Intertemporal Choice
Intertemporal Choice
Intertemporal Choice
E.g., if r = 0.1 then Rs.100 saved at the start of period 1 becomes Rs110 at
the start of period 2.
The value next period of Rs1 saved now is the future value of that unit of
money.
Future Value
Given an interest rate r the future value one period from now of Rs1 is
FV 1 r.
Given an interest rate r the future value one period from now of Rsm is
FV m(1 r ).
Present Value
Suppose you can pay now to obtain Rs1 at the start of next period.
What is the most you should pay?
Rs1?
No. If you kept your Rs1 now and saved it then at the start of next
period you would have Rs(1+r) > Rs1.
Q: How much money would have to be saved now, in the present,
to obtain Rs1 at the start of the next period?
A: Rs m saved now, becomes Rs m(1+r) at the start of next period,
so we want the value of m for which
m(1+r) = 1
That is, m = 1/(1+r),
the present-value of Rs1 obtained at the start of next period.
Present Value
The present value of Rs1 available at the start of the next period
𝟏
is 𝑷𝑽 =
𝟏+𝒓
And the present value of Rs. m available at the start of the next period is
𝒎
𝑷𝑽 =
𝟏+𝒓
E.g., if r = 0.1 then the most you should pay now for Rs.
1 available next period is is 𝑷𝑽 =
𝟏
=0.91
𝟏+.𝟏
And if r = 0.2 then the most you should pay now for Rs. 1
available next period is
𝟏
𝑷𝑽 = =0.833
𝟏+.𝟐
The Intertemporal Choice
Problem
Let m1 and m2 be incomes received in periods 1 and 2.
Let c1 and c2 be consumptions in periods 1 and 2.
Let p1 and p2 be the prices of consumption in periods 1 and 2.
The intertemporal choice problem:
Given incomes m1 and m2, and given consumption prices p1 and p2, what is the
most preferred intertemporal consumption bundle (c1, c2)?
For an answer we need to know:
the intertemporal budget constraint
intertemporal consumption preferences.
p1 = p2 = Rs1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
m2
0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
So (c1, c2) = (m1, m2) is the
consumption bundle if the
consumer chooses neither to
save nor to borrow.
m2
0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
m2
0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
𝑐1 , 𝑐2 = (0, 𝑚2 + (1 + 𝑟) 𝑚1 )`
𝑚2 + (1 + 𝑟) 𝑚1
is the consumption bundle when all
period 1 income is saved.
m2
0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
Only $m2 will be available in period 2 to pay back $b1 borrowed in period 1.
So b1(1 + r ) = m2.
That is, b1 = m2 / (1 + r ).
So the largest possible period 1 consumption level is
𝑚2
𝑐1 = 𝑚1 +
1+𝑟
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2 (c1 , c2 ) 0, m2 (1 r )m1
(1 r )m1 is the consumption bundle when all
period 1 income is saved.
m2 the present-value of
the income endowment
0 m2c1
0 m1 m1
1 r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2 (c1 , c2 ) 0, m2 (1 r )m1
(1 r )m1 is the consumption bundle when
period 1 saving is as large as possible.
( c1 , c 2 ) m1
m2
,0
1r
m2 is the consumption bundle
when period 1 borrowing
is as big as possible.
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
Suppose that c1 units are consumed in period 1. This costs c1 and leaves m1-
c1 saved. Period 2 consumption will then be
c2 m2 (1 r )( m1 c1 )
c2 (1 r )c1 m2 (1 r )m1 .
slope
intercept
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2 (c1 , c2 ) 0, m2 (1 r )m1
is the consumption bundle when
(1 r )m1
period 1 saving is as large as possible.
( c1 , c 2 ) m1
m2
,0
1r
m2 is the consumption bundle
when period 1 borrowing
is as big as possible.
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
c2 (1 r )c1 m2 (1 r )m1 .
m2
( 1 r)m1
slope = -(1+r)
m2
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
m2
c2 (1 r )c1 m2 (1 r )m1 .
( 1 r)m1
slope = -(1+r)
m2
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1
1r
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
(1 r )c1 c2 (1 r )m1 m2
is the “future-valued” form of the budget
constraint since all terms are in period 2
values. This is equivalent to
c2 m2
c1 m1
1 r 1 r
which is the “present-valued” form of the
constraint since all terms are in period 1
values.
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
m2 (1 r )m1
m2 (1 r )m1
c2 .
p2
Intertemporal Choice
Similarly, maximum possible expenditure in period 1 is
m2
m1
1 r
m1 m2 /(1 r )
c1 .
p1
Intertemporal Choice
Finally, if c1 units are consumed in period 1 then the consumer spends p1c1 in
period 1, leaving m1 - p1c1 saved for period 1. Available income in period 2
will then be
so
m2 (1 r )( m1 p1c1 )
p2 c2 m2 (1 r )( m1 p1c1 ).
Intertemporal Choice
p2 c2 m2 (1 r )( m1 p1c1 )
rearranged is
(1 r ) p1c1 p2 c2 (1 r )m1 m2 .
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
(1 r )m1 m2 c2
p2
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
(1 r )m1 m2 c2
p2
m2/p2
m1 m2 / (1 r )
0 c1 p1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2
(1 r ) p1c1 p2 c2 (1 r )m1 m2
(1 r )m1 m2
p2 p1
Slope = (1 r ) p
2
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1 m2 / (1 r )
p1
The Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2 (1 r ) p1c1 p2 c2 (1 r )m1 m2
(1 r )m1 m2
p2
p1
(1 r )
Slope = p2
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1 m2 / (1 r )
p1
Price Inflation
p2 m2
as p1c1 c2 m1
1 r 1 r
1 p m2
c1 c2 m1
1 r 1 r
Price Inflation
1 p m2
c1 c2 m1
1 r 1 r
rearranges to
1 r m1
c2 c1 (1 p ) m2
1 p 1 r
Now, with price inflation, the slope of the budget constraint is -(1+r)/(1+ p). This
can be written as
1 r
(1 r )
r is known as the real interest rate. 1 p
If you save Rs. I unit today you get Rs. (1+r) in next period. In real terms it is
(𝟏+𝒓)
equivalent to (𝟏+𝝅) where p1 =1 and p2=1+ 𝝅.
Thus in real terms extra you have earned over your savings of one unit is
(𝟏+𝒓) 𝒓−𝝅
-1=𝟏+𝝅 =𝝆 = 𝒓𝒆𝒂𝒍 𝒓𝒂𝒕𝒆 𝒐𝒇 𝒊𝒏𝒕𝒆𝒓𝒆𝒔𝒕.
(𝟏+𝝅)
Real Interest Rate
1 r
(1 r )
1 p
gives
r p
r .
1 p
For low inflation rates (p 0), r r - p .
For higher inflation rates this
approximation becomes poor.
Real Interest Rate
1 r
(1 r ) .
1 p
The constraint becomes flatter if the interest rate r falls or the inflation rate
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Preference
U= 𝒖 𝒄𝟏 + 𝛅𝒖(𝒄𝟐 ) 0< 𝛅 ≤ 𝟏
Here 𝛅 is the discount rate by which consumer is
discounting future utility.
What is the MRS?
𝒖, (𝒄𝟏 )
MRS= ,
𝜹𝒖 (𝒄𝟐 )
𝒖, (𝒄𝟏 )
Slope of the indifference curve: -
𝜹𝒖, (𝒄𝟐 )
As 𝛅, consumer becomes more impatient , the
indifference curves become steeper.
Comparative Statics
c2
slope = 1 r
(1 r )
1 p
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 (1 r )
1 r
slope = 1 p
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: A Fall in r
c2 1 r
(1 r )
slope = 1 p
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 (1 r )
1 r
slope = 1 p
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1 r
slope = (1 r ) 1 p
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 (1 r )
1 r
slope = 1 p
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: A fall in r
c2 (1 r )
1 r
slope = 1 p
m2/p2
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics: A fall in r
c2 1 r
slope = (1 r )
1 p
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Proposition: Suppose first that the consumer is a lender. Then it turns out that if interest
rate increases, the consumer must remain a lender.
◎ .
Valuing Securities : Present Value for
several periods
A financial security is a financial instrument that promises to deliver an income stream.
E.g.; a security that pays
m1 at the end of year 1,
m2 at the end of year 2, and
m3 at the end of year 3.
What is the most that should be paid now for this security?
Suppose interest rate varies over time. Suppose, for example, that the interest earned on savings from
period 1 to 2 is r1, while savings from period 2 to 3 earn r2. Then Rs. 1 in period 1 will grow to (1+r1)(1+r2)
dollars in period 3. The present value of Rs1 in period 3 is therefore 1/(1 + r1)(1 + r2). This implies that the
correct form of the budget constraint is
Valuing Bonds
A bond is a special type of security that pays a fixed amount $x for T years (its
maturity date) and then pays its face value $F.
What is the most that should now be paid for such a bond?
Valuing Bonds
End of
1 2 3 … T-1 T
Year
Income
x x x x x F
Paid
Present x
1 r
x
(1 r )2
x
(1 r )3 … x
(1 r )T 1
F
(1 r )T
-Value
x x x F
PV T 1
.
1 r (1 r ) 2
(1 r ) (1 r )T