Theories Lec 3
Theories Lec 3
https://prezi.com/6kjelob55mj9/development-and-the-linear-stages-theories/
(1) The Linear-Stages Theories
1.1. Rostow’s Stages of Growth
• According to Rostow, the transition from underdevelopment to development
can be described in terms of a series of steps or stages through which all
countries must proceed.
➢The advanced countries had all passed the stage of “take-off into self-sustaining growth,”
➢The underdeveloped countries that were still in either the traditional society or the
“preconditions” stage had only to follow a certain set of rules of development to take off
in their turn into self sustaining economic growth.
• One of the principal strategies of development necessary for any takeoff was the
mobilization of domestic and foreign saving in order to generate sufficient investment to
accelerate economic growth.
• The economic mechanism by which more investment leads to more growth can be
described in terms of the Harrod-Domar growth model, today often referred to as the AK
model because it is based on a linear production function with output given by the
capital stock K times a constant, often labeled A.
1.2. The Harrod-Domar Growth Model
• Every economy must save a certain proportion of its national income, if only to replace
worn-out capital goods (buildings, equipment, and materials).
• However, in order to grow, new investments representing net additions to the capital
stock are necessary.
• There is a direct economic relationship between the size of the total capital stock, K, and
total GDP, Y.
• For example, if $3 of capital is always necessary to produce an annual $1 stream of GDP—
it follows that any net additions to the capital stock in the form of new investment will
bring about corresponding increases in the flow of national output, GDP.
• This relationship, known in economics as the capital-output ratio.
If we define the capital-output ratio as k and assume further that:
• the national net savings ratio, s, is a fixed proportion of national output
• the total new investment is determined by the level of total savings,
1. Net saving (S) is some proportion, s, of national income (Y) such that we
have the simple equation
S = sY (1)
2. Net investment (I) is defined as the change in the capital stock, K, and can be represented
by ΔK such that
I = ΔK (2)
• But because the total capital stock, K, bears a direct relationship to total national income
or output, Y, as expressed by the capital-output ratio, c, it follows that
𝐾 ∆𝐾
=c or =𝑐
𝑌 ∆𝑌
or, finally,
ΔK = cΔY (3)
1/c is a measure of the efficiency of capital utilization.
3. Finally, because net national savings, S, must equal net investment, I, we can write this
equality as
S=I (4)
• But from Equation (1) we know that S = sY, and from Equations (2) and (3) we know that
I = ΔK = cΔY
• It therefore follows that we can write the “identity” of saving equaling investment shown by
Equation (4) as
S = sY = cΔY = ΔK = I (5)
or simply as
sY = cΔY (6)
• Dividing both sides of Equation (6) first by Y and then by c, we obtain the following
expression:
∆𝑌 𝑠
= (7)
𝑌 𝑐
∆𝑌
• Note that the left-hand side of Equation (7), , represents the rate of change or rate of
𝑌
growth of GDP.
• Equation (7), which is a simplified version of the famous equation in the
Harrod-Domar theory of economic growth, states simply that “the rate of
growth of GDP (ΔY/Y) is determined jointly by the net national savings ratio, s,
and the national capital-output ratio, c”.
• More specifically, it says that in the absence of government, the growth rate
of national income will be directly or positively related to the savings ratio
(i.e., the more an economy is able to save—and invest—out of a given GDP,
the greater the growth of that GDP will be) and inversely or negatively related
to the economy’s capital-output ratio (i.e., the higher c is, the lower the rate
of GDP growth will be).
• Equation (7) is also often expressed in terms of gross savings, 𝑠 𝐺 , in which
case the growth rate is given by
∆𝑌 𝑠𝐺
= −𝛿 (7`)
𝑌 𝑐
Where, δ is the rate of capital depreciation.
• The economic logic of Equations (7) and (7’) is very simple. To grow,
economies must save and invest a certain proportion of their GDP.
• The more they can save and invest, the faster they can grow.
• But the actual rate at which they can grow for any level of saving and
investment—how much additional output can be gained from an
additional unit of investment—can be measured by the inverse of the
capital-output ratio, c, because this inverse, 1/c, is simply the output-
capital or output-investment ratio. It follows that multiplying the rate of
new investment, s = I/Y, by its productivity, 1/c, will give the rate by which
national income or GDP will increase.
• In addition to capital accumulation (investment), two other components of economic
growth are labor force growth and technological progress.
• In the context of the Harrod-Domar growth model, labor force growth is not described
explicitly. This is because labor is assumed to be abundant in a developing country context
and can be hired as needed in a given proportion to capital investments (this assumption
is not always valid).
• In a general way, technological progress can be expressed in the Harrod-Domar context as
a decrease in the required capital-output ratio, giving more growth for a given level of
investment, as follows from Equation (7) or (7’). This is obvious when we realize that in the
longer run, this ratio is not fixed but can change over time in response to the functioning
of financial markets and the policy environment.
• The focus of this model was on the role of capital investment.
https://youtu.be/rol2aKFZ_IE
Some Criticisms of the Stages Model