0% found this document useful (0 votes)
63 views69 pages

Varian9e LecturePPTs Ch10

The document discusses intertemporal choice and presents the intertemporal budget constraint. It shows that given interest rate r and period incomes m1 and m2, the maximum possible consumption bundles are (0, m2 + (1+r)m1) if all income in period 1 is saved, and (m1 + m2/(1+r), 0) if maximum borrowing against period 2 income occurs in period 1. More generally, period 2 consumption c2 is shown to equal - (1+r)c1 + m2 + (1+r)m1, depicting the intertemporal budget constraint as a line with slope -(1+r).

Uploaded by

王琦
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
63 views69 pages

Varian9e LecturePPTs Ch10

The document discusses intertemporal choice and presents the intertemporal budget constraint. It shows that given interest rate r and period incomes m1 and m2, the maximum possible consumption bundles are (0, m2 + (1+r)m1) if all income in period 1 is saved, and (m1 + m2/(1+r), 0) if maximum borrowing against period 2 income occurs in period 1. More generally, period 2 consumption c2 is shown to equal - (1+r)c1 + m2 + (1+r)m1, depicting the intertemporal budget constraint as a line with slope -(1+r).

Uploaded by

王琦
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 69

Chapter 10

Intertemporal
Choice
Intertemporal Choice
 Persons often receive income in
“lumps”; e.g. monthly salary.
 How is a lump of income spread over
the following month (saving now for
consumption later)?
 Or how is consumption financed by
borrowing now against income to be
received at the end of the month?
Present and Future Values
 Begin with some simple financial
arithmetic.
 Take just two periods; 1 and 2.
 Let r denote the interest rate per
period.
Future Value
 E.g., if r = 0.1 then $100 saved at the
start of period 1 becomes $110 at the
start of period 2.
 The value next period of $1 saved
now is the future value of that dollar.
Future Value
 Given an interest rate r the future
value one period from now of $1 is
FV  1  r .
 Given an interest rate r the future
value one period from now of $m is
FV  m(1  r ).
Present Value
 Suppose you can pay now to obtain
$1 at the start of next period.
 What is the most you should pay?
 $1?
 No. If you kept your $1 now and
saved it then at the start of next
period you would have $(1+r) > $1,
so paying $1 now for $1 next period
is a bad deal.
Present Value
 Q: How much money would have to be
saved now, in the present, to obtain $1
at the start of the next period?
 A: $m saved now becomes $m(1+r) at
the start of next period, so we want
the value of m for which
m(1+r) = 1
That is, m = 1/(1+r),
the present-value of $1 obtained at the
start of next period.
Present Value
 The present value of $1 available at
the start of the next period is
1
PV  .
1r
 And the present value of $m
available at the start of the next
period is m
PV  .
1r
Present Value
 E.g., if r = 0.1 then the most you
should pay now for $1 available next
period is 1
PV   $0  91.
1 01
 And if r = 0.2 then the most you
should pay now for $1 available next
period is 1
PV   $0  83.
1 0 2
The Intertemporal Choice
Problem
 Let m1 and m2 be incomes received in
periods 1 and 2.
 Let c1 and c2 be consumptions in
periods 1 and 2.
 Let p1 and p2 be the prices of
consumption in periods 1 and 2.
The Intertemporal Choice Problem
 The intertemporal choice problem:
Given incomes m1 and m2, and given
consumption prices p1 and p2, what is
the most preferred intertemporal
consumption bundle (c1, c2)?
 For an answer we need to know:
– the intertemporal budget constraint
– intertemporal consumption
preferences.
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 To start, let’s ignore price effects by
supposing that

p1 = p2 = $1.
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Suppose that the consumer chooses
not to save or to borrow.
 Q: What will be consumed in period 1?
 A: c1 = m1.
 Q: What will be consumed in period 2?
 A: c2 = m2.
The Intertemporal Budget
c2 Constraint

m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget
c2 Constraint
So (c1, c2) = (m1, m2) is the
consumption bundle if the
consumer chooses neither to
save nor to borrow.
m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Now suppose that the consumer
spends nothing on consumption in
period 1; that is, c1 = 0 and the
consumer saves
s 1 = m 1.
 The interest rate is r.
 What now will be period 2’s
consumption level?
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Period 2 income is m2.
 Savings plus interest from period 1
sum to (1 + r )m1.
 So total income available in period 2 is

m2 + (1 + r )m1.
 So period 2 consumption expenditure
is
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Period 2 income is m2.
 Savings plus interest from period 1
sum to (1 + r )m1.
 So total income available in period 2 is

m2 + (1 + r )m1.
 So period 2 consumption expenditure
c 2  m2  (1  r )m1
is
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2
m2 
the future-value of the income
endowment
(1  r )m1

m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 ( c1 , c 2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
m2 
is the consumption bundle when all
(1  r )m1 period 1 income is saved.

m2

0 c1
0 m1
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Now suppose that the consumer
spends everything possible on
consumption in period 1, so c2 = 0.
 What is the most that the consumer
can borrow in period 1 against her
period 2 income of $m2?
 Let b1 denote the amount borrowed in
period 1.
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Only $m2 will be available in period 2
to pay back $b1 borrowed in period 1.
 So b1(1 + r ) = m2.
 That is, b1 = m2 / (1 + r ).
 So the largest possible period 1
consumption level is
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Only $m2 will be available in period 2
to pay back $b1 borrowed in period 1.
 So b1(1 + r ) = m2.
 That is, b1 = m2 / (1 + r ).
 So the largest possible period 1
consumption level is m
c1  m1  2
1r
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 ( c1 , c 2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
m2 
is the consumption bundle when all
(1  r )m1 period 1 income is saved.

m2 the present-value of
the income endowment

0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 ( c1 , c 2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
m2 
is the consumption bundle when
(1  r )m1 period 1 saving is as large as possible.
 m2 
( c1 , c 2 )   m1  ,0
 1r 
m2 is the consumption bundle
when period 1 borrowing
is as big as possible.
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Suppose that c1 units are consumed
in period 1. This costs $c1 and
leaves m1- c1 saved. Period 2
consumption will then be
c 2  m2  (1  r )(m1  c1 )
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Suppose that c1 units are consumed
in period 1. This costs $c1 and
leaves m1- c1 saved. Period 2
consumption will then be
c 2  m2  (1  r )(m1  c1 )
which is
c 2   ( 1  r ) c1  m2  ( 1  r )m1 .






slope intercept
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 ( c1 , c 2 )  0, m2  (1  r )m1 
m2 
is the consumption bundle when
(1  r )m1 period 1 saving is as large as possible.
 m2 
( c1 , c 2 )   m1  ,0
 1r 
m2 is the consumption bundle
when period 1 borrowing
is as big as possible.
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 c 2   (1  r )c1  m2  (1  r )m1 .
m2 
(1  r)m1 slope = -(1+r)

m2

0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 c 2   (1  r )c1  m2  (1  r )m1 .
m2 
(1  r)m1 Sa slope = -(1+r)
vi
ng

Bo
m2 rro
wi
ng
0
0 m1 m2 c1
m1 
1r
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
( 1  r )c1  c 2  (1  r )m1  m2
is the “future-valued” form of the budget
constraint since all terms are in period 2
values. This is equivalent to
c2 m2
c1   m1 
1r 1r
which is the “present-valued” form of the
constraint since all terms are in period 1
values.
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
 Now let’s add prices p1 and p2 for
consumption in periods 1 and 2.
 How does this affect the budget
constraint?
Intertemporal Choice
 Given her endowment (m1,m2) and
prices p1, p2 what intertemporal
consumption bundle (c1*,c2*) will be
chosen by the consumer?
 Maximum possible expenditure in
m2  (1  r )m1
period 2 is
so maximum possible consumption
m2  ( 1  r )m1
in period 2 is c 2  .
p2
Intertemporal Choice
 Similarly, maximum possible
expenditure in period 1 is
m2
m1 
1r
so maximum possible consumption
in period 1 is
m1  m2 / ( 1  r )
c1  .
p1
Intertemporal Choice
 Finally, if c1 units are consumed in
period 1 then the consumer spends
p1c1 in period 1, leaving m1 - p1c1
saved for period 1. Available income
in period 2 will then be
m2  (1  r )(m1  p1c1 )
so
p 2c 2  m2  (1  r )(m1  p1c1 ).
Intertemporal Choice
p 2c 2  m2  (1  r )(m1  p1c1 )
rearranged is
( 1  r )p1c1  p 2c 2  ( 1  r )m1  m2 .
This is the “future-valued” form of the
budget constraint since all terms are
expressed in period 2 values. Equivalent
to it is the “present-valued” form
p2 m2
p1c1  c 2  m1 
1r 1r
where all terms are expressed in period 1
values.
The Intertemporal Budget
c2 Constraint

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget
c2 Constraint
(1  r )m1  m2
p2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
The Intertemporal Budget
c2 Constraint
(1  r )m1  m2
p2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1  m2 / ( 1  r )
p1
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 (1  r )p1c1  p 2c 2  (1  r )m1  m2
(1  r )m1  m2
p2
p1
Slope =  (1  r )
p2

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1  m2 / ( 1  r )
p1
The Intertemporal Budget
Constraint
c2 (1  r )p1c1  p 2c 2  (1  r )m1  m2
(1  r )m1  m2
p2
Sa p1
vi Slope =  (1  r )
ng p2

Bo
m2/p2 rro
wi
ng
0 c1
0 m1/p1
m1  m2 / ( 1  r )
p1
Price Inflation
 Define the inflation rate by  where
p1 (1   )  p 2 .
 For example,
 = 0.2 means 20% inflation, and
 = 1.0 means 100% inflation.
Price Inflation
 We lose nothing by setting p1=1 so
that p2 = 1+  .
 Then we can rewrite the budget
constraint p m
p1c1  2 c m  2
2 1
1r 1r
1  m2
as c1  c 2  m1 
1r 1r
Price Inflation
1  m2
c1  c 2  m1 
1r 1r
rearranges to
1 r  m1 
c2   c1  (1  )  m2 
1   1 r 
so the slope of the intertemporal budget
constraint is 1 r
 .
1 
Price Inflation
 When there was no price inflation
(p1=p2=1) the slope of the budget
constraint was -(1+r).
 Now, with price inflation, the slope of
the budget constraint is -(1+r)/(1+ ).
This can be written as
1r
 (1   )  
1 
 is known as the real interest rate.
Real Interest Rate
1r
 (1   )  
1 
gives
r
 .
1 
For low inflation rates ( 0),  r -  .
For higher inflation rates this
approximation becomes poor.
Real Interest Rate
Comparative Statics
 The slope of the budget constraint is
1 r
 (1  )   .
1 
 The constraint becomes flatter if the
interest rate r falls or the inflation
raterises (both decrease the real
rate of interest).
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 
The consumer saves.

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 
The consumer saves. An
increase in the inflation
rate or a decrease in
the interest rate
m2/p2 “flattens” the
budget
constraint.
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 
If the consumer saves then
saving and welfare are
reduced by a lower
interest rate or a
m2/p2 higher inflation
rate.
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 
The consumer borrows.

m2/p2

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 
The consumer borrows. A
fall in the inflation rate or
a rise in the interest rate
“flattens” the
m2/p2 budget constraint.

0 c1
0 m1/p1
Comparative Statics
c2 1r
slope =  (1   )  
1 
If the consumer borrows then
borrowing and welfare are
increased by a lower
interest rate or a
m2/p2 higher inflation
rate.
0 c1
0 m1/p1
Valuing Securities
 A financial security is a financial
instrument that promises to deliver
an income stream.
 E.g.; a security that pays
$m1 at the end of year 1,
$m2 at the end of year 2, and
$m3 at the end of year 3.
 What is the most that should be paid
now for this security?
Valuing Securities
 The security is equivalent to the sum
of three securities;
– the first pays only $m1 at the end of
year 1,
– the second pays only $m2 at the
end of year 2, and
– the third pays only $m3 at the end
of year 3.
Valuing Securities
 The PV of $m1 paid 1 year from now is
m1 / (1  r )
 The PV of $m2 paid 2 years from now is
2
m2 / ( 1  r )
 The PV of $m3 paid33 years from now is
m3 / ( 1  r )
 The PV of the security is therefore
m1 / (1  r )  m2 / (1  r ) 2  m3 / (1  r ) 3 .
Valuing Bonds
 A bond is a special type of security
that pays a fixed amount $x for T
years (its maturity date) and then
pays its face value $F.
 What is the most that should now be
paid for such a bond?
Valuing Bonds

x x x F
PV     .
1  r (1  r ) 2 T 1 T
(1  r ) (1  r )
Valuing Bonds
 Suppose you win a State lottery. The
prize is $1,000,000 but it is paid over
10 years in equal installments of
$100,000 each. What is the prize
actually worth?
Valuing Bonds
$100,000 $100,000 $100,000
PV   
1  0  1 (1  0  1) 2 (1  0  1) 10

 $614,457

is the actual (present) value of the prize.


Valuing Consols
 A consol is a bond which never
terminates, paying $x per period
forever.
 What is a consol’s present-value?
Valuing Consols

x x x
PV    .
1  r (1  r ) 2 t
(1  r )
Valuing Consols
x x x
PV    
1  r (1  r ) 2 (1  r ) 3
1  x x 
 x    
1r  1  r (1  r ) 2 
1

1r
 x  PV . Solving for PV gives
x
PV  .
r
Valuing Consols
E.g. if r = 0.1 now and forever then the
most that should be paid now for a
console that provides $1000 per year is
x $1000
PV    $10,000.
r 01

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy