Lecture 1
Lecture 1
Econ 6022
Lecture 1
Fall, 2021
1 / 96
Course Information
• Instructor: Heng Chen (Henry)
- Email: hengchen@hku.hk
- Office: 915, KKL
- Office hour: 17:30 - 18:30 Wednesday (Online) and by
appointment
• Teaching Assistant: Ellen Tai and Xiaoting Mai
- Office hour: By email appointment
- Tutorial: TBA
• Exams and assignments
- 2-3 Assignments: 20%
- Mid-term: 20% (Sept 17)
- Final: 60%
• Course Website:
- Moodle course title: ECON6022 Macroeconomic Analysis
ECON6022_1AB_2021
2 / 96
Prerequisites and Textbooks
Prerequisites
• Be comfortable with basic calculus and optimization
• Intro Macro
Textbooks
• Macroeconomics: Modern Approach (Robert Barro)
Readings
• Extra book chapters/notes
• Articles from magazines, newspapers or blog entries
3 / 96
Topics and Methodology
Topics
• Economic growth
• Business cycles
• Money and prices
• Macroeconomic policies
Methodology
• Inter-temporal approach
• Dynamic models
• Overview of modern macroeconomics
4 / 96
Preliminary Schedule
• Introduction and Growth Facts
• Economic Growth: Solow Model
• Consumption and Saving
• Business Cycles I: Facts
• Business Cycles II: A Framework
• Mid-Term Exam (Sept 17)
• Business Cycles III: Extensions
• Money and Prices I: Demand and Inflation
• Money and prices II: Non-Neutrality
• Money Supply and non-conventional policy
5 / 96
Applications
• QE in the U.S.;
6 / 96
Growth Facts
7 / 96
8 / 96
Measure income growth rates:
• We now consider in more detail how to measure
differences in the rate of income growth among countries.
• An (annual) growth rate of a variable X is defined as the
change of X from the first to the second year divided by
the value of X in the first year:
Xt+1 − Xt
g=
Xt
• The equation for the annual growth rate can also be
rewritten as follows:
Xt+1 = Xt × (1 + g)
• For two years we then have:
Xt+2 = Xt+1 × (1 + g)
= Xt × (1 + g) × (1 + g)
= Xt × (1 + g)2
9 / 96
• More generally, for n years:
Xt+n = Xt × (1 + g)n
10 / 96
Growth rates and changes in GDP over long periods:
• Even seemingly small differences in annual growth rates,
when sustained over long periods can give rise to
substantial changes in GDP levels.
• For instance, in 1950
GDPCH GDPCH
= 1.34, = 1.45
GDPUK GDPNOR
• The average annual growth rates 1950-2004 have been,
respectively,
• As a result, in 2004
GDPCH GDPCH
= 1.09, = 0.84
GDPUK GDPNOR
11 / 96
Growth before 1820:
12 / 96
GDP per Capita by Country Group, 1820-1998
13 / 96
Growth since 1820:
14 / 96
Stylized fact 1: large differences in living standards
15 / 96
Stylized fact 2: very different growth experiences
16 / 96
Table 6.1 Economic Growth in Eight Major Countries,
1870-2006
17 / 96
Two basic questions about growth
18 / 96
Kaldor’s Facts: Industrialized Countries
19 / 96
Recap - Stylized facts:
20 / 96
Overview of Growth Theories
21 / 96
Plan
• Physical capital
• Production function
• Solow model
- Dynamics: model mechanisms
- Reality checks: taking the model to data
- Extensions
• Growth accounting
22 / 96
Physical Capital
23 / 96
24 / 96
Five features of capital:
1. It is productive: it raises the amount of output that a
worker can produce.
2. It is produced: Capital has itself been produced through
the process of investment (private or public). Investment
corresponds to saving, which means that the resources
used to produce capital could have been consumed
instead. They are invested today to yield a higher
consumption tomorrow.
3. It is rival in its use: only a limited number of people can
use a given piece of capital at one time (different from
ideas which can be used by an infinite number of people at
the same time).
4. It yields a return: Since it makes a worker more productive,
the worker or its firm will be willing to pay to use it.
5. It wears out: Using capital causes it to wear down a little,
which is called depreciation.
25 / 96
The Production Function
Y = AF (K , N)
26 / 96
Assumption 1: constant returns to scale.
• If we multiply the quantities of each input by some factor,
the quantity of output will increase by the same factor:
F (zK , zN) = zF (K , N)
• Can be transformed into a relationship between output per
worker and capital per worker:
1 1 K N K
Y = AF (K , N) = AF , = AF ,1
N N N N N
K Y
...or defining k = N and y = N,
rewrite
1 K
Y = AF ,1
N N
as
y = AF (k , 1) = Af (k )
• Output per worker is a function only of capital per worker.
27 / 96
Assumption 2: diminishing marginal product
∂F (K , N) ∂F (K /N, 1) df (k )
MPK = = =
∂K ∂K /N dk
• Diminishing MP of capital: if we keep adding units of
capital, then the quantity of new output added by each new
unit of input is smaller than that added by previous units of
input.
28 / 96
29 / 96
Assumption 3: Competitive economy.
Factors of production (labor, capital) are paid their marginal
products.
• The value of the MP of a worker is the maximum the firm is
willing to pay each worker.
• In a competitive environment, firms cannot pay wages
below the value of the MP of labor.
• Similarly, the MPK equals to the equilibrium “rental rate” of
capital, that is the cost of renting one unit of capital for one
unit of time.
∂Y
w = MPN =
∂N
∂Y
R = MPK =
∂K
30 / 96
Cobb-Douglas Production Function
• The most common functional form is the Cobb-Douglas:
F (K , N) = K α N 1−α
• α (which is assumed to lie between 0 and 1) denotes the
elasticity of output per worker to capital per worker.
• Note that
ln(Y ) = ln A + α ln(K ) + (1 − α) ln(N)
and
ln(Y /N) = ln(Y ) − ln(N) ≡ ln (y )
ln(K /N) = ln(K ) − ln(N) ≡ ln (k )
thus
ln (y ) = ln (A) + α ln (k )
• Therefore
∂ ln y ∂y k
α= =
∂ ln k ∂k y
31 / 96
• α denotes then how much percent y increases when k is
increased by 1%.
• α can be estimated from the data (under the maintained
hypothesis of a Cobb-Douglas functional form).
• Left to you as an exercise (good exam question): show that
the Cobb-Douglas production function above indeed
features constant returns to scale.
• Express it in per-worker terms:
α 1−α
Y F (K , N) K N K N
y= =A = AF , =A = Ak α
N N N N N N
32 / 96
• Under Cobb-Douglas:
∂Y
MPK = = αAK α−1 N 1−α
∂K
• Note that the MPK is indeed diminishing:
∂MPK ∂2Y
= = (α − 1)αAK α−2 N 1−α < 0
∂K ∂K 2
33 / 96
Income shares of capital and labor:
• The total amount paid out to capital will equal the rental
rate per unit of capital times the total amount of capital:
R × K.
• The capital’s share of income is the fraction of total income
that is paid out as rent of capital:
w ×N (1 − α) AK α N 1−α
Labor’s share of income ≡ = = 1−α
Y AK α N 1−α
34 / 96
Cobb-Douglas property: Constant income shares.
35 / 96
36 / 96
Empirical facts about the capital share of income:
37 / 96
The Solow model:
38 / 96
Solow model
• Assumptions that help to simplify our discussion.
- Economy is closed and G = 0.
Yt = Ct + It . (6.4)
∆Kt = Kt+1 − Kt = It − Dt = St − d · Kt
∆Kt = s · Yt − d · Kt
39 / 96
Solow model
• But we care more about the capital stock per worker and
income per worker. Income per worker is a measure of
standards of living.
• We want to rewrite everything in per-worker terms: for
example, yt = Yt /Nt ; ct = Ct /Nt ; kt = Kt /Nt
• kt is also called the capital-labor ratio
• This transformation needs some math manipulation.
40 / 96
Transformation
∆Kt 1 Kt
= · s · A · Ktα · Nt1−α − d ·
Nt Nt Nt
• Using the def. of capital-labor ratio,
∆Kt
= s · A · ktα − d · kt
Nt
Kt
• Note that ∆kt = ∆( N ∆Kt
t
) 6= Nt , instead, we know,
41 / 96
Transformation
• Rearrange this equation, we have
∆Kt ∆Nt
∆kt = · kt − · kt
Kt Nt
• Using the def. of population growth rate and capital-labor
ratio,
∆Kt Kt
∆kt = · − n · kt
Kt Nt
• Now we find out that ∆Kt
Nt ,
∆Kt
= ∆kt + n · kt
Nt
• Therefore,
∆kt + n · kt = s · A · ktα − d · kt
42 / 96
Solow model
• Finally, we arrive at
∆kt = s · A · ktα − (n + d) · kt
43 / 96
Dynamics
44 / 96
Figure 6.5 Determining the capital-labor ratio in the steady
state
45 / 96
Solve for the steady state
• k ∗ is the steady state capital, such that ∆k ∗ = 0.
• Set ∆k ∗ = 0,
s · A · (k ∗ )α = (d + n) · k ∗
1
∗ s·A 1−α
k =( )
d +n
• Similarly, the steady state income
1 α
∗ ∗ α s
y = A · (k ) = A 1 − α · ( )1 − α
d +n
• High saving rate, s, leads to high k ∗ and y ∗ .
46 / 96
Converging to the steady state
47 / 96
Converging to the steady state
48 / 96
Consumption at the Steady State (Tutorial)
• Consumption at the steady state is the difference between
output and investment at the steady state.
• Note that we are talking about consumption at the
steady state
• Trade-off:
- The higher k ∗ , the higher output, f (k ∗ )
- The higher k ∗ , the higher investment needed to keep k ∗
from falling
- c ∗ = (1 − s) · A · f (k ∗ )
- k ∗ is affected by saving rate, s, given A, n and d.
• Increasing k ∗ will increase c ∗ up to a point
- This is kG in the figure, the Golden Rule capital-labor ratio
- For k ∗ beyond this point, c ∗ will decline
- But we assume henceforth that k ∗ is less than kG , so c ∗
always rises as k ∗ rises.
- Why is it a reasonable assumption?
49 / 96
The relationship of consumption per worker to the capital-labor
ratio in the steady state
50 / 96
Data I: Explain income differences
51 / 96
• Consider two countries, which we denote by i and j.
α/(1−α)
si
yiss = A1/(1−α)
n+d
α/(1−α)
sj
yjss = A1/(1−α)
n+d
• Dividing the first equation by the second yields the ratio of
income per worker in Country i to income per worker in
Country j.
α/(1−α)
yiss si
=
yjss sj
52 / 96
• For example, suppose that Country i has an investment
rate of 20% and Country j has an investment rate of 5%.
53 / 96
• It smells bad! Example:
ss 1
yU.S.
sU.S. 2
ss =
ypoor spoor
ss
yU.S.
• ss = 32 and sU.S. ≈ 25% and implies ...
ypoor
• spoor ≈ 25%/322 ≈ 0.02%, if we assume the Solow model
could explain away all the income differences.
54 / 96
55 / 96
Theory under-predicts actual differences:
56 / 96
Why are the predictions imperfect?
• Possible reasons:
1. Other important factors are left out (e.g., human capital,
technology).
2. Countries might not be in their steady state as assumed by
the model. Reasons:
2.1 shocks (e.g., wars),
2.2 changes in investment behavior over time.
• Capital accumulation accounts for only a small
fraction of cross-country income gaps.
57 / 96
Data II: Explain differences among growth rates
58 / 96
Evidence: OECD
• Absolute convergence:
• “Poor countries grow faster?”
• It seems not true.
• Actually, it is NOT what the Solow model says.
• evidence: no absolute convergence.
• Conditional convergence:
• grow faster, when it is further away from its own steady
state.
• different steady states, hold fixed country characteristics,
e.g. saving rate, technology level etc.
• evidence: some conditional convergence.
61 / 96
The Solow model and Kaldor’s Facts (Tutorial)
MPK · K 1
=α=
Y 3
• Capital-output ratio,
k∗ s
∗
= ≈3
y n+d
• Return to capital,
α
R = r + d = MPK = ≈ 11%
k∗
( ∗)
y
• Long run growth
62 / 96
Exogenous TFP Growth (Tutorial)
63 / 96
Exogenous TFP Growth (Tutorial)
64 / 96
Sources of Growth
65 / 96
Growth Accounting
66 / 96
Hong Kong’s takeoff
67 / 96
Understanding China’s Growth
(Zhu, 2012)
68 / 96
Understanding China’s Growth
69 / 96
Investment-driven growth in China?
70 / 96
Understanding China’s Growth (Zhu, 2012)
Y = AK α (hL)(1−α)
Rearranging it leads to:
Y L K (α/(1−α)) (1/(1−α))
= ( ) hA
Pop Pop Y
Further,
71 / 96
72 / 96
Trade-driven growth in China?
73 / 96
Trade-driven growth in China?
74 / 96
Spatial distribution of income
75 / 96
Spatial distribution of income
76 / 96
Immigration and interregional trade
77 / 96
Migration
78 / 96
Inter-regional trade
79 / 96
Inter-regional trade
80 / 96
Quantify trade and immigration barriers
81 / 96
Quantify trade and immigration barriers
82 / 96
Quantify trade barriers
83 / 96
Potential benefits of continuing reform
84 / 96
Growing like China (1992-2007)
85 / 96
Return to capital
86 / 96
Private employment
87 / 96
Foreign reserves
88 / 96
Why is it a puzzle?
89 / 96
Distortions in capital market
90 / 96
Distortions in capital market
91 / 96
Understanding the puzzle
92 / 96
The 4-trillion stimulus plan (2008-2019)
93 / 96
The stimulus plan
94 / 96
The stimulus plan
95 / 96
96 / 96