22, Philadelphie.
Twaddle WW, Malloy JB (1966) Evaluating and sizing new chemical plants. Chem. Engng.,
62,7, pp 90-96.
Nitchie EB (1967) Accounting data and methods help control costs and evaluate profits.
Chem. Engng. 74, 1, pp 87-92.
Herron DP (1967) Comparing investment evaluation methods. Chem. Engng. 74,2, pp 125-
132.
Allen DH (1967) Two new tools for project evaluation. Chem. Engng. 74, 15, pp 75-78.
Allen DH (1969) Economic evaluation and taking decision. British Chem. Engng. 14, 6,
pp 790-793.
Chilton TH (1969) Investment return via the engineer’s method. Chem. Engng. Progr. 65, 7,
pp 29-34.
Depallens G (1970) Gestion financihre de l’entreprise. Sirey, Paris.
Malloy JB (1969) Instant economic evaluation. Chem. Engng. Progr. 65, 11, pp 47-54.
Mapstone GE (1971) The present value of plant allowances. Chem. and process Engng.,
April, pp 66-69.
Leibson I, Trischman CA, Jr. (1 97 1- 1972):
Part 1 (1971) Spotlight on operating cost. Chem. Engng. 78, 12, pp 69-74.
Part 2 (1971) How to cut operating costs: evaluate your feedstocks. Chem. Engng. 78, 13,
pp 92-95.
Part 3 (1971) How to get approval of capital projects. Chem. Engng. 78, 13, pp 95-102.
Part 4 (1971) Avoiding pitfalls in developing a major capital project. Chem. Engng. 78,
18, pp 103-110.
Part 5 (1971) A realistic project development case study. Chem. Engng. 78,20, pp 86-92.
Part 6 (1971) Case study shows project development in action. Chem. Engng. 78, 22,
pp 85-92.
Part 7 (1971) Final stage in the project. Chem. Engng. 78,25, pp 78-85.
Part 8 (1971) When and how to apply discounted cash flow and present worth. Chem.
Engng. 78,28, p 97-105.
Part 9 (1972) Decision trees: a rapid evaluation of investment risk. Chem. Engng. 79, 2,
pp 99- 105.
Part 10 (1972) Should you make or buy your major raw material? Chem. Engng. 79,4,
p 76-83.
Part 11 (1972) Zeroing in on “make or buy” decisions. Chem. Engng. 79,6, pp 113-118.
Part 12 (1972) How to profit from product improvement and development. Chem. Engng.
79, 8, pp 103-112.
Ohsol EO (1972) Commercial evaluation of new projects. American Chemical Society, 164th
meeting, Aug.-Sept., New York.
Allen DH (1972) A guide to the economic evaluation of projects. Department of Chemical
Engineering, University of Nottingham, The Institution of Chemical Engineers, London.
448 Bibliography
Alain CHAUVEL
Engineer, ENSIC, Nancy
Doctor of Engineering, Paris
Professor at the IFP School
Deputy Director, Strategy & Corporate Planning Division, IFP
Senior Director, Scientific Division, IFP
Gilles FOURNIER
Engineer, ENSIGC, Toulouse
Doctor of Economics, Dijon
Engineer, Strategy & Corporate Planning Division, IFP
Claude RAIMBAULT
Degree in Science, DES in Physics
Engineer, IFP School
Senior Engineer, Strategy & Corporate Planning Division, IFP
Prb-Estime Method A2
Evaluation of Pressure Vessels 1
Evaluation of Furnaces A2
5
Evaluation of Storage A2
9
APPENDIX1
Functional Modules
Method (FMM)
Although the FMM resembles other modular methods, it differs from them in that its princi-
ple is not to look at each item of equipment in a plant, but rather at the groups of equipment
required to perform a particular physico-chemical operation (distillation, reaction, etc.).
However, it has proved possible to establish a direct relationship between the prices of such
groupings, called “modules”, and the basic physico-chemical parameters that control their
functioning.
The choice of the most important technical parameters (the key variables) for each of the
functional modules emerges from a prior statistical analysis. In practice, the base price of a
module is obtained from regressions or graphics, by assigning each representative parameter
its actual or approximate value. The erected cost (or the battery limits cost) is obtained by
using correction factors that are characteristic for each module, and which themselves come
from a statistical correlation.
The overall battery limits investment is obtained by adding up the erected costs of the var-
ious modules identified on the plant’s flowsheet l .
The statistical analysis performed on the selected samples had three objectives:
0 Confirmation of the consistency and representativeness of each module’s database,
0 Selection of the most significant technical parameters in each case, i.e., the key vari-
ables,
0 Definition of regression models.
The collection of information involved more than nine hundred different sets of equip-
ment. After being accepted into the sampling, each one was recalculated to identify possible
1. The flowsheet may include several successive modules of the same kind. This is particularly
true for reaction, when there are reactors in series, or for distillation when this operation includes a
series of columns, each with a specific function.
3 10 Appendix 1. Functional Modules Method (FMM)
10 15 20 25 30
disparities that were too large and/or impossible to explain in terms of the model, which was
being developed in parallel. At the end of this primary selection process, just over six hundred
sets were retained.
In addition, the choice involved equipment for treating a wide range of chemical products.
For this purpose the range selected was designed to be wide enough for the method to have
the broadest possible coverage. The following items were included
n-paraffins, from c1to C20
Branched paraffins
Olefins, from C2 to C9
Diolefins
Aromatics
Cycloparaffins and cyclo-olefins A1
Alcohols
Acetylene and butyne
Chloroparaffins and aromatics
Carbon dioxide and monoxide
Hydrogen, nitrogen, water, and ammonia
Hydrogen sulfide and acetone.
Similarly, in compiling the sample, a special effort was made to obtain a representative
grouping, providing the best possible coverage of the various industrial operating conditions
normally encountered in operating this equipment. Thus in Fig. A1 .1 for example, we see that
although the range for the number of plates in a distillation column covers values as extreme
as 12 and 138, in practice most of the numbers fall between 20 and 40. This same procedure
was also followed for the other variables.
The data analysis techniques that had already been applied in studying the consistency of
the sampling proved to be particularly valuable in selecting the key variables, especially in
the case of unit distillation and reaction operations, given their complexity and the large num-
ber of interdependent parameters. The construction of predictive models, using the appropri-
ate regression techniques, was also made easier in both cases by the prior application of these
techniques. For “reaction”, for example, it was quickly shown that a single model could not,
by itself, reflect the diversity of the situations encountered.
The models that have been developed, which can be applied by using regressions or nomo-
grams that enable determination of a total erected price, take the following headings into
account:
The cost of principal equipment (columns, drums, tanks, heat exchangers, evaporators,
ovens, boilers, compressorsand drives, control instruments and various accessories,etc.),
The cost of secondary material (valves, piping, thermal insulation, steel structures, instru-
mentation and electrical systems, buildings including the control room, painting, etc.),
Erection and civil engineering expenses (site preparation, foundations, setting up equip-
ment, hookups and connections, road construction, etc.),
312 Appendix 1. Functional Modules Method (FMM)
0 Indirect construction and transport expenses (rental and positioning of special hoisting
equipment, temporary site buildings, tax, insurance, and miscellaneous site costs, etc.),
0 Contingencies.
The cost of the principal equipment is determined at the level of each module. It represents
what we will call here the base price. The application of assembly factors for each type of
module provides for inclusion of the other components of the erected cost, as mentioned
above.
To extend the method to materials that are different from the (carbon steel) ones taken as
references for the models, we employ another series of multiplying factors. In the same way,
certain operating parameters, whose effect is not dominant but which may have a significant
weight, may also be considered.
A1 The utilization of the method does not necessarily require that the exact structure of the
modules concerned be known in advance. However, when this information is available,
Table Al. 1 presents a partial list of the equipment likely to be used in each one.
The five modules examined in this way cover, by themselves, almost all of the equipment
involved in current petrochemical and organic chemical processes. These are the ones that are
generally used in the evaluation of a plant for which we have only a block diagram, a material
balance for the main production lines, and approximate knowledge of the operating condi-
tions (pressure and temperature levels).
Nevertheless, we sometimes have to allow for additional equipment such as tanks, drums,
furnaces, or exchangers that cannot be included in any of the modules considered. In this case
the method provides for the use of auxiliary modules. They are listed in Table A1.2.
A1
Module Auxiliary
no. module
A. 1 Flash/separating/refluxdrums
A.2 Intermediate storage drums
A.3 Blenders
A.4 Heating furnaces
AS Heat exchangers
(Source: IFP)
In order to make the method easier to use, we have emphasized the presentation of the equa-
tions themselves rather than their expression in graphical form. In fact, the accuracy of the
calculations is improved by doing this, in that it is freed from the constraints imposed by
drafting and printing the diagrams. Moreover, currently available personal computing
devices allow the equations to be programmed into a pocket calculator without difficulty.
With this in mind, Table A1.3 shows the regressions that enable determination of the base
prices of the modules considered here. Accompanying each one are the factors that are
required for obtaining the corresponding actual prices, depending on the kind of material uti-
lized, in particular, and in some cases factors for other parameters (pressure, type, etc.), and
also for “erection”. In addition, the recommended limits of variation are shown for all the key
variables involved. Thus, it is strongly recommended not to go above or below the maximum
and minimum limits specified, even when applying the equation gives a final total within the
range of variation of the base price parameter. A more realistic solution would then be to
adopt the minimum price as the base price in the low case, or in the high case, to consider
doubling the offending module.
Table A l . 3 Functional modules method. Determination of base and real prices of modules
Jeat exchangers In (PB) = 10.3530 PB=baseprice (lo3FF), early 1985 10.0-2 000.0 Shell/ Pressure 2.84
tubes
+0.5880 In (Q) Q = quantity of heat exchanged 0.1-10.0 cs/cs 0.00 <lobar 0.00
(MkcaVhr)
-0.7375 In (U) U = overall transfer coefficient 1000.0-100.0 cs/cu 0.30 10-20 0.08
(kcalhm*."C)
-0.5365 In (TML) TML = log mean temperature ("C) 100.0-1.0 CS/304 1.60 20-30 0.20
304/304 2.40 3WO 0.35
Another general observation concerns the problem posed by a missing piece of informa-
tion. For example, in the case of distillation, while it is often easy to find the distillate output,
the concentration of the key light component in the feed, and the column’s top pressure, it is
not so simple to find the relative volatility of the principal constituents, which moreover is a
particularly sensitive variable. To deal with problems of this nature, a dual parameter
approach can be employed: the first stage consists of using the actual values if they are avail-
able; the second is aimed at defining a reference, in practice a qualitative scale which repre-
sents the degree of difficulty in performing the operation.
Thus, in the specific case of the distillation module, a statistical analysis has produced the
results presented in Fig. Al.2, which is expressed as an auxiliary calibration by means of five
pointers that identify the relative difficulty, measured qualitatively, of separating the feed’s
constituents. A1
Notes:
a) Each symbol represents an observation.
b) Symbol Number Mean Std. Deviation Corresp. Value
V. DIFFICULT A 7 -1 367 0.178 1.167
DIFFICULT B 6 -1.235 0.209 1.338
AVERAGE C 39 4.335 0.163 2.046
EASY D 16 0.423 0.192 4.602
V.EASY E 7 0.921 0.100 12.327
COMMENTS
a) Each symbol represents an observation
Std. Corresponding
Separation Symbol No. Mean
deviation volatility
-
Very difficult A 7 -1.867 0.178 1.167
Difficult B 6 - 1.235 0.209 1.338
Average C 3.9 -0.335 0.163 2.046
Easy D 16 0.423 0.192 4.602
Very easy E 7 0.92 1 0.100 12.327
(Source: IFP)
318 Appendix 1. Functional Modules Method (FMM)
For modules where the calculation can be based either on the residence time or on the
quantities of heat to be exchanged (heat of reaction), it was decided to leave the users to select
the values most widely used in their fields of activity, either directly, or by using a scale sim-
ilar to the one employed to allow for relative volatilities in the case of distillation.
However, in the case of the reaction module (multitubular reactors), a dual parameter
method was suggested, using two exclusive variables I I and Z, that are bivalent integers (0 or
l), so that the calculation can be made using either the residence time or the quantity of heat
exchanged. In practice, when these two parameters are both available, the user should per-
form the calculation with each of them and select the result that gives the most unfavorable
result as regards base price. In physical terms, this approach amounts to favoring the variable
that happens to be decisive, depending on whether reaction kinetics or heat transfer is con-
A1 cerned.
In conclusion, two comments should be added. First of all, given that the throughputs are
always expressed in kilomoles in the regression, and that in addition the unit commonly avail-
able is the ton or the kilogram, it may be useful to program the pocket calculator with the
expression for relating them via molecular mass.
Throughput (kmolh) = throughput (kghr) / molar mass
(1.0to 10000) (100.0 to 100000) (300.0 to 1.0)
Finally, it would seem desirable to emphasize that, when the functional modules are being
defined by means of a plant flowsheet, their principal equipment consists of the items consid-
ered to be essential for the achievement of the intended operation. Exchangers, for example,
will only be considered to be auxiliary modules as long as they do not directly belong to the
whole module for distillation, reaction, or other unit operation. To obtain a better understand-
ing of this matter, Table A 1.1 should be consulted.
APPENDIX 2
Pr6-Estime Method
As already mentioned in Chapter 3 (Section 3.3.3.1), this method, which was first described
in the 1975 edition of the Manuel d '&valuationdconomique desproc&dds,published by Tech-
nip, was based on the prior application of rapid sizing procedures for principal equipment,
using graphics grouped in various appendices for each of the major equipment categories. A2
Since then, progress in computing and the marketing of user-friendly software have greatly 1
reduced the attraction of this type of tool. As a result, with certain exceptions, the appendices for
the new presentation of the Prd-Estime method no longer include the rapid, pre-sizing approach
for equipment, especially as concerns the graphics: they assume that the principal dimensional
characteristics (diameter, height, area, power, etc.) are known, or determined elsewhere.
By pressure vessel we mean any system including a shell with bottoms, enclosingcertain contents.
These include:
0 Various kinds of columns: with trays, with packing
0 Drums
0 Related reactors (tubular reactors or ones having a heating jacket and stirred beds are not
0 Absorption-stripping
0 Solvent extraction.
where
f?b is the base case thickness of the vessel (mm)
P is the relative operating pressure (bar)
R the radius of the vessel (mm)
t the maximum allowable stress (bar)
a the welding coefficient.
A. Welding Coefficient
a = 1.OO if there is a complete X-ray
a = 0.85 if there are spot X-rays
a = 0.70 if there are no X-rays.
A2 For a first approximation, take a = 1.OO.
1
B. Maximum Allowable Stress
Use the values in Tables A2.1.1a and A2.1.1b. They depend on:
0 The kind of material
Table A2.1 .la Value of the maximum allowable stress (bar) as a function
of utilization temperature, for commonly used steels
Table A2.1.1 b (concl.) Value of the maximum allowable stress (bar) as a function
of utilization temperature, for commonly used steels
ASTM-AISI
designation
1- r r r 149 204 260 316 343 371 399 427 454 482 510
ij
--
Stainless
alloy steels
SA 240-304 1318 1195 1125 1086 1044 1040 1033 1023 1005 984 942
SA 304 L 1230 1195 1125 1055 879 844 808 773
SA 310 S 1318 1318 1301 1279 1188 1167 1142 1104 1047 970 879
SA 316 1318 1318 1258 1230 1199 1195 1188 1178 1160 1125 1062
SA 316 L 1230 1230 1111 1037 1047 946 93 1 914 893 861
SA 317 1318 1318 1258 1230 1209 1199 1195 1188 1178 1160 1125 1062 984
SA 321 1318 1318 1195 1111 1069 1044 1040 1033 1016 1005 991 974 949
SA 347 1318 1318 1195 1111 1069 1044 1040 1033 1016 1005 991 974 949
SA410 1142 1097 1062 1026 995 963 942 92 1 896 851 773 619 450
(Source: Perry k Chemical Engineers 'Handbook) A2
1
A2.1.1.3 Application
Determine the thickness of the vessel using Eq. (A2.1.1). Add an extra thickness se for cor-
rosion, usually 3 m.The total thickness then becomes:
e = eb + se
The value of e must not be less than:
0 6 mm, including corrosion addition, for drums
A2.1.2.1 Principle
The method consists of determining the prices, as a function of the weight and the material
used, for:
0 Externals:
Depending on the thickness of the shell and bottoms, economics may dictate different
materials:
0 Homogeneous steel (carbon or stainless): thickness less than 8 mm
In all three cases, the calculation is based on carbon steel; if necessary, correction factors
are applied for stainless steels. The cladding or coating is treated as a supplement. Generally
speaking, the skirt is of carbon steel, the accessories and trays of homogeneous steel.
The expression (A2.1.2) then enables calculation of the weight of the skirt.
There are two of these bottoms: they include the top and the bottom, or the two ends of the
pressure vessels.
Assuming that they are elliptical, with a diameter equal to that of the shell, their total
weight (i.e., for both of them), for a unit thickness (1 mm), is given by curve 2 in Fig. A2.1.1.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 323
100 1000
g
- 10 100
m
f
a,
m
5
rn 1
A2
1
Figure A2.1.1 Determination of surface area and weight for
two bottoms. (Source: IFP)
a. Homogeneous Material
Correction factors
Effect of thickness
The correction factorf, is obtained from Fig. A2.1.3.
324 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
5.5
0
8
cy
.-6 3.5
E
f 3.0
.-u
t
2.5
A2 0 1 000 2 000 3 000 4 000 5 000 6000 7 000
Diameter (mm)
1
Figure A2.1.2 Determination of base price for shell and bottoms.
(Source: IFP)
Effect of material
Table A2.1.2 gives the correction factorf
, for the various materials.
Code designation
fm
ASTM AISI Other
SA 285 C - - 1.o
SA 203 A and D - - 1.3
SA 357 - - 1.8
SA 240 304 - 2.3
SA 240 304 L - 2.3
SA 240 310 S - 3.8
SA 240 316 - 3.0
SA 240 316 L - 3.2 A2
SA 240 316 (Ti) - 3.1
SA 240 32 1 - 2.6 1
SA 240 347 - 2.9
SA 240 410 - 2.4
- - Uranus 50 3.6
- - Uranus B6 4.8
- - Monel400 6.5
- - Inconel 600 10.0
- - Inconel 625 16.0
- - Hastelloy G 12.5
(Source: IFP)
Totalprice
corrected price of shell and bottoms = (€/kg). (weight of shell + weight of bottoms. ff).f,.f,
where
ff = 2.8 for a shell diameter less than 1 m
2.5 for a shell diameter between 1 and 1.5 m
2.0 for a shell diameter between 1.5 and 2 m
1.5 for a shell diameter greater than 2 m.
Correction factors
A2 Effect of thickness
1 The corresponding correction factorfk is obtained from Fig. A2.1.4.
1.9
1.8
-g 1.7
8 1.6
d
-=
0
1.5
g 1.4
s
0 1.3
1.2
1.1
1
8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22
Thickness of surface for cladding (mm)
Price of cladding
.f En .fc
corrected price of cladding = base price *ye
Correction factors
A2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Thickness of lining (mm)
1
Figure A2.1.5 Thickness correction factor for liningsf;.
(Source: IFP)
w p e of stainless steel
304 1.oo
304 L 1.10
310 S 1.35
316 1.25
347 1.10
410 0.95
Monel 2.50
Inconel 2.80
Natural rubber 0.30
Synthetic rubber 0.40
(Source: IFP)
Price of lining
corrected lining price = base price -fl -yA
B. Price of Skirt
Generally speaking, the skirt is:
0 Of homogeneous steel
0 Of carbon steel.
Consequently:
corrected skirt price = skirt price . ( a g ) .f,
where
€/kg is the price given by the curve in Fig. A2.1.2 for a thickness of 8 mm
f, is the correction factor for thickness, given by the curves in Fig. A2.1.3 for thick-
nesses greater than 8 mm.
A2
C. Price of Accessories 1
Determination of Base Price
This price (in mid-2000 €) is obtained directly from the curves in Fig. A2.1.6, which are
based on carbon steel:
0 For columns and reactors, as a function of the total weight of externals: shells, bottoms,
and skirt
0 For tanks, as a function of the total weight of the externals: shell and bottoms.
Correction Factor
Correction factors are applied according to the machining qualities of the various steels
(Table A2.1.5).
Code designation
ASTM AISI fam
designation designation
SA 285 C 1.o
SA 203 A et D 1.2
SA 357 1.6
SA 240 304 2.5
SA 240 310 S 3.5
A2 SA 240 316 3.0
1 SA 240 32 1 2.5
SA 240 347 3.0
Monel 7.0
Inconel 8.5
Price of accessories
corrected price = base price *fa
A. Price of Trays
The main kinds of tray are:
Bubble cap trays
0 Valve trays, where the valve can be tared as required, depending on the steam output
0 Sieve trays, with an overflow, used to give low load losses, but unsuitable for corrosive
or dirty products; there are versions without an overflow, the corrugated iron type for
example
Jet trays.
Determining the base price
The price of trays, established for valve trays, is a function of:
Diameter (m)
Material
Tray thickness (mm)
Number of fluxes.
Appendix 2. Pr4-Estime Method 33 1
A2
1
0.1 1 10
Diameter (m)
Correction factors
Bubble cap
Valve
Sieve
(Source: IFP)
332 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estirne Method
Thickness (mm) f,
2.0 1.oo
3.5 1.25
6.0 1.60
12.0 2.50
Price of trays
corrected price = base price .fpl .f,'fpa * f a m ' f p n
Appendix 2. Pr&Estime Method 333
B. Price of Packings
Table A2.1.7 gives an approximate idea of the prices for a number of packings, assumed to
be sold in lots of 20 m3.
0 Reduce the amount by 10% for quantities greater than 50 m3.
0 Reduce the amount by 15% for quantities greater than 100 m3.
m
) -1 25 35 50
Raschig rings
ceramic 725 665 665
carbon steel 1795 1360 1105 A2
304 stainless 4 140 3 220 3 000 1
Pall rings
carbon steel 1735 1105 1010
304 stainless 3 255 2 545 2 095
3 16 stainless - - 2 380
monel - - 4090
polypropylene 740 545 440
Intalox saddles
ceramic 880 725 695
polypropylene 835 545 545
de Berl saddles
ceramic 850 760 695
Packing cups
carbon steel 870 675 610
304 stainless 3 620 2 825 2 590
(Source: IFP)
to take into account annealing, X-ray, packaging if required, possible extras, etc. Then:
total price (mid-2000 €) = (price of shell and bottoms + price of cladding or lining
+ price of skirt + price of accessories + price of trays or packings) . 1.10 to 1.15
COMMENT
When the diameter of the shell is large (greater than 5 to 6 m), assembly is done
onsite; the cost of erecting the shell itself must be added to the setting-up cost nor-
mally employed. As a rough guide, the price of the equipment alone should be dou-
bled.
A2
1
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 335
In most cases, reactors are comparable to columns or even to simple drums. The determina-
tion of the corresponding prices is similar to the calculation procedure used for pressure ves-
sels, i.e.:
Calculation of the thickness of the shell and the bottoms, as a function of diameter and
pressure,
0 Determination of the components of the total price:
- Price of the shell, the bottoms, and the skirt, if required, from the weight and kind of
material utilized,
- Price of accessories: for a rough estimate, use a comparable column,
- Price of internals: trays, coils, baffles, etc. (see columns, exchangers, etc.).
For agitated reactors with heating jackets, of Grignard type, and for simple mettler-mixers,
use the graph in Fig. A2.2.1, which gives the total cost, including stirrer and motor.
1 o0oooo I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
A2
2
6
2 100000
a
W
0
0
-z
-E
C
."""" . 10
0.1 1
Capacity (m3)
For the other types of agitated reactors, the price of the shell with bottoms, accessories, and
internals is calculated separately, as discussed above, and the cost of the agitator is given by
Fig. A2.2.2, for 304 stainless steel and an average viscosity on the order of 1000 CPO.
Depending on the material employed, use the correction factors from Table A2.2.1, and
the following expression: corrected price = base price .f,.
336 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
I I I I I I I I I I I I I I l l l /
1 10 100
Power (HP)
Material
304 stainless
3 16 stainless
Rubber coated 1.25
Monel 1.30
(Source: IFP)
As a rough guide, the power ranges for the motors utilized with dispersers and reactors
with heating jackets are presented in Table A2.2.2.
0 Air-coolers
0 Plate exchangers.
A2
Heavy hydrocarbon - residue 3
(without phase change)
Light hydrocarbon
(with phase change)
Cooling water
Fluid
~~
U
'hbe side Shell side
1. Cooling exchanger
Butadiene Steam 60
Olefinic C4 Propylene (vaporization) 65-90
Ethylene vapor Condensate and steam 450-600
Ethylene vapor Cold water 250-400
Liquid ethylene Ethylene vapor 50-100
Propane vapor Liquid propane 30-75
Oleiinic light hydrocarbons, Steam 50- 100
CO, CO2. H2
Light and chlorinated Steam 60- 150
hydrocarbons
Ethanolamine Steam 75-125
Solvent Propylene (vaporization) 150-200
Solvent Solvent 170-200
Solvent Cold water 170-350
Oil Oil 300-400
Condensate Propylene 300-600
A2 Calcium chloride 25% Chlorinated C, 200-300
3 Steam Air (mixture) 50-100
Steam Styrene and tars 250-300
Cold water Freon 12 500-600
Cold water Recycle oil 200-350
Water Treated water (35-45°C) 500-600
Water Treated water (100-35OC) 800-1 100
Water Light chlorinated C2 hydrocarbons 30-50
Water Heavy chlorinated C2 220- 150
hydrocarbons
Water Perchloroethylene 270-170
Water Air-C12 40-90
Water HCl 35-75
Water Air and water vapor 100-170
Water Adsorption oil 400-560
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 339
Fluid
U
'hbe side Shell side
2. Condenser Propylene (cooling) 330-390
Butadiene Propylene 290-330
Olefinic C4 Propylene 300-450
Ethylene Propylene 250-300
Olefinic light hydrocarbons Propylene 300-550
HCl Propylene 75-125
Light ends and chloroethanes Water 450-600
Olefinic chlorinated hydrocarbons Water 100-150
Chlorinated hydrocarbons Water 125-75
Solvent and non-condensables Propylene vapor 650-750
Water Propylene 300-500
Water Steam 600-1,100
Water Steam 100-150
Treated water Steam 350-550
Oil Air-Cl, 40-75
(partial condensation)
Cold water Propylene (cooling and
condensation)(')
A2
Water Light hydrocarbons 200-450 3
(cooling and condensation)(')
Water Ammonia 700-800
Air-water vapor Freon 50-250
3. Reboiler
Olefinic C4 Steam 450-550
Chlorinated hydrocarbons Steam 170-120
Olefinic chlorinated hydrocarb ns Steam 500-700
Dichloroethane Steam 350-450
Heavy solvent Steam 350-550
Mono- and diethanolamine Steam 750-1,000
Organic acids-water Steam 300-500
Amine-water Steam 600-700
Steam Naphtha 75-100
Propylene Ethane-ethylene 600-700
Propylene-butadiene Propylene-butadiene 75-90
(1) Depending on the temperature level: 550-750 (-10 to -5OC); 125-250 (0 to 7°C).
(Source: Perry k Chemical Engineers 'Handbook,IF8 etc.)
340 Appendix 2. Pr.6-Estime Method
A. Determination of Type
Table A2.3.3 provides a rough guide.
Floating head The cap is removable Temperature difference Risk of leaking from
and reveals the ends of greater than 100OC. joints. Corrosion in the
the tubes: May be used with floating parts.
- the head and the tube dirty fluids.
pull through sheet are bolted
together;
- the tube sheet is
split ring floating; the tube
bundle may be
removed or not. A2
U-tubes One single tube sheet Big temperature hTk of failure at b e n d s
3
with U-tube bundle. difference. due to erosion at high
Removable bundle. Considerable speeds. Particle-free
expansion. Clean fluids.
fluids.
Kettle Kettle. Removable Reboiling or Bulk. High price.
bundle of U-tube or evaporation in the
floating head type. shell. High rate of
vaporization: 60% of
weight.
Thermosiphon Immersion reboiler with Reboiling in the tubes: Low vaporization rate:
natural circulation(') vertical. 35 to 40% by weight.
Reboiling in the shell:
horizontal.
Double pipe Concentric tubes Small exchanger Similar performance
surface. High provided by fin tubes.
pressure. Lower bulk and price.
I I
(1) Forced circulation reboiler: add the pump.
(Source: IFP)
342 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estirne Method
Examples:
0 Condensers: AES, BES, etc.
a. Principle
Basic expression:
corrected price = base price .fd .fi .Ap.fp - f ; .f
,
where
fd is a factor characteristic of the type of exchanger
fi is the correction factor for tube length
fnp is a factor for the number of tube passes
fp is the correction factor for the pressure in the shell and tubes
f; is the temperature correction factor
f, is a factor characteristic of the kinds of material used.
-
Front end stationary
head types
Shell types I Rear end head types
Split flow
Ip Outside packed
floating head
________
-ft-:-:
......... A2
u. ....,...
...,:~:,~.
.......
.
.I
3
Floating head
C with backing device
Pull through
floating head
Channel integral
with tube sheet
and removable cover
U-tube bundle
D ::.
Ill-
Special high-pressure Externally sealed
- closure "Kettle type" reboiler I floating head tube sheet
Bundle characteristics:
- tube diameter: 3/4";BWG: 14
- square pitch
- length: 16 8,or = 4.9 m.
1 oooo00
6
H
c
100 000
loo00
A2
3 .-8
p'
1 000
the other coefficients have a lesser effect; these are: the tube diameter and pitch, the length of
the bundle, the number of tube passes, and the utilization temperature.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 345
5Pe fd
AES 1.oo
AEM 0.90
AEU 0.90
AKT 1.30
BES 0.95
BEM 0.86
BEU 0.86
BKT 1.25
Thermosiphon 1.20
+
e. Effect of maximum pressure
I I
Temperature ("C) ft
t < 350 1.oo
350 < t < 550 1.08
(Source: IFP)
Material of shellkubes fm
CSICS 1.o
CSl304 L stainless 1.9
CSl3 16 stainless 2.2
CSICU 1.3
csmo 2.0
CSIMonel 4.0
CSlTi 10.0
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estirne Method 347
COMMENT
When the parameters that define the tube bundle (diameter, pitch, length, number of
passes) are unknown, it is best to adopt standard dimensions, i.e., to set the corre-
sponding correction factors equal to 1.OO.
c. Price Determination
Use the graph in Fig. A2.3.3 to obtain the base price, and apply correction factors from
Tables A2.3.4a through A2.3.4g. Add 5% to cover possible extras.
a. Basic Expression
This takes the same form as that utilized for exchangers with tube bundles. There is only one
type of exchanger: double pipe, sofd = 1.OO.Similarly, numerous other correction factors can
be taken as 1.OO;only the effects of pressure and the kind of materials employed are consid-
ered.
The base price conditions are also identical: only the type of reference changes (double
pipe exchanger).
Pressure (bar) fP
4 1.oo
4 to 6 1.10
6 to 7 1.25
(Source: IFP)
I Material of shelYtubes I fm I
CSICS 1.o
CS1304 L stainless 1.9
CS13 16 stainless 2.2
(Source: IFP)
348 Appendix 2. PrcCEstirne Method
c. Price Determination
Use the graph in Fig. A2.3.4 to obtain the base price. Add 5% to cover extras.
10000
E
B
c
E
d
?!
*;
m
e
s
8
8
zE
.-
-8
t
1 000
0.1 1 10
Exchanger surface (m2)
C. Special Case
It may be useful to know the price of exchanger tubes, when they are used separately in a shell
of particular size, or as a coil. Figure A2.3.5 gives the prices of these tubes for carbon steel.
As a first approximation, we may use the correction factors for double pipe exchangers,
according to the kind of material. The cost of welded and extruded tubes is strongly affected
by supply and demand. In 1974, it reached a particularly high level, as also shown by the
Nelson index for exchangers. Current prices have fallen back strongly: Fig. A2.3.5 therefore
presents average values. On this subject, the Nelson index for exchangers does not seem to
give as accurate a picture as other kinds of index, such as those from the LASL (Los Alamos
Scientific Laboratory).
Figure A2.3.5 was based on lots equivalent to a length of 20000 m, and carbon steel tubes.
Correction factors must be applied when conditions are different.
For unwelded tubes, we may use the following factors, depending on the kind of material
employed:
1.2 for low alloy steel (ASTM A 199)
2.5 for 304 stainless
4.0 for 3 16 stainless.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 349
10
0
P
c)
(D
c
K
0
i$
1
4.0
6
e l
W
QY
rr
E
.-E
.-0
h
0.1
0.4 1 2
Internal diameter (inches)
A2.3.2 AIR-COOLERS A2
3
Some chemical engineering software does not give methods for sizing air-coolers: to provide
an answer in case one is needed, we present here a rapid procedure for obtaining the correct
sizing.
Air-coolers are used for the cooling and condensation of certain fluids, which can also be
done with tube-type heat exchange equipment. We therefore have a choice between these two
kinds of apparatus. Our preference for one or the other will primarily depend on the availabil-
ity of utilities, and secondly on economic considerations. In evaluation, where it is difficult
to optimize equipment or even individual units, only the first point is generally considered,
unless additional information is provided.
The usual kind of air-cooler has stacked rows of fin tubes. A fan provides forced air circu-
lation around the tubes. The sizing and costing of this equipment may be performed in greater
or lesser detail.
0 T I and T2, the inlet and outlet temperatures of the fluid to be cooled
350 Appendix 2. Pre-Estime Method
3
Film Fouling r
coefficient ri coefficient rd (hr-m2.0C/kcal)
Cooling:
water 0.000 16 0.0002 0.00036
aqueous solutions 0.0002 0.0004 0.0006
GPL 0.0004 0.0002 0.0006
light hydrocarbons 0.0005 0.0003 0.0008
medium hydrocarbons:
average viscosity 1 cPo 0.0010 0.0004 0.0014
average viscosity 5 cPo 0.0032 0.0006 0.0038
average viscosity 10 cPo 0.0050 0.0008 0.0058
Condensation:
steam 0.0002 0.0001 0.0003
ammonia 0.00028 0.0002 0.00048
GPL 0.0006 0.0002 0.0008
light hydrocarbons 0.0008 0.0003 0.001 1
light naphtha 0.0010 0.0004 0.0014
heavy naphtha 0.0014 0.0004 0.0018
gasoline 0.0008 0.0002 0.0010
diesel 0.0014 0.0004 0.00 18
(Source: IFP)
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 35 1
1
-
U
= ri + rd + Y, + ra
an expression in which
r, is the transfer resistance of the metal, usually equal to 0.00015 (hr . m2 . OCkcal)
ra is the external film coefficient, i.e., the coefficient for air. Table A2.3.7 gives its val-
ues as a function of the number of rows of tubes, which itself depends on the ratio:
T1 -ta
U
A very quick calculation by approximation thus becomes necessary.
We utilize the corrected Logarithmic Mean Temperature Difference (LMTD). To obtain it
from Fig. A2.3.6 we must not only know TI, T2, and ta, but also th, the outlet temperature of
the hot air; th is a function of the power required by the fan and the face velocity of the air Vf
(given in Table A2.3.7); it can therefore be calculated only after having obtained a figure for
this power. The same applies to the correction factor, which, as in the case of a tube-type
exchanger, is determined by knowing:
A2
and: 3
Table A2.3.7 Air-coolers: external film coefficient and superficial air velocity
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
15
A2
3
At, or A t 2
At, or A t p
For this, we use the curves in Fig. A2.3.7,which are valid for one or more tube passes.
Since the flows have perpendicular instead of parallel directions, the correction factors for
air-coolers are different from those applicable to tube-type exchangers.
Appendix 2. Pr&Estime Method 353
8 0.9
‘ii
e
-
C
4-
e
8
0.8
0.7
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
R factor
A2
8
0.9 3
H
r
.-s
c)
e
b
0.8
0.7
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
R factor
A2
3
The power requirement PCV is then calculated from the following expression:
Pcv = K . S
1. There are various methods for air-cooler calculations. Since the common sizing software does
not necessarily include one, it seems desirable to make an exception and suggest such a procedure here.
Appendix 2. Pr&Estime Method 355
This temperature is obtained as a function of the power requirement and the face velocity of
the air, using the following equation:
t - Q
- 1061 Vf .Cv + ta
where
Q is in k c a l h
Vf is i n d s
P,, is in CV
th and ta are in "C.
A= Q A2
U .corrected LMTD 3
where
A is in m2
Q is in k c a l h
U is in kcalhr. m2. "C
LMTD isin"C.
wall thickness, aluminum fins of type "G" (grooved tubes with embedded fins), six rows
Operating pressure: < 10 bar
Bolted return-type end cover, in carbon steel
Manually adjustable fan blade angle
Driver motor of type TEFC (Total Enclosed Fan Cooled) with V-belts.
We first determine the cost coefficient C by using Fig. A2.3.9, knowing R and r.
356 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
The tax-free, ex factory base price in mid-2000 f is given by the following expression:
base price (mid-2000 f ) = 0.35 . C . S
100000
loo00
lo00
0.0001 0.001 0.01
A2 r factor
3
Figure A2.3.9 Air-coolers: determination of Cas a function of Y and R.
(Source: IFP)
B. Correction Factors
Depending on the technical characteristics of the air-cooler concerned, we multiply the base
price by one or more of the correction factors shown in Tables A2.3.8a through A2.3.8e. We
then have:
air cooler price = base price .S, .fp .A . f N . f ,
where
f , is the correction factor for tube thickness
fp is the pressure correction factor
fi is the correction factor for tube length
f N is the correction factor for number of rows
f , is the correction factor for the kind of material employed.
Appendix 2. Pr6-fstime Method 357
2.11
1.65 0.8
1.24 0.7
(Source: IFP)
b. Effect of pressure
Pressure (bar) fP
4 0 1 .oo
10 to 20 1.03
20 to 30 1.06
30 to 50 1.10
50 to 75 1.13
75 to 100 1.15
100 to 150 1.20
A2
3
Tube length (m) A
12 0.90
10 1.oo
8 1.05
6 1.12
5 1.15
Number of rows fN
3 1.25
4 1.15
5 1.05
6 1 .oo
8 0.90
10 0.85
358
'hbe material
(aluminum fins) fm
The method does not apply to vacuum exchangers. Its accuracy depends essentially upon the
accuracy of the determination of r (or U).
Plate exchangers were designed for the purpose of improving heat management. Their overall
transfer coefficients are generally much higher than those obtained for tube-type exchangers.
They have several other advantages, notably:
0 Their mass and footprint are smaller than those for traditional exchangers: for this reason
a stack of plates in a frame, sealed by intervening joints that are secured by tie beams;
they offer great flexibility of operation, since the number of plates can easily be
changed,
0 Part-welded or chambered exchangers, a modification of the first category: every other
joint is replaced by a weld; this type of equipment is very useful when one of the two
fluids is likely to cause joint deterioration,
Appendix 2. Prk-Estime Method 359
The defining size is the exchanger surface and it is calculated in a similar fashion to the size
of tube-type exchangers, i.e., by using the following formula:
where
Sexch is the exchanger surface (m2)
Q is the quantity of heat exchanged (kcal/hr)
U is the overall heat-transfer coefficient (kcal/hr. m2. “C)
LMTD is the Logarithmic Mean Temperature Difference (“C).
The difference as compared with traditional exchangers lies in the value of the coefficient
U.As a rough guide, Table A2.3.9 provides an outline of the ranges given by manufacturers
(Baniquand in particular).
360 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
A2
3 1 000 000
100 000
loo00
1 000
10 100 1wO
Surface area (m2)
1.8
1.7
1.6
L
s
m
1.5
-
0
c.
1.4
8
E
3 1.3
a
g!
n
1.2
1.1
1
10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25
Pressure (bar)
A2
1ooooo00 3
I Oooo00
loo 000
100 1000 10000
Surface area (m2)
1.3
1.25
b
‘i, 1.2
d
E
e 1.15
e
E
n
l.l
1.05
I
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Pressure (bar)
A2
3
Base price conditions
This is a tax-free, ex factory price, expressed in mid-2000 €, for a pressure of 10 bar and
nitrile rubber joints.
There are now hardly any exchangers with joints in a material other than nitrile rubber or
EPDM (the use of this latter material has little effect on the price: 5 to 10%).
Although a fully welded exchanger is generally more attractive from a technical view-
point, we sometimes find P E s with Viton joints, which can withstand temperatures up to
170°C. In this case, a good approximation of the price may be obtained by adding together
the corrected price and the value of the base price in stainless steel for the calculated
exchanger surface, i.e., by multiplying the base price by 1 + f p instead offp.
A2.3.3.4 Comment
All these graphs have been compiled by using the MAP-H modeling software, without which
the approach would not have been possible. In fact, only a dozen points were available and
the use of linear regressions would not have provided answers.
In terms of the figures, thanks to the “universal” equations and the functional descriptions
that it employs, the model was able first of all to determine the form of the various curves,
and then to position them appropriately by using the available points.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 363
The price includes the electric motor driver (or turbine driver, if the appropriate correction
factor is applied).
Price Determination
Use the graphs in Figs. A2.4.la and A2.4.lb for process pumps, supplied with driver. If
necessary, apply the corrections from Tables A2.4.la through A2.4.le. For vertical centrifu-
gal pumps with high outflows (axial flow and mixed types), use Fig. A2.4.2, which gives their
prices, complete with driver.
3 64 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
Electric motor
Turbine: power rating between 8 and 10 kW
Turbine: power rating between 11 and 30 kW
Turbine: power rating between 3 1 and 100 kW 1.50
Turbine: power rating greater than 100 kW 1.20
m e fm
Cast steel 1.oo
Bronze 1.15
Cast steel. 3 16 stainless 1.10
A2 3 16 stainless 1.20
4 Monel 1.45
3 16 stainless 1.20
Monel 1.45
Temperature (“C) ft
450 1.oo
150-250 1.15
>250 1.30
100000
f
zm
lo00 1
1 10 100 loo0
Outflow (m3hr)
1 oo0000
A2
4
1OOo00
100
Outflow ( m 3 h r )
1 o00000
6
ti
3
X
5f 100000
6
e
w
1000
100 1 000 loo00
Outflow (m3hr)
A2.4.1.2 ReciprocatingPumps
A2 Use the graph in Fig. A2.4.3, which gives the cost of reciprocating pumps for two pressure
4 domains, as a function of the hydraulic power (the product of outflow and manometric
height). It applies to duplex (2-cylinder) cast iron pumps, with manual regulation of outflow
for suction pressures below 20 bar. Various corrections must be applied, depending on the
following characteristics:
0 Number of cylinders utilized,
Only the correction factors for the type of material utilized and the effect of discharge pres-
sure (Tables A2.4.2a and A2.4.2b) can easily be defined.
Figure A2.4.4 gives the electrical power requirements of centrifugal and reciprocating
pumps, based on the required hydraulic power.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 367
1o
oom
1oOooO
1om
loo00
I I 1 1 1 1 1 1 I I 1 l l l l I I I I 1 1 1 1 1 I 1 I I 1 1 1 1
1
I I I
lo00
/I
t
I I I I I I I I I I I I 1 1 1 1 1 1 I I I 1 T l I I I I I l l l l
0.1
10 100 lo00 loo00
Outflow (m3hr) * AP(bar)
100OOO
P
B
e
-8
t
lo00
1 10 100 1OOO loo00
Outflow (m3hr)
A2
4
Figure A2.4.6 Compressorprices (electric motor driver included).
(Source: IFP)
Figure A2.4.7 gives the cost of lower powered compressors (particularly reciprocating
compressors for air and hydrogen).
The cost of turbo-blowers, superchargers, and fans may be evaluated using the data in
Fig. 142.4.8,for the range of conditions defined above.
The data in these figures cover the cost of equipment that is unassembled, but that includes
reducing gear, base, ancillary equipment, and electric motor driver. For turbine driven compres-
sors we apply the correction coefficienth, defined in Table A2.4.3a; the effects of maximum
pressure and of materials are corrected by the coefficients& max and f, from Tables A2.4.3b
and A2.4.3~.
(Note that the manufacturers may include the costs of erection of some of the equipment
in the ex factory cost.)
Appendix 2. PrkEstime Method 371
1 o00000
100ooO
loo00
10 100 lo00
Power (kw)
1mm -
A2
4
1OOo00
loo00
1OOO
lo00 loo00 100OOO
Intake volume (m3/hr)
fp max
Maximum pressure (bar)
Centrifugal compressor Reciprocating compressor
<75 1.oo 1.00
75- 100 1.08 1.05
100-150 1.16 1.10
150-200 1.25 1.18
200-300 1.38 1.30
300-400 1.52 1.43
400- 500 1.68 1.57
500-600 1.86 1.72
(Source: IFP)
We may distinguish:
Heating furnaces
0 Reaction furnaces (see Reactors, Appendix A2.2).
agent that then transmits its heat to a product that cannot be directly heated, the heating
of feeds in certain plants, or the intermediate heating of certain outflows.
For heating a fluid with partial vaporization. These are, for example, distillation fur-
naces.
In the second type, not only are the feeds brought to the desired temperature, they are also
maintained for a certain time at that level so that the desired reaction may take place (furnaces
for steam cracking, thermal reforming, etc.).
Sizing a furnace is a very complicated matter, best left to specialists. However, the heating
power to be provided is a characteristic dimension that can easily be calculated, and by itself
is sufficient to determine the price.
We note however that a distinction is often made between furnaces that are delivered pre-
assembled, generally for plants of smaller capacities, and ones that have to assembled in
place, and which are of larger scale.
0.1 1 10 100
Heating power (106 kcallhr)
Type fd
Material fm
Carbon steel 0.00
Chrome-molybdenumsteel 0.50
18-8 stainless steel 0.75
(Source: IFP)
c. Effect of pressure
Pressure (bar) fP
<30 0.00
30-70 0.10
70- 100 0.15
100-150 0.25
150-200 0.45
200-250 0.60
Butane 30.0
Propane 23.0
Natural gas:
Lacq 9.6
Hassi R’Mel 10.6
Groningue 8.4
Previous Page
Steam ejectors, used for vacuum operations, do not in themselves require a very accurate
evaluation, since their price is usually low, even negligible, in comparison with the other
components of a unit’s principal equipment. But it is desirable to determine the consumptions
of utilities, particularly steam, that their use entails. The performance of ejectors, i.e., the vac-
uum that they produce, depends on the number of stages (Table A2.6.1).
Number of stages 1 2 3 4 5
Absolute suction pressure (mmHg) 276 10-100 1-25 0.15-4 0.05-0.20
0
Intermediate condensers
} steam, and if necessary to recover these components.
A final condenser before venting to the atmosphere, if necessary.
The cooling fluid is cold water or brine.
To the extent that the most commonly used software programs do not spell out the procedures
for obtaining the characteristic dimensions of ejectors, it seems desirable to provide some
guidance on methods for supplying possible deficiencies or answering specific needs.
A2
A2.6.1.1 Determining the Maximum Suction Flow 6
The calculation has the following steps:
0 Selection of the absolute suction pressure in millimeters of mercury
The values, provided by the Heat Exchange Institute, are for perfectly sealed commercial
systems. In practice, the value obtained from Fig. A2.6.1 is doubled.
378 Appendix 2. Pr6-EstirneMethod
Determine:
The partial pressure of condensable components at the operating temperature:
For air, the molecular weight is 29. For a mixture, calculate the average molecular weight,
or consider each constituent separately and add them up.
Appendix 2. Pr4-Estirne Method 379
For a mixture, take the average molecular weight or consider each constituent separately
Use Fig. A2.6.2, which enables the correction coefficients to be determined according to:
0 The temperature at which the operation takes place:
Temperature(“C)
200 300 400
1.8
1.6
1.4
c
$ 1.2
E
8 1
c
0.8
IE
5
W
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 180 180
Molecular weight
0 With intermediate condensers: water vapor and cooling water (or brine).
COMMENT
Only the intermediate condensers that are integral parts of the ejector system are con-
sidered. The pre-condensers and the final condenser are calculated separately.
A2 Use the water vapor consumptions given in Table A2.6.2 as a function of the suction pressure.
Interpolate if necessary.
6
When the water vapor is used at a different pressure from that selected for the reference
case (7 bar), apply the correction factor given by Fig. A2.6.3.
COMMENT
In Table A2.6.2 we consider only two stages. In manufacturing, this number is rarely
exceeded.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 381
Table A2.6.2 Steam requirement (kgkg of air) for ejectors without intermediate condenser
1.3
1.2
1.1
0.9
0.8 A:
6
0.7
0.6
4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20
Steam pressure (bar)
b. With IntermediateCondensers
Determine the percentage of noncondensables in the load (wt. %).
Use the utility consumptionsgiven in Table A2.6.3 (water vapor at 7 bar and cooling water
at 20°C) for the various suction pressures and equally various noncondensable contents.
If necessary, interpolate for the various suction pressures or noncondensable contents that
are different from those shown in Table A2.6.3.
Table A2.6.3 Requirements of steam (kg/kg of air) and cooling water (m3ikg of air)
for ejectors with intermediate condensers
If necessary, correct the steam consumption by the pressure factor from Fig. A2.6.3.
COMMENT
There are two kinds of intermediate condenser, mixture or surface type. The first are
less and less frequently used; the second are traditional tube-type exchangers.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 383
Use Figs. A2.6.4a through A2.6.4c, according to whether the ejector has:
0 One stage only
The base conditions for which the price curves were compiled are as follows:
0 Exhaust pipe in stainless steel, ejector body and diffuser in cast iron
0 Reference year: mid-2000.
COMMENT
To determine the price of a two-stage ejector with intermediate surface condenser,
simply take the cost of an ejector without intermediatecondenser and add the amount
for the required tube-type exchanger.
5M)
450
400
350
: 300
5 250
u 200
150
100
A2
6
50
I I I I I I
0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5
Mid-2000 price in 103 Euro. tax-free. ex factory
3oc
250
- 200
55 150
P 100
50
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 9 10
Mld-2000 price in 103 Euro, tax-free, ex factory
350
300
250
A2
6 100
50
0
5 10 15 20 25
Mid-2000 price in I@ Euro, tax-free, ex factory
Generally speaking, it is very difficult to present simple, practical rules for sizing special
equipment, even for quick sizing, in view of the range of apparatus on the market, and the
multiplicity of uses for which they are designed. For this reason, the current software does
not include any general options that are altogether satisfactory.
This is also why the generally available price curves refer to a parameter that is character-
istic of the type of equipment employed, but difficult to determine by means of simplified cal-
culations.
In estimation, consulting a manufacturer will easily solve the problem; in evaluation, we
must proceed in an empirical fashion, by similarity, given that even the basic information that
the vendors of special equipment require for defining their sizing and their prices is usually
unknown.
Accordingly, this appendix presents various pieces of information obtained from a variety
of sources, as well as dimensional items that may help in gaining access to the most recently
available correlation parameters.
The following special equipment is discussed:
A2.7.1 Dryers A2.7.6 Crushers and grinders
A2.7.2 Crystallizers A2.7.7 Cyclones
A2.7.3 Evaporators A2.7.8 Conveyors
A2.7.4 Filters A2.7.9 Vibrating screens
A2.7.5 Centrifuges A2.7.10 Instrumentation
Kinds of
drying
Applications 1 Liquid
gases I Suspensions
Continuous
6lms
Adsorption, absorption
Cooling, compression, coalescence
Flash drying X X x x x x x x
spray drying x x x x x x X -
Cylinder dryer - - - - -
Drum dryer X X X - -
Steam tube rotary dryer - X X x x x x
Conduction or
Screw conveyor dryer X X x x x x x x
indirect heat - -
Vibrating tray dryer - x x x x
Vacuum rotary dryer - X X x x x x
Cabinet (vacuum) (batch) - X x x x x x x
X X: commonlyused
X : limiteduse
- : rarelyused
(Source: IFP)
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 387
The sizing of the vessels is done in the same way as for reactors. The quantity of the adsorbent
determines the volume of the shell and hence its dimensions.
Since this kind of drying proceeds in a cyclical fashion, we may need to provide two, if not
three identical columns to allow for the regeneration phase as well as the essential ancillary
equipment (furnace, exchanger, pumps, etc.).
The initial load of sieves or alumina depends on the adsorbent power and the length of the
cycle. In fact, the duration of the cycle is determined by an economic optimization, involving
the utilization time of the auxiliary equipment (particularly the furnace).
As for the adsorbent power, it is much higher during the first few cycles than during the
final ones. The overall lifetime, measured by the number of cycles, depends on the water con-
tent of the product being dried.
Roughly speaking, we may take the following figures:
0 Length of cycle: 24 to 48 hours
0 Lifetime:
Considering how many ways of drying there are, it is impossible not only to give a detailed
discussion of how the sizing is to be done in each case, but even to define the information that
the manufacturers need for such calculations.
Obviously, the physico-chemical characteristics of the product to be dried are important
parameters; but since dryers have standardized dimensions, we have to consider the volume
of the feed to be treated, and the duration of the operation. Roughly speaking, this depends
on the exchanger surface available (direct or indirect heating), the average transfer coeffi-
cient, the temperature difference between the product to be dried and the heat transfer fluid
circulating in the vessel (gas, steam, fumes, etc.), and the quantity of water to be removed
(evaporation capacity).
Accordingly, we return to the general expression for heat transfers:
Q = U . S . At (A2.7.1) A2
where
7
Q is in kcal/hr
U is in kcal/hrm2."C
s is in m2
At is in OC.
For a solution of salts, U lies between 100 and 350 kcal/hr.m2."C (generally 200). For
sludges, powders, and granules, U is on the order of 25 to 200 kcal/hr.m2."C.
388 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
Since it would be difficult to assemble the characteristics and general performances for
every type of dryer, the information given in Tables A2.7.2a through A2.7.2f concerns only
the equipment most commonly used in the chemistry of the major organic intermediates, cat-
alysts, and sometimes inorganic products.
a. Spray Dryers
The heat requirement of spray dryers is proportional to their maximum thermal efficiency,
i.e., to the ratio:
where
T, is the inlet temperature of the drying gas
Ts is the outlet temperature of the drying gas.
The consumption of electricity is a function of the flow of drymg gas; it also depends on
the temperature.
By way of example, Table A2.7.2a shows the energy requirements for a sludge containing
40% water, a gas inlet temperature of 4OO0C, and an outlet temperature of 120OC.
The inlet gas temperature generally lies between 150 and 350"C, the outlet temperature
between 80 and 90°C.
A2 b. Flash Dryers
7 For a sludge containing 40% water, a gas inlet temperature of 400°C and an outlet tempera-
ture of 1OO"C, Table A2.7.2b shows the energy requirement for flash dryers. These figures
are only indicative, and depend on the characteristics of the product being dried.
Appendix 2. Pr4-Estime Method 389
with paddles, and a jacket for circulation of the heat transfer fluid (hot water, steam,
etc.).
Bicone dryers whose double shell pivots around a horizontal axis (perpendicularto the
cones’ axis of symmetry).
Apply Eq. A2.7.1 to obtain the heat transfer fluid requirement (low pressure steam: 6 bar
in the jacket) from the quantity of heat required (see Appendix A2.3).
390 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estirne Method
Free surface area (m2) 0.6 1.3 2.4 2.4 2.4 4.0 4.0 4.0
Motor power (CV) 5 7.5 15 20 20 20
-
(Source: IFP)
To calculate the heat requirement we use Eq. A2.7.1; the overall transfer coefficient in
steam tubes ranges from 25 to 75 kcal/hr.m2."C (m2 of tube).
A2
7
A2.7.1.3 Dryer Prices
A. Base Prices
Figures A2.7. la and A2.7.1 b give an order of magnitude for the base prices of various types
of convection and conduction dryers, whose characteristicswere presented in Tables A2.7.2a
through A2.7.2f.
392 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estirne Method
1 10 100
Surface area (m*)
A2
7
-8
h
Corrections must be made according to the kind of material employed or the operating
conditions.
B. Price Corrections
Table A2.7.3a Effect of kind of material on the cost of rotary vacuum dryers
Table A2.7.3b Price correction factors Cf, andf,) for rotary drum dryers
Pressure fP Material fm
where
C is the weight of crystallized product obtained (kg of hydrated or anhydrous crystals)
R is ratio of the molecular weight of the hydrated product to the molecular weight of the
anhydrous product
Appendix 2. PrcSEstirne Method 395
S is the weight solubility (parts of anhydrous product per 100 parts of solvent) at the
final drying temperature
W, is the weight of anhydrous product in the initial solution (kg)
Ho is the weight of solvent in the initial solution (kg)
E is the quantity of solvent evaporated during the drying (kg).
When E is unknown it can be calculated from the expression:
where
C is the specific heat of the initial solution (kcal/kg*"C)
At is the temperature differential between entry and exit ("C)
qc is the crystals' latent heat of crystallization per unit of weight (kcalkg)
L, is the solution's latent heat of evaporation (kcaVkg).
When the required production is known, these equations enable calculation of the feed to
the crystallizer.
E
s
0
e
A2
7
Corrections have to be made according to the kind of material employed or the perfor-
mance required (Table A2.7.4a and A2.7.4b):
corrected price = base price .film
.fm
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 397
Dimensions fiim
90% + 16 mesh 1.oo
90% + 20 mesh 0.90
90% + 30 mesh 0.75
(Source: IFP)
I m e I Material I fm
small production. They consist of a vertical tube whose lower portion is fitted with a jacket,
with a high-speed rotor inside.
A. Principle
As a rough guide, the exchanger surface can be taken as the principal parameter for determin-
ing a price. In fact, numerous other factors are involved in defining the essential characteris-
tics of an evaporator (dimensions, agitator power, etc.).
The basic expression that is employed has already been utilized for heat exchanger calcu-
lations (Appendix A2.3), namely:
where
S is the surface area (m2)
Q is the total quantity of heat transferred (kcal/hr)
U is the heat transfer coefficient (kcal/hr*m2."C)
At is the average temperature difference ("C).
where
t is the temperature of the fluid ("C)
U is in kcal/hrm2."C.
In addition, Table A2.7.5 gives the heat transfer coefficients for thin-film evaporators,
according to their intended application.
U
Applications
(kcaYhr.m2-oC)
Steam heating:
Concentration of aqueous solutions 1 100-1 600
Dehydration of organic solutions 700-950
Distillation of organic liquids 700- 1 000
Stripping of organic liquids 400-600
Operation as a reboiler 850- 1 000
Recovery of solvents 750-800
Heating by heat transfer fluid:
Distillation of liquids with high boiling points 350-500
Stripping of organic liquids 200-350
Operation as a reboiler 500-550
(Source: IFP)
A. Base Prices
Figure A2.7.3 gives the base prices for various types of evaporators as a hnction of the
exchanger surface, for equipment in the following materials:
Jacketed evaporators: 3 16 L stainless
Thin-film evaporators: 3 16 L stainless
Shell-and-tube evaporators: cast iron shell and copper tubes
10 000 000
1 000 000
100 000
A2
7
loo00
0.1 1 10 100
Exchanger surface (m*)
B. Price Corrections
Material
Carbon steel
304 L stainless
3 16 L stainless
Hastelloy G 2.50
(Source: IFP)
Material: shelytubes
Cast iron-copper
Carbon steel
Carbon steel-aluminum 0.7
Nickel-nickel
(Source: IFP)
Material: shelytubes fm
Cast iron-copper 1.oo
Monel-cupronickel 1.35
Cast nickel iron-nickel 1.80
402 Appendix 2. Pr&€stirne Method
Types of filter:
0 Batch filters:
0 Cartridge filters
0 Basket strainers
0 Bag filters
0 Sheet filters
0 Rotary vacuum filters: string, roll, blade, or belt discharge, with or without pre-coating
0 Belt filters
Sizing a filter, i.e., determining the surface area required for treating a given feed, depends
on the characteristics of the product to be separated and the properties of the filter. Test mea-
surements are used as references in the consideration of each case.
As a result, it is practically impossible to find even an approximate rule that would be gen-
erally applicable for calculating the surface area.
A2 Nevertheless, Table A2.7.8 presents performance figures for the filters whose prices are
given in this appendix.
7
The power of the motors required to drive rotary or belt filters averages around 4 to 10 HP.
Appendix 2. Pre-Estirne Method 403
x x : standard operation
x : possible operation
(Source: IFP)
I 000 000
2
c
m
r
X
6
e
*;
m
c
UI
?
w
0
0
:
E
.-E
0
.-
t
10000 J I I I I I I Ill
1 10 100 1000
Surface area (m2)
Some corrections need to be made, particularly for the kind of material employed, by mul-
tiplying the base price by&. Tables A2.7.9a and A2.7.9b present the base characteristics and
possible correction factors for each type of filter appearing in Fig. A2.7.4.
The pump unit and the price of filter cloths are included in the base cost of automatic frame
filters.
Table A2.7.9a Effect of kind of material on prices of vertical and horizontal frame filters
For the other filters whose cost is shown in Fig. A2.7.4 the base conditions are as follows:
0 Rotary vacuum filters: 304 stainless
A2.7.5.1 General
The principal methods of separation using centrifuges, and their applications, are presented
in Table A2.7.10.
Particle
Solids
Applications diameter
(%)
tP)
~
Centrifugal dryers
- cyclic:
pusher C 20 to 75 10 to 5000
knife b(?) and c 5 to60 0.7 to 1000
pendular C 5 to60 0.7 to 1000
- spiral screw rotary decanter b(?) and c 2 to40 0.3 to 3000
High-speed disk separators
nozzle b and c 5 to25 0.07 to 70
aperture b and c 1 to10 0.07 to 70
hermetic bowl a, b and c Oto 1 0.07 to 70
a: liquid-liquid separation.
b: liquid-liquid-solid separation.
c: liquid-solid separation.
(Source: IFP)
0.1 1 10
Bowl or basket diameter (m)
1 000 000
d
g 1ooOoo
a
w
Q9
P.-c
.-8
t
10000
0 1 10
Bowl or basket diameter (m)
1 000 000
100ow)
A2
loo00
7
1 10 100
Capacity (m3/hr)
A2.7.6.1 General
A very rough classification of crushers and grinders can be made on the basis of the hardness
of the product to be processed, and the initial and final sizes of the solid particles. This is illus-
trated in Table A2.7.11, which also makes possible a quick selection of the type of equipment
to employ.
Product Size in cm
OpCration ‘Qpe of equipment
hardness Feed Product
Crushing:
primary hard 150-30 50-10 Jaw & gyratory crushers
50-10 12-2.5 Roller & bar mills
secondary hard 12-2.5 2.5-0.5 Jaw & gyratory crushers
4-0.6 0.5-0.08 Roller, bar, disk, & hammer mills
weak 50-10 5- 1 Roller, disk, hammer, & rotary knife
mills
Grinding:
coarse hard 0.5-0.08 0.06-0.008 Roller, disk, hammer, & rotary knife
mills
Mills with low and medium
tangential speeds
fine hard 0.12-0.015 0.008-0.001 Mills with low, medium, and high
tangential speeds
Fluid drive mills
Disintegration:
coarse weak 1.2-0.17 0.06-0.008 Mills with high tangential speeds
fine weak 0.4-0.05 0.008-0.001 or fluid drive
(Source: IFP)
A2
7
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 409
A. Base Prices
Figure A2.7.6 gives the average prices of various types of crushers and grinders as a function
of their processing capacity in t/hr. This graph represents standard steel equipment.
A variety of supplemental information can be supplied.
I00 000000
10 000 000
1 000 000
100 000
a. Bar Mills
Table A2.7.12a Effect of product grain size on the cost of rod mills
Table A2.7.12b Rod mills: effect of capacity on rod load and motor power
Capacity (t/hr) 3 10 25
Rod load (t/hr) 12 30 70
Power (CV) 125 400 960
Capacity (thr) (min. & max. settings) 4-9 7-17 15-30 30-70 50-90
Motor power (CV) 13 25 35 50 60
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 41 1
95
90
50
10
100 000
10000
1 000
1 000 10000 100000 1 000 000
Capacity (m3hr)
A2.7.8.1 General
Price data are more readily available for vibrating screens than for other equipment used in
separating grains of varying size.
The price of the equipment essentially depends on the screen surface area, and this param-
eter is dependent on the granulometry of the feed to be processed and the products sought, as
well as the type of screen utilized.
Although precise standards do exist, it appears difficult to develop a quick calculation
method: it is preferable to consult the manufacturers directly.
As a rough guide, Fig. A2.7.8 shows the variation of simple (one stage only) vibrating screens
as a function of their surface area.
Corrections may be applied for the number of stages, by multiplying the base price byf,,
(Table A2.7.13).
The most common sizes and the power required are summarized in Table A2.7.14.
a
E
w
Qv
0
E
.-C
A:
7
I
1
2
3
II 1.oo
1.20
1.35
II
(Source: IFP)
A2.7.9.1 General
A2 The main types of conveyor are the following:
7 0 Belt conveyors: flat or raised edge. These are horizontal or inclinable, characterized by the
width of the transporter belt, the distance between roller axles, the linear speed of the belt,
and the motor power, as required by the flow of product to be carried and its density.
Screw conveyors. These too may or may not be inclined, and are characterized by the
diameter of the Archimedes screw, the distance between its ends, the speed of the rotor, and
the power of the motor, considering the required output. The kind of product to be transported
also affects the choice of the material from which the equipment is made.
Appendix 2. Pr&Estime Method 415
0 Bucket elevators. The most important parameters are the unit capacity of the buckets, the
height of the lift, the speed of the chain that carries the buckets, and the power of the driver:
these are a function of the flow of product to be moved, and its density.
1 000 000
100 000
a
e
w
0
8 10 000
7
E
E
.-C
.-8
t
1 000
A. Belt Conveyors A2
7
a. Technical Parameters
Capacity (t/hr) (Table A2.7.15a)
Motor power (CV) (Table A2.7.15b).
416 Appendix 2. Pre-Estime Method
Table A2.7.15a Belt conveyors: effect of belt width and speed on quantity carried (d = 1)
(Source: IFP)
Table A2.7.15b Belt conveyors: effect of belt width on driver power, for a given speed (1 d s )
and a particular product tonnage (d c- 1)
b. Price Corrections
0 Base price. The prices in Fig. A2.7.9 are for flat or raised edge belt conveyors with the
following characteristics:
- Width: 0.50 m
- Speed: 1 m l s .
0 Correction factor (Table A2.7.16).
A2
Width (m) Aarg
7
0.500 1.oo
0.650 1.20
0.800 1.30
1.000 1.50
1.200 1.70
Appendix 2. PrtLEstirneMethod 417
B. Screw Conveyors
Table A2.7.17 Capacity (t/hr) and motor power (CV) of screw conveyors
b. Price Corrections
0 Base price. The curve in Fig. A2.7.9 for screw conveyors in carbon steel is based on the
following conditions:
- Diameter of Archimedes screw: 0.40 m
- Rotor speed: 60 rpm.
0 Correction factors (Table A2.7.18).
For screw conveyors in 304 L stainless steel the price curve may be obtained from the pre-
vious one (for carbon steel) by using a multiplying factor of about 1.7.
Diameter fdiam
(m) Conveyor: carbon steel Conveyor: 304 L stainless
0.150 0.65 0.60
0.300 0.85 0.80
0.400 1.oo 1.oo
0.500 1.15 1.20
C. Bucket Elevators
Base price. The curve in Fig. A2.7.9 for bucket elevators was based on the following
conditions:
- Capacity: 80 tfhr
- 304 L stainless steel buckets.
418 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
Capacity(') (tlhr)
1.oo
120 1.20
(1) Density near 1.
(Source: IFP)
The factorfg, which is applied to determine the erected cost of each category of equipment
and which is given in Tables 3.21 and 3.22, covers standard instrumentation.
However, it does not cover automatic controls, whose cost depends not only on the number
of lines, but also on just how complex each one is. Moreover, such controls are installed only
in the final stages of plant construction, by specialist companies whose fees cover both the
equipment and its installation on the unit. In other words, in this case it is not possible to sep-
arate the equipment part of the cost from the other items, in particular the cost of erection. In
practice, then, the price of the automatic control system is added to the production battery
limits investment, as calculated without including this item. In any event, a rough estimate of
this amount may be obtained from the cost of the principal equipment or its component
pieces. Accordingly, there are two possible options:
(a) For standard units, add 10% of the overall price of the principal equipment
(b) Or break it down by categories of equipment, taking:
15% for the reactor and column set-up
0 5%fordmms
A2 IMPORTANT COMMENT
7 It should be emphasized that the values calculated by either method are assumed to
already include the costs of erection or other related expenses, and are to be added to
the erected costs of the principal equipment.
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 419
0 Electricity generation
0 Obtaining boiler water, process water, and cooling water (including recycling, i.e.,
A. Base Price
-36
%
(Y
O0 Oo0 Oo0
$
-7
8
c
10000000
m
W
8
:
0
.z 1000000
.-C
.-i3
B
jj
e
w 100000
1 10 100 1000
Capacity (t/hr of steam)
B. Correction Coefficients
Table A2.8.1 Correction factors for boiler base prices
a. Effect of type
I Type of boiler I fc
Natural gas boiler -0.3
Heating fuel oil boiler 0.0
Boiler with anti-pollution system 0.7
(desulphurization, de-nitrogenization)
(Source: IFP)
1 1
b. Effect of superheating
I I f t
;:;:
Temperature of superheating ("C)
A2 Saturation
l;;
8
150 0.20
200 0.25
(Source: IFP)
Appendix 2. Pr@-EstirneMethod 42 1
c. Effect of pressure
I Pressure (bar) I fP I
10 0.00
40 0.65
100 0.75
Table A2.8.2 Electricity generation: overall energy efficiencies for various alternatives
'Qpe of facility
V
r
K
1000000000
t
5
I
* 100000000
2
w
0
0
10 000 000
1 000 000
100 000
1 10 100 1 000
Power (MW)
p 100000000
0
c)
3
P
0
g 10000000
z- in,,,,, , I , I I I U
d
L
g 1000000
0
B
E
E
.-c
p) 100000
.-0
k
x
c)
F
w 10000
1 10 100 1000 10 000 100 000
Capacity (m3/hr)
Finally, in some plants the temperature of the cooling water is allowed to rise by more than
10°C: the basic investment then has to be corrected by means of a coefficient whose value is
given in Table A2.8.3.
3
1
(Source: IFP)
At (“C)
1.8
A2.8.1.4 Refrigeration A2
8
In chemical plants it is often necessary to have production cycles for various levels of cold.
The systems employed vary considerably depending on the temperature required (propane,
ethane, or methane cycles): the investment cost depends on the temperature and the maximum
unit production capacity.
424 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estirne Method
Figure A2.8.4 shows the unit price (mid-2000 Mf per Mkcal) as a function of temperature
for the corresponding maximum unit capacity: it refers to installed units, including centrifu-
gal compressors, evaporators, condensers, etc., and connection and erection costs.
The investment cost is calculated from the maximum capacity selected, by applying an
extrapolation exponent of 0.7 for the smaller sizes; otherwise we determine the number and
capacity of the modules required to service the perceived overall needs.
c.
3
X
6 2000000
?!
zI
m^ 1500000
e
W
0
0
1000000
.-
E
.-E
.-0 500000
-
h
P
?!
W 0
-100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 40 -30 -20 -10 0
Temperature (“C)
The production cost includes the considerable electricity consumption, which rise in pro-
portion to the temperature level sought (Fig. A2.8.5).
Lastly, we can consider the consumption ofwater, which can be obtained from Fig. A2.8.6.
A2 The facilities that consume utilities are often close to their point of production. For this rea-
son distribution costs are sometimes negligible in comparison to the cost of the production
8 units.
However, in some cases the investment required by distribution is on the same order of
magnitude as that for production: this may be due to distance, or to the particular nature of
the utility concerned (insulation of steam pipes, for example).
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 425
2 500
2 000
500
0
-1 00 -80 40 40 -20 0
Temperature (“C)
300
250
200
-m
$
n
150
E
100
50
0
-1 00 -80 -60 40 -20 0
Temperature (“C) A2
8
Figure A2.8.6 Cooling water requirement for refrigeration.
(Source: IFP)
426 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
0 Cooling water
0 Electricity.
A2.8.2.1 Steam
Depending on the distance between the producing and consuming facilities, and the size of
the steam production unit, the amount of the investment assigned to distribution may vary
from:
3 500 to 13000 mid-2000 € per t/hr of steam produced.
If data concerning distance are lacking, it is wise to increase the fixed costs in the steam
transaction price by 10%.
A2.8.2.3 Electricity
There are several different cases, depending on the area of investment:
0 Electricity for general use (lighting circuits): 340 to 480 mid-2000 €/kW
0 Primary transformer: 150 to 240 mid-2000 €/kVA; it is necessary to correct for capacity
3 000 1 .o
5 000 0.6
10000 0.4
20 000 0.3
A2 (Source: IFP)
8
0 Secondary transformer: 140to 190 mid-2000 €/kVA; it is necessary to correct for capac-
ity (see Table A2.8.5).
Appendix 2. Pre-Estime Method 427
1500
2 000 0.5
(Source: IFP)
Some types of utility are produced using standard equipment, whose price can be found in
Appendices A2.1 to A2.7. This provides the investment for principal equipment.
We can also calculate the investment costs for distribution.
Utilities whose use involves the common types of equipment include:
Compressed air (compressor, filter, dryer)
Treated water (filter, reactor, distillation column)
0 Fuel (pump, storage tank, etc.).
A2
8
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 429
0 Pressurized vessels:
- Cylindrical
- Spherical.
Figures A2.9. la, A2.9.lb, A2.9.2, and A2.9.3 give prices for this equipment as a function
of capacity, for very specific types of storage and particular conditions of utilization. Correc-
tion factors must be applied for other cases.
Material fm
Carbon steel 1.oo
Aluminum 1.40
Rubber coated 1.50
Lead coated 1.55
Stainless steel 3.20
Enameled steel 3.25
A2
9
430 Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method
pi
r
F!
ic
+
u)
e
W 10000
0
0
2
.-
E
.-0
C
.-
h
P
L
F! 1 000
W
0 1 10 100
Capacity (m3)
I 000 000
100 000
10 000
100 1 000 10000 100 000 1 000000
Capacity (m3)
5 1000OOO
0
4-
100OOO
1oOOO
1000
1 10 100 1000
Capacity (m3)
100OOO
1 10 100 1 000
Capacity (m3)
TYPe fd
Cone roof 1.o
Floating roof 1.1
Elevator-type roof 1.3
(Source: IFP)
Material
Carbon steel
Rubber coated
Lead coated
304 stainless steel 2.8
(Source: IFP)
A2
9
Appendix 2. Pr6-Estime Method 433
Pressure (bar) fP
<lo 1.oo
10 to 15 1.20
15 to 20 1.so
Pressure (bar) fP
3 1.o
5 1.3
7 1.5
10 1.8
15 2.3
A2
9
INDEX
Cash flow 72
annual discounted calculation 86
capital repayment 111
capitalized discounted 93
financing capacity 111
growth 111
maintenance 111
practical significance 111
Cash from operations (see Cash flow)
Catalysts 179
heterogeneous phase 118
homogeneous phase 120
mass 135
supported 135
CE (chemical engineering) plant cost index 200
Centrifuges 405
Charges
financial (interests) 72 163
fixed 151
capital 154
operating 151
indirect 271
variable 116
Chilton C.H. 270
Civil engineering 264
Cladding (see Vessels, pressure) 66
Clerk J. 274
Coefficient
α 96
β 98
overall gross heat transfer (tube-type heat
exchangers) 337
Coefficient (Cont.)
overall gross transfer coefficient (tube-type
exchangers) 338 339
overall heat transfer (evaporated) 398
Columns (see Vessels, pressure)
Commodity material 264
Compressed air 427
Compressor 368
prices 370
types 368
Construction (see Erection)
Contingencies 264
Contractor fees 175
Conveyors 414
belt conveyors 415
bucket elevators 417
general 414
price 416
screw conveyors 417
sizes 415
Co-products 117
Correlation (mathematical with precursor index) 26
Cost
definition 264
direct
average structure 270
Guthrie method 279 280 284
solids handling or special equipment 284
standard chemical equipment 280
economic cost of price 107
operating expenses invariant 108
operating expenses variable 109
Cost (Cont.)
indices (see Indices)
examples 195
use 194
indirect, Guthrie method 280 284
labor 149
location effect (see Investments)
of price 112
operating 112 182 183
breakdown 114
components 115
production (see Price, cost of)
shadow - of equity fund 90
transport costs and risks standardized
language 128
utilities, definition 137
Cran J. 208
Criteria of profitability 71
standardization 71
typological classification 71
criteria based on the concept of present
value 71
empirical criteria 71
Crushers (see Grinders) 408
performance 409
price 409
Crystallizers 394
crystallization efficiency 394
prices 396
selection 395
Cumulative discounted cash flow (see
Capitalized discounted cash flow)
Depreciation
background 155
calculating depreciation 158
declining balance 159
economic 109
of currency (rate of) 84
operating period and depreciation period 156
provision, allocation for 72 155
salvage value of facilities 158
sinking fund 162
straight-line 159
sum of the years’ digits 162
Direct analogy (see Estimation)
Distribution of utilities 424
cooling water 426
electricity 426
steam 426
Driver, pump 363
Drums (see Vessels, pressure)
Dryers 385
flash dryers 388
multipurpose dryers 391
Dryers (Cont.)
prices 391
rotary drum dryers 390
selection 385
sizing 385
alumina or molecular sieves 387
surface exchange drying 387
spray dryers 388
steam-tube rotary dryers 391
vacuum rotary dryers 389
Ejectors, steam
calculations 377
consumption of utilities 380
maximum suction flow 377
number of stages 377
prices 383
steam 377
Elasticity 6
anticipation elasticity 7
coefficient 7 18
cross elasticity of demand 8
empirical or casual elasticity 7
price-demand elasticity 7
substitution price elasticity 9
theoretical elasticity 7
Electric motor 364
Electrical systems (see Secondary material)
EMIP (Equivalent maximum investment
period) 78
Engineering, fees 172
Exchangers (Cont.)
prices of exchanger tubes 349
prices of tube-type 342
double pipe exchangers 347
exchangers with tube bundles 342
selection 341
TEMA standard 342
tube-type heat 337
Experts
Delphi method 35
Exponential methods (see Investments,
methods for determining)
“extrapolation factor” procedure 248
flow methods 253
Allen D.H. and Page R.C. 254
Stallworthy E.A. 253
functional modules method 263
notional operating unit methods 248
Hill R.D. 248
Wilson G.T. 251
Zevnik F.C. and Buchanan R.L. 249
significant steps methods 256
Taylor J.H. 256
Viola J.L. 260
External (see Vessels, pressure)
Extrapolation
exponent 189
factor 186
Forecasts (Cont.)
intuitive procedures 20
limits of methods 38
long-term 20
medium-term 20
methods 18
objective procedures 20
processing and extrapolation of historical
data 20
short-term 20
types 19
very long-term 20
very short-term 20
Foundations (see Civil engineering and also
Secondary material)
Functional modules method (FMM) 292 309
application 313
auxiliary modules 313
description of the method 311
distillation module 310
functional modules 312
principle 292
Furnaces 373
energy cost 375
general observations 373
price 373
Indices (Cont.)
industrial production (IPI) 27
location (Boyd) 214
tightness 55
updating or cost index 190
Boulitrop’s 195
chemical engineering 200
concept of 190
ENR (Engineering news-record)
construction cost index 196
equipment cost 196
IFP Eval and bieval 220
Laspeyres index 192
M&S 196
Nelson 197
Paasche (De) index 192
principal features and consistency 201
Vandamme 195
Von Kölbel and Schulze 201
WEBCI (Werkgroep Begrotingsproblemen
in der Chemische Industrie) 201
Initial loads 178
Instrumentation 264 268 418
Insulation (see Secondary material)
Insurance 153
Interest
compound 79
continuous compound 80
on construction loans 179
simple 79
Internals (see Trays, packings)
Investments
adjustment of capacity 185
battery limits
definition 166
determination of 223
structure 263
charges 164
location effect 185 206
location effect 206
background 206
first Attempt 207
systematic methods 211
methods for determining 247
total grass roots 166
updating 190
concept 190
examples 195
problem 190
use 194
IRP (Interest recovery period) 78
IRR 55
Labor 146
concept of the shift worker 146
costs 149
Methanol
example 46 47
Methods
Allen D.H. and Pages R.C. 254
Bach N.G. 266
exponential 248
factorial 263
functional modules 309
Guthrie K.M. 279
Hand W.E. 267 274
Hill R.D. 248
Hirsch J.H. and Glazier E.M. 275
IFP 291
Klumpar I.V. and Slavsky S.T. 286
Lang 266
least square (linear regressions) 22
Miller C.A. 211 276
pré-estimation 286
pre-estime method 319
return on investment (ROI) 75
SRI (Stanford research institute) 290
Stallworthy E.A. 253
Taylor J.H. 256
variable multiplying factors 269
Viola J.L. 260
Wilson G.T. 251
Zevnik F.C. and Buchanan R.L. 249
Miller C.A. 211 276
Models
econometric 30
behavioral 31
economic analysis 31
Models (Cont.)
several explanatory variables 30
inter-industry exchange 31
Molecular sieves (see Dryers)
Moving average method 22
MTBE
example 11
Price (Cont.)
reference 122
spot 122
threshold 127
Process Data Book 177
Production of utilities 419
cooling, boiler, and process waters 422
electricity 421
refrigeration 423
steam 419
Products
evolution 48
price structure 48
raw materials/products duality 5
Profitability
project 67
Profits
gross 72
real 72
Pumps 363
centrifugal pumps 363
driver 363
reciprocating pumps 366
rotary and metering pumps 368
Rate
currency depreciation 84
discount (see Present value) 81
constant money 83
current money 83
Rate (Cont.)
growth
average 63
constant real 64
real 63
variable real 65
Internal rate of return (IRR) 99
load 112
psychological discount 84
taxation 69
utilization and load 113
Raw materials 41 116
products duality 5 6
Reactors (see Vessels, pressure)
agitated 335
comparable to columns or drums 335
Reagents 118
Relationships prices raw materials and line
of equivalence 41
Relative capital enrichment (RCE) 106
Repayment 91
Representatives (future-oriented method,
forecasting) 34
ROI 55 71 75
Royalties
paid-up 175
running 176
Sales
annual 72
normalization of evolution curves 58
volume 58
This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.
Index Terms Links
Sales volume 39 58
Salvage value (see also Depreciation
provision) 87
“Scaling factor” or “six tenths factor” 185
Secondary material 264 268 283
287 289 303
Sensitivity (estimation) 232
Shell (see Vessels, pressure)
exchangers 343
Shift worker 146
Site preparation (see Civil Engineering)
Skirt (see Vessels, pressure)
Smoothing, exponential 24
Spare parts 174
SRI (Stanford Research Institute) method 290
Stages in the progress of a project 224
implementation phases 228
construction proper 229
studies and supplies 228
study or pre-study stages 225
feasibility studies 226
identification 226
transition period 227
Stallworthy E.A. 253
Startup expenses 180
Steel structures (see Secondary material)
Stevenson D. 61
Storage 169 429
atmospheric pressure 429
3
capacity greater than 100 m 432
capacity less than 100 m3 429
definition 169
Storage (Cont.)
pressurized storage tanks 432
cylindrical tanks 432
spherical tanks 433
Study (market)
general procedure 36
Styrene-butadiene rubber (example) 62
Superchargers 369
Supervision 150
Taxes 68 153
Taylor J.H. 256
Technical dollar exchange rate (IFP) (see
Investment cost, location effect)
Terris P. 209
Thermal insulation (see Secondary material)
Thickness 319
application 321
basic formula 319
maximum allowable stress 320
welding coefficient 320
Timmerhaus K.D. 270
Traceability 232
Trays 330
price 330
Treated water 427
Trend, strong 49
Tube bundles 342
Turbines 364
Turbo-blowers 369
Turnover ratio 76