0% found this document useful (0 votes)
222 views59 pages

Intertemporal Choice

This document discusses intertemporal choice and how individuals allocate consumption over time. It begins by introducing the concepts of future value and present value when there is interest. It then presents the consumer's intertemporal budget constraint graphically, showing the tradeoff between consuming now versus later depending on whether they save, borrow, or do neither. The budget constraint is a downward sloping line, with a slope of -(1+r) where r is the interest rate. Finally, it notes that introducing prices for consumption in each period modifies the budget constraint by changing the maximum possible consumption amounts. The key ideas are the intertemporal budget constraint, future and present values, and how saving, borrowing or doing neither affects consumption possibilities over time.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
222 views59 pages

Intertemporal Choice

This document discusses intertemporal choice and how individuals allocate consumption over time. It begins by introducing the concepts of future value and present value when there is interest. It then presents the consumer's intertemporal budget constraint graphically, showing the tradeoff between consuming now versus later depending on whether they save, borrow, or do neither. The budget constraint is a downward sloping line, with a slope of -(1+r) where r is the interest rate. Finally, it notes that introducing prices for consumption in each period modifies the budget constraint by changing the maximum possible consumption amounts. The key ideas are the intertemporal budget constraint, future and present values, and how saving, borrowing or doing neither affects consumption possibilities over time.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 59

Intertemporal Choice

Intertemporal Choice

 Persons often receive income in “lumps”; e.g. monthly salary.


 How is a lump of income spread over the following month (saving now for
consumption later)?
 Or how is consumption financed by borrowing now against income to be
received at the end of the month?
Present and Future Values

 Begin with some simple financial arithmetic.


 Take just two periods; 1 and 2.
 Let r denote the interest rate per period.
Future Value

 E.g., if r = 0.1 then Rs.100 saved at the start of period 1 becomes Rs110 at
the start of period 2.
 The value next period of Rs1 saved now is the future value of that unit of
money.
Future Value

 Given an interest rate r the future value one period from now of Rs1 is

FV  1  r.
 Given an interest rate r the future value one period from now of Rsm is

FV  m(1  r ).
Present Value
 Suppose you can pay now to obtain Rs1 at the start of next period.
 What is the most you should pay?
 Rs1?
 No. If you kept your Rs1 now and saved it then at the start of next
period you would have Rs(1+r) > Rs1.
 Q: How much money would have to be saved now, in the present,
to obtain Rs1 at the start of the next period?
 A: Rs m saved now, becomes Rs m(1+r) at the start of next period,
so we want the value of m for which
m(1+r) = 1
That is, m = 1/(1+r),
the present-value of Rs1 obtained at the start of next period.
Present Value
 The present value of Rs1 available at the start of the next period
𝟏
is 𝑷𝑽 =
𝟏+𝒓
 And the present value of Rs. m available at the start of the next period is
𝒎
 𝑷𝑽 =
𝟏+𝒓
 E.g., if r = 0.1 then the most you should pay now for Rs.
1 available next period is is 𝑷𝑽 =
𝟏
=0.91
𝟏+.𝟏
 And if r = 0.2 then the most you should pay now for Rs. 1
available next period is
𝟏
 𝑷𝑽 = =0.833
𝟏+.𝟐
The Intertemporal Choice
Problem
 Let m1 and m2 be incomes received in periods 1 and 2.
 Let c1 and c2 be consumptions in periods 1 and 2.
 Let p1 and p2 be the prices of consumption in periods 1 and 2.
 The intertemporal choice problem:
Given incomes m1 and m2, and given consumption prices p1 and p2, what is the
most preferred intertemporal consumption bundle (c1, c2)?
 For an answer we need to know:
 the intertemporal budget constraint
 intertemporal consumption preferences.

 To start, let’s ignore price effects by supposing that

p1 = p2 = Rs1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Suppose that the consumer chooses not to save or to


borrow.
 Q: What will be consumed in period 1?
 A: c1 = m1.
 Q: What will be consumed in period 2?
 A: c2 = m2.
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2

m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

c2
So (c1, c2) = (m1, m2) is the
consumption bundle if the
consumer chooses neither to
save nor to borrow.
m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Now suppose that the consumer spends nothing on consumption in period 1;


that is, c1 = 0 and the consumer saves
s1 = m1.
 The interest rate is r.
 What now will be period 2’s consumption level?
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
 Period 2 income is m2.
 Savings plus interest from period 1 sum to (1 + r )m1.
 So total income available in period 2 is
m2 + (1 + r )m1.
 So period 2 consumption expenditure is
 𝑐2 = 𝑚2 + (1 + 𝑟) 𝑚1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
the future-value of the income
𝑚2 + (1 + 𝑟) 𝑚1 endowment

m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
𝑐1 , 𝑐2 = (0, 𝑚2 + (1 + 𝑟) 𝑚1 )`
𝑚2 + (1 + 𝑟) 𝑚1
is the consumption bundle when all
period 1 income is saved.

m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Now suppose that the consumer spends everything possible on consumption in


period 1, so c2 = 0.
 What is the most that the consumer can borrow in period 1 against her period
2 income of m2?
 Let b1 denote the amount borrowed in period 1.
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Only m2 will be available in period 2 to pay back b1 borrowed in period 1.


 So b1(1 + r ) = m2.
 That is, b1 = m2 / (1 + r ).
 So the largest possible period 1 consumption level is
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Only $m2 will be available in period 2 to pay back $b1 borrowed in period 1.
 So b1(1 + r ) = m2.
 That is, b1 = m2 / (1 + r ).
 So the largest possible period 1 consumption level is
𝑚2
 𝑐1 = 𝑚1 +
1+𝑟
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2  (c1 , c2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
(1  r )m1 is the consumption bundle when all
period 1 income is saved.

m2 the present-value of
the income endowment

0 m2c1
0 m1 m1 
1 r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2  (c1 , c2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
(1  r )m1 is the consumption bundle when
period 1 saving is as large as possible.


( c1 , c 2 )   m1 
m2 
,0
 1r 
m2 is the consumption bundle
when period 1 borrowing
is as big as possible.
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Suppose that c1 units are consumed in period 1. This costs c1 and leaves m1-
c1 saved. Period 2 consumption will then be

c2  m2  (1  r )( m1  c1 )
c2  (1  r )c1  m2  (1  r )m1 .
slope
intercept
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2  (c1 , c2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
is the consumption bundle when
(1  r )m1
period 1 saving is as large as possible.

( c1 , c 2 )   m1 
m2 
,0
 1r 
m2 is the consumption bundle
when period 1 borrowing
is as big as possible.
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
c2  (1  r )c1  m2  (1  r )m1 .
m2 
( 1  r)m1
slope = -(1+r)

m2

0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2 
c2  (1  r )c1  m2  (1  r )m1 .
( 1  r)m1
slope = -(1+r)

m2

0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
(1  r )c1  c2  (1  r )m1  m2
is the “future-valued” form of the budget
constraint since all terms are in period 2
values. This is equivalent to
c2 m2
c1   m1 
1 r 1 r
which is the “present-valued” form of the
constraint since all terms are in period 1
values.
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint

 Now let’s add prices p1 and p2 for consumption in periods 1 and 2.


 How does this affect the budget constraint?
Intertemporal Choice
 Given her endowment (m1,m2) and prices p1, p2 what intertemporal
consumption bundle (c1*,c2*) will be chosen by the consumer?
 Maximum possible expenditure in period 2 is
so maximum possible consumption in period 2 is

m2  (1  r )m1
m2  (1  r )m1
c2  .
p2
Intertemporal Choice
 Similarly, maximum possible expenditure in period 1 is
m2
m1 
1 r

 so maximum possible consumption in period 1 is

m1  m2 /(1  r )
c1  .
p1
Intertemporal Choice
 Finally, if c1 units are consumed in period 1 then the consumer spends p1c1 in
period 1, leaving m1 - p1c1 saved for period 1. Available income in period 2
will then be

so
m2  (1  r )( m1  p1c1 )

p2 c2  m2  (1  r )( m1  p1c1 ).
Intertemporal Choice

p2 c2  m2  (1  r )( m1  p1c1 )

rearranged is
(1  r ) p1c1  p2 c2  (1  r )m1  m2 .

This is the “future-valued” form of the


budget constraint since all terms are
expressed in period 2 values. Equivalent
to it is the “present-valued” form
p2 m2
p1c1  c2  m1 
1 r 1 r
where all terms are expressed in period 1
values.
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
(1  r )m1  m2 c2
p2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
(1  r )m1  m2 c2
p2

m2/p2
m1  m2 / (1  r )
0 c1 p1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
(1  r ) p1c1  p2 c2  (1  r )m1  m2
(1  r )m1  m2
p2 p1
Slope =  (1  r ) p
2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1  m2 / (1  r )
p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2 (1  r ) p1c1  p2 c2  (1  r )m1  m2
(1  r )m1  m2
p2
p1
 (1  r )
Slope = p2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1  m2 / (1  r )
p1
Price Inflation

 Define the inflation rate by p where


p1 (1  p )  p2 .
 For example,

p = 0.2 means 20% inflation, and


p = 1.0 means 100% inflation.
Price Inflation

 We lose nothing by setting p1=1 so that p2 = 1+ p.


 Then we can rewrite the budget constraint

p2 m2
as p1c1  c2  m1 
1 r 1 r
1 p m2
c1  c2  m1 
1 r 1 r
Price Inflation
1 p m2
c1  c2  m1 
1 r 1 r
rearranges to
1 r  m1 
c2   c1  (1  p )  m2 
1 p 1 r 

so the slope of the intertemporal budget


constraint is 1 r
 .
1 p
Price Inflation
 When there was no price inflation (p1=p2=1) the slope of the budget constraint was -
(1+r).

 Now, with price inflation, the slope of the budget constraint is -(1+r)/(1+ p). This
can be written as
1 r
 (1  r )  
r is known as the real interest rate. 1 p
 If you save Rs. I unit today you get Rs. (1+r) in next period. In real terms it is
(𝟏+𝒓)
equivalent to (𝟏+𝝅) where p1 =1 and p2=1+ 𝝅.

 Thus in real terms extra you have earned over your savings of one unit is
(𝟏+𝒓) 𝒓−𝝅
 -1=𝟏+𝝅 =𝝆 = 𝒓𝒆𝒂𝒍 𝒓𝒂𝒕𝒆 𝒐𝒇 𝒊𝒏𝒕𝒆𝒓𝒆𝒔𝒕.
(𝟏+𝝅)
Real Interest Rate
1 r
 (1  r )  
1 p
gives
r p
r  .
1 p
For low inflation rates (p  0), r  r - p .
For higher inflation rates this
approximation becomes poor.
Real Interest Rate

r 0.30 0.30 0.30 0.30 0.30

p 0.0 0.05 0.10 0.20 1.00

r - p 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.10 -0.70

r 0.30 0.24 0.18 0.08 -0.35


Comparative Statics

 The slope of the budget constraint is

1 r
 (1  r )   .
1 p
 The constraint becomes flatter if the interest rate r falls or the inflation rate

p rises (both decrease the real rate of interest).


Comparative Statics
c2
slope = 1 r
 (1  r )  
1 p

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Preference
U= 𝒖 𝒄𝟏 + 𝛅𝒖(𝒄𝟐 ) 0< 𝛅 ≤ 𝟏
Here 𝛅 is the discount rate by which consumer is
discounting future utility.
What is the MRS?
𝒖, (𝒄𝟏 )
MRS= ,
𝜹𝒖 (𝒄𝟐 )

𝒖, (𝒄𝟏 )
Slope of the indifference curve: -
𝜹𝒖, (𝒄𝟐 )
As 𝛅, consumer becomes more impatient , the
indifference curves become steeper.
Comparative Statics
c2
slope = 1 r
 (1  r )  
1 p

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2  (1  r )  
1 r
slope = 1 p

The consumer saves. Or a lender

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: A Fall in r

c2 1 r
 (1  r )  
slope = 1 p

The consumer saves. A


decrease in the interest
rate “flattens” the
budget constraint.

If inflation rate goes


m2/p2
up then budget line
flattens, as well as
m2/p2 0 c1
falls. 0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: fall in r
c2 1 r
slope =  (1  r )  
1 p

If the consumer saves then


saving and welfare are
reduced by a lower
interest rate.
m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2  (1  r )  
1 r
slope = 1 p

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1 r
slope = (1  r )   1 p

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2  (1  r )  
1 r
slope = 1 p

The consumer borrows.

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: A fall in r
c2  (1  r )  
1 r
slope = 1 p

The consumer borrows. A


fall in the interest rate “flattens” the
budget constraint.

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: A fall in r
c2 1 r
slope =  (1  r )  
1 p

If the consumer borrows then


borrowing and welfare are
increased by a lower
interest
m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Proposition: Suppose first that the consumer is a lender. Then it turns out that if interest
rate increases, the consumer must remain a lender.

◎ Qs.If the consumer is initially a lender, then his


consumption bundle is to the left of the endowment
point. Now let the interest rate increase. Is it ◎
possible that the consumer shifts to a new
consumption point to the right of the endowment?
◎ Ans. No, due to Revealed Preference theory.
◎ Because that would violate the principle of revealed
preference: choices to the right of the endowment
point were available to the consumer when he
faced the original budget set and were rejected in Slope=-(1+𝝆)
favor of the chosen point. Since the original optimal
bundle is still available at the new budget line, the
new optimal bundle must be a point outside the old
◎ budget set—which means it must be to the left of
the endowment. The consumer must remain a
lender when the interest rate increases.
There is a similar effect for borrowers: if the consumer is initially a
borrower, and the interest rate declines, he or she will remain a borrower

◎ .
Valuing Securities : Present Value for
several periods
 A financial security is a financial instrument that promises to deliver an income stream.
 E.g.; a security that pays
m1 at the end of year 1,
m2 at the end of year 2, and
m3 at the end of year 3.
 What is the most that should be paid now for this security?

m1 /(1  r )  m2 /(1  r )  m3 /(1  r ) . 2 3


Three Period Budget Constraint

 Ignoring inflation and commodity prices as constant at unity

 Suppose interest rate varies over time. Suppose, for example, that the interest earned on savings from
period 1 to 2 is r1, while savings from period 2 to 3 earn r2. Then Rs. 1 in period 1 will grow to (1+r1)(1+r2)
dollars in period 3. The present value of Rs1 in period 3 is therefore 1/(1 + r1)(1 + r2). This implies that the
correct form of the budget constraint is
Valuing Bonds

 A bond is a special type of security that pays a fixed amount $x for T years (its
maturity date) and then pays its face value $F.
 What is the most that should now be paid for such a bond?
Valuing Bonds
End of
1 2 3 … T-1 T
Year
Income
x x x x x F
Paid
Present x
1 r
x
(1  r )2
x
(1  r )3 … x
(1  r )T 1
F
(1  r )T

-Value

x x x F
PV    T 1
 .
1  r (1  r ) 2
(1  r ) (1  r )T

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy