Morale and Workplace Performance
Morale and Workplace Performance
net/publication/258200282
CITATIONS READS
59 8,582
2 authors, including:
Stephen Frenkel
UNSW Sydney
136 PUBLICATIONS 4,602 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Stephen Frenkel on 09 July 2021.
David L. Weakliem
University of Connecticut
Stephen J. Frenkel
Australian Graduate School of Management
This study considers the relationship between morale and workplace produc-
tivity in a representative sample of Australian workplaces. It focuses on three
questions: the shape of the relationship, whether the effects of morale are
contingent on other factors, and the paths by which any effect takes place.
The results show that morale influences productivity in an approximately
linear fashion. The effect of morale on productivity appears to be larger when
management regards product quality as important and attempts to develop a
corporate ethic and culture. Morale is associated with greater work effort, but
the relationship between work effort and productivity becomes stronger at
higher levels of morale. Thus, part of the influence of morale on productiv-
ity is a matter of increasing the effectiveness of workers’ efforts.
335
336 Work and Occupations
Most research and theory suggests that there is at least some positive
relationship between morale and productivity. However, there is uncertainty
about the shape of the relationship, with some accounts implying diminish-
ing returns. Also, many discussions suggest that the degree to which morale
influences productivity will differ, depending on various characteristics of
the job or organization. Finally, there is uncertainty about the paths through
which morale influences productivity. The most straightforward possibility
is that workers with higher morale are willing to work harder, but several
other avenues have been suggested. This section develops hypotheses relat-
ing to these three general areas.
Overall Relationship
Some accounts suggest that increases from low to moderate levels of
morale will have more effect on productivity than increases from moderate to
high levels. Workers with sufficiently low morale can respond by poor work-
manship, wasting resources, or even sabotage. However, workers with unusu-
ally high morale may not be able to do much to enhance productivity. Perrow
(1986) argues that many jobs do not offer much scope for exceptionally good
performance and observes that special effort by workers may reduce produc-
tivity from management’s point of view. For example, workers who try to
provide customers with the best possible service will spend more time on
each one and hence serve fewer customers than workers who aim for merely
adequate service. A second reason for diminishing returns is that measures to
increase morale often have costs (Shister, 1950). Inexpensive measures such
as using reasonable care in selection of supervisors could increase morale but
raising it to unusually high levels might require expensive measures such as
keeping workers on the payroll during periods of low demand. These argu-
ments suggest that the effects of morale on productivity are nonlinear: dimin-
ishing and possibly even becoming negative at higher levels of morale.
Interactions
The idea that the effects of morale are contingent on other factors has a
prominent place in the literature. Table 1 lists plausible interactions that can
be considered using the AWIRS data; although many variables are listed,
the hypotheses follow from a small number of basic principles. First, it is
often suggested that morale will have more effect where workers have more
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 339
Table 1
Variables in Hypothesized Interactions With Morale
Autonomy
1. Workers’ average rating of “How much influence or input do you have about. . . the
type of work you do?”
2. Workers’ average rating of “How much influence or input do you have about. . . how
you do your work?”
3. Workers’ average rating of “how much influence or input do you have about. . . the
pace at which you do your job?”
4. Proportion of workers who are union members.
5. Number of union delegates at workplace per worker.
6. Proportion of nonmanagerial workers who are professionals or semiprofessionals.
7. Proportion of nonmanagerial workers who are operatives or laborers.
8. Agreement that “management would choose quality improvements over price reductions.”
9. Choosing “quality of product,” “quality of workforce,” or “response to consumer
needs” as the most important factor for competitive success.
Management Strategy
Size
Characteristics of Workers
There are a number of ways that autonomy can be defined and mea-
sured. As Slichter (1920/1961) noted, autonomy can result either from for-
mal organization or from workers’ position in the day-to-day process of
production. The AWIRS contains a relatively direct measure of autonomy
in everyday tasks—employees’ ratings of how much “control or influence”
they have over various aspects of their work. The three aspects listed in
Table 1 are selected, because they involve the process of production and
hence are most closely related to autonomy on the job.
Several other variables, although not measures of autonomy, are poten-
tially relevant because they may influence autonomy. Unionization may
enhance autonomy by giving workers protection against dismissal and
other forms of discipline. Autonomy is generally greater in skilled jobs,
because they generally require more judgment on the part of the workers.
In the AWIRS, managers are asked to classify their workforce into several
groups, so average skill can be measured by the reported proportion of
skilled manual workers and professionals. These variables affect many
aspects of the organization; so any interactions involving them could be
interpreted in other ways. Hence, the results for these variables should be
taken in conjunction with those for the direct measure.
Finally, the difficulty of measuring output enhances autonomy, because
workers whose output is hard to measure can reduce their effectiveness
with less risk of detection. Quality of output is generally more difficult to
measure than quantity, because quality problems may not become apparent
until after the product is in the hands of the consumer. Hence, morale might
have more effect on productivity when quality is an important factor in
competitive success. The AWIRS survey contains two questions involving
the importance of quality: whether management would choose quality
improvements over cost reductions and whether quality is the crucial factor
for competitive success with the workplace’s major product or service.
A second general factor that may affect the importance of morale is the
organization’s general approach to management. Kalleberg (2003) notes
that firms facing similar competitive pressures may have a choice of strate-
gies. One approach is to attempt to build commitment to the organization
and create a sense that workers and management are part of a team. An
alternative is to avoid any sense of lasting commitments and motivate work-
ers by a combination of immediate rewards and punishments. One would
expect morale to have more effect on productivity in firms that followed the
first strategy. It should be noted that this hypothesis is not equivalent to the
claim that morale will be higher when management follows a strategy of
this type. Rather, the hypothesis is that in such firms, the state of morale
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 341
will have more effect on productivity, for better or for worse. A firm that
tries to cultivate a sense of community may still suffer from low morale
because of lack of management skill, a history of poor labor relations, or
other factors, and the hypothesis predicts that such firms will have low pro-
ductivity. Conversely, high morale will not result in high productivity
unless the company follows a strategy that takes advantage of its potential.
As Whyte (1955) puts it:
If workers are well satisfied with their jobs and think well of management,
then high productivity does not necessarily follow. People may simply be
happy to be members of the organization and have no urge to contribute to its
goal of production. (p. 1)
Paths of Influence
There are several channels through which morale may affect productiv-
ity. The most straightforward possibility is that higher morale leads to more
work effort, which in turn increases productivity. Workers with higher
morale will generally enjoy their work more and will also feel more deter-
mination to carry out the task even when the work itself is disagreeable.
An alternative path is suggested by recent discussions of “organizational
citizenship behavior”—activity that makes the organization work more
smoothly and effectively (Hodson, 2001; Organ, 1988). Some types of orga-
nizational citizenship behavior require little or no extra effort—for example,
giving good advice to a coworker or bringing a problem to the attention
of management. Such actions will enhance productivity by increasing the
effectiveness of coworkers’ efforts. Leibenstein (1975) observes that effort
alone will not necessarily increase productivity and may even reduce it—for
example, a worker who devotes effort to seeing that rules are followed to the
letter may make it more difficult for other workers to carry out their jobs.
At low levels of morale, workers’ efforts may be predominantly defensive,
directed toward protecting themselves against criticism or advancing their
own status at the expense of their coworkers. At higher levels of morale,
in contrast, workers will direct their efforts toward accomplishing the goals
of the organization. Also, Bakker and Guerts (2004) suggest that work can
be characterized by a state of “flow” or being “fully concentrated and
engrossed in one’s work, whereby time passes quickly” (p. 350). Workers in
this state are likely to perform more effectively, because there will be less
struggle and wasted effort. High morale may increase productivity by being
associated with greater levels of “flow” rather than greater effort.
A final way that morale may enhance productivity is by facilitating
agreement between workers and employers. There is always a good deal of
uncertainty about the effects of any proposed change to an organization.
Where morale is low, workers may suspect that any changes proposed by
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 343
the employer are intended to reduce their wages, job security, or quality of
work. Where morale is high, they may be more willing to believe that pro-
posed changes will work to their benefit, making it easier for firms to adopt
the most effective practices and equipment.
Productivity
In a sample covering workplaces producing different goods and services,
it is difficult to employ objective measures of productivity. Measures based
on physical output, such as those used by Appelbaum et al. (2000), are not
feasible. Tomaskovic-Devey and Skaggs (1999) use financial data to con-
struct measures of productivity in a diverse sample of workplaces. However,
the AWIRS does not contain financial data, and for reasons of confidential-
ity, it is not possible to identify the companies and add information from
outside sources. Hence, we use a subjective measure of productivity from a
question in the general management survey: “In your opinion, how does the
level of labour productivity here compare with your major competitors?”
Respondents chose answers from a 5-point scale, ranging from a lot lower
to a lot higher. This measure of productivity is also used in the recent stud-
ies of Moreton (1999) and Addison and Belfield (2001), which are based on
the WERS. Although a subjective judgment necessarily involves some mea-
surement error, managers have access to the relevant data and strong incen-
tives to get accurate knowledge about productivity.
There is a clear tendency for managers to give their own company the
benefit of the doubt: Nearly half think that their productivity is higher than
their competitors, and only 12% think that it is lower. However, for the pur-
poses of explaining differences in productivity, the important question is
not whether there is a tendency toward “optimism,” but whether any indi-
vidual differences in this tendency are correlated with the independent vari-
ables. A uniform tendency to evaluate performance favorably will affect the
intercept but will have no impact on the estimated effects of the indepen-
dent variables. Individual differences in optimism that are uncorrelated
with the independent variables will also have no effect on the estimated
effects of independent variables, because they can be regarded as part of the
regression error term (Machin & Stewart, 1990). There may be some sys-
tematic differences in managers’ optimism, but they are likely to depend on
characteristics of the managers themselves. Hence, they will not affect the
estimated effects of variables that are measured by workers’ reports—such
as our key variable, morale.
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 345
Morale
As discussed above, we define morale as positive attitudes toward the
“prescribed activities of the group” (Manning, 1991, p. 455). Because it is
management that determines those activities, morale in this sense is largely
a matter of attitudes toward management.3 The AWIRS employee survey has
three questions concerning management at the workplace: whether it “does
its best to get along with employees,” whether it “can be trusted to tell things
the way they are,” and satisfaction with “the way management treat you and
others here.” It is possible to make conceptual distinctions between these
variables—for example, one can imagine a management that is trustworthy
but also rigid and authoritarian. However, all attitudes go together in prac-
tice, with correlations of between .70 and .75 at the workplace level.4 Hence,
we use the sum of the three items as an overall index of morale. Values range
from 3 to 9, with larger numbers indicating greater morale.
Control Variables
Economic theorists have proposed a number of production functions
relating output to capital and labor inputs. However, these do not provide
much guidance for the selection of control variables, because they include
constants that might represent the effects of a variety of factors, such as the
state of technology, the quality of management, or the organization of pro-
duction. The most relevant empirical works are those of Moreton (1999)
and Addison and Belfield (2001), who analyze productivity in a wide vari-
ety of workplaces. The choice of control variables is guided by their find-
ings and general considerations of plausibility:
1. Age: Older workplaces may be less well adapted to new conditions and
may have older equipment. On the other hand, firms that are less pro-
ductive are more likely to go out of business, so that the firms that have
survived longer will tend to be among the more efficient ones. In this
case, age is not a true cause of productivity but a proxy for variables that
contribute to productivity and are not separately measured. Age is mea-
sured by two variables, one for time operating at the current location, and
one for time that the firm has been producing its major product.
2. Introduction of new plant equipment or office machinery in the past 2
years: Plants with more up-to-date equipment are expected to be more
productive.
3. Size of workplace and of company: There may be economies or disec-
onomies of scale.
346 Work and Occupations
4. Multiplant firm: Workplaces that are part of a multiplant firm may benefit
from the ability to specialize, suggesting that they will be more productive.
On the other hand, multiplant firms may find it more difficult to coordinate
the activity of different plants, which could reduce productivity.
5. Unionization rate: Many economists have argued that unions reduce
productivity by restricting management’s power to organize production
in the most efficient way. On the other hand, Freeman and Medoff
(1984) argue that unions provide regular channels for workers to voice
their concerns and resolve grievances that would otherwise produce
turnover or covert resistance. Their account suggests that unionization
will generally increase productivity.
6. Number of union representatives in the workplace: This is an alterna-
tive measure of union strength.5
7. Number of unions: The existence of multiple unions may lead to disrup-
tion because of demarcation disputes and rivalry for members. Moreton
(1999) finds evidence that multiple unionism reduces productivity.
8. Workers’ average education: Productivity can be expected to depend
not only on the quantity of labor but also on its “quality.” Education is
an important aspect of labor quality, because it can affect a range of
skills and attitudes.
9. Average wage: Wages may be related to worker quality, because more
capable workers will be able to command higher wages. In this case,
higher wages would be associated with higher productivity. However,
managers may take account of labor costs when they answer the question
on productivity. If they think of productivity in terms of output relative to
labor costs, higher wages will tend to go with lower reported productivity.
Because labor markets are structured by occupation, levels of edu-
cation and wages must be understood in relative terms. An employer
seeking to attract high-quality workers for a particular job will need to
consider the typical wage rate for that job and similar jobs. Hence, in
the analysis, education and wages are adjusted for occupational group.
Specifically, the relative wage (w*) in a workplace is w* = ∑pi(wi-mi),
in which pi is the proportion of the workers in occupational group i, wi
the workplace average wage of workers in that occupation, and mi is the
average wage of workers in that occupation across all workplaces.
Thus, a value of 0 for workplace wages indicates that wages are normal
given the occupational composition of the workplace, and positive or
negative values indicate that they are above ore below what would be
expected. A corresponding adjustment is used for education.
10. Organization status: The AWIRS includes all types of workplaces, not
just private for-profit firms. Because the standards of productivity may
differ depending on the type of organization, we include dummy vari-
ables for each category distinguished in the AWIRS (private, government
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 347
Intervening Variables
Two additional variables are involved in the hypotheses about how
morale influences productivity—work effort and the difficulty of reaching
agreement. The AWIRS employee survey contains a straightforward mea-
sure of effort—a question asking workers whether they put “a lot of effort”
into their job. Unfortunately, they were offered only a choice of agree, dis-
agree, or neither agree nor disagree. The great majority of workers chose
agree, and in about 40% of workplaces, all the employees surveyed chose
that response. Hence, although the variable is conceptually appropriate,
the measurement is not very precise. A measure of the difficulty in reaching
agreement can be obtained from the management survey, which asks
whether there are any productivity-related changes that management would
like to make but cannot. About 40% of managers mention no such changes,
48% mention one, and 12% mention two or more. The total number of
desired changes can be taken as an indicator of difficulty in reaching agree-
ment. In principle, an agreement can always be devised so that both work-
ers and management benefit from changes that enhance productivity—some
of the additional revenue can be used to compensate workers for any dis-
ruption and job loss. Collom (2003) finds that greater worker influence over
production is associated with higher managerial salaries and suggests that
managers share in gains resulting from greater influence. Hence, failure to
implement a change would indicate that there was some barrier to develop-
ing an agreement that shared the benefits in a mutually satisfactory way.
Results
from samples of the employees, they are affected by sampling error, and the
magnitude of this error increases as the sample size decreases. The accuracy
of estimates of workplace morale can be increased by taking account of sam-
pling error. We use a procedure suggested by James and Stein (1961; see Efron
& Morris, 1975, for a simpler exposition), which uses a weighted average
of the overall mean and the workplace mean. Specifically, the weights are
k/(k + n) for the overall mean and 1-k/(k + n) for the observed workplace mean,
in which n is the number of workers surveyed in a workplace and k is an esti-
mate of the ratio of individual-level to workplace-level variation. In these data,
k is approximately 5.0. As mentioned above, the possible values of morale
range from 3 to 9. Using the James-Stein estimates, the workplace averages
cover most of the theoretically possible range. Figure 1 shows a histogram of
the levels of morale estimated by the James-Stein procedure. The figure makes
it clear that the differences among workplaces are not only statistically signif-
icant but also large enough to be of substantive interest.
Figure 1
Distribution of Morale by Workplaces
160
140
120
Number of Cases
100
Std. Dev = .65
80 Mean = 5.37
N = 1,819.00
60
40
20
0
3.
3.
4.
4.
4.
4.
5.
5.
5.
5.
6.
6.
6.
6.
7.
7.
7.
63
88
13
38
63
88
13
38
63
88
13
38
63
88
13
38
63
Union density –.065 .158 .006 .159 .017 .156 .017 .156
Workplace size (log) .090* .058 .114* .058 .117** .058 .118** .058
Average education –.049 .065 –.038 .066 –.037 .066 –.037 .066
Number of unions –.038 .036 –.034 .036 –.034 .036 –.033 .036
Number of delegates –.017 .011 –.017 .011 –.016 .011 –.016 .011
Firm size –.039 .029 –.043 .029 –.045 .029 –.044 .029
Time at location (log) –.102** .050 –.092* .050 –.090* .050 –.090* .050
Average wage –.002 .009 –.002 .009 –.002 .009 –.002 .009
Time producing –.129** .054 –.132** .054 –.133** .054 –.133** .054
Multiplant .002 .166 –.048 .167 –.051 .167 –.052 .167
New office equipment .218** .098 .213** .099 .214** .099 .215** .099
New machinery –.012 .109 –.021 .110 –.017 .109 –.018 .110
Morale (observed) .132*** .045
Morale (estimated) .271**** .081 .410** .183
Morale2 (estimated) –.013 .087
Table 3
Predicted Distribution of Productivity,
by Level of Morale (in Percentages)
Productivity Low Morale Baseline High Morale
Note: Baseline is the distribution of reported productivity in the entire sample. High morale
is 1.0 unit (about 1.5 standard deviations) above the mean level of morale, whereas low
morale is 1.0 unit below the mean.
effects from model 2 of Table 2 translate into the original probabilities. The
baseline is the distribution of productivity is the entire sample. The compar-
isons are the predicted distributions if morale were increased by one unit
(about 1.5 standard deviations) in one case and reduced by one unit in the
other, while holding all other independent variables constant. For example,
a one-unit reduction in morale would reduce the chance that productivity is
rated a lot higher than most competitors from .156 to .123, and a one-unit
increase would increase the chance to .195. That is, having high rather than
low morale would increase the probability of having the highest level of pro-
ductivity by about 50%. Whether an effect of this size should be considered
large or small is a matter of judgment, but the differences seem large enough
to be of practical interest.
Interactions
The analysis of interactions is largely exploratory, because even with a
sample of this size, the estimates of interaction terms have relatively large
standard errors. To give a sense of magnitude, we show the minimum and
maximum effects of morale implied by the estimated interaction term. For
example, the smallest possible value of autonomy is 1, when all respondents
in a workplace say that they have no influence, and the largest is 4, when all
say that they have a lot of influence. The minimum and maximum column
shows the implied effect of morale on productivity at the minimum and max-
imum possible values of autonomy. Because a large number of possible
interactions are considered, it is not practical to include them all in a single
352 Work and Occupations
model. Rather, the figures are from models in which a single interaction
effect added to the independent variables included in Model 2 in Table 2.
The estimated interactions involving autonomy, occupation, and firm
size are all well short of statistical significance and small in magnitude.7 For
example, the estimated effect of morale is only about 25% larger in fully
unionized workplaces than in workplaces with no union members (.306 vs.
.245), and the t ratio of the interaction effect is less than 0.5. However, the
estimated interactions involving management strategy and the importance
of quality are substantial and approach statistical significance. The interac-
tion involving stated emphasis on human resources is significant at the 10%
level, and the estimate suggests that the effect of morale disappears entirely
in organizations that do not claim to emphasize human resources. The inter-
action involving emphasis on corporate culture is also substantial and has a
t ratio of greater than 1.0. The estimated interaction involving quality as the
most important factor in success is close to the 10% significance level,
whereas the interaction involving preference for quality improvement is
also in the expected direction and has a t ratio of approximately 1.0. There
is little or no evidence of interactions involving the other variables.
One response to these results would be simply to conclude that there is no
compelling evidence of any interactions. That is, we fail to reject the hypoth-
esis that the effects of morale are uniform with respect to all of the variables
considered here. However, given the large standard errors, there is also a sub-
stantial possibility of a Type II error: failure to reject a false null hypothesis.
The pattern of results in Table 4 suggests that the possibilities of interactions
with management strategy and emphasis on quality deserve further consider-
ation. The items can be combined into two indexes: one composed of human
relations and corporate culture; the other of preference for quality improve-
ment and quality as the most important factor in success.8 Also, accounts of
high-performance workplaces suggest there will be some overlap between
these two features—when management regards quality as important, it will
attempt to foster organizational commitment. Hence, it is reasonable to com-
bine all items into a single index, which could be interpreted as the degree to
which the workplace follows the high-performance model.
Table 5 shows fit statistics and relevant coefficients from models includ-
ing interactions of morale and the indexes. The interactions with each index
are significant at the 10% level, and the interaction with the combined index
is significant at the 5% level. The magnitude of the estimated effects is
substantial—the estimates from Model 5 imply an average morale effect of
about .23 with a standard deviation of about .16. That is, the estimates sug-
gest that in workplaces that are farthest from the high-performance model,
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 353
Table 4
Estimated Interactions Between Morale and Other Factors
Minimum Maximum
Estimate SE Morale Effect Morale Effect N
*p < .10.
Morale .212*** .082 –.302 .290 –.190 .235 –.530 .333 –.533 .333
Strategy .094*** .033 –.225 .176 .094*** .033 –.183 .264
Quality .168*** .045 .167 .045 –.265 .241 –.166 .364
High-performance model –.173 .130
Morale × Strategy .088* .048 .071 .049
Morale × Quality .120* .065 .097 .067
Morale × High-Performance .081** .035
Model
–2 log-likelihood 3,907.7 3,904.5 3,904.5 3,902.5 3,904.0
Note: Models also include the control variables in Table 2. Estimates for the control variables are omitted to save space.
*p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01.
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 355
Table 6
Effect of Morale on Effort and Number
of Desired Productivity Changes
Effort SE Number of Changes SE
Table 7
Effects of Morale and Work Effort on Productivity (N = 1,491)
Model 1 SE Model 2 SE Model 3 SE
Note: All models also include control variables from Table 2. Estimated effects of the
controls are omitted to save space.
*p < .10. **p < .01.
chosen to maximize the relationship. The estimates from this model imply
that work effort has essentially no relationship to productivity in the two
lower groups but a positive effect in the highest group. The results of
Models 2 and 3 suggest that the effect of work effort on productivity
increases with morale. As suggested above, this may mean that workers
direct their efforts in more useful ways: Rather than considering only what
is best for themselves, they also consider what is best for their coworkers
and the general goals of the organization. Unfortunately, the AWIRS does
not contain any variables that could be used to evaluate this interpretation.
However, the results suggest that the usual model of morale affecting pro-
ductivity through a simple increase in work effort may be incomplete.
Summary
Conclusions
Notes
1. It should be noted that this sense of autonomy is somewhat narrower than the usual
sense. A worker who has control over how to do the work but whose output is easily moni-
tored is not autonomous in the sense used here.
2. The World Values Surveys (Inglehart, Basanez, Diaz-Medrano, Halman, & Luijkx,
2004) include a question on whether “one should follow one’s superiors instructions even
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 359
when one does not fully agree” or follow instructions “only when one is convinced that they
are right.” Educated people are substantially more likely to choose the second answer in nearly
all nations, including Australia.
3. Another component of morale in this sense might be views about the value of the prod-
uct or service produced, but the Australian Workplace Industrial Relations Survey does not
contain any information on this topic.
4. Although all categories of workers are surveyed, we exclude managerial employees
from these calculations, because their views on these topics may diverge from those of ordi-
nary workers.
5. The survey question refers to “union delegates,” which are equivalent to American shop
stewards.
6. The F statistic is 2.683 with 1,824 degrees of freedom in the numerator and about
15,000 in the denominator, far beyond the 0.1% critical value of 1.13.
7. In addition to the variables shown in Table 4, the Australian Workplace Industrial
Relations Survey includes three others that might be considered forms of autonomy, control
over “when you start and finish work,” over “the way that this workplace is managed or organ-
ised,” and “decisions which affect you at this workplace.” The estimated interactions for these
variables also do not approach significance.
8. Because both the management strategy variables are measured on the same scale (1 to 5),
the index is the unweighted sum of the two items. The two quality variables are measured on
different scales, so they are weighted to give them approximately equal influence in the index.
9. The groups are defined as ranking in the lowest 25%, 25% to 75%, and top 25% of morale.
References
Addison, J. T., & Belfield, C. R. (2001). Updating the determinants of firm performance:
Estimation using the 1998 UK Workplace Employee Relations Survey. British Journal of
Industrial Relations, 39, 341-366.
Appelbaum, E., Bailey, T., Berg, P., & Kalleberg, A. L. (2000). Manufacturing advantage:
Why high-performance work systems pay off. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Bakker, A. B., & Guerts, S. E. B. (2004). Toward a dual-process model of work-home inter-
ference. Work and Occupations, 31, 345-366.
Bewley, T. F. (1999). Why wages don’t fall in a recession. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Blinder, A. S., & Choi, D. H. (1990). A shred of evidence on theories of wage stickiness.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, 89-96.
Campbell, C. M., & Kamlani, K. S. (1997). The reasons for wage rigidity: Evidence from a
survey of firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 760-789.
Collom, E. (2003). Two classes and one vision: Managers’ and workers’ attitudes toward
workplace democracy. Work and Occupations, 30, 62-96.
Efron, B., & Morris, C. (1975). Data analysis using Stein’s estimator and its generalizations.
Journal of the American Statistical Association, 70, 311-319.
Fox, A. (1974). Beyond contract: Work, power, and trust relations. London: Faber & Faber.
Freeman, R. B., & Medoff, J. L. (1984). What do unions do? Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Frenkel, S. J. (2003). The embedded character of workplace relations. Work and Occupations,
30, 135-153.
360 Work and Occupations
Grunberg, L., Anderson-Connolly, R., & Greenberg, E. S. (2000). Surviving layoffs: The effects
on organizational commitment and job performance. Work and Occupations, 27, 7-31.
Haire, M. (1954). Industrial social psychology. In G. Lindzey (Ed.), Handbook of social
psychology (pp. 1104-1123). Cambridge, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Harter, J. K., Schmidt, F. L., & Hayes, T. L. (2002). Business-unit-level relationship between
employee satisfaction, employee engagement, and business outcomes: A meta-analysis.
Journal of Applied Psychology, 87, 268-279.
Hodson, R. (2001). Dignity at work. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Hodson, R. (2002). Management citizenship behavior and its consequences. Work and
Occupations, 29, 64-96.
Inglehart, R., Basanez, M., Diaz-Medrano, J., Halman, L., & Luijkx, R. (2004). Human beliefs
and values. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
James, W., & Stein, C. (1961). Estimation with quadratic loss. In J. Neyman (Ed.),
Proceedings of the fourth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability,
(Vol. 1, pp. 361-379). Berkeley: University of California Press.
Judge, T. A., Thoresen, C. J., Bono, J. E., & Patton, G. K. (2001). The job satisfaction–job per-
formance relationship: A qualitative and quantitative review. Psychological Bulletin, 127,
376-407.
Kalleberg, A. (2003). Flexible firms and labor market segmentation. Work and Occupations,
30, 154-175.
Kohn, M. L., & Schooler, C. (1969). Class, occupation, and orientation. American
Sociological Review, 34, 659-678.
Leibenstein, H. (1975). Aspects of the X-efficiency theory of the firm. Bell Journal of
Economics, 6, 580-606.
Lincoln, J. R., & Kalleberg, A. L. (1990). Culture, control, and commitment. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Machin, S., & Stewart, M. (1990). Unions and the financial performance of British private sec-
tor establishments. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 5, 327-350.
Manning, F. J. (1991). Morale, cohesion, and esprit de corps. In R. Gal & A. D. Mangelsdorff
(Eds.), Handbook of military psychology (pp. 453-470). Chichester, UK: Wiley.
McCullagh, P. (1980). Regression models for ordinal data. Journal of the Royal Statistical
Society (series B), 42, 109-142.
Morehead, A., Steele, M., Alexander, M., Stephen, K., & Duffin, L. (1997). Changes at work:
The 1995 Australian Workplace Industrial Relations Survey. Melbourne. Australia:
Addison Wesley Longman.
Moreton, D. (1999). A model of labour productivity and union density in British private sec-
tor unionised establishments. Oxford Economic Papers, 51, 322-344.
Organ, D. W. (1988). Organizational citizenship behavior. Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath.
Organ, D. W. (1997). Toward an explication of ‘morale’: In search of the M factor. In C. L.
Cooper & S. E. Jackson (Eds.), Creating tomorrow’s organizations (pp. 493-504).
Chichester, UK: Wiley.
Perrow, C. (1986). Complex organizations: A critical essay (3rd ed.). New York: Random House.
Porter, L. W., Steers, R. M., Mowday, R. T., & Boulian, P. V. (1974). Organizational commit-
ment, job satisfaction, and turnover among psychiatric technicians. Journal of Applied
Psychology, 59, 603-609.
Roethlisberger, F. J. (1941). Management and morale. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Shister, J. (1950). Trade union policies and nonmarket values. American Economic Review, 40,
292-305.
Weakliem, Frenkel / Effects of Workplace Morale 361
Slichter, S. (1961). Industrial morale. In S. Slichter (Ed.), Potentials of the American economy
(pp. 167-183). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. (Original work published 1920)
Tomaskovic-Devey, D., & Skaggs, S. (1999). An establishment-level test of the statistical dis-
crimination hypothesis. Work and Occupations, 26, 422-445.
Whyte, W. F. (1955). Money and motivation: An analysis of incentives in industry. New York:
Harper.