0% found this document useful (0 votes)
30 views69 pages

FIN4110 Options and Futures S2, 2023 Topic 7

The document provides an overview of the key concepts needed to understand the Black-Scholes-Merton model, including: 1) Markov processes and how they apply to stock prices. 2) Wiener processes and generalized Wiener processes, which describe stock price movements as random walks. 3) Ito processes, which allow the drift and variance rates of stock prices to change over time. 4) Ito's lemma, which is needed to apply calculus to stochastic processes like stock prices. The document reviews these statistical and calculus concepts to lay the foundation for presenting the Black-Scholes-Merton model in a subsequent section.

Uploaded by

Shuen Wu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
30 views69 pages

FIN4110 Options and Futures S2, 2023 Topic 7

The document provides an overview of the key concepts needed to understand the Black-Scholes-Merton model, including: 1) Markov processes and how they apply to stock prices. 2) Wiener processes and generalized Wiener processes, which describe stock price movements as random walks. 3) Ito processes, which allow the drift and variance rates of stock prices to change over time. 4) Ito's lemma, which is needed to apply calculus to stochastic processes like stock prices. The document reviews these statistical and calculus concepts to lay the foundation for presenting the Black-Scholes-Merton model in a subsequent section.

Uploaded by

Shuen Wu
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 69

FIN4110

Options and Futures


S2-2023

Topic 7
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Haifeng Wu
Expected Learning Outcomes

1. Markov process
2. Wiener process
3. Generalized Wiener process
4. Ito process
5. Ito’s Lemma and its applications
6. Construction of Black-Scholes risk-free portfolio
7. The Black-Scholes-Merton model
8. Explaining the Black-Scholes-Merton differential equation
9. Black-Scholes-Merton model on a dividend paying stock
Markov processes
◼ In a Markov process, future movements in a variable
depend only on where they are now, not on the history
of how they got there.
◼ We assume that stock prices follow a Markov Process.
This is consistent with a weak form of market
efficiency.
◼ Mathematically, this means that for any “reasonable”
function, f, the conditional expectation satisfies:
E[f(St)|all past prices] = E[f(St)|today’s price only]

◼ This implies that the changes in value at different time


intervals are independent.
Markov process – stock returns and variances
◼ Therefore, a stock’s return on day t+1, Rt+1, is
independent of the stock’s return on day t, Rt.

◼ If they’re independent, then they are uncorrelated. So,


variances of stock return over a period of time are
additive:

Var(R t + R t +1 ) = Var(R t ) + Var(R t +1 )


Markov process – stock returns

◼ If we use continuously compounded returns, then


 St 
Rt = ln   = ln St − ln St -1
 St -1 
 St +1 
Rt +1 = ln   = ln St +1 − ln St
 St 

◼ So that the two-period return is

Rt + Rt +1 = ln St +1 − ln St − (ln St − ln St -1 )
= ln St +1 − ln St -1 = ln (St +1 / St -1 )
Markov process – variances
◼ In general, the T-period return is
ln (ST / S0 ) = R1 + R2 + ... + RT
◼ taking variances (and assuming independence)

Var(R T − periods ) = Var(R1 ) + Var(R 2 ) + ... + Var(R T )


◼ if we assume that variances are equal from period to
period
Var(R1 ) = Var(R 2 ) = ... = Var(R T )
 Var(R T − periods ) = T  Var(R1 )
Markov process – variances

◼ If we know the variance of daily returns and if we


assume that there are 252 trading days in a year,
then

◼ Var(annual returns) = 252×Var(daily returns),

◼ And standard deviations are (taking square roots):


St.Dev(annual returns) = 252×St.Dev(daily returns)

◼ This means that variances are additive, while


standard deviations are not additive.
Weak-form market efficiency

◼ This asserts that it is impossible to produce


consistently superior returns with a trading rule
based on the past history of stock prices. In other
words technical analysis does not work.

◼ A Markov process for stock prices is clearly


consistent with weak-form market efficiency.
Question:

◼ A stock price is currently at $40. The change in


its value during one year is N(0,10) where N(µ,σ)
is a normal distribution with mean µ and standard
deviation σ.

◼ What is the probability distribution for the change


in the value of the stock price during 2 years, ½
years, ¼ years, and any time interval?
Wiener process (brownian motion)
◼ We consider a variable Z whose value changes
continuously over time. For a small change in time,
∆t, we’ll call the change as the random (stochastic)
process, ∆Z.

◼ The process {Z} follows a Wiener process if


1. Z =  t , where ε follows a standard normal
distribution, and εt and εt + 1 are independent.
2. The values of ∆Z for any two non-overlapping
periods of time are independent.
3. Z has continuous paths.
Plot of wiener process

Z = t
where  ~ N (0,1)

Z0 = 0

0 t
Properties of wiener process

◼ For each t, Z is normally distributed.


◼ The mean of [ZT − Z0] is E[ZT − Z0] = 0.
◼ The variance of [ZT − Z0] is Var[ZT − Z0] = T
◼ The standard deviation of [ZT − Z0] is T

◼ NOTE: it is usually assumed that Z0 = 0.


◼ Taking the limit as ∆t approaches zero, we replace

Z =  t by dZ =  dt
Generalized wiener processes

◼ A Wiener process has a drift rate of 0 and a


variance rate of 1.

◼ Note that the mean change per unit time for a


stochastic process is known as the drift rate and the
variance per unit time is known as the variance rate.

◼ In a generalized Wiener process the drift rate and


the variance rate can be set equal to any chosen
constants.
More specifically:
◼ A variable X follows a generalized Wiener process with
drift rate a and variance rate b2 (with a and b constant)
if
dX = adt + bdZ
◼ or
x = a t + b  t
➢ Mean change in X over t is at
➢ Variance of change in X over t is b2 t
➢ Standard deviation of change in X over t is b t
Drift and variance rates
◼ X is just a simple function of the Brownian motion, Z.
2
◼ How do we interpret the drift rate, a, and the variance rate, b ?
◼ We can see that the mean change in X in the time interval T is

EXT − X0  = EaT + bZT  = aT


◼ The variance of change in X in the time interval T is

Var X T − X 0  = Var aT + bZT  = b 2 T

◼ The standard deviation of change in X in time interval T is

St.DevX T − X 0  = b T

◼ Note that initial time t is assumed to be zero.


Distribution of XT

◼ It follows that XT is normally distributed with mean


X0 + aT, and standard deviation b T

◼ We sometimes write that XT has the probability


distribution N(X0 + aT, b T ) which is written as

XT ~ N(X0 + aT, b T)
Example 1

◼ Suppose a stock price starts at $40 and the price


follows a generalized Wiener process with no drift
and standard deviation 10 (i.e., $10 per year):

dS = 10dZ.

◼ Then the stock price in one year is normally


distributed with a probability distribution N(40,10).
Example 2

◼ If the stock price is expected to grow by $8 on


average during the year, then the process is

dS = 8dt + 10dZ

◼ and the stock price in one year is normally distributed


with a probability distribution N(48,10).

◼ Question: What is the distribution of the stock price in


one month?
Generalized wiener process: is this a reasonable
process to describe dynamics of stock prices?
◼ There are two principal reasons of why a generalized
wiener process is NOT appropriate.
◼ A generalized Wiener process is normally distributed,
=> it can become negative. But stock prices can’t be
negative. A more reasonable model would assume that
continuously compounded returns are normally
distributed
ln(ST / S0 ) = aT + bZ T
◼ If stock prices follow a generalized Wiener process, then
the variance of stock’s prices is constant, regardless of
price level. It’s more reasonable to assume that returns
have a constant variance, regardless of price level.
Itô process

◼ In an Itôprocess the drift rate and the variance


rate are functions of time and underlying
variable:
dx=a(x,t) dt+b(x,t) dz

◼ The discrete time equivalent

x = a ( x, t )t + b( x, t ) t
is only true in the limit as t tends to zero
An Itô process for stock prices

dS = mS dt + sS dz
◼ where m is the expected return and s is the
volatility.

◼ The discrete time equivalent is

S = mSt + sS t
Monte-carlo simulation

◼ We can sample random paths for the stock


price by sampling values for 

◼ Suppose m= 0.14, s= 0.20, and t = 0.01,


then

S = 0.14 S t + 0.2 S  (t )^ (0.5)


Monte-carlo simulation of stock prices

Stock Price at Random Change in Stock


Period Start of Period Sample for  Price, S

0 20.000 0.52 0.236


1 20.236 1.44 0.611
2 20.847 -0.86 -0.329
3 20.518 1.46 0.628
4 21.146 -0.69 -0.262
Review of ordinary calculus I
◼ Before presenting Ito’s lemma, we need to review some
results from ordinary calculus.
◼ Derivatives of some common functions:

d x
e =  e x
dx
d n
x = nxn−1
dx
d 1
ln(x) =
dx x
Review of ordinary calculus II

◼ The second derivative is just the derivative of the first


derivative.

d2 d d 
f(x) =  f(x)
dx 2
dx  dx 
◼ Example

d 1  d
 
2
d 1
ln(x) =  = x = −x = − 2
-1 -2

dx 2
dx  x  dx x
Review of ordinary calculus III
◼ Differentiation with two or more variables:
◼ Consider a function of two variables, say G(x,t).
If we want to find the partial derivative of G with respect
to x, we can treat the other variable as a constant.
◼ Example with

G(x, t) = xet
  t
G ( x, t ) = xe = et
x x
  t
G ( x, t ) = xe = x(et ) = xet
t t
Review of ordinary calculus IV
◼ the (total) differential of G(x,t) is given by

G G
dG = dx + dt
x t

◼ In the case where G is independent of time, and is only a


function of x: G = G(x). Then integrating the differential
dG from a to b, say, is
b dG b
G (b) − G ( a ) = a dx
dx = 
a
G( x) dx

which called the Fundamental Theorem of Calculus.


Itô’s Lemma

◼ If x follows an Ito process, dx=a(x,t) dt+b(x,t) dz, then a


function of x and t, G (x, t ), also follows an Ito process,
specifically,

 G G 1  G 2  G
2
dG =  a+ + b dt + bdz
 x t 2 x x
2

Applications: process of a derivative price

◼ Assume that stock price S follows an Ito process:


dS=µSdt + σSdZ. We want to know the process of a
derivatives price, where
1 3
F= S
3
◼ We apply Ito lemma: if S follows an Ito process, F
also follows an Ito process and is given by

(i) a = mS (ii ) b = sS
F F  2
F
(iii) = 0 (iv) = S (v)
2
= 2S
t S S 2
Applications: process of a derivative price
 F F 1  2 F 2 2  F
dF =  mS + + s S  dt + sSdZ
 S t 2 S S
2

 2 1 2 2 
=  S mS + s S 2 S  dt + S2sSdZ
 2 
( )
= m + s S dt + sS dZ; since F = S
2 3 3 1 3
3
= 3( m + s ) Fdt + 3sFdZ
2

◼Hence, if the stock price process is dS = µSdt + σSdZ,


then the derivative price process is dF = 3(µ+σ2)Fdt+3σFdZ
Process of stock prices (St)

One type of Ito process takes the form:

dS = mS dt + sS dz
◼ dS is the change in S over a small time interval dt
◼ m is the expected rate of return per unit time for S
◼ s is the volatility of S.
◼ We call this process Geometric Brownian motion
◼ Is this process a reasonable model of how stock
prices evolves? (how about jumps?)
Process of ln(St)

◼ If S follows: dS = mS dt + sS dz
◼ Let G = Ln(St). Then G also follows an Ito process:
G G 1  G 2 2 2
G
dG = ( mS + + s S )dt + sSdz
S t 2 S 2
S
◼and we know:

G 1 G 2
1 G
= =− 2 =0
S S S 2
S t
◼given we have a=μS and b=σS
Properties of ln(St)

◼So: dG = d {ln(St)} = (m - s2/2) dt + s dz

◼ G is a Generalized Wiener process

1 2
◼ G (ln(St)) has a drift rate (“a”) of:m − s
2

◼ and a variance (“b2”) of: s 2T


G=ln(St) is normally distributed

◼ Integrate dG, dG = (m - s2/2) dt + s dz, from 0 to t (m, s are


constants)
 s2
G (St ) − G (S 0 ) =  m − t + s (Z t − Z 0 )
 2 

ln (St ) − ln (S 0 ) =  m −
s2
(
t + s  t −  0 )
 2 

ln
(St ) 
=  m −
s2 
( )
t + s  t
(S0 )  2 

◼ Note:  is a normally distributed random variable N(0,1)

 ST   s2 
ln   ~ N  m − T , s T 
 S0   2  
Mean and variance of log returns

◼ The mean and standard deviation of log returns


over the period [0, T] are:

 ST   s2 
Mean of ln   =  m −  T
 S0   2 
 ST 
Stdev of ln   = s T
 S0 

◼ We can also write

 ST 
(
ln   ~  ( m − 12 s 2 )T , s T )
 S0 
St is lognormally distributed

◼ If we use the following Geometric Brownian Motion


process to model stock price S:
dS = mS dt + sS dz
◼ then continuously compounded returns are normally
distributed.
◼ and St is lognormally distributed with

2 2 m (T −t ) s 2 (T − t )
E ( ST ) = S 0 e m (T −t )
and var(ST ) = S e
0 [e − 1]

◼ Lower bound of St is 0
◼ Stock prices cannot be negative
Pricing derivatives

◼ The price of a derivative is a function of:


1. the price of the underlying asset (which follows a
stochastic process)
2. Time

◼ Use Ito Lemma to characterize the behavior of a


function of a stochastic variable, e.g., the derivative’s
process is described using the process followed by the
underlying stock
Parameters

◼ m : the expected continuously compounded return


earned by the stock per year

◼ The value of a derivative dependent on a stock is


generally independent of the return

◼ s : the stock price volatility


➢ Critically important to value most derivatives
➢ Volatility can be interpreted as the standard deviation
of the change in the stock price in one year
The Black-Scholes-Merton differential equation

◼ Assumptions:

➢ The stock price follows a geometric Brownian motion.


➢ The short selling of securities is permitted.
➢ There are no transactions costs or taxes.
➢ All securities are perfectly divisible.
➢ There are no dividends during the life of the option.
➢ There are no arbitrage opportunities.
➢ Security trading is continuous.
➢ The risk-free rate of interest is constant and the same
for all maturities.
Step 1: form a risk-free portfolio
◼ The Black-Scholes analysis is similar to the no-
arbitrage analysis in valuing options when stock price
changes are binomial.

◼ Step 1: construct a riskless portfolio which consists


of a position in the option and a position in the
underlying stock.
➢ Under the assumption that stock price follows a
geometric Brownian motion, i.e.,

dS = mS dt + sS dz
Step 1: form a risk-free portfolio
◼ Based on Ito’s lemma, the price of a call option, f,
contingent on S (which is a function of S and t) follows a
process of
f f 1  2 f 2 2 f
df = ( mS + + s S )dt + sSdz
S t 2 S 2
S
◼ Comparing dS with df, note that they have the same
underlying uncertainty, dZ. This means that we can
construct a portfolio by writing one call option and buying
 f / S shares to eliminate this uncertainty (Wiener
processes cancel each other out) for a short period of
time. So the value of portfolio over the short time interval
does not follow a stochastic process.
Step 2: calculate value of the portfolio
◼ Define  as the value of the portfolio.
◼ By definition,
 = - f + (f /S)*S
◼ So, the change in the value of the portfolio, Δ, in the
time interval Δt is given by
Δ = - Δ f + (f /S)* ΔS
◼ Substituting the discrete versions of equations into the
above equation yields
Δ = (-f /t - 1/2 [2f /S2] s2S2 )Δt
◼ Since Δ does not involve Δz, the portfolio is riskless
during the time interval Δt.
Step 3: obtain Black-Scholes-Merton
differential equation
◼ In the absence of arbitrage opportunities, the return from
the portfolio should be the risk-free interest rate, i.e.,
 = rt
◼ Simplify this equation and obtain:

f f 1 2 2  2 f
+ rS + s S = rf
t S 2 S 2

◼ This is the Black-Scholes-Merton differential equation.


This equation must be satisfied by the price of any
derivative dependent on a non-dividend paying stock.
Solve for derivative price with boundary
conditions
◼ The derivative obtained when the equation is solved with
the boundary conditions :

➢ for a European call option, the condition is


f = Max(St-X , 0) when t = T.

➢ for a European put option, the condition is


f = Max(X-St ,0) when t = T.

◼ The closed form solution is the price of option, i.e., Black-


Scholes formula.
An alternative approach: risk-neutral
valuation
◼ Notice: m does not appear in the B-S-M differential
equation. That is, all variables pertaining to risk
preference are canceled out of the equation.

◼ Therefore, the solution to the equation, the price of the


derivative, is the same regardless of the riskiness of the
underlying.

f f 1 2 2  f 2
+ rS + s S = rf
t S 2 S 2
Risk-neutral valuation

◼ Since risk preference is not important, we can assume


that investors are risk neutral
◼ If investors are risk neutral, i.e. demand no premium
for risk, then μ=r
◼ Hence,

dS = rSdt + sSdZ
◼ Find the expected payoff
◼ Discount at r
Risk-neutral valuation of European options
◼ For European call & put options on non-dividend-paying
stocks:

c = e − r (T −t ) Eˆ maxST − X ,0 p = e E maxX − ST ,0


− r (T −t ) ˆ

◼ The solutions are:

c = SN (d1 ) − Xe− r (T −t ) N (d 2 )
p = − SN ( − d1 ) + Xe − r ( T − t ) N ( − d 2 )
◼ where:
ln( S / X ) + (r + s 2 / 2)(T − t )
d1 = ,
s T −t
ln( S / X ) + (r − s 2 / 2)(T − t )
d2 = = d1 − s T − t
s T −t
Risk-neutral probability of exercising a call options
◼ Risk-neutral probability that:
➢ ST>X, then ln(ST)>ln(X) and dS = rSdt + sSdZ
➢ It shows:
 ST  s2 s2
ln   ~ [(r − )(T − t ), s T − t ], so ln( ST ) ~ [ln( St ) + (r − )(T − t ), s T − t ]
 St  2 2
P ( ST  X )
ln( ST ) − mean ln( X ) − mean
= P(ln( ST )  ln( X )) = p (  )
stdev stdev
s2
ln( X ) − ln( St ) − (r − )(T − t )
= P(   2 )
s T −t
s2 s2
ln( X ) − ln( St ) − (r − )(T − t ) ln( St ) − ln( X ) + (r − )(T − t )
= P( Z  − 2 ) = P( Z  2 )
s T −t s T −t
s2 s2
ln( St / X ) + (r − )(T − t ) ln( St / X ) + (r − )(T − t )
= P( Z  2 ), given d 2 = 2
s T −t s T −t
= N (d 2 )
Risk-neutral probability of exercising a call options

◼ P(standard normal random variable < d2)= N (d 2 )

◼ 1-N(d2) = is the risk neutral probability that a put option


(ST<X on the same underlying with the same X and T)
will be exercised.
What about the volatility parameter?
◼ All inputs except the volatility are observable.
◼ In theory, the BS model has no room for dynamic/stochastic
volatility; it is assumed to be constant and thus identical under
both measures
◼ In practice, the BS volatility should be set to today’s expectation
of the underlying’s volatility over the life time of the option (under
the risk-neutral measure)
➢ This requires a more complex model of stochastic volatility
◼ Because high-vol states are considered bad states, BS-implied
variance should be higher than realized variance alone for that
reason
➢ There are several additional reasons that make the BS-implied
volatilities different from realized and even different by strike of the
option. We’ll discuss these later.
What about the volatility parameter?

◼ Holding all other parameters constant, there is a 1-to-1


mapping between option price and option volatility
➢ Given a price, we can back out the volatility. That’s why
we call it implied volatility (IV)

◼ Option traders use IV as a means to communicate


prices.
Implied volatility
◼ It is the volatility implied by an option price observed in the
market.
◼ For example, suppose that the value of a European call on a
non-dividend-paying stock is 1.875 when S=$21, X=$20, r=0.1
and T- t = 0.25. Based on the Black-Scholes model, we can
find the value of s (implied volatility) using an iterative search
procedure.
◼ There is no closed form equation to solve the implied
volatility directly, however we can obtained it by
approximation.
◼ Use more actively traded options to find s
◼ Implied volatilities are used to monitor the market’s opinion
about the volatility of a particular stock.
◼ Implied volatilities are forward-looking whereas historical
volatilities are backward looking.
◼ VIX index
Problems with Black-Scholes-Merton Model

◼ Pricing bias:
➢ Stock price does not follow a Geometric Brownian
Motion such as a “jump” stochastic process
➢ Interest rate is stochastic
➢ Volatility is stochastic
Black-Scholes pricing model for European
options on a dividend-paying stock
◼ If the amount and timing of the dividends during the life
of a European option can be predicted with certainty, the
Black-Scholes formula can be used provided that the
stock price is reduced by the present value of all the
dividends during the life of the option

− r (T −t )
c = S N (d1 ) − Xe
*
N (d 2 )
− r (T − t )
p = Xe N (−d 2 ) − S N (−d1 )
*
Black-Scholes pricing model for European
options on a dividend-paying stock

where
S * = S −  e − rt k Dk
k

ln( S * / X ) + (r + s 2 / 2)(T − t )
d1 =
s T −t

d 2 = d1 − s T − t
Example
◼ Consider a European call option on a stock when
there are ex-dividend dates in two months and five
months. The dividend on each ex-dividend date is
expected to be $0.50. The current stock price is $40,
the strike price is $40, the stock price volatility is 30%
per annum, the risk-free rate of interest is 9% per
annum, and the time to maturity is six months. What
is the option price?
Solution

◼ PV(D) = 0.9741

◼ S* = 40-0.9741=39.0259

◼ d1= 0.2020, and N(d1)=0.5800 (using the table given in


the textbook)

◼ d2 = -0.0102, and N(d2)=0.4960 (using the table given


in the textbook)

◼ c = 3.67
Early exercise of American call options
◼ RECALL: An American call on a non-dividend paying
stock should never be exercised early.

◼ If an American call on a dividend-paying stock is


exercised early, it should only be exercised immediately
prior to an ex-dividend date (i.e., before the price drops
due to the dividend payment).

◼ Suppose the stock pays n dividends, D1,..., Dn at times t1,


…, tn, between now (time 0) and maturity (time T).
Early exercise of American call options

◼ Consider the possibility of exercising before the final


dividend: if the call is exercised just before time tn, the
holder receives the intrinsic value = S(tn) - K.

◼ If the call is not exercised, the stock price will be


expected to drop to S(tn) - Dn. We know that the call
price is bounded below: C(tn)> S(tn) - Dn - Ke-r(T-t(n)).

◼ If S(tn) - K < S(tn) - Dn - Ke-r(T-t(n)), the intrinsic value is


less than the call price. DO NOT EXERCISE the call;
keep it alive.
Early exercise of American call options
◼ Consider the dividend at tn-1: if call is exercised then holder
receives S(tn-1) – K; if call is not exercised stock price drops
to S(tn-1) – Dn-1.

◼ If S(tn-1) – K < S(tn-1) – Dn-1- Ke-r[t(n)-t(n-1)] not optimal to


exercise the option at tn-1.

◼ it may be optimal to exercise the option immediately prior to


an ex-dividend date ti if
− r ( t i +1 − t i )
Di  X (1 − e )
where Di is a dividend and ti is the time right before the
stock going ex-dividend.
Pricing for American call options
◼ For an American call option on non-dividend-paying
stock, the value is the same as the value of the
corresponding European call option.

◼ For an American call option on dividend-paying stock,


Black suggests an approximation procedure:
➢ calculate the prices of European call options that mature at
times T and ti (time you may consider to exercise the
options prior to maturity), respectively
➢ Approximate the American price as the greater of the two.

◼ Alternatively use Binomial model


Example
◼ Consider six-month American call option with S=40,
X=40, r=0.09, D1=D2=0.5, s=0.30, t1 occurs after two
months, and t2 occurs after five months. When might
the option be exercised ? What is the price of option?
− r ( t 2 − t1 )
X (1 − e ) = 0.89
− r ( T − t2 )
X (1 − e ) = 0.30

◼ Because 0.89 > 0.5 and 0.3 <0.5, the option might be
exercised right before the second ex-dividend date.
◼ A stock has an expected return of 16% and a volatility of 35%.
The current stock price is 68 and the risk-free rate is 10%
1. What is the real probability that the stock price will higher than
75 and in 6 months?
2. What is the risk-neutral probability that a European Call option
on the stock with exercise price of 75 and a maturity date in 6
months will be exercised?
3. What is the risk-neutral probability that a European Put option on
the stock with same exercise price and maturity will be
exercised?

◼ Show that the BSM model for call and put options satisfy put-call
parity.
◼ Calculate the price of a 3-month European put option an a non-dividend-
paying stock with a strike price of 50 when the current stock price is 50,
the risk-free rate is 10% per year, and the volatility is 30% per year?
What will be the price for the same put option if a dividend of 1.5 is
expected in 2 months?

◼ Consider an American call option on a stock, the stock price is 50, it has
15 months maturity time, risk-free rate is 8%, the exercise price is 55
and the volatility is 25%. Dividends of 1.5 are expected in 4 months, 10
months and 18 months. It this call option optimal to be exercised prior to
these three dividend dates and what is the price of the option?
◼ A variable, x, starts at -20 and follows a generalized Wiener process dx = adt
+ bdz During the first two years, a = 5 and b = 4. During the following three
years, a = 8 and b = 6. What is the mean value of the change of variable x
after five years?
a. 45
b. 65
c. 14
d. 34
e. none of the above

◼ What is the standard deviation of the variable x after five years?


a. 26
b. 5.09
c. 11.83
d. 140
e. none of the above
◼ The share price of company CBA exhibits an instantaneous drift of 17%
per year with a return volatility of 23%. What is the probability of the
CBA shares fall below $105 after 9 months when that cost $120 today?

◼ If a stock price S follows GBM, what will be a 95% confidence interval


for ST in time T? (GBM ~ dS=μS dt+σS dz)
◼ A stock has an expected return of 16% and a volatility of 35%. The
current stock price is 68 and the risk-free rate is 10%
1. What is the real probability that the stock price will higher than 75 and
in 6 months?
2. What is the risk-neutral probability that a European Call option on the
stock with exercise price of 75 and a maturity date in 6 months will be
exercised?
3. What is the risk-neutral probability that a European Put option on the
stock with same exercise price and maturity will be exercised?
Thank You

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy