Inequality Measurement: Development Issues No. 2
Inequality Measurement: Development Issues No. 2
Inequality Measurement
Development Issues No. 2
21 October 2015
Development Issues are intended to clarify concepts used in the analytical work of the Division, provide references to current development issues and offer a common
background for development policy discussions. This note was prepared by Helena Afonso, Marcelo LaFleur and Diana Alarcón in the Development Strategy and Policy
Analysis Unit in the Development Policy and Analysis Division of UN/DESA. For more information, contact: alarcond@un.org. The full archive is available at:
www.un.org/en/development/desa/policy/wess/ 1
100%
Ratios
Ratios constitute the most basic inequality measures available.
They are simple, direct, easy to understand, and they offer
few data and computation challenges. Accordingly, they do
A not provide as much information as the complex measures
rve
Index
It is the ratio of the average income of the richest x per cent of
ine
Cu
°) L
enz
the population to the average income of the poorest x per cent. It
(45
Lor
ion
income of the 10 per cent richest to that of the 10 per cent poor-
est; D9/D5: ratio of the income of the 10 per cent richest to the
Cumulative percentage of households 100% income of those at the median of the earnings distribution; D5/
Lorenz Curve and Robin Hood Index
D1: ratio of the income of those at the median of the earnings
distribution to the 10 per cent poorest. The Palma ratio and the
20/20 ratio are other examples of decile dispersion ratios.
Hoover index (also known as the Robin Hood index,
Schutz index or Pietra ratio) Palma ratio
It shows the proportion of all income which would have to It is the ratio of national income shares of the top 10 per cent of
be redistributed to achieve a state of perfect equality. In other households to the bottom 40 per cent. It is based on economist
words, the value of the index approximates the share of total José Gabriel Palma’s empirical observation that difference in
income that has to be transferred from households above the the income distribution of different countries (or over time) is
mean to those below the mean to achieve equality in the distri- largely the result of changes in the ‘tails’ of the distribution (the
bution of incomes. Higher values indicate more inequality and poorest and the richest) as there tends to be relative stability in
that more redistribution is needed to achieve income equality. It the share of income that goes to the ‘middle’ (Cobham, 2015).
can be graphically represented as the maximum vertical distance
between the Lorenz curve and the 45-degree line that represents
20/20 ratio
perfect equality of incomes.
It compares the ratio of the average income of the richest 20
Theil index and General Entropy (GE) measures per cent of the population to the average income of the poor-
est 20 per cent of the population. Used by the United Nations
The values of the GE class of measures vary between zero (perfect Development Programme Human Development Report (called
equality) and infinity (or one, if normalized). A key feature of “income quintile ratio”).
these measures is that they are fully decomposable, i.e. inequal-
ity may be broken down by population groups or income sources
or using other dimensions, which can prove useful to policy
References
Bellù, L. G., and Liberati, P. (2006), ‘Policy Impacts on Inequality: Welfare
makers. Another key feature is that researchers can choose a
Based Measures of Inequality – The Atkinson Index’, Food and
parameter α that assigns a weight to distances between incomes Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
in different parts of the income distribution. For lower values Bellù, L. G., and Liberati, P. (2006), ‘Describing Income Inequality: Theil
of α, the measure is more sensitive to changes in the lower tail Index and Entropy Class Indexes’, Food and Agriculture Organization
of the distribution and, for higher values, it is more sensitive to of the United Nations.
changes that affect the upper tail (Atkinson and Bourguignon, Cobham, A., Schlogl, L., and Sumner, A. (2015), ‘Inequality and the Tails:
2015). The most common values for α are 0, 1, and 2. When The Palma Proposition and Ratio Revisited’, Department of Economic
and Social Affairs Working Paper No. 143 (ST/ESA/2015/DWP/143).
α=0, the index is called “Theil’s L” or the “mean log deviation”
‘Handbook of Income Distribution Volume 2’ First Edition (2015), edited by
measure. When α=1, the index is called “Theil’s T” index or, Anthony Atkinson and François Bourguignon, North-Holland (Elsevier).
more commonly, “Theil index”. When α=2, the index is called United Nations Development Programme, ‘2014 Human Development
“coefficient of variation”. Similarly to the Gini coefficient, when Trends by Indicator’, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/data.
income redistribution happens, change in the indices depends World Bank, World Development Indicators. Accessed 13 October 2015.
on the level of individual incomes involved in the redistribution
and the population size (Bellù, 2006).
2 October 2015