Political Parties and The Crisis of Democracy
Political Parties and The Crisis of Democracy
This is an open access publication, available online and distributed under the terms of a
Creative Commons Attribution – Non Commercial – No Derivatives 4.0
International licence (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), a copy of which is available at
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.
Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of this licence
should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the address above
Published in the United States of America by Oxford University Press
198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016, United States of America
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Control Number: 2023951783
ISBN 9780198888734
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.001.0001
Printed and bound in the UK by
Clays Ltd, Elcograf S.p.A.
Links to third party websites are provided by Oxford in good faith and
for information only. Oxford disclaims any responsibility for the materials
contained in any third party website referenced in this work.
Contents
Index 592
List of Figures
14.1 Evolution of seat shares in the Mexican Chamber of Deputies by party 291
14.2 Evolution of the effective number of electoral parties and the effective
number of legislative parties 292
16.1 Evolution of the number of parties, effective number of parliamentary
parties (ENPP), and party switching in the Chamber of Deputies 335
16.2 Sources of financing of Brazilian political parties (%), 2007–2021 338
16.3 Party preference and membership as a proportion of the electorate (M/E) 339
17.1 Presidential elections 362
19.1 The history of the two main political parties in Korea 407
Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Introduction. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas
Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0001
2 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
all, however, they are part of the solution, because modern democracy cannot
function without political parties (Dalton and Wattenberg 2000).
Yet, as the late Peter Mair (2013) famously put it, they are in danger of
‘ruling the void’, being relegated to a largely ceremonial role in democracy. Are
they really becoming the ‘dignified part of the constitution’ without having a
real say over how political decisions are made (Mair 2013: 18)? Are modern
democracies drifting towards a technocratic mode of governance (Caramani
2017) where (supranational) elites are those who really control the course of
events? From this point of view, the (re)emergence of populist parties and
We ask why parties fail today, why new parties emerge and displace old
parties, and also what parties need to do in order to survive cutthroat com-
petition, above all with new (and sometimes not so new) variants of populist
parties (Mudde 2004; Mudde and Kaltwasser 2012). Current developments
must therefore also be understood as a challenge to party research. If it is true
that the parties play a decisive role in the development, consolidation, and
stabilization of democratic systems, then the question is what specific organi-
zational, strategic, and programmatic characteristics of parties are conducive
to the protection of the democratic order. This question applies to the parties
Research Questions
Each country chapter will address the most topical issues regarding the role
of parties for the functioning of the democratic order in the context of the
current crisis of democracy. The chapters begin with general information
about the country and its party system, including relevant framework con-
ditions such as party legislation concerning party organization and internal
party democracy, party finance, and electoral system. Furthermore, relevant
developments with respect to electoral volatility, party system fragmentation,
party membership, and other aspects affecting the structure of parties and
the party system are covered. In order to ensure maximum comparability,
all country chapters follow a common set of questions; in addition, many
authors are also members of the Political Party Database Project (PPDB)
coordinated by Susan Scarrow, Paul Webb, and Thomas Poguntke and can
therefore draw on the same data source. The volume begins with a conceptual
discussion of the study of political parties, which is followed by 23 country
chapters. It concludes with a review of the experiences of international party
assistance and a short comparative reflection.
4 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
The chapters conclude with a discussion of the reasons for the rise and
decline of individual parties and, above all, with an evaluation of the role
of political parties for the future development of democracy. Will the par-
ties be able to defend the democratic system in the future? What are the
most promising—or successful—responses of political parties to challenges
to democracy? What pressure can be expected on the political system?
As always, publications such as this have a long history. This book started as
a conference in Madrid in October 2021, which was generously supported by
the Konrad Adenauer Foundation. We also gratefully acknowledge the finan-
cial support of the Konrad Adenauer Foundation to make the open access
publication of this volume possible. Last but not least, we are indebted to
Julian Bogenrieder, Nico Bodden, Pauline Marquardt, and Benjamin Hoss
Introduction 5
at the Düsseldorf Party Research Institute (PRUF) for their help in getting
the manuscripts into shape.
The Madrid meeting was one of the first face-to-face events after the
COVID-19 pandemic, and even then some contributors could not be present
due to travel restrictions. These extraordinary circumstances remind us of
the importance of a functioning democracy—of which political parties are
an essential element—to cope with crises. Unlike some suspected at the
beginning of the pandemic, China did not set the standards.
References
Caramani, Daniele. 2017. ‘Will vs. Reason: The Populist and Technocratic Forms
of Political Representation and Their Critique to Party Government’. American
Political Science Review, 111:54–67.
Dalton, Russell J. and Martin P. Wattenberg (eds). 2000. Parties without Partisans.
Political Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Diamond, Larry. 2008. ‘The Democratic Rollback. The Resurgence of the Predatory
State’. Foreign Affairs, 87(2):36–48.
Diamond, Larry. 2015. ‘Facing Up to the Democratic Recession’. Journal of Democ-
racy, 26(1):141–155.
Diamond, Larry. 2019. Ill Winds: Saving Democracy from Russian Rage, Chinese
Ambition, and American Complacency. New York: Penguin Press.
Economic Intelligence Unit (EIU). 2022. Democracy Index 2021: The China Chal-
lenge. https://www.eiu.com/n/campaigns/democracy-index-2021/ (Accessed 6
December 2023).
International IDEA. 2019. The Global State of Democracy 2019: Addressing the Ills,
Reviving the Promise. Stockholm: IDEA.
International IDEA. 2021. The Global State of Democracy Report 2021: Building
Resilience in a Pandemic Era. Stockholm: IDEA.
Katz, Richard S. and Robin Kolodny. 1994. ‘Party Organization as an Empty Vessel:
Parties in American Politics’. In: Richard S. Katz and Peter Mair (eds), How Parties
Organize: Change and Adaptation in Party Organizations in Western Democracies.
London/Thousand Oaks/New Delhi: Sage, 23–50.
6 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Levitzky, Steven and Daniel Ziblatt. 2018. How Democracies Die: What History
Reveals About Our Future. New York: Penguin Press.
Mair, Peter. 2013. Ruling the Void: The Hollowing of Western Democracy. London:
Verso.
Mudde, Cas. 2004. ‘The Populist Zeitgeist’. Government and Opposition, 39:
541–563.
Mudde, Cas and Cristóbal Rovira Kaltwasser (eds). 2012. Populism in Europe and the
Americas: Threat or Corrective for Democracy? Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Introduction
No one doubts that political parties play a central role in democratic gover-
nance around the globe.1 However, many doubt that they are doing it well.
The writings on the wall are manifold: the decline of former core parties, the
fragmentation of party systems, the rise of populist challenger parties, the rise
of populist leaders within established parties—the list could easily be contin-
ued. Not all failures are of the parties’ own making. While they may be able to
perform better on some accounts, they could also be victims of wider societal
trends over which they have little control.
This volume, taking a global view, takes stock of where the causes of party
failure may lie and where parties could do better—or simply do something
different. It also looks for evidence of some ‘better practices’, areas in which
some parties seem to be doing comparatively well. To this end, this chapter
presents an inventory of perspectives and questions that serve as guidance for
the country chapters. Given that the volume covers parties and party systems
across very diverse regions and political systems, the editors have chosen not
to propose a rigid framework of analysis; instead, they present an inventory
of theoretical and empirical questions that are addressed by the authors in the
light of their specific conditions of the country which they study (see intro-
duction). This chapter groups these questions into several thematic blocs. In
particular, we suggest that parties should be analysed as products of their
(changing) environment, as professionalized organizations, as actors that
create and maintain organized linkages to other collective actors, as recip-
ients of public funding, as legislators who may act more or less cohesively
Thomas Poguntke, Susan E. Scarrow, and Paul D. Webb, Analysing Political Parties and Democracy. In: Political Parties and
the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Thomas Poguntke,
Susan E. Scarrow, and Paul D. Webb (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0002
8 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Parties as Organizations
As cleavages based on class and religion began to weaken from the 1960s
onwards (in Europe, at least), Otto Kirchheimer (1966) identified the catch-
all party as the new modal party type. Characterized by weaker but more
diverse ties to society, the catch-all party was mainly an elite-dominated cam-
paign organization that de-emphasized the group linkage function and the
role of party members. Party competition was less about how to change the
system than about who would run it better. In light of this, elections became
more competitive to the extent that they were less about parties mobiliz-
ing their own camps of core identifiers and more about persuading more
However, whatever the explanations for why these new rules have been
adopted, in practice when these rules are used, they do not necessarily serve
to consolidate the power of existing leaders. For instance, analysis of recent
leadership contests in European parliamentary democracies reveals that they
tend to be more genuinely competitive where they are decided by member-
ship ballots than by other means, such as votes by party congress delegates
(Scarrow et al 2022). Nor does it seem likely that most parties have been able
to respond to membership decline exclusively by substituting professional
staffing for ‘footsoldiers’ on the ground, not least because few parties have
14 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
predictions of the cartel party model, namely, that parties will increase their
reliance on public funding as a way of compensating for decreased revenue
from party members (Katz and Mair 1995). Yet while there has been policy
contagion or convergence in regard to the acceptance and introduction of
public funding for political parties, this is not to say that public funding plays
the same role in all political systems. In fact, countries differ widely in the
per capita amounts they allocate for such funding and in how they distribute
these funds. They also differ widely in the extent to which the introduction
and expansion of public funding has been accompanied by limits or bans on
How much do the funding rules favour large parties? One important dis-
tinction between systems of public funding is the extent to which funds are
available to small parties, including ones that do not win seats in the national
legislature. Rules for distributing public subsidies can discriminate against
smaller parties by excluding parties that do not win legislative seats. Rules
on donation limits can discriminate against small parties by setting no lim-
its, or high limits, on campaign donations, thus favouring established parties
which have had more opportunities to connect with (and do favours for)
potential donors. In their cartel party article, Katz and Mair (1995) suggested
that established parties would use systems of public funding for their own
benefit and would therefore seek to exclude new entrants to the party. If suc-
cessful, this would then increase party system stability and potentially limit
the range of party competitors. Others predicted that the spread of public
funding for parties could have the opposite effect, encouraging new party
entrants (Mendilow 1992). Perhaps not surprisingly, research in this area has
found some support for both assertions, suggesting that the effects are more
nuanced than merely the presence or absence of public funding. According to
some research, public funding is indeed associated with greater party system
stability (Booth and Robbins 2010). It may nevertheless support and sustain
a greater number of small parties (Pierre et al. 2000; Scarrow 2006; Rashkova
and Su 2020), but it is not necessarily associated with new party survival
Analysing Political Parties and Democracy 17
(Bolleyer and Bytzek 2013). Other research suggests that it is the combina-
tion of subsidies and restrictions that matter, with combinations favourable
to new parties associated with more parties than would be expected purely on
the basis of social structures and electoral systems (Potter and Tavits 2015).
Whereas some research has found that far-right parties have a disproportion-
ately high reliance on public funds (Biezen and Kopecký 2017: 96), research
on European party systems has found that access to public funding exerts a
moderating influence on the small and new parties that compete in elections
(Casal Bertoa and Rama 2022).
Parties as Legislators
Anyone who knows anything about intra-party politics would recognize the
truth in Giovanni Sartori’s claim that, ‘as with icebergs, it is only a small part
of politics that rests above the water-line’ (1976: 106). Students of party pol-
itics have long been fascinated by the periodic (and in some cases seemingly
endemic) bouts of internal conflict and factional infighting that afflict parties.
Intra-party politics can be as important as inter-party competition for public
policy outcomes; a party which cannot deliver on promises made to voters
because it lacks legislative cohesion will be ineffectual and will likely lose the
confidence of those who gave it their support via the ballot box.
In general, legislative parties tend to be more cohesive in parliamentary
systems than in presidential regimes (Sieberer 2006; Carey 2007). This is
because legislative defeats in parliamentary systems often lead to loss of
office (via parliamentary votes of no confidence or dissolution of parlia-
ment and early elections), but this is rarely true in presidential regimes with
separation of powers. Under presidentialism, the head of both the execu-
tive and state generally has his or her own direct mandate from the people
and cannot (except in extraordinary circumstances) be removed by a sep-
arately elected legislature (Poguntke and Webb 2005: ch. 1). Even so, it is
certainly not the case that legislative parties in parliamentary democracies
Analysing Political Parties and Democracy 19
are completely unified. Even in the UK system, renowned for its party dis-
cipline, MPs have always had the capacity to exert pressure on their leaders
by threatening or enacting rebellion against the party line. Moreover, their
willingness to do so has been increasingly apparent since the 1960s (Cowley
2005)—never more so than in the tortuous passage of Brexit-related legisla-
tion in the late 2010s (Webb and Bale 2021: ch. 7). As Anthony King once
pointed out, whereas a government can usually withstand the attacks of the
opposition, it ‘cannot always shrug off attacks from its own backbenchers’
(1976: 214).
they are associated. These predictions fit what Anstead and Chadwick (2009)
labelled the ‘normalization’ scenario.
Others, whom Anstead and Chadwick (2009) label the ‘optimists’, have
seen these new technologies as having much more potential to disrupt tra-
ditional patterns of political organizing. Such disruption could take multiple
forms. For instance, because the new technologies make it easier and cheaper
to disseminate political messages, they decrease the entry costs for new
parties and make it easier for small parties to maintain their positions by
implementing communications strategies that do not rely on traditional
Conclusion
This chapter has sketched out the arguably most important aspects of politi-
cal parties’ characteristics and functions that are relevant for their success or
failure in facilitating democratic governance. Yet we have been largely silent
about what exactly we mean by these terms. At the level of party systems, the
most important sign of success surely is the peaceful alternation of govern-
ment, which is an essential and powerful mechanism for the legitimation of
democracy. For any individual party, the terms encompass the basic metrics
Analysing Political Parties and Democracy 23
of electoral performance or longevity, but for the set of parties within a single
country, the standards are probably somewhat different. For instance, while
it is commonplace to regard the rise of extreme challenger parties as indica-
tion of party failure in established democracies, party systems that entirely
block the rise of new parties are sometimes described as ‘cartelized’, or as
lacking in democratic responsiveness. In other words, the success or failure
of party democracy is not the same as the longevity or continued dominance
of a particular set of party options. Moreover, party success and failure is cer-
tainly context-bound—and the standards of judgement vary with the context.
Notes
1. The authors share equal responsibility for this chapter.
2. https://www.idea.int/data-tools/data/political-finance-database (Accessed on 25 Septe–
mber 2023).
References
Allern, Elin Haugsgjerd and Tim Bale (eds). 2017. Left-of-centre Parties and Trade
Duverger, Maurice. 1954. Political Parties: Their Organisation and Activity in the
Modern State. London: Methuen.
Elischer, Sebastian. 2013. Political Parties in Africa: Ethnicity and Party Formation.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fink, Alexander. 2017. ‘Donations to Political Parties: Investing Corporations and
Consuming Individuals?’. Kyklos, 70:220–255.
Franklin, Mark. 1992. ‘The Decline of Cleavage Politics’. In Mark Franklin, Thomas
T. Mackie and Henry Valen (eds), Electoral Change. Responses to Evolving Social
and Attitudinal Structures in Western Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
Hopkin, Jonathan and Caterina Paolucci. 1999. ‘The Business Firm Model of Party
Organisation: Cases from Spain and Italy’. European Journal of Political Research,
35(3):307–339.
Hutter, Sven and Hans-Peter Kriesi (eds). 2019. European Party Politics in Times of
Crisis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ichino, Nahomi and Noah L. Nathan. (2022). ‘Democratizing the Party: The Effects
of Primary Election Reforms in Ghana’. British Journal of Political Science, 52(3):
1168–1185.
Inglehart, Ronald. 1990. Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Society. Princeton, NJ:
Poguntke, Thomas and Susan E. Scarrow. 2020 ‘Intra-party Democracy and Rep-
resentation: Necessity, Complement, or Challenge?’ In: Robert Rohrschneider
and Jacques Thomassen (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Political Representation
in Liberal Democracies. Oxford, Oxford University Press, 323–339.
Poguntke, Thomas, Susan E. Scarrow, Paul D. Webb et al. 2016. ‘Party Rules, Party
Resources and the Politics of Parliamentary Democracies: How Parties Organize
in the 21st Century’. Party Politics, 22(6):661–678.
Poguntke, Thomas and Johannes Schmitt. 2018. ‘The Crisis, Party System Change,
and the Growth of Populism’. In Brigid Laffan and Lorenzo Cicchi (eds), 2017:
Spierings, Niels and Kristof Jacobs. 2019. ‘Political Parties and Social Media Cam-
paigning’. Acta Politica, 54:145–173.
Stolle, Dietlind and Marc Hooghe. 2011. ‘Shifting Inequalities: Patterns of Exclusion
and Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political Participation’. European Societies,
13(1):119–142.
Vaccari, Cristian and Augusto Valeriani. 2016. ‘Party Campaigners or Citizen Cam-
paigners? How Social Media Deepen and Broaden Party-related Engagement’. The
International Journal of Press/Politics, 21:294–312.
Ward, Stephen and Rachel Gibson. 2009. ‘European Political Organizations and
The United Kingdom (UK) party system is ‘one of the oldest, strongest, and
most stable of the party systems in Europe’ (Mair 2009: 283). Simplifying
only a little, it comprises two major parties—Conservative and Labour—that
dominate both government and the House of Commons. These parties have
collectively shaped the agenda, generated most of the ‘big ideas’, and made the
UK what it is today. The performance of British democracy depends almost
entirely on these two parties (Bartle et al. 2019, Clark 2018, McGann et al.
2023).
The current UK party system has moulded British politics for 100 years.
For much of the last 50 years, commentators have speculated whether that
mould might break (Webb and Bale 2021). Such speculation has sometimes
been based on incontrovertible evidence that the public are discontented
with the parties and the choices they provide. At other times it has been based
on little more than the ‘unnatural’ longevity of the system. It often seems that
the system does not adequately reflect contemporary political conflicts. Nev-
ertheless, the two parties have staggered on, fitfully adapting to preserve both
themselves and the system.
John Bartle, Nicholas Allen, and Thomas Quinn, The United Kingdom Party System. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of
Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © John Bartle, Nicholas Allen, and
Thomas Quinn (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0003
34 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
5,000 1951–64
4,000 1931–40 2010–19
3,000
1918–24 1924–29
2,000 1970–74
1,000
0
–1,000 1924
1929–31
–2,000
1945–51 1964–70 1974–79
–3,000
–4,000
–5,000 1997–2010
85
80
75
70
65
60
55
19 3
24
29
31
35
45
50
51
55
59
19 4
66
19 70
O
79
83
92
97
01
10
19
05
15
17
19 4 F
87
1
6
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
74
20
20
20
19
7
Figure 3.2 Conservative and Labour joint seat and vote share, 1918–2019
Source: Authorsʼ calculations based on Pilling and Cracknell 2021
two parties. From 1931 to 1970 the difference between the two parties’ seat
and vote shares averaged just 6 points. From 1974 to 2015, it averaged 18
points.
To make comparisons with other multi-party systems, it is useful to exam-
ine standardized indicators. Figure 3.3 displays the effective number of elec-
toral parties (ENEP) and effective number of parliamentary parties (ENPP)
from 1945 to 2019. The two-party dominance is illustrated by the almost flat
line for the ENPP, which varies between 2 and 2.5. The increased willing-
ness of voters to support parties other than the two parties of government is
illustrated by the increase in the ENEP from around 2 in the 1950s to 3.9 in
2015. The gap between the two indices increased from roughly 0 in the 1950s
to around 1 by 2010. It then peaked at 1.35 in 2015. The gap closed in 2017
as both major parties made gains but re-opened as Labour lost votes in 2019.
Figures 3.2 and 3.3 both illustrate that the electorate has become more willing
to vote for parties that had little prospect of either forming or participating
in the government.
Although the two parties disliked coalitions with other parties, electoral
competition compelled them to become broad coalitions themselves (King
2009). These coalitions were so broad that it should have been possible to
form a party made of the left wing of the Conservative party and right wing
of the Labour Party or have some degree of cooperation ‘across the aisle’, as
Americans say. National governments of the sort seen on continental Europe
were never needed, but even when they were possible, they were never seri-
ously considered. While the parties often struggled to agree on policy, the one
thing that both parties agreed on was that the ‘other’ party was ‘beyond the
pale’.
36 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
4.50
4.00
3.50
3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
0.50
0.00
45
50
51
55
59
64
66
70
74
74
79
83
87
92
97
01
05
10
15
17
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
ENEP ENPP
Framework Conditions
The ‘closed’ nature of the party system provides the electorate with the same
binary choice at every general election (Mair 2009). This limited choice is a
product of the ‘framework conditions’—constitutional rules or conventions,
and the electoral system. Most studies tend to emphasize the impact of the
electoral system (Duverger 1954). Nevertheless, other constitutional rules
matter a lot. In the UK’s ‘political’ constitution the enforcement of conven-
tions is a matter for politicians drawn from the two major parties, not the
courts (Griffiths 1979). These parties have a common interest in maintain-
ing the conditions that sustain the system (Katz and Mair 1995). This is
most obvious in relation to the electoral system but extends to the broader
constitution.
Constitution
One of the reasons for the longevity of the party system is the importance that
the constitution attaches to ‘strong government’ (King 2009). This is a prod-
uct of parliamentary sovereignty, the rule that Parliament has unlimited legal
The United Kingdom Party System 37
agenda and provide content that satisfies the media’s news values. The major
party domination of the media has changed a little with the rise of social
media, which provide platforms to those beyond the mainstream. Populists
on both the right and the left have used social media to shift the major parties
towards their polar positions. Both the election of Jeremy Corbyn as Labour
leader in 2015 and the victory of the Leave Campaign in the 2016 referendum
on the UK’s membership of the European Union owed much to the activities
of these ‘keyboard warriors’.
Changes in the framework conditions have produced party system change.
Electoral system
The UK’s plurality electoral system for elections to the House of Commons
awards seats based on votes obtained in constituencies. Put simply, the can-
didate with the most votes is elected. If there were just two candidates, the
plurality winner would necessarily gain a majority (50% plus one). If there
are two or more candidates a candidate can win with significantly less than a
majority. This rule affects both voters and parties (Quinn 2017). Voters must
consider both their preferences and the probable election outcome. If they
The United Kingdom Party System 39
vote for a candidate that cannot win, they arguably ‘waste’ their vote. Voters
may vote strategically or tactically for a less preferred party to stop another
less preferred party from winning. Minor parties must consider the likeli-
hood of winning before entering the race. If they nominate a candidate and
fail to obtain 5% of the vote in a seat, they will lose their £500 deposit. And,
if parties from the same side contest a seat, this may split the vote and let
the other side win. This consideration may also dissuade politicians from
breaking with their party (Cox 1997).
The plurality system has different effects on minor parties depending on
of the nation decide that they no longer want to remain in the union, these
considerations become less important. By 2014 many Scots concluded that
they could achieve more by abandoning the pro-Union Labour Party (Johns
2018). This example illustrates how a plurality electoral system can produce
rapid transformation of party systems at the regional level.
UK elections, 1918–2019
Figure 3.4 displays the vote share received by parties from 1918 to 2019.
Over those 101 years the Conservative party averaged 41.8% of the vote and
Labour 37.5%. From 1945 to 2019 the advantage is somewhat smaller (40.9%
to 39.3%) but still visible.
Figure 3.5 displays the seat share won by parties from 1918 to 2019. Over
the whole period Conservatives won an average of 49.9% of seats compared
to Labour’s 40.9%. From 1945 to 2019 the figures are almost exactly equal
(46.8% to 46.6%). Figure 3.4 illustrates the pattern of ‘alternating predom-
inance’ since 1979 (Quinn 2012). The Tories won comfortable majorities
in 1979 and 1992 and massive majorities in 1983 and 1987. Labour won
‘landslide majorities’ in 1997 and 2001 and a large majority in 2005. The
Conservatives have won the four subsequent elections. While the first three
victories were unconvincing, the party’s 56.2% share of the seats in 2019 was
impressive.
Votes for ‘challenger parties’ are the ‘canary in the coalmine’—they indicate
discontent with the two-party system. The vote share of the UK’s traditional
third party, the Liberal Democrats, is displayed in Figure 3.4. In the 1950s
42 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
70.0
60.0
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
19 1
55
59
64
66
74 0
74 )
19 )
79
83
87
92
97
01
20 5
10
15
17
19
(O
19 ( F
5
19 197
0
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
Con Lab Lib Dem SNP/PC Others
its share of the vote share fell to 2% but then trended upwards until 2010.
This rise was driven by social changes, including a larger middle class and
the expansion of higher education (Heath et al. 1989), the periodic tendency
of the major parties to ‘vacate the centre’ (Nagel and Wlezien 2010) and both
parties’ poor performance in office (Bartle et al. 2019). Figure 3.5 shows that
the electoral system failed to reward the Liberal Democrats with seats even
when their vote increased dramatically in February 1974 and 1983. From
1997 onwards, however, it picked up more seats because of tactical voting
by Labour voters in Conservative seats.
By 2010 the Liberal Democrats had gained enough for it to enter a coalition
with the Conservatives and govern in accordance with a coalition agreement
(Quinn et al. 2011). This experiment in coalition politics proved disastrous
for the third party (Curtice 2018). Its share of the vote plummeted from 23%
in 2010 to 7.9% in 2015 (see Figure 3.4). Its share of the seats fell from 8.8% to
1.2% (see Figure 3.5). This reversal of fortunes represented the largest change
in vote share for any party in any general election.
The vote for ‘other’ or ‘minor’ parties has generally been small but tended
upwards since the early 1970s (Figure 3.4). It peaked in 2015 following the
collapse of the Liberal Democrats, a large rise in UKIP vote, a surge in votes
for the SNP, and a smaller rise in the Green Party vote. The rise in support
for UKIP before 2015 was politically consequential because it was one of the
factors that persuaded the Conservative government to hold a referendum
on the UK’s membership of the EU. UKIP claimed that the two major parties
The United Kingdom Party System 43
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
19 5
79
83
87
92
97
01
05
10
15
17
19
7
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
Con Lab Lib Dem SNP/PC Other
agreed about transferring sovereignty to the EU. They argued that switching
from one side to the other would not provide voters with more control over
policy towards the EU. Instead, they argued that the people should be given
a direct say in a referendum. These arguments initially had limited impact
because sovereignty was an abstract issue. They became more impactful after
2010 when sovereignty became bundled with the issue of immigration. UKIP
claimed that the UK could not control immigration while a member of the
single market. This made the invitation to ‘take back control’ much more
appealing and was a major factor in both the growth in UKIP vote in 2015
and the Leave vote in 2016.
The variations in the vote for ‘other’ parties did not generally translate into
seats at Westminster. The only exception was the vote for the SNP since 2015.
Nevertheless, the threat of challenger parties meant that the two major parties
had to factor in these parties to a degree when formulating their electoral
strategies.
The present party system is the third system in the UK. The first, between
1740 and 1840, pitted the Whigs against the Tories. The Whigs opposed
expand the state, while the right wanted to consolidate. In the 1960s Wil-
son emphasized the ‘white heat of technological change’ (Ponting 1989),
which untied the party for a time. Nevertheless, Labour again descended
into factional infighting as the economic crisis of the 1970s unfolded (Jenkins
1988).
From 1945 to 1970 the Labour leadership was protected from the demands
of the left by the trade unions. From the late 1960s, however, the trade unions
swung leftwards in response to the failures of Labour governments. Labour
lurched left in February 1974 and again in 1983, vacating the centre, increas-
2019 coalition quickly eroded. Labour was soundly defeated in 2019, winning
fewer MPs than at any election since 1935. Most strikingly, the Conservatives
outpolled Labour among the working class. Many seats with long Labour tra-
ditions (the so-called ‘red wall’) fell to the Conservatives. While the vote for
‘Remain’ parties exceeded that for ‘Leave’ parties, it was scattered across more
parties (Johns 2021).
After the defeat, Labour elected Starmer as leader. Despite making
promises to retain the left-wing policies of his predecessor, he reined in
the party’s ambitious spending and nationalization plans. He also nodded
personal incentives had been eroded (Bartle et al. 2011). In a two-party sys-
tem the Conservatives were the only other option. The Conservative party’s
continued association with symbols of ‘Britishness’ including the monarchy,
armed forces, and churches consolidated its reputation as the ‘national’ party.
The Conservative party of Churchill and Macmillan in the 1950s prided
itself in its pragmatism (Heywood 2017). Some have claimed that party ideol-
ogy was summarized by a principled commitment to the free market (Willetts
1992). Yet while this is true of Margaret Thatcher, she is the exception to
the rule. The Conservative party has usually simply tried to ‘conserve’. It has
warned his party that ‘banging on about Europe’ was damaging. He appeared
to win the argument. Over time, however, support for withdrawal from the
EU increased, especially among party members.
The Conservative party has traditionally been advantaged in the com-
petitive struggle for the vote by the fact that party members rarely tried to
determine policy or constrain its leaders. Only the leader has authority to
make party policy in consultation with colleagues. The leaders’ duty was
simply to stop Labour from winning. The Conservative party made little pre-
tence to be democratic until the late 1990s. Conservative leaders sometimes
decision to call an election backfired, and the party lost its majority (Bartle
2018).
The May government from 2017 to 2019 became dependent on the small
Democratic Unionist Party from Northern Ireland. For two years May’s
efforts to get a withdrawal agreement were blocked by a combination of
opposition MPs, Remainer Conservatives, and Eurosceptics who demanded
a clean break with the EU (Quinn 2021). Many Brexiteers feared that ‘the
Westminster establishment’ would block withdrawal and joined the new
Brexit party. This party’s success in the European elections of June 2019, like
The Future
If an intelligent designer who was otherwise ignorant about the past were
to design a two-party system to reflect contemporary political conflicts,
Electoral reform would break the mould of the party system, but it is not
on the agenda. Only Parliament can change the electoral system, and both
the parties that dominate at Westminster and are likely to control govern-
ment have resisted reform. The Conservatives are steadfastly opposed. The
Labour leadership has ignored calls from party members for proportional
representation. The party’s experience in Scotland illustrated the dangers
of that system to the party. Labour still jealously guards its monopoly on
anti-Conservative opposition even though its electoral record is poor. And
even if Labour were to contemplate reform, it is less likely to happen than in
60
% preferring
50
40
30
20
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
Notes
1. Figure 3.1 excludes the wartime coalition from 1940 to 1945.
2. The party system in Northern Ireland has always been different from that on the British
mainland.
3. Non-conformists hold Christian beliefs that do not conform to the established Church
of England.
References
Butler, David and Donald Stokes. 1974. Political Change in Britain: The Evolution of
Electoral Preference. London: Macmillan.
Clark, Alistair. 2018. Political Parties in the UK. London: Macmillan.
Clarke, Harold, Paul Whiteley, and Matthew Goodwin. 2017. Brexit: Why
Britain Voted to Leave the European Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Cox, Gary. 1987. The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political
Parties in Victorian England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, Gary. 1997. Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral
Jenkins, Peter. 1988. Mrs Thatcher’s Revolution: The Ending of the Socialist Era.
London: Jonathan Cape.
Johns, Robert. 2018. ‘Squeezing the SNP: The Election in Scotland’. In Nicholas Allen
and John Bartle (eds), None Past the Post: Britain at the Polls 2017. Manchester:
Manchester University Press, 100–120.
Johns, Robert. 2021. ‘Why Did the Conservatives Win?’. In Nicholas Allen and
John Bartle (eds), Breaking the Deadlock: Britain at the Polls 2019. Manchester:
Manchester University Press.
Katz, Richard and Peter Mair. 1995. ‘Changing Models of Party Organization and
Elodie Fabre, French Political Parties and Democracy. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Elodie Fabre (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0004
French Political Parties and Democracy 59
and ideology both influence the type of organization of each party. This
chapter will focus on the following aspects: parties and society, relationship
with the state through party funding, and differences in organization and
organizational change. Overall, we observe a tendency of increased direct
participation of members in some areas of party life and high levels of pub-
lic funding, both symptoms of party cartelization as defined by Katz and
Mair (1995). However, the party system has remained open, and parties have
remained a vital part of French democracy.
The French party system has undergone significant changes in the last few
decades. After the period described as a ‘bipolar four-party system’ composed
of the Gaullist party Rally for the Republic (RPR)2 , the centre-right Union
for French Democracy party (UDF)3 , the PS, and the Communist Party
(Duverger 1973; Cole 2003: 12), new parties emerged in the mid-1980s, most
notably the radical right FN and the Green party Les Verts. The period that
followed saw a regular pattern of alternation between left and right in power,
with smaller parties, except the FN, often aligning behind the RPR/UMP
(Union for a Popular Movement) on the right or the PS on the left (Grun-
berg and Haegel 2008), with the FN as a third electoral force. However, it
is in the centre ground that recent changes have most shaken French poli-
tics. The election of Emmanuel Macron as President of the Republic and the
parliamentary elections that followed have placed both traditional govern-
ing parties in the opposition and significantly reduced their representation
in parliament. This shows that newcomers have overcome obstacles to entry
for new parties (presidential elections, a majoritarian electoral system, and
the party funding regime).
French electoral politics have become increasingly volatile. The semi-
presidential nature of the French regime has always tended to focus party
competition on candidate-centred politics and the main parties that have
a realistic chance of winning the Presidency. Since 2002, four parties have
placed a candidate in the second round of the presidential election, whereas
only two parties had managed that in the previous two decades. Table 4.1
shows that the effective number of presidential candidates (ENEP Pres)
decreased and then increased again after 2007, and the effective numbers
of electoral parties and parliamentary parties increased every year after
the 2002 election. In 2017–2022, these indicators returned to pre-2002
levels.
60 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
values and identity axis of party competition at the expense of the traditional
left–right economic axis (Sauger 2017: 21–22). While this focus on identity
issues was originally initiated by the FN, these issues have become increas-
ingly important for the main centre-right party LR and the PS, as voters found
it increasingly difficult to tell the difference between the economic policies
of the two traditional parties. In parallel, some newer parties have empha-
sized other issues (notably the Greens with the environment), while others
have argued that the traditional left–right cleavage has lost its relevance. The
FN/RN accused the mainstream parties of forming a cartel (‘UMPS’), and
The 1958 Constitution recognizes in its Article 4 the role of parties as orga-
nizations that contribute to the expression of suffrage and allows them to
form and organize freely (Légifrance 2021). Parties are free to organize as
they please, and there are no requirements in terms of intra-party democ-
racy or territorial organization, as exists in other countries. The law started
to regulate some aspects of party life in 1988 with the first law on financial
transparency in public life (Marcilloux-Giummarra 2011: 164). Later, leg-
islation to ensure gender parity, enshrined in the Constitution in 2000 and
in 2008, added to the legislative framework that applies to political parties
(Lépinard 2016).
The PS is the oldest of the four parties. Although it only existed under
this name since 1969; it used to be the Section Française de l’Internationale
Ouvrière (SFIO, French Section of the Workers’ International), founded in
62 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
1905. It is a social democratic party, although it does not use the term
(Deschodt 2007). The party adopted a traditional form of assembly-based
intra-party democracy, and the party in public office has dominated the party
since the 1980s (Bachelot 2007: 151). Local branches send representatives to
a national congress, which debates motions and policy. The party recognizes
tendencies (called ‘currents’), and these factions propose distinct lists and
motions to the conference. If no list receives a majority of the vote, a second
round is organized, and motions may merge to form a winning coalition.
The making of ‘syntheses’ (merger of different motions to form intra-party
farmers, women, workers, and people working in the security forces (Marcus
1995: 47; Mayer 1998: 15–16). Under Marine Le Pen’s leadership, the FN and
then the RN adopted similar strategies to attract new members and potential
candidates from a range of civil society backgrounds (Dezé 2016: 55–56). The
leader selects the members of the executive and represents the party publicly.
The election of 100 delegates to the National Council allows the membership
to express preferences in terms of orientation and shows who is popular in
the party. However, the leader’s ability to choose another 20 members of the
National Council limits the membership’s influence in a body that is mostly
The leaders of LR, the PS, and the FN are all elected by membership bal-
lot, whereas the leader of LaREM is selected by the party Council, which
mixes elected officials and party members. The party leader (first secretary)
of the PS has been elected by membership in a two-round ballot since 1995.
The leadership election used to follow the national congress, so that party
motions were debated first and the leader elected second. Since 2010, the vote
membership ballot ahead of the 2022 elections. In the RN, the congress
selects the candidate, but there has never been a candidate against the party
president, who has always been the party candidate for the presidential elec-
tion. The congress closest to the election is therefore the moment when the
party president is announced as the party’s official candidate. LaREM has yet
to set out how it will select its presidential candidate in the post-Macron era,
an issue they will have to address ahead of the 2027 presidential election.
The selection of presidential candidates has returned to being a purely par-
tisan affair. We have seen a retreat from open primaries, as they had led to
Two major factors contribute to this centralization: electoral pacts and gen-
der parity legislation. As parties build election pacts, they need to be able
to tell local branches that they should not select a candidate and support
another party’s candidate instead. This particularly applies for the PS and LR,
which have had long-standing pacts with smaller parties. This has remained
true in 2017 and 2022, in particular for the PS, which joined the NUPES
(Nouvelle Union Populaire, Ecologique et Sociale, New Ecological and Social
People’s Union) left-wing coalition in 2022. LaREM made some strategic
withdrawals in 2017 and formed a pre-electoral coalition with the MoDem in
taxation for the very rich, was recently seen as a symbol of the shallowness
of politicians’ promises. New parties such as LaREM but also the left-wing
LFI reject the word ‘party’, usually preferring the term ‘movement’; argue
that parties are out-of-date organizations; and prefer ‘more flexible’ forms
of organization in which membership is only a click away and policy debates
are often online.
Party membership data are not always reliable, as parties often exaggerate
the size of their membership base. Party membership was among the lowest
in Europe, at roughly 2% of the electorate in the 2000s (Scarrow and Gezgor
FN/RN LaREM
100% 100%
90% 90%
80% 80%
70% 70%
60% 60%
50% 50%
40% 40%
30% 30%
20% 20%
10% 10%
0% 0%
1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2017 2019 2017 2018 2019
Private ordinary and campaign donations have a rather low cap, making
it hard for parties to find important resources from private sources. As elec-
tion campaigns have become more expensive, parties have tried but often
failed to find additional sources of funding. With low donation caps on cam-
paign donations, many parties and candidates have been found to have been
at the limits of legality over the years, with several condemned for illegal party
funding (like former President Jacques Chirac) or campaign funding (such
as former President Nicolas Sarkozy). Although these examples come from
the main right-wing party, politicians from all parties, including the PS and
Edouard Philippe, who had supported Juppé in the primary, and Gérard
Darmanin, an ambitious conservative deputy who had supported Sarkozy,
became Prime Minister and Minister for the Budget, respectively, in Macron’s
first government.
The FN and then RN were and are traditional radical right organizations
in which the party leader suffers little challenge. However, the late 1990s
saw a brief period of intra-party divisions between the supporters of party
leader Jean-Marie Le Pen and those of Bruno Mégret, who was then Le Pen’s
second-in-command. The division, over the extent to which the party should
Communications
Like all parties, French parties face citizens who are harder to reach and less
deferential to elites. In a context of an increased variety of online sources that
citizens use to find political information and express political views, French
parties have had to engage with the online space.
All four parties naturally have a website. These websites provide informa-
tion about party positions, campaign activities during pre-election periods,
recent events, and discourses from prominent party leaders. These websites
French political parties vary greatly in age and ideological leanings; they also
vary in their organization, although there are some similarities. Party mem-
bers are generally involved in the selection of party leaders and candidates
for the Presidency, and the party leadership is responsible for party pol-
icy and the overall selection of parliamentary candidates. Parties are quite
centralized, but this centralization also goes together with divisions and occa-
sional splits and defections. Like parties elsewhere, French parties have lost
members, and innovations to attract new members and engage members
differently are rare.
The French party system has undergone significant changes, most notably
in the range and strength of relevant parties. These changes, though, do
not necessarily mean that France is facing a decline of parties. The semi-
presidential system allows some personalities to build a large following
outside of parties, but the example of Macron shows that a President elected
without a traditional party to support his candidacy then builds a party to
back his action. French democracy has not become any less centred around
French Political Parties and Democracy 77
Notes
1. This chapter chooses to use the acronym LaREM, which is used by the party itself,
although other acronyms can be found, including LREM (see Perottino and Guasti 2020)
and LRM (see Le Monde 2017 and all Le Monde articles on the subject). The party was
renamed Renaissance in 2022.
2. The RPR is the result of the transformation of the old Gaullist party UDR (Union of
Democrats for the Republic) into a new party by Jacques Chirac in 1976.
78 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
3. The UDF was created in 1978 as an electoral alliance of small non-Gaullist centre-right
parties to support President Valéry Giscard d’Estaing against the hegemony of Gaullism
on the right.
4. Article 49.3 of the Constitution allows the Government to pass legislation if a majority
of deputies reject a motion of no confidence. The motion of no confidence on pension
reform failed by nine votes.
5. There is also a convention, which includes all party members, but no party congress
proper made up mainly by delegates elected by lower-level party bodies.
6. LaREM became Renaissance after the 2022 presidential elections, with new statutes
adopted in September 2022. This chapter does not include details about these changes,
References
Amjahad, Anissa and Clément Jadot. 2012. ‘Le modèle organisationnel du Front
National’. In Pascal Delwit (ed), Le Front national. Mutations de l’extrême droite.
Bruxelles: Editions de l’Université de Bruxelles, 57–76.
Bachelot, Carole. 2007. ‘La culture d’organisation au Parti socialiste: De l’explication
à l’appropriation des normes’. In Florence Haegel (ed), Partis politiques et système
partisan en France. Paris: Presses de Science Po, 145–181.
Cevipof. 2010–2020. ‘Le Baromètre de la confiance politique’. https://www.
sciencespo.fr/cevipof/fr/content/les-resultats-par-vague.html (Accessed 21 July
2021).
Charlot, Jean. 1986. ‘La transformation de l’image des partis politiques français’.
Revue Française de Science Politique, 36(1):5–13.
CNCCFP. n.d. ‘Nos Ressources’, https://www.cnccfp.fr/nos-ressources/?category_
resource=49 (Accessed 13 July 2021).
Clift, Ben and Justin Fisher. 2004. ‘Comparative Party Finance Reform: The Cases of
France and Britain’. Party Politics, 10(6):677–699.
Cole, Alistair. 2003. ‘Stress, Strain and Stability in the French Party System’. In Jocelyn
Evans (ed), The French Party System. Manchester: Manchester University Press,
11–26.
Delaurens, Diane. 2018. ‘En marche, la politique moderne?’. Esprit, 4:11–17.
Deschodt, Jean-Pierre. 2007. ‘Du collectivisme radical à l’exercice du pouvoir. Les
socialistes’. In Guillaume Bernard and Eric Duquesnoy (eds), Les forces politiques
françaises: genèse, environnement, recomposition. Paris: Presses Universitaires de
France, 253–267.
French Political Parties and Democracy 79
Sauger, Nicolas. 2017. ‘Raisons et évolution du rejet des partis’. Pouvoirs, 163:16–26.
Scarrow, Susan E. 2015. Beyond Party Membership: Changing Approaches to Partisan
Mobilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Scarrow, Susan E. and Burcu Gezgor. 2010. ‘Declining Memberships, Chang-
ing Members? European Political Party Members in a New Era’. Party Politics,
16(6):823–843.
Squarcioni, Laure. 2017. ‘Devenir candidat en France: règles et pratiques de sélection
au PS et à l’UMP pour les élections législatives’. Politique et Société, 36(2):13–38.
Svåsand, Lars. 1994. ‘Change and Adaptation in Norwegian Party Organisations’. In
Introduction
Michael Angenendt and Simon D. Brause, The Long Way towards Polarized Pluralism. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of
Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Michael Angenendt and Simon
D. Brause (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0005
The Long Way towards Polarized Pluralism 83
After the first federal election in 1949, 10 parties entered the Bundestag,
covering a broad spectrum from left to right. However, the strong fragmen-
tation decreased noticeably in the three subsequent federal elections. In the
84 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
election to the fourth Bundestag in 1961, three parties still managed to enter
parliament: the Christian Democrats, the Social Democrats, and the Liber-
als. For the next 22 years, they shaped German politics in different coalition
constellations. This period represents the famous 2.5-party system, in which
one of the two catch-all parties—together with the Liberals as ‘kingmaker’—
formed either a centre-left or centre-right cabinet (except for the first grand
coalition from 1966 to 1969) (Niedermayer 2006: 115). After the initial phase
of relatively high fragmentation and the subsequent phase of the stable 2.5-
party system, the spectrum has widened since the 1980s. Figure 5.1 illustrates
5
Effective Number of Parties
0
49
53
57
61
65
19 9
72
76
80
83
87
90
94
98
02
05
09
13
17
21
6
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
the political agenda which led to permanent changes to the party system. Due
to a general increase in prosperity in Western European societies, economic
issues became less relevant, and a new, socio-cultural conflict was gradually
established. This differs from the old class conflict between labour and cap-
ital and shifts public attention to issues such as environmental protection,
emancipation, and the inclusion of social minorities. Various labels in politi-
cal science now address the two opposing poles (e.g. Kriesi et al. 2006; Merkel
2017). Essentially, the contrast refers to green, alternative, and libertarian
values (GAL) on the one hand and traditional, authoritarian, and national
the Social Democrats than for the Christian Democrats, as the former came
under competitive pressure due to the success of the Greens and The Left
party. Thus, the first grand coalition under Chancellor Merkel, from 2005
to 2009, was already the consequence of the declining support of the catch-
all parties, especially the Social Democrats. The effective number of parties
(see Figure 5.1) reflects this development. In 2009, we see almost the same
picture of a fragmented party system as in 1949. The second grand coalition
under Chancellor Merkel, which governed between 2013 and 2017, triggered
a dynamic that accelerated the downward electoral spiral and put the Chris-
Our empirical analysis illustrates the development of the party system and
the resulting challenges for parties and voters based on various established
Volatility
Figure 5.2 shows the changes in aggregate voting behaviour. The high volatil-
ity in the initial phase weakened until the 1980s but has increased since then.
While the increased volatility indicates a dealignment process (Norris 1999),
it is also an indicator of intensified competition for votes, which puts catch-all
parties in particular under competitive pressure. Our data correspond to
40
30
Volatility in %
20
10
0
49
53
57
61
65
69
72
76
80
83
19 7
90
94
98
20 2
05
09
13
17
21
8
0
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
When examining the vote share development6 in West and East Germany,
several significant patterns emerge. First and foremost, it is evident that the
catch-all parties experienced a decline in electoral support in both the federal
and federal state elections across the country. Moreover, while The Left party
and the AfD have particularly strong support in East Germany, the strength
of the Greens is primarily concentrated in West Germany. The notable pres-
ence of the Greens in West Germany and the AfD in East Germany illustrates
the pronounced cultural divide within German party competition that exists
between the East and West.
In terms of voter turnout7 , we observe an initial increase until the mid-
1970s, reaching a peak of approximately 91%, followed by a decline to an
all-time low of 71% in the 2009 federal elections. In eastern Germany, turnout
is lower than in western Germany, reflecting a relatively weak anchoring of
party democracy. Despite starting at lower levels during federal state elec-
tions, a decline in voter turnout from the 1970s until the mid-2000s can be
observed. Since then, voter turnout has been rising in western and eastern
German states. The increase has been particularly noticeable in the east since
2013, indicating an ongoing politicization of citizens due to the emergence of
the AfD, which mobilizes both supporters and opponents to cast their vote
(e.g. Schulte-Cloos and Leininger 2022).
This section addresses the altered party competition. To this end, we inves-
tigate the polarization within the party system and the resulting changed
patterns of coalition formulae.
The Long Way towards Polarized Pluralism 89
Polarization
10
7
Party System Polarization
0
9
3
7
72
83
20 2
21
5
69
80
90
94
98
09
13
17
19 7
05
76
4
5
5
0
6
8
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
19
19
centre parties and strengthened the bilateral opposition on the left (The Left)
and the right (AfD). However, these dynamics exhibit asymmetry as the AfD
achieves greater electoral success compared to The Left, which encountered
challenges in securing parliamentary representation during the 2021 federal
election.
Coalition governments
100
80
60
%
40
0
1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 2010s
This last section analyses the challenges that the transformation of German
politics pose for parties as organizations. The German Party Law governs the
organizational structure of German parties and prescribes several obligatory
components of party organization, e.g. the requirement to be internally
democratic (Poguntke 1994: 189). Hence, party organizations in Germany
are remarkably similar. However, we now see a change in German party orga-
Membership ratios
Table 5.1 displays membership figures at the time of each federal election
from 1965 until 2021. To control the changes in the size of the electorate,
we refer to the ratio of membership figures and the electorate (Katz et al.
1992: 331).
The catch-all parties reach their highest level at the end of the 1970s
(Social Democrats) and the beginning of the 1980s (CDU/CSU). There-
after, they almost continuously lose members. Until the beginning of the
2000s, the Social Democrats could retain more members than the Christian
Democrats. Since then, both parties are at about the same level. The general
pattern is in line with the declining membership figures in other Euro-
pean countries (Biezen and Poguntke 2014). The membership decline also
affects other, previously large mass organizations, such as trade unions and
churches.
For the smaller parties the change does not follow such a uniform pattern.
The membership figures of the Liberals rise until the 1980s, after which they
stabilize at a lower level (apart from a temporary increase due to German
reunification). A slight increase can be seen in 2009 after the Liberals entered
as a junior partner in coalition with the CDU/CSU, also after parliamentary
re-entry in 2017. Nevertheless, the level is clearly below that of the 1970s
and 1980s. The membership of the SED successor party halved after German
reunification. After the fusion with the West German left-wing protest party
WASG, it briefly gained members but overall has remained at the same level
since the beginning of the millennium.
94 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Notes: The figures are calculated as the membership share of the electorate (M/E).
M/E was multiplied by 100 and represents the percentage share of the electorate.
(Source: Niedermayer (2020, 2022).
Although the Greens’ mobilization capacity has been low, they managed to
grow—a rare exception for an established party; since 2016, it has recorded
a noticeable increase compared to the previous three decades. Typically for
a new party, the AfD has been gaining members since its foundation in 2013
but has remained at a rather low level. Looking at the growth of both since the
refugee crisis in 2015–2016, it is apparent that parties on the GAL–TAN axis
fringes are increasing their membership base. The growing mobilization may
indicate a polarizing electorate, as the socio-cultural dimension has recently
structured party competition (Franzmann et al. 2020).
Intra-party democracy
Party funding
The cartel party thesis (Katz and Mair 1995) suggests a closure of party
competition and a withdrawal of parties from civil society. Parties are increas-
ingly losing members and are forced to draw more financial resources from
96 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
(a)
.54
CDU .56
.78
SPD
.85
.81
FDP
.86
.84
Left .85
.84
AfD .85
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
AIPD
2011 2017
(b)
.25
CDU .5
.25
SPD
.5
.25
FDP
.5
.25
Left
.5
.25
Greens
.5
CSU .5
AfD .5
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
PIPD
2011 2017
state sources (Katz and Mair 1995: 16). As a result, parties secure their sur-
vival and simultaneously hinder the emergence of new alternatives. This
can result in a loss of legitimacy and trust and prevent functioning party
competition. Therefore, we turn to party funding in this section. Germany,
in 1959, became the first state in Europe to introduce public party funding
(Koß 2008: 289).
The main funding sources for parties in Germany are donations and fees
through party members, private and corporate donations, and state subsidies.
The German Political Parties Act sets a cap on state funding. Parties earn
CDU 2011
2017
SPD 2011
2017
FDP 2011
2017
Left 2011
2017
Greens 2011
0 20 40 60 80 100
Share of total funding in percent
Party communication
194
AfD 141
560
380
CDU 114
230
231
CSU 57.6
221
415
FDP 146
167
Greens 648
222
232
SPD 428
101
215
Twitter Instagram
Facebook
Facebook, and then Instagram. However, the outreach of the parties dif-
fers considerably between the platforms. While the AfD has by far the most
followers on Facebook, the Greens have the most followers on Twitter. There-
fore, the results support the thesis that the relevance of different social media
platforms varies between parties (Kelm et al. 2023). Moreover, the results
reveal that parties differ in their coverage more generally, i.e. in their capa-
bility to generate followers in the digital sphere. The Greens have by far
the highest range with a total of over one million followers on the social
networks, followed by the AfD with nearly 900,000 followers. The other
four parties all have a similar coverage, with slightly more than 700,000
followers.
Both parties are effectively mobilizing support online, mirroring their
real-world success. This online engagement also indicates that socio-cultural
divisions, characteristic of these parties’ support bases, are present in the
digital sphere. With digital communication becoming an important arena
of political competition, this could potentially amplify polarization. The
phenomenon of media fragmentation should be considered in this context.
The digital divide and the reliance on social networks can contribute to the
100 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
the coalition formation of the unequal alliance of SPD, Greens, and FDP
succeeded quite quickly—it remains to be seen how open to compromise
parties in Germany will be. A serious threat to liberal democracy is the rise
of right-wing populism. In Germany, the AfD has been radicalizing since
its foundation in 2013 and is currently a populist radical right party with
extreme tendencies. However, even if German party competition has become
polarized and pluralized, it would be too far-reaching to speak of a crisis
of democracy, as strong centrifugal dynamics are only apparent in the east-
ern German federal states. Nevertheless, the increasing polarization must be
Notes
1. The chapter was written in equal parts by Michael Angenendt and Simon D. Brause. We
are grateful to Pauline Marquardt, Nico Bodden, and Aaron Schlütter for their help. Fur-
thermore, we would like to thank Simon Franzmann, who provided data on the left–right
positions of parties.
2. The Christian Democratic Union (CDU) and the Christian Social Union (CSU) are two
autonomous parties, whereby the CSU only exists and competes in elections in Bavaria
and the CDU in all other federal states of the country. In the Bundestag, the national
parliament, a joint parliamentary group is always formed. For most analyses, they are
treated as one party.
3. The developments in German local politics are outside the scope of our analysis. For the
role of national parties and independent local parties, see Angenendt (2021, 2023). For
the local party system, see Linhart and Eichhorn (2022), and for party competition, see
Gross and Jankowski (2020).
4. We use the effective number of parties (ENP) based on the vote share as an indicator to
measure party system fragmentation (see Laakso and Taagepera 1979: 4–7).
5. During the 1960s and 1980s other right-wing parties had some electoral successes in
some of the federal states and one of them even entered the European Parliament for one
electoral period in the 1980s, but they never succeeded in winning a seat in the Bundestag.
6. See Schmitt-Beck et al. (2022: 5) for further insightful information on the development
of the vote share over time.
7. These data were obtained from Voter Turnout Database (International IDEA 2022).
8. Relevant parties include those that gained at least one seat in the German Bundestag, the
FDP, and the AfD in 2013, due to their high blackmail potential. The index was weighted
by the vote share of each party.
9. This loosely translates to a ‘moral turning point’.
10. In the 1950s, there were a few coalitions with four or more parties. In order to keep the
presentation clear, these coalitions have been grouped under the coalitions with three
parties. These are the governments Hellwege I (Lower Saxony), Bartram (Schleswig-
Holstein), Müller I, Müller II, Müller III, and Kiesinger I (all Baden-Württemberg).
The Long Way towards Polarized Pluralism 103
11. In Berlin from 2002 until 2011 and in Mecklenburg-Western Pomerania from 1998 until
2006, as part of an SPD-PDS/The Left government.
12. Data are derived from the Political Party Database Project. A detailed conceptualisation,
as well as the index construction, can be found in Berge and Poguntke (2017) and for
round 2 of the IPD in Brause and Poguntke (2021).
13. For the AfD, a comparison between both time points is not possible, as the party was
founded in 2013.
References
Katz, Richard S, Peter Mair, Luciano Bardi et al. 1992. ‘The Membership of Polit-
ical Parties in European Democracies, 1960–1990’. European Journal of Political
Research, 22(3):329–345.
Kelm, Ole, Michael Angenendt, Thomas Poguntke, and Ulrich Rosar. 2023. ‘Which
Candidates Benefit from Social Media? An Analysis of the 2021 German Federal
Election’. Electoral Studies, 86:1–12.
Koß, Michael. 2008. Staatliche Parteienfinanzierung und politischer Wettbewerb.
Wiesbaden: Springer VS.
Kriesi, Hanspeter. 2011. ‘Personalization of National Election Campaigns’. Party
Introduction
The electorally volatile and highly unstable party systems in the post-
communist countries of central-eastern Europe are associated with the con-
stant (re)emergence of new parties. The Czech Republic had for a long time
after the emergence of democracy defied these patterns of unstable party
politics. In the first few decades following the fall of communism, the polit-
ical competition was based on the clearly defined, ideology-driven conflict
between two relatively stable and numerically limited blocs of political par-
ties. The left-wing social democracy, with the Czech Social Democratic Party
(ČSSD) as the main protagonist, and right-wing neoliberalism, with the Civic
Democratic Party (ODS) as the key player, represented the two opposing
views on how to run the country and economy that structured the country’s
political competition. Consequently, some referred to the Czech party sys-
tem as institutionalized or consolidated (Berglund and Dellenbrant 1991),
well established with a high level of programmatic crystallization, and not
being fragmented into many smaller parties (Hanley 2008). The above char-
acteristics made the Czech party system de facto an exception in the context
of post-communist countries. Only a few other countries, such as Slovenia or
Hungary, witnessed similar developments.
However, the Czech party system has registered fundamental changes in
recent years in terms of the number of (new) parties that compete in elec-
tions and enter the parliamentary arena, as well as in the issues structuring
the political struggle between the parties. Beginning with the 2010 elections,
the relatively predictable pattern of party competition and the stable format
of the party system started to unravel. No longer driven only by left–right
Tomáš Cirhan and Petr Kopecký, Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of
Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Tomáš Cirhan and Petr Kopecký
(2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0006
Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics 109
Parties play a fundamental role in Czech politics. This is certainly true for the
first two decades of post-communist politics, but even the recent wave of ant-
establishment politics did not fundamentally alter the overall strong role of
parties in the system. Parties enjoy a near monopoly of representation, and
alternative channels of representation such as social movements and trade
unions are relatively weak (Kopecký 2001; 2007). Some of the longer estab-
recruited to a cabinet post from outside of parliament are often party mem-
bers or part of wider party networks; even the few non-partisan experts in
coalition governments that Czech politics has known were pressured to act
within the political guidelines of the nominating party. Finally, there are only
very few regional governors (Hejtman), the highest administrative positions
at the sub-national level, who are not members of one of the political parties.
There are at least two important institutional features that are responsible
for the strong role of parties in Czech politics. The first one is a generous
system of state subsides which favours (registered) political parties over all
made electoral breakthrough, with ANO nearly winning these elections. The
2017 elections further strengthened this trend of anti-establishment parties´
emergence and electoral success. Three other such parties succeeded elec-
torally and performed above the electoral threshold—Pirates, Freedom and
Direct Democracy (SPD), and Mayors and Independents (STAN). It was only
in the 2021 elections that, for the first time in nearly a decade, no new polit-
ical party entered the lower chamber of Czech parliament. However, two
long-standing parties ČSSD and KSČM—disappeared from it, leaving the
left-of-centre largely unrepresented in parliament.
In this section we focus on two new political parties that perhaps best embody
the recent changes in the Czech party system. VV was established in 2002 in
Prague. Similar to other new parties, in particular Pirates, it was founded as a
local party that was initially embedded solely in municipal politics. However,
unlike some other new parties like US-DEU or TOP 09, VV lacked connec-
tion to pre-existing party structures or to individuals with political capital
and, nationwide, made an electoral breakthrough only in the 2010 general
elections. Together with TOP 09, it immediately participated in the govern-
ment led by ODS. Nevertheless, VV´s engagement in this government was
marred by scandals, and thus short-lived, and the party fell apart not much
later.
VV´s ideology was always rather shallow, centred around anti-corruption
and anti-establishment appeals, combined with calls for simpler laws and
slim state administration. Initially, the party initially did not attract many
charismatic individuals to lead it, but this changed in 2009 when some
celebrities became associated with the party, in particular the investigative
journalist Radek John, who became the party leader. Other individuals, like
the businessman Vít Bárta, became highly influential within the party (ČTK
2011). Because of his prominence in VV and the closeness of his business and
VV´s politics, some researchers have referred to the party as to a business-
firm party (Hloušek 2012). Indeed, a close proximity to business groups is
what differentiates VV (and ANO) from the other new Czech parties, many
of which were associated with different social groups. For instance, the Green
party (SZ) was connected to various ecological initiatives and environmental
organizations, while Pirates started around the community of the PirateLeaks
website (the Czech equivalent of WikiLeaks) organizing online petitions pro-
moting internet freedom. In contrast, VV´s and ANO´s electoral success
can be seen as a part of the wider phenomenon of political entrepreneurs
infiltrating the Czech party system (Hloušek et al. 2020).
Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics 115
Unlike other studies of these two parties which deal mainly with their
ideology (e.g. Haughton and Deegan-Krause 2015; Hanley and Vachudova
2018), we now focus on their party organization (party membership and
party elite) and financing. Both parties share a number of party organiza-
tional approaches, which differ from the established parties (ODS or ČSSD).
We start by looking at party membership.
As we can see from Table 6.3, the number of party members in ANO
and VV is much lower when compared to the established parties (i.e.
those established prior to or shortly after the 1989 revolution). The con-
trast is particularly stark when comparing ANO and VV to the two estab-
lished parties with long historical roots: KSČM and KDU-ČSL (see also
Rovenský 2018). Nevertheless, ANO’s and VV’s membership is fairly com-
parable with that of the other newer parties, such as Pirates, SPD, TOP
09, or STAN (see Mazancová 2018). All the newer parties in the country,
that is those which have emerged in the last decade or so, register very few
members compared to their established counterparts from the 1990s and
before.
In a post-communist social environment hostile to partisanship and other
conventional forms of political participation, extensive organization building
Source: Political Party Database Round 2 V4 (Scarrow et al. 2022), data retrieved for 2017; the
reported income share refers to the total party income; M/E was multiplied by 100 and presents the
percentage share of the electorate
Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics 117
also invested in a specialized social media team in order to boost this impor-
tant strategy of party marketing (Cirhan and Stauber 2018: 475). In contrast,
VV did not invest so much in its online activities, most likely because the
party emerged prior to the spread and popularity of social media
Arguably, the strategy based on alternative forms of membership is advan-
tageous with regard to the maintenance of the party organization: both ANO
and, to lesser extent, VV focus on the advantages of membership in the
form of voluntary labour and restrict those types and aspects of member-
ship that are not easily maintained organizationally (Cirhan and Stauber
Party elites
Another aspect of VV´s and ANO´s party organization that is crucial for
understanding their involvement in Czech politics relates to the party elite.
Previous research has established that the contrasting political and organi-
zational fortunes of VV and ANO can be partially explained by the different
composition of their party elites (Cirhan and Kopecký 2017). Concretely,
the similarity in professional and career backgrounds among the party elite
could act as one of the contributing factors for their organizational survival
(by facilitating party cohesion). In theory, party cohesion is a crucial part of
party unity (see Andeweg and Thomassen 2010); commonly shared career
and professional backgrounds of party elites are variables that support party
cohesion (Putnam 1973). ANO displayed a highly homogenous party elite,
(67% of its party elite were managers), while VV´s party elite included indi-
viduals with much more heterogenous career pathways (only 24% of its party
elite shared the same career background). Also, in ANO a non-negligible pro-
portion of the party elite (17%) was recruited from the Agrofert business
conglomerate of the party leader. Many of these individuals associated with
Babiš´s business hold important posts within ANO (see Cirhan and Kopecký
2017 for more details).
For the ANO, party cohesion resulting from this organizational strategy of
relying on Agrofert managers proved to be especially relevant and advanta-
geous when it had to deal with major scandals. It was most strongly tested
when Babiš began to be investigated by The European Anti-Fraud Office
(OLAF) and by the Czech police for an alleged fraud in the application for
Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics 119
EU funding for one of his companies (Rankin, 2018). When the party faced
serious scandals concerning the party leader, the party elite stayed firmly
united behind him, and none of the party elite voiced any opposition towards
Babiš in public (ČTK 2015). There was no publicly visible faction within
ANO asking for his resignation, questioning his position, or even suggesting
changes in the leadership. On the contrary, in the months and years following
the scandal, all members of ANO´s elite continued and continue to support
Babiš publicly in the media and in parliament (Kosová 2018).
When VV went through a similar test concerning a scandal with much
in the 1990s it unified the party ideologically. The common ground on main
policies and a common-sense technocratic approach shared by ODS’s elite
helped it to share common political attitudes which, in turn, protected the
party organization from larger conflicts and the risk of disintegration.
While in ANO and ODS the parties’ unity stemmed partially from the
similarity in the career profiles of their party elites, other parties relied on
connections to social groups (e.g. the Greens with environmental organiza-
tions) as their source of cohesion. The same cannot be said about some of
the other Czech parties, notably ČSSD, where the conflicts between different
elite would matter less for such a party, as its source of party unity could
be based elsewhere. However, research on Pirates indicates that although
the so-called ‘member initiative’ theoretically gives members more power to
influence the internal party functioning than in the established parties, its
actual usage in the party is limited (Michalčák 2018). The party leadership
of Pirates maintains autonomy in matters related to the programmatic prior-
ities and organization of campaigns. Another limitation of members’ impact
within the party is related to their relative passivity: the party members in
Pirates seem to be much more active locally than at the national level. This
Party financing
One can only speculate if Babiš learnt from the mistakes of VV when he
established ANO and recruited its party elite. However, one aspect that most
certainly contributes to any new party´s success, especially at the early stage
of its formation, is the availability of party financing. There is no doubt that
the vast financial resources of its party leader were an obvious advantage at
the beginning of ANO’s existence, as nearly all of its total revenue before the
party won parliamentary seats was donated by Babiš or by companies affili-
ated with his Agrofert business conglomerate. In this part of the chapter, we
therefore pay close attention to how Czech parties are funded.
Between 1990 and 2012, Czech parties received over 40% of party fund-
ing from public subsidies (Kopecký and Biezen 2017); the data in Table 6.3
indicate that this percentage is now well over 50%, representing a very large
proportion of their overall finances. In the context of the Czech party sys-
tem, parties are highly dependent on public subsidies for their existence and
long-term survival. Indeed, as can also be seen from Table 6.3, which reports
some of the most recent data, public subsidies constitute the largest share of
income for most parties. ODS and KDU-ČSL, which receive a sizeable pro-
portion of their party finance from private donations and their own economic
activities, are an exception. Most Czech parties represented in parliament
depend almost exclusively on funding from the state. In some cases, like
ANO or Pirates, public subsidies are almost the sole source of party income,
with income from members in particular representing only a very negligible
source of money.
However, as mentioned in the second section of this chapter, parties are
only entitled to receive the funds from the state when they perform well in
122 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
elections (when the party receives at least 3% of the vote in general elections).
The availability of private funding for a party at the time of its emergence (or,
alternatively, at the time of a disastrous electoral performance) may therefore
be a crucial aspect of its success, and indeed also an opportunity to control
the party organization from the early days. Babiš seem to be the case in point
here. As mentioned previously, ANO (unlike VV ) depended highly on private
sources during its emergence, in particular from Babiš and his companies.
Importantly, this private funding from Babiš to ANO was made in the form of
loans to the party. The fact that these loans represented a large proportion of
Conclusion
The Czech party system in the 2020s is more volatile than in the late 1990s,
with new parties making an electoral breakthrough and gaining seats in
parliament while some of the seeming mainstays of the party system, like
ČSSD and KSČM, have been forced to leave it. Simultaneously, it is more
difficult for the parties to form a government, and coalition governments
consisting of three or more parties are likely to become the norm. Some
of the newcomers into the party system fall apart quickly after making an
electoral breakthrough, while some appear to be here to stay. The com-
parison drawn in this chapter focused on two new parties with opposite
political and organizational fortunes. The successful ANO has become one
of the biggest and most important parties in the country, while VV has failed
and disappeared despite a successful start. The focus of this comparison
was on how these two political parties’ organizational features have influ-
enced their survival. On one hand, they are fairly similar in their approach
towards party membership, although ANO is much more restrictive and
closed, almost elite-like in this respect. Both parties rely on alternative forms
of membership that provide the perks of having members without having to
pay for their maintenance organizationally. On the other hand, the homo-
geneity of the ANO party elite, absent in VV, facilitated the party’s survival
even when it was severely tested in government. The overlap between the
party leadership structures and private company networks seems to have
facilitated unity within the party. In the absence of such unity, the shocks
Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics 123
coalition of Pirates and STAN, they hold a majority of seats in the lower
house of parliament and now form the government under the leadership of
Petr Fiala (ODS). To make things worse for Babiš, he decided to run for the
presidency but was decisively defeated in the 2023 direct presidential elec-
tions by Petr Pavel, a non-affiliated former NATO general, who was politically
supported by all the parties in the government coalition.
This now leaves the country and its party system in a somewhat paradox-
ical situation: Babiš has been replaced in government by some of the very
same parties whose past scandals led to his successful entry into politics.
Note
1. Depending on the individual party rules, either the local or district branches draft the
candidate lists that are sent for approval to the higher levels of party organization, be it
the regional executive committee or the national executive committee. Additionally, in
the case of some parties, the party leadership maintains a veto right on the candidate
selection.
References
Andeweg, Rudy and Jacques Thomassen. 2010. ‘Pathways to Party Unity: Sanction,
Loyalty, Homogeneity and Division of Labour in the Dutch Parliament’. Party
Politics, 17(5):655–672.
Berglund, Sten and Jan Ake Dellenbrant. 1991. The New Democracies in East-
ern Europe: Party Systems and Political Cleavages, Studies of Communism in
Transition. Hants: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
Biezen, Ingrid van. 2003. Political Parties in New Democracies: Party Organisation
in Southern and East-Central Europe. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Fragmentation and Anti-Establishment Politics 125
Casal Bértoa, Fernando. 2022. ‘Database on WHO Governs in Europe and Beyond:
Party Systems and Governments Observatory’. https://whogoverns.eu/ (Accessed
23 March 2023).
Čermák, Daniel and Jana Stachová. 2010. ‘Sources of Trust in Institutions in the
Czech Republic’. Czech Sociological Review, 46(5):683–717.
Cirhan, Tomáš, and Petr Kopecký. 2017. ‘Career Backgrounds, Professional Network
and Party Cohesion’. Czech Journal of Political Science, 2:116–136.
Cirhan, Tomáš, and Petr Kopecký. 2019. ‘From Ideology to Interest-driven Poli-
tics: Václav Klaus, Andrej Babiš and Two Eras of Party Leadership in the Czech
Havlík, Vlastimil and Petr Voda. 2016. ‘The Rise of New Political Parties and Re-
alignment of Party Politics in the Czech Republic’. Acta Politologica, 8(2):119–144.
Hloušek, Vít. 2012. ‘Věci veřejné: politické podnikání strany typu firmy’. Czech
Journal of Political Science, 4:322–340.
Hloušek, Vít, Lubomír Kopeček, and Petra Vodová. 2020. The Rise of Entrepreneurial
Parties in European Politics. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.
IDEA. 2022. Voter Turnout Database. https://www.idea.int/data-tools/data/voter-
turnout-database (Accessed 10 April 2022).
Innes, Abby. 2016. ‘Corporate State Capture in Open Societies: The Emergence
Nattrass, William. 2021. ‘The Remarkable Rise of the Czech Pirate Party’. Spec-
tator (23 February). https://www.spectator.co.uk/article/the-remarkable-rise-of-
the-czech-pirate-party (Accessed 3 November 2021).
Rankin, Jennifer. 2018. ‘EU antifraud office finds 'irregularities' in payments allegedly
obtained by Czech PM’. The Guardian (5 January) Available at: https://www.
theguardian.com/world/2018/jan/05/eu-antifraud-office-finds-irregularities-in-
payments-allegedly-obtained-by-czech-pm (Accessed 21 January 2024).
Pšenička, Stanislav. 2019 ‘Financování politických stran po novele č. 302/2016
Sb., MVČR’, date unknown. https://knihovna.usoud.cz/arl-us/en/detail-us_us_
The party system that had been established in Italy after the end of the Sec-
ond World War suddenly collapsed around 1992–1993 as a consequence of a
combination of both exogenous and endogenous shocks (Harmel and Janda
1994; Pizzimenti 2020).1 Party system change was attributed to a number of
different factors: a) the collapse of international communism and its impact
on domestic electoral alignments; b) the disclosure of a widespread system of
political corruption; c) the country’s fiscal crisis at a critical time in the pro-
cess that eventually gave birth to the euro; and d) a referendum that forced
radical changes in parliamentary election rules. All these factors climaxed at
the same time, and at least some of them had mutually reinforcing effects.
The general elections held in March 1994 marked the beginning of the so-
called Italian ‘Second Republic’. A systemic change had occurred (Jones and
Pasquino 2015), although the institutions did not significantly change com-
pared to the previous period. In fact, the modification of the format and
mechanics of the party system, as well as of the relevant parties, was signif-
icantly profound. Thus, the Second Republic has been characterized by an
over-production of political reforms, in particular, concerning electoral rules
and the public funding regime.
As for the electoral rules, three reforms were approved by Parliament, in
1993, 2005, and 2017. The underlying logic of all these reforms was the lim-
itation of proportionality to strengthen the link between the parliamentary
majority and the executive. Disproportional mechanisms were introduced
in order to favour the establishment of a bipolar competition. A mixed elec-
toral system (3/4 single member plurality and 1/4 party list proportional)
Enrico Calossi and Eugenio Pizzimenti, Italian Parties and Party System(s). In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Enrico Calossi and Eugenio Pizzimenti
(2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0007
Italian Parties and Party System(s) 129
was initially introduced, which lasted until 2005; it was then replaced by a
proportional system strongly unbalanced in favour of the winning coalition,
which was guaranteed the absolute majority of seats in the Chamber of
Deputies. In 2014, the Constitutional Court established the partial uncon-
stitutionality of this law. Three years later, a new mixed electoral system
was approved (2/3 single member majority, 1/3 party list proportional).
However, the debate about the need for a new reform persists.
Regarding the funding and regulation of party politics, the Italian con-
stitution (Article 49) mentions political parties as fundamental actors in
To appreciate the patterns of continuity and change between the First and
the Second Republic, it is helpful to resort to a set of party system indicators
130 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
1953 1958 1963 1968 1972 1976 1979 1983 1987 1992 1994 1996 2001 2006 2008 2013 2018
Our empirical analysis focuses on four parties: the largest parties of the two
main competing coalitions and two parties that have played (and still play) a
crucial role in influencing the mechanics of the party system. These four are
the Partito Democratico (PD) and its major predecessors, the Partito Demo-
Table 7.2 Aggregated votes and seats to the four parties (%), 1994–2018
elections to choose the party leader. Voting rights in primary elections are
granted to all those who agree to pay a small contribution (over time it
has increased from one to two euro). Furthermore, voters must agree to be
registered as ‘party supporters’ (Seddone and Sandri 2020).
By focusing on the rights and powers accorded to ordinary members, it is
possible to resort to the Index of Members’ Prerogatives. This is calculated by
combining eight variables, which assess the prerogatives of members within
party organizations2 . We rest on the rationale of the Political Party Database
Project; thus, we analysed and codified party statutes by assigning values
ranging from 0 to 1. The two polar models are represented by a party in which
democracy follows a bottom-up process of delegation and membership bor-
ders are clearly defined (score: 1). In contrast, in a plebiscitary/top-down
Italian Parties and Party System(s) 135
Concerning party ideologies, in Italy all the main spiritual families have
been represented in Parliament, except the agrarian/rural parties (Pizzimenti
2020). This was facilitated by the electoral system, which was almost purely
proportional in the First Republic; the Second Republic forced the main
136 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
In the First Republic, many strong links existed between Catholic asso-
ciations and the Christian Democrats (DC), between some trade unions
138 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
PROGRESSIVE
STATE INTERVENTISM
FREE MARKET
and some leftist parties, and between sporting and cultural associations
and parties. However, these connections with social groups have never
been made explicit formally in party statutes. In this respect, we do not
observe any evolution in the past 25 years. A partial exception is consti-
tuted by Lega, which tried to establish a party-associated trade union, the
‘Sindacato Padano’, which however did not have significant success. In con-
trast, the M5S has never been supported by any collateral organization.
Moreover, the movement did not create intermediate organizational lay-
ers (such as regional or provincial layers). Further, the M5S had expressed
its rejection several times for any kind of intermediate organs that might
interfere with the direct connection between the leader and the members
(Mosca 2020).
If we focus on party organizations, some kinds of special representation
exist, especially for younger members. In the PDS-DS, young people were
given a special status through the ‘Sinistra Giovanile’; the same happened
Italian Parties and Party System(s) 139
The structure of party revenues followed the main trajectories of the reforms
of state funding (Table 7.5). From 1994 to 2007, all the analysed parties show
decreasing ratios between private funding (grassroots revenues plus pluto-
cratic funding) and total party income. Needless to say, the data must be
interpreted in the light of the dramatic increase in state funding, which had
a clear impact on the relative weight of parties’ autonomous financing. Be
that as it may, all parties (apart from Lega) were heavily dependent on pub-
Table 7.5 Party private revenues on total party income, expenditures for
personnel and electoral campaigns on total expenditures (%), 1994–2018
of its income for party staff. In the centre-left camp, the tendency is less
clear. PDS and DS prioritized the maintenance of party staff (in line with the
mass-party principle), while the interpretation of the balance sheets of their
successor PD is less univocal. Finally, it is not possible to assess the profile of
the M5S along this dimension, as the movement reports neither income nor
expenditure.
Number of leaders 2 3 6 1 1 3 2
Significant splits 0 0 1 0 1 0 0
two parties as one, there were four general secretaries from 1991 to 2007. The
average time in office is reduced for PD leaders. In fact, after Walter Veltroni
(founder and first general secretary in 2007), we find a long list of ‘regents’
(temporary leaders) and new appointed secretaries—a total of 7 in 14
years.
Less variance is recorded for relevant party splits. By taking into account
only those splits that gave birth to a competitive party (i.e. a party that is able
to appoint some cabinet members or to elect parliamentary representatives
in the following elections), we can identify a few episodes. On the left, we
Means of communication
Regarding the means of communication, the PDS had inherited from the PCI
the historical communist newspaper l’Unità. Although it saw a huge crisis in
the early 2000s—it was temporarily closed between 2000 and 2002—in 2007
it became the official newspaper of PD. The party also inherited the newspa-
per Europa from La Margherita, the other merging party. Eventually, the two
newspapers closed in the 2010s (Europa in 2014 and l’Unità in 2017), leaving
the PD without any official newspaper. Even the online magazine Democrat-
Table 7.8 The four parties and their leaders in social media
(number of followers)
Summary Evaluation
The Italian political system has often been depicted as an outlier (Lijphart
1999). Although this well-rooted image mainly referred to the First Repub-
lic, the heavily criticized Italian ‘particracy’ has given way to an even more
anomalous party system. The so-called Second Republic is characterized—
since its beginning in the early 1990s—by a persistent weakness. The contin-
uous reforms of the ‘rules of the game’ have been (erroneously) considered
the means through which the party system and its units could have been rein-
forced. The perverse effects produced by redundant and incoherent political
regulation has come to reduce the (already limited) incentives to party orga-
nizational consolidation. Parties have privileged their competitiveness in the
electoral arena to survive in the institutions, thus becoming heavily depen-
dent on the state (Pizzimenti 2018, 2020). This long-lasting dependency is no
longer based on direct public funding—which was abolished in 2017. How-
ever, looking at the present parties’ balance sheets, other public resources
(such as parliamentary salaries) are still relevant.
To date, we can identify at least three problem areas in the relationship
between political parties and the functioning of representative democracy:
146 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
institutional design, the format and mechanics of the party system, and party
organizational features.
Considering institutional design, the electoral system is a factor of per-
sistent instability and uncertainty. As we have outlined, the last 30 years
have been characterized by frequent changes in electoral law. In some
phases, these changes have also become prominent themes of political
debate, with two negative effects on the proper functioning of Italian
democracy. On the one hand, the instability of the ‘rules of the game’
has made the ‘game’ itself less credible and legitimized. On the other
fortunes and evolutions of their leaders. Forza Italia has not been able to expe-
rience a different leadership than that of its founder, Berlusconi; the M5S
has unsuccessfully tried to overcome Grillo’s prominence, first by electing
Luigi Di Maio as a leader and then choosing former Prime Minister Giuseppe
Conte. The parties’ adaptation to their leader is also evident for the Lega. In
2012, the election of Salvini as federal secretary provoked a change in the
party’s goals. It moved from being an organization rooted in a specific area of
the country (the North) to behaving as an ‘opinion party’, attractive to occa-
sional sympathizers from the whole country. The extreme personalization of
Post-script
In late July 2022, the technical government led by Mario Draghi resigned due
to increasing political tensions among the heterogeneous coalition of sup-
porting parties. The President of the Republic, Sergio Mattarella, opted to
dissolve Parliament and called for early elections, to be held in September.
The unexpected resignation of the technical executive forced parties to run
an unusual summer election campaign. While centre-right parties (FI, the
Lega, and Fratelli d’Italia) had already agreed on a possible coalition pact,
the other parties showed no clear strategies. The PD decided to break up
the existing coalition with the M5S, as it was considered the main culprit
Italian Parties and Party System(s) 149
for Draghi’s resignation. At the same time, the centrist liberal parties Azione
and Italia Viva opted for a solo race by launching a new electoral cartel
(AZ-IV ).
These sudden events further hindered the (already unlikely) reform of the
electoral system, which was deemed necessary after the reduction of the num-
ber of deputies and senators. As widely forecast, the centre-right coalition
won the elections. However, compared to the past, the political profile of the
coalition had changed. In fact, the extreme-right parties (Lega and the post-
fascist Fratelli d’Italia) overwhelmed the parliamentary representation of the
Notes
1. Acknowledgments. We would like to thank Editage (www.editage.com) for English
language editing.
2. The variables are: 1. Leader’s selection, 2. Candidates’ selection, 3. Differentiated mem-
bership, 4. Registration of non-members, 5. Possibility of party affiliation directly to the
150 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
References
Archury, Susan, Susan E. Scarrow, Karina Kosiara-Pedersen, and Emilie Van Haute.
2018. ‘The Consequences of Membership Incentives: Do Greater Political Benefits
Attract Different Kinds of Members?’. Party Politics, 20:1–13.
Arter, David and Elina Kestila Kekkonen. 2014. ‘Measuring the Extent of Party Insti-
tutionalization: The Case of a Populist Entrepreneur Party’. West European Politics,
37(5):932–956.
Bardi, Luciano and Peter Mair. 2008. ‘The Parameters of Party Systems’. Party
Politics, 14(2):147–166.
Bardi, Luciano and Eugenio Pizzimenti. 2020. Perché falliscono i partiti?. Roma:
Carocci.
Bardi, Luciano, Enrico Calossi, André Krouwel, Yordan Kutiyski, Beniamino Masi,
and Eugenio Pizzimenti. 2018. The Positioning of the Italian Voters in the 2018
Elections. Highlights from the VAA ‘NavigatoreElettorale.it’, Paper presented at
6–8 September 2018 SISP Conference, Torino.
Biezen, Ingrid van, Peter Mair, and Thomas Poguntke. 2012. ‘Going, Going, …
Gone? The Decline of Party Membership in Contemporary Europe’. European
Journal of Political Research, 51(1):24–56.
Calossi, Enrico and Lorenzo Cicchi. 2018. ‘The Italian Party System’s Three Func-
tional Arenas after the 2018 Election: The Tsunami after the Earthquake’. Journal
of Modern Italian Studies, 23(4):437–459.
De Sio, Lorenzo. 2018. Il ritorno del voto di classe, ma al contrario (ovvero: se il PD
è il partito delle élite). Centro Italiano Studi Elettorali. https://cise.luiss.it/cise/
2018/03/06/il-ritorno-del-voto-di-classe-ma-al-contrario-ovvero-se-il-pd-e-il-
partito-delle-elite/ (Accessed 11 December 2023).
Gerbaudo, Paolo. 2018. Il partito piattaforma. Milano: Feltrinelli.
Hanley, David. 2008. Beyond the Nation State: Parties in the Era of European
Integration. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Italian Parties and Party System(s) 151
Harmel, Robert and Kenneth Janda. 1994. ‘An Integrated Theory of Party Goals and
Party Change’. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 6(3):259–287.
Hartleb, Florian. 2015. ‘Here to Stay: Anti-Establishment Parties in Europe’. Euro-
pean View, 14(1):39–49.
Hix, Simon. 1999. The Political System of the European Union. London: Macmillan
International Higher Education.
Ignazi, Piero and Chiara Fiorelli. 2021. ‘The End of Cornucopia: Party Financing
after the Great Recession’. Government and Opposition, 57(1):193–216.
IPSOS. 2018. Elezioni politiche 2018: Analisi post voto. https://www.ipsos.com/it-it/
Seddone, Antonella and Giulia Sandri. 2020. ‘Primary Elections and Party Grass-
roots: Participation, Innovation and Resistance’. European Political Science,
20:483–501.
Siaroff, Alan. 2019. Comparative European Party Systems. New York: Routledge.
Tizian, Giovanni. 2021. ‘Così è fallita la propaganda “populista” di Salvini’. In
Domani, 13 February.
Viviani, Lorenzo. 2019. ‘Populist Anti-party Parties’. In Paul Blokker and Manuel
Anselmi (eds), Populism and Democracy. London/New York: Routledge, 106–123.
Costas Eleftheriou
Political parties have always been relatively strong in Greece. Due to their
pivotal role in the democratization process during ‘Metapolitefsi’ (‘regime
change’) from 1974 onwards, they enjoyed primacy vis-à-vis civil society
organizations and exercised privileged access to state resources. Notably,
political parties emerged as champions of democratization due to the low
acceptance of other institutions, such as the monarchy, Church of Greece,
Hellenic Army, or trade unions; this was the direct by-product of parties’
performance during the colonels’ dictatorship of 1967–1974. Political par-
ties were the only institutions that could claim to ensure the transition to
and consolidation of democracy, and to achieve the legitimacy of the new
democratic regime (Spourdalakis 1996).
Article 29 of the 1975 Greek Constitution (along with its four amend-
ments) states that ‘Greek citizens possessing the right to vote may freely found
and join political parties, the organization and activity of which must serve
the free functioning of democratic government’. While the parties constitute
one of the foundations of the Greek polity, only their management and the
transparency of party finances are subject to legal regulation. There is no
party law regulating intra-party democracy or defining what it means to be
a democratic party; the only prerequisite for a party to participate in Greek
elections is to file a declaration at the ‘Supreme Civil and Criminal Court of
Greece’ (Areios Pagos).
In this sense, in party statutes, most parties opted for structures
corresponding to the mass type (centralized and organized on a local basis),
which gradually incorporated procedures of direct democracy (primaries).
To fulfil their role in the democratization process as it unfolded in Greece,
parties utilized the following type of party organization: mass inclusion of
Costas Eleftheriou, The Greek Party System’s Ongoing Crisis. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Costas Eleftheriou (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0008
154 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
50
43.92
45
39.85
40 36.34 35.46
33.47
Percentage of votes (%)
35 31.53
29.66
30 26.89 27.81 28.09
25
18.85
20 16.78
13.18 12.28
15
8.1
10 6.29
ND PASOK/KINAL SYRIZA
Figure 8.1 ND, SYRIZA, and PASOK/KINAL electoral results, 2009–2019. At the May
2023 elections, the respective results were 40.79%, 20.07%, 11.46%. At the June 2023
elections, the results were 40.56%, 17.83%, 11.84%.
Source: https://ekloges.ypes.gr/en, Ministry of Interior (Accessed 1 March 2024)
competition and not interact substantially with other parties. After 2019, the
extreme-right Golden Dawn dissolved and its leaders are in prison. Lastly, the
radical right Greek Solution (Kyriakos Velopoulos) and radical left MERA25
(Yanis Varoufakis), which entered the parliament at the 2019 elections, still
have not institutionalized in a way that predicts their resilience2 .
In general, current Greek party organizations originate from the mass party
organizations of the 1970s and 1980s that shifted to the implementation of
a catch-all strategy. This meant that party members gradually shifted from
being ‘party militants’ to become leadership ‘cheerleaders’. This is one devel-
opment from the early 1990s onwards that, in one sense, undermined the
participatory spirit of the early Metapolitefsi period. Mass membership, espe-
cially the urge for party organizations to attract and recruit party members on
a quantitative basis, was directly connected to democratization and was ini-
tially considered a project occupying the parties on the left (Eleftheriou and
Tassis 2013). During the 1980s, the conservatives experienced their own ver-
sion of the ‘contagion from the left’ (Duverger 1964) by embracing the need
for mass organization and becoming the most populous party, in terms of
members, in the Greek party system (Kalyvas 1998; Papavlassopoulos 2004).
From the mid-1990s, the epicentre of party politics was the technocratic
capacity of each governmental party. Thus, the previous politicization of
The Greek Party Systemʼs Ongoing Crisis 157
mass membership gave way to direct and non-mediated links between the
technocratic elites and voters. This usually took the form of a firm and client-
style relationship between parties and society (Vernardakis 2011). This had
a profound impact on party members deprived of motives to join party
organizations. Available party organization data for Greece reveal a trend of
non-decline of party membership (Biezen et al. 2012), something that pushed
some scholars to think that Greece is an exception to the party decline the-
sis. However, it is usual for party membership data in Greece to be largely
unreliable. Frequently, party members register whenever their favoured party
Table 8.2 Membership and party finance of ND, SYRIZA, and KINAL
Note: Party income data were retrieved for 2019; the reported income share refers to the total party
income; M/E was multiplied by 100 and presents the percentage share of the electorate. In Greek parties’
financial reports, members’ contributions are not discerned from MPs’ contributions.
Sources: Annual financial reports for 2019 (epitropielegxou.parliament.gr); PPDB Round 2 Data;
author; the data for KINAL came from the financial reports of KINAL, PASOK, Democratic Alignment
(DISI), and Olive Tree–Democratic Alignment combined
160 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
may choose a different method of leadership selection, thus paving the way
for open primaries—a development that unfolded in 2022 both for lead-
ership selection and selection of central committee members and again in
2023 for leadership selection (SYRIZA 2022). In general, after 2012, the
party had difficulties in keeping membership numbers corresponding to its
expanded electorate. In organizational terms, the low numbers in member-
ship recruitment were the result of the activities of factions, which functioned
as gatekeepers by excluding potential members to preserve their positions
in the intra-party power balance. This was particularly visible in 2015 when
In general, through the democratization process and until the late 1990s,
most Greek parties ‘colonized’ civil society by transferring the dynamics
Source: Author
The Greek Party Systemʼs Ongoing Crisis 163
The significance of state subsidies in the development of the Greek party sys-
tem is one of the most evident features of the symbiotic relationship between
the Greek political parties and the state (Vernardakis 2012; Rori 2015). Party
funding comes from the following sources: state subsidies, parliamentarians’
and members’ contributions and donations, bank loans, and the utilization
of party-owned real estate. State subsidies are divided into three types: the
Political parties, as we know, are not unitary actors (Sartori 2005 [1976]);
they comprise intra-party groups that reflect either different ideological
approaches or competing personalistic networks. The Greek case is no excep-
tion. Nevertheless, the culture of the mass-type organization imposes the
logic of internal homogeneity for all parties, thus suppressing overt factional
activity (Eleftheriou and Tassis 2013). Every Greek party, except the Euro-
communists and SYN, presented itself as comprising non-organized internal
groupings. The post-1974 rapid institutionalization of the party system and
the hybrid character of the relevant parties, especially the governmental
ones, created favourable conditions for internal fragmentation. The polariza-
tion of the 1980s forced the main parties to conceal their internal diversity;
after 1990, the salience of intra-party conflict in party competition revealed
the reality of PASOK and ND as multi-tendency actors. The only party
166 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
that sanctioned the existence and free activity of factions was SYN, which
conducted its decision-making process, at least until mid-2000s, through
compromises between existing factions (Eleftheriou 2009).
ND does not allow formal factional competition, though three distinct
tendencies have characterized its intra-party politics from its earliest years
(Kalyvas 1998; Alexakis 2020). The first tendency, ‘karamanlist’, stems from
the tradition of the party founder, Konstantinos Karamanlis, who empha-
sized conservatism, moderate statism, and paternalistic social protection. The
second, ‘popular rightist’, appeals to the popular strata of ND’s electoral base
The Greek party system has followed the trend towards professionalized
political communication strategies, especially from the 1990s, when the
168 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Concluding Remarks
In general, the Greek party system was relatively stable until the so-called
electoral ‘earthquake’ of 2012 that demolished the electoral base of PASOK
and ensured the electoral rise of SYRIZA (Voulgaris and Nicolacopoulos
2014). The system of ‘two-partyism’ reproduced itself through the confronta-
tion of two mass socialist and conservative poles, and the parallel existence
of radical left actors. This system started displaying signs of delegitimization
from the mid-2000s, when the radical left and emerging far right challenged
the two-party consensus. In this sense, the economic crisis and the deep polit-
ical crisis that followed functioned as a catalyst for the collapse of the old
party system.
The decline of PASOK was the landmark event of the period as it had
been the ‘hegemonic party’ in Greek party competition (Eleftheriou and
Tassis 2013). PASOK had a pivotal role in promoting organizational inno-
vations and programmatic shifts, as well as influencing its main political
adversary. Yet PASOK’s decline is the embodiment of various developments
170 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
bailout programme; this was mostly because it emerged from the anti-bailout
camp that could legitimize the necessity of the bailout programmes and
finally conclude the last of them. This was something that cost SYRIZA cred-
ibility and, more importantly, the capacity to present itself as an alternative
to systemic politics.
The 2019 elections, as the first post-crisis poll, seemed to provide a repe-
tition of the old two-party system: a conservative pillar versus a radical left
pillar, with the parallel presence of a centre-left minor party. However, the
2023 elections confirmed the dominance of the conservative party with over
Notes
1. From 2017 to 2022 PASOK was the core party of KINAL (coalition with centre-left
groupings). In 2022 KINAL was renamed PASOK-KINAL.
2. The chapter mainly covers developments in the Greek party system up to the summer
of 2022. It does not address extensively the context of party competition after the two
elections in 2023. Greek Solution managed to remain in parliament, while MERA25 did
not. There are two new far right parties in the parliament – Spartans and Niki – and
Course for Freedom a sovereigntist left party originating from SYRIZA.
3. Prior to its April 2022 party congress, SYRIZA claimed 61,600 members. At the May
2022 leadership selection, SYRIZA claimed the participation of 151,842 members. Given
the abstention of almost one-third of pre-congress members at the leadership selection
process, the party claimed the recruitment of 110,000 additional members who enrolled
before the leadership selection day. 148,821 party members participated in the September
2023 leadership selection, of which 40,000 were new members registered on the day of
the first round of the selection process.
References
Aranitou, Valia. 2013. Social Dialogue and Employers’ Associations. Athens: Savalas
(in Greek).
Andreadis, Ioannis, Eftychia Teperoglou, and Emmanouil Tsatsanis. 2011. ‘The
Structure of Ideological Space in Greece’. Greek Political Science Review, 38:5–32
(in Greek).
Biezen, Ingrid van, Peter Mair, and Thomas Poguntke. 2012. ‘Going, Going, …
Gone? The Decline of Party Membership in Contemporary Europe’. European
Journal of Political Research, 51(1):24–56.
Bithymitris, Giorgos. 2018. ‘An Exceptional Social Democratic Trade Union Identity:
Katsourides, Yiannos. 2020. ‘The Radical Left’. In Kevin Featherstone and Dimitris
A. Sotiropoulos (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Modern Greek Politics. Oxford,
New York: Oxford University Press, 299–315.
Katz, Richard S. and Peter Mair. 1993. ‘The Evolution of Party Organizations in
Europe: The Three Faces of Party Organization’. American Review of Politics,
14(4):593–617.
Katz, Richard S. and Peter Mair. 1995. ‘Changing Models of Party Organization and
Party Democracy: The Emergence of the Cartel Party’. Party Politics, 1(1):5–28.
Katz, Richard S. and Peter Mair. 2009. ‘The Cartel Party Thesis: A Restatement’.
Tsirbas, Yannis. 2020. ‘The Party System’. In Kevin Featherstone and Dimitris A.
Sotiropoulos (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Modern Greek Politics. Oxford, New
York: Oxford University Press, 219–239.
Vernardakis, Christoforos. 2011. Political Parties, Elections and Party System: The
Transformations of Representation 1990–2010. Athens, Salonica: Sakoulas (in
Greek).
Vernardakis, Christoforos. 2012. ‘From Mass Parties to Cartel Parties: The Evolution
of the Structure of Political Parties in Greece through Changes in Their Statutes
and Systems of Financing’. Working Paper Series on the Legal Regulation of Politi-
Toygar Sinan Baykan, Parties and the Party System in Turkey. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Toygar Sinan Baykan (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0009
178 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
system remains intact to the present day, with various important modifica-
tions. The result of this proportional system, combined with a more liberal
constitutional framework and rapid industrialization and urbanization, was
the rise of a remarkably more fragmented and unstable party system in the
1960s and 1970s. More problematically, the rising political polarization from
the mid-1970s onwards escalated into a civil-war-like left–right conflict in
Turkey.
These developments culminated in another military coup in 1980 which,
this time, was led by top military commanders and resulted in unprecedented
due to the 10% electoral threshold, the party won 363 seats out of 550 seats
in the parliament. Around 45% of all votes cast in this election were wasted.
These wasted votes mostly belonged to the ruling parties of the 1990s and—
combined with their failure in government throughout that period—their
failure in this critical election suddenly pushed these centre-right and centre-
left parties out of parliament, and incrementally out of the political system in
the 2000s.
There are two major points that needed to be asserted for the period until
the rise of the AKP. One of them is that the party system in Turkey during the
The system of ‘double tutelage’ in Turkey that was based, on the one hand, on
frequent interventions from non-party actors (such as the army and the high
judiciary) in party politics and, on the other hand, on authoritarian domi-
nation of powerful political elites/patrons (Akarlı and Ben-Dor 1975; Bektaş
1993; Ayan-Musil 2011) over poor, segmented, and subjugated social sectors
gradually started to dissolve in the years preceding the rise of the AKP. In the
1980s and 1990s, urbanization and domestic migration gained momentum,
2007 general elections (namely the AKP, CHP, pro-Kurdish parties, and the
MHP-Milliyetçi Hareket Partisi—Nationalist Action Party) were, more or
less, able to protect their vote and seat shares in the 2015 and 2018 general
elections, with the exception of the rise of a splinter party from the MHP,
Meral Akşener’s İyi Parti—The Good Party, in the 2018 elections. Thus, it is
safe to argue that the volatility in the Turkish party system remained limited
throughout the AKP years.
Nevertheless, the process of AKP’s rise into a predominant party within
the system by getting around twice the number of votes received by the main
opposition for more than two consecutive elections, and the seeming party
system stability this predominance has provided so far in terms of core party
system indicators, has been accompanied by a process of autocratization.
While this process was not clearly discernible before 2015, as Sözen (2020)
states, there were signs regarding this authoritarian tendency, such as the
‘aggrandizement in the executive branch’ well before this date. Yet the author-
itarian characteristics of the AKP more clearly emerged after 2015. Thus, the
case of Turkey demonstrates that improvements in the quantitative indica-
tors of party system stability may not always accompany democratic stability
(Yavuzyılmaz and Tsarouhas 2022). Not only the relationship between par-
ties but also the complex relationships among parties, non-party institutional
actors (such as the military), and patronage-oriented societal actors (such as
Parties and the Party System in Turkey 183
The AKP
The AKP was founded under the leadership of Erdoğan in 2001 as a reformist
splinter from the strictly Islamist National View tradition. While it was
founded within the parliament with the participation of deputies from the
Islamist Fazilet Partisi, the party was in fact partially based on an Islamic
social movement. One of its main organizational characteristics, particularly
throughout its first decade, was its successful blending of features of a classi-
cal mass party (local embeddedness, ideologically motivated mass following,
strong grassroots organizations, year-round routine organizational activity)
with modern political marketing techniques and a catch-all (Kirchheimer
1966) orientation that highlights the role of the party leadership. This hybrid
Parties and the Party System in Turkey 185
model provided the AKP with superior leverage compared with its rivals
within the party system in the 2000s.
An important point that should be asserted here is that this hybrid model
was very different from the organizational culture of pre-existing and effec-
tive right- and left-wing parties which heavily relied on amalgamations of
various patronage networks across Turkey. In those parties, power was much
more dispersed among a plethora of locally embedded elites, and despite
the predominance of the top leadership role (the party chair), there were
always powerful figures within these parties that could counterbalance the
The CHP
The CHP is the founding party of the modern Turkish Republic; as such,
its position within the Turkish party system has always been profoundly
defined by the party’s historical legacy. The party was incorporated into
the state institutions throughout the decades after the foundation of the
Republic in 1923. However, with the transition to multi-party politics, except
for a couple of short periods in office, the CHP remained in opposition
throughout the following 75-year period of tumultuous democratic experi-
ence. As a consequence of its origins as the party of ‘secular nation builders’,
the CHP always struggled to directly appeal to broad, mostly conservative
188 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
in civil society and the CHP are not stable at all, and such associations and
trade unions are completely autonomous entities.
Having said all this, the CHP also had a non-clientelistic appeal to a broad
and better-off constituency in Turkey as the representative of a certain type
of secular middle-class lifestyle. While the party defines the principles of
Atatürk as its raison d’être and embraces a social-democratic identity,18 it
is misleading to think that these principles constitute a well-defined ideology
like socialism, liberalism, or Islamism. It is at best a broadly defined world-
view appealing to secular segments of society. Hence, the party’s ideology
Concluding Remarks
has undergone profound changes since the 1950s, the firm hold of political
and military–bureaucratic elites over society remained intact despite the rel-
ative decline of the latter in recent decades under populist AKP rule. The
decline of the military–bureaucratic leg of double tutelage ironically resulted
in a further deterioration of democracy, and Turkey moved into a fragile,
personalistic hybrid regime under a civilian government.
This outcome testifies to the fact that, at least in their personalistic, clien-
telistic and centralized shape (Sayarı 2014; Laebens 2020; Massicard 2021),
Turkish parties have been part and parcel of the perennial problems of
unintended outcome of the AKP’s prolonged and firm hold on power, relying
on widespread clientelistic relations, should also be emphasized: a powerful,
routinized organization that has penetrated the veins of Turkish society. The
AKP today seems under the total control of Erdoğan, but it is by no means
a ‘personal party’ (Calise 2005; McDonnell 2013) lacking a solid, routinized
organization. Although the party’s demise after Erdoğan is certainly a possi-
bility, it should be noted that the AKP today is a 20-year-old, bureaucratic
entity with its own life. Under a skilful new leader with a democratic orien-
tation,22 it may survive after Erdoğan. Under the circumstances of a more
Notes
1. The impact of the law on political parties should be seen in combination with a previ-
ous regulation promulgated just after the military coup in 1960s which banned all the
sub-district level official organizational activity of political parties in Turkey lest there be
social polarization. From the introduction of this regulation onwards, ‘linkages between
parties and society gradually deteriorated’ (Kabasakal 1991: 233).
2. Party typologies widely used for describing organizational characteristics of parties have
recently been subject to compelling, empirically robust criticism. See the volume by Scar-
row et al. (2017). Nevertheless, distinctions between cadre, mass, catch-all, and cartel
Parties and the Party System in Turkey 193
models still have value in guiding empirical research and presentation of findings in an
accessible way.
3. For the role of military elites in Turkish politics, see Cizre (1999) and Karaosmanoğlu
(2016).
4. From the perspective of the distinction between ‘predominant’ and ‘hegemonic’ parties
proposed by Sartori (2005), it is currently hard to fit the AKP clearly into one of these
categories. While the AKP enjoys privileges in the Turkish party system that a predomi-
nant party in a democratic system cannot benefit from, the AKP’s position is not as safe
as a consolidated ‘hegemonic party’ in an authoritarian system, such as the PRI analysed
by Magaloni (2006) and Greene (2007) in Mexico or Putin’s United Russia analysed by
18. See page 9 of the party’s constitution for these principles: https://content.chp.org.tr/file/
chp_tuzuk_10_03_2018.pdf (Accessed 14 May 2021).
19. See page 606 of the party’s ‘activity report’ on the period between 2018 and 2020 for
party income in 2018: https://chp.azureedge.net/56b9d40cdf3b478b8f24da9887a9c05e.
pdf (Accessed 14 May 2021).
20. Turkey was defined as ‘not free’ by Freedom House in 2020. See https://freedomhouse.
org/country/turkey/freedom-world/2021 (Accessed 16 May 2021).
21. Two important trends are worthy of indication here. One is that the AKP lost two
major municipalities (İstanbul and Ankara metropolitan municipalities) to the opposi-
tion alliance among the CHP, İYİ Parti, and the HDP. The other trend is, as addressed
References
Akarlı, Engin D. and Ben-Dor, Gabriel (eds). 1975. Political Participation in Turkey.
İstanbul: Boğaziçi University Publications.
Akdoğan, Yalçın. 2004. Ak Parti ve Muhafazakar Demokrasi. İstanbul: Alfa.
Algül, Süreyya. 2015. DİSK (1967–1975). İstanbul: İletişim.
Arat, Yeşim and Şevket Pamuk. 2020. Turkey between Authoritarianism and Democ-
racy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ark-Yıldırım, Ceren. 2017. ‘Political Parties and Grassroots Clientelist Strategies
in Urban Turkey: One Neighbourhood at a Time’. South European Society and
Politics, 22(4):473–490.
Arıkan-Akdağ, Gül. 2014. Ethnicity and Elections in Turkey. London: Routledge.
Arslantaş, Düzgün and Şenol Arslantaş. (2020). ‘How Does Clientelism Foster Elec-
toral Dominance? Evidence from Turkey’. Asian Journal of Comparative Politics,
7(3):559–575.
Aslan-Akman, Canan. 2012. ‘The 2011 Parliamentary Elections in Turkey and Chal-
lenges ahead for Democratic Reform under a Dominant Party System’. Mediter-
ranean Politics, 17(1):77–95.
Ayan-Musil, Pelin. 2011. Authoritarian Party Structures and Democratic Political
Setting in Turkey. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Parties and the Party System in Turkey 195
Largely due to the huge economic and financial crisis that befell Europe from
2009 onwards, there have been important electoral and voting consequences
(Bellucci et al. 2012). Across Europe, the last few years have been character-
ized by a greater fluidity in party systems (Hutter and Kriesi 2019), with the
emergence of challengers to mainstream parties. In Southern Europe, and
in general in the eurozone countries that were forced to implement difficult
austerity measures, there was first the emergence of parties to the left of the
socialist parties in countries where the far left had long since become resid-
ual (Hernández and Kriesi 2016). This was the case of Syriza in Greece and
Podemos in Spain (Santana and Rama 2018). More recently, in Spain and
Portugal the extreme right has also established itself, namely Vox in Spain
and Chega in Portugal (Mendes and Dennison 2021). In Northern Europe,
the fragmentation of the party system was already much more pronounced,
as a result of the greater number of cleavages existing in the societies of the
oldest EU member states in more permissive electoral systems but also due
to realignments that occurred in the eighties, which led to the emergence of
Green parties and far-right parties (Hutter and Kriesi 2019) at an earlier stage.
In the case of Portugal, which had hitherto had a tendentially majoritarian
party system but underwent a bailout in 2011, recent analyses have marked
the small, incremental change which has occurred in the Portuguese party
system since the eurozone crisis (Morlino and Raniolo 2017; Jalali 2018, Lisi
et al. 2021).
Our argument is in line with these analyses, namely that the Portuguese
party system has evolved with comparative stability in the last decade.
The continuing strength of the two main parties in the system, as well
Marina Costa Lobo, The Portuguese Party System. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Marina Costa Lobo (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0010
200 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Portugal initiated the third wave of democratization in 1974, after forty years
of authoritarian regime. The ‘rules of the game’ which were agreed to in 1976
largely reflect the historical and political circumstances of that period, which
was characterized by a strong presence of the military in the political life of
the country, an ascendancy of the left, and a strong cleavage concerning the
future nature of the political regime (Lobo et al. 2011). Following a turbu-
100 5.00
4.57
90
80 3.72 4.18 4.23 4.26 3.66 3.75 4.00
3.54 3.49 3.49
70 3.20
2.99 2.97 3.05
3.43 2.91 2.78 3.41 2.80 2.86
60 2.61 3.13
3.00
2.93 2.87
50 2.71 2.66
2.56 2.61 2.57 2.57
40 2.37 2.00
2.24 2.56
Figure 10.1 The effective number of parliamentary and electoral parties in Portugal,
1976–2022 and the sum of the two major parties, PS and PSD
Source: Döring et al. 2022 (ParlGov) and National Electoral Committee
60%
50% 50%
50% 47%
44% 44% 45%
42% 40% 42%
38% 39%
40% 38% 36% 37% 37% 36%
35% 34%
32% 32%
28% 30% 29% 29% 29% 28% 29% 29%
30% 28% 27%
26%
24%
22%
21%
20%
10%
0%
1975 1976 1979 1980 1983 1985 1987 1991 1995 1999 2002 2005 2009 2011 2015 2019 2022
Figure 10.2 Comparing the votes for the two major Portuguese parties, PS and PSD,
1976–2022
Source: National Electoral Committee
has largely outvoted the PSD. As a result, the Socialists governed for 12 years
between 2002 and 2022, while in the same period the PSD governed for only
eight years. Following this long spell in opposition for the PSD, in the 2022
The Portuguese Party System 205
election two new parties made large gains, both on the right: Chega (7%) and
IL (5%). They pose a threat to the PSD’s dominance on the right in future
elections.
What may explain such stability? Several hypotheses have been put for-
ward to explain the relative lack of change in the Portuguese party system
when compared to other Southern European countries. Morlino and Raniolo
(2017) develop the idea that the stability of the Portuguese party system can
only be understood in light of the high abstention levels which characterize it.
More recently, Lisi et al. (2021) also test this idea that abstention levels con-
Party Organization
As explained above, the main Portuguese parties, with the exception of the
Communist Party, were formed on the eve of or just following the transition
206 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
to democracy. Not only the Communists but also the Socialists and the right-
wing parties adopted a proximate mass-based organization. This means they
are parties which tried to maximize the number of members, where mili-
tancy is highly prized. During the transition to democracy, the Communists
and the Socialists diverged on the issue of trade union membership, with the
resulting creation of two trade union umbrella organizations, one umbili-
cally linked to the Communists (the CGTP-IN) and the other closely aligned
with the Socialists and the PSD (the UGT). These two umbrella organizations
have been the major associations with links to the mainstream parties in Por-
of the anti-Europeans. They are the ones who agreed to negotiate a common
government programme without jeopardizing Portugal’s commitments as an
active member of the eurozone’2 .
This was the first time since democratization that the Socialists had agreed
to a coalition with the Communists. Indeed, in 40 years of democracy, no
such agreement had occurred, thus marking a fundamental change in the way
parliamentary parties in Portugal relate to each other. As explained above, the
divide between these two parties was key to explaining the Portuguese party
system dynamics up to that time.
managed to elect one MP. The entry of the far-right Chega into parliament
constituted an important watershed, as Portugal was one of the few remaining
countries of Europe without an extreme-right populist party (Mendes and
Dennison 2021).
Following the 2019 elections, the Socialists improved their share of the
vote; there was little change in the vote for the BE, while the Communists
actually lost votes (Table 10.2). There had been expectations that António
Costa would re-enact the left-wing parliamentary coalition government or
even enter a full-blown coalition with one or both of the left parties. Despite
Table 10.2 The distribution of votes in elections and seats in the Portuguese
Parliament, 2015–2022
documented in Figure 10.1. While BE and PCP may have hoped that the
results of 2022 would force the Socialists to negotiate with these parties in
parliament, the results in effect spell the death knell of the left alliance and
ensure that the Socialists can govern for the full legislature.
In 2022, it seems the election campaign may have made a difference for
the election results. Opinion polls carried out late in the campaign seemed
to indicate a great proximity between the two major parties, the PS and PSD.
During the campaign, Prime Minister Costa on the one hand dramatized
the possible entry of Chega into government if the PSD came first with-
Figure 10.3 presents the left–right positioning of the main parties from 2011
to 2019, using CHES data. From the point of view of programmatic evolu-
tion on the left–right axis, there had been a modest increase in polarization;
that is, there was a gap between PS and PSD. An ‘anti-austerity’ stance was
consolidated from the last quarter of 2014, when António Costa was elected
Secretary-general. This bipolarization occurred due to a growing divergence
in relation to the theme of the European Union. The parties’ positioning in
10
8.8
9 8.5
8.0 8.0
8
6.7 6.7 6.4
7
Left-right Scale
6.0
6
5 4.5
4.2 4.1
4 3.4 3.4
3.3
3
2 1.2 1.3
0.7 0.9
1 0.5
0
2011 2015 2019
closer to both the BE and the PCP. In addition, the importance of the left–
right issue has remained the main ideological anchor in Portugal (Heyne et al.
forthcoming), and this benefits the major existing parties which compete on
those issues.
Although this left-wing positioning and Euroscepticism marked the posi-
tion of the PS before the legislative elections in 2015, some fundamental
differences remained on the left. Namely, the PS maintained that it would
‘fulfil and honour all of Portugal’s external commitments’, while in their man-
ifestos both the BE and the PCP did not rule out a possible exit from the Euro;
Conclusion
In this chapter, we aimed to present the Portuguese party system and its
development since democratization. We explained the way in which the party
214 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
system consolidated around four parties which dominated the system since
1974, and how, from 1987 to 2009 it was characterized by a majoritarian logic
with alternation between the two major parties, the PS and the PSD.
Next, we introduced the main parties in the system, as well as some of the
characteristics which have contributed to their endurance. The main par-
ties have mass organizations, and links to interest groups. Yet, there is an
undeniable trend towards both personalization and dependence on public
funding.
We have been witnessing slow and hitherto modest changes to party system
Notes
1. The military coup of 25 April 1974 marks the beginning of democratic transition.
2. https://www.tsf.pt/politica/e-como-se-estivessemos-a-deitar-abaixo-o-resto-do-muro-
de-berlim-diz-antonio-costa-4833329.html (Accessed 18 December 2023).
3. https://visao.sapo.pt/atualidade/politica/2022-01-27-ps-e-a-esquerda-o-divorcio-que-
ja-tem-dois-anos/ (Accessed 18 December 2023).
Bellucci, Paolo, Marina Costa Lobo, and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 2012. ‘Economic
Crisis and Elections: The European Periphery’. Electoral Studies, 31(3):469–471.
Cancela, João, Camacho Giestas, and Marta Vicente. 2019. Abstenção e Participação
Eleitoral em Portugal: Diagnóstico e Hipóteses de Reforma. Lisboa: IPRI.
Da Silva, Frederico Ferreira and Mariana Mendes. 2019. ‘Portugal: A Tale of Appar-
ent Stability and Surreptitious Transformation’. In Swen Hutter and Hanspeter
Kriesi (eds), European Party Politics in Times of Crisis. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 139–164.
De Giorgi, Elisabetta and José Santana-Pereira. 2016. ‘The 2015 Portuguese Legisla-
tive Election: Widening the Coalitional Space and Bringing the Extreme Left In’.
South European Society and Politics, 21(4):451–468.
Döring, Holger, Constantin Huber, and Philip Manow. 2022. Parliaments and Gov-
ernments Database (ParlGov): Information on Parties, Elections and Cabinets in
established Democracies. Development version. https://www.parlgov.org/about/
(Accessed 15 December 2023).
Fernandes, Jorge M., Pedro C. Magalhães, and José Santana-Pereira. 2018. ‘Portugal’s
Leftist Government: From Sick Man to Poster Boy?’. South European Society and
Politics, 23(4):503–524.
Hernández, Enrique and Hanspeter Kriesi. 2016. ‘The Electoral Consequences of the
Financial and Economic Crisis in Europe’. European Journal of Political Research,
55(2):203–224.
Heyne, Lea, Marina Costa Lobo, and Roberto Pannico. (forthcoming). ‘The Left–
Right Dimension, Europe and Voting in Bailout Europe’. In Marina Costa Lobo
(ed.), EU Politicization and Voting. London: Palgrave MacMillan.
Hutter, Swen and Hanspeter Kriesi. 2019. European Party Politics in Times of Crisis.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jalali, Carlos. 2007. Partidos e Democracia em Portugal: 1974–2005: da revolução ao
bipartidarismo. Lisboa: Instituto Ciências Sociais.
216 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Jalali, Carlos. 2018. ‘“The Times (May) Be A-changin”? The Portuguese Party Sys-
tem in the Twenty-First Century’. In Marco Lisi (ed.), Party System Change, the
European Crisis and the State of Democracy. Abingdon: Routledge, 213–230.
Jalali, Carlos, Patricia Silva, and Sandra Silva. 2012. ‘Givers and Takers: Parties, State
Resources and Civil Society in Portugal’. Party Politics, 18(1):61–80.
Lago, Ignacio and Marina Costa Lobo. 2014. ‘Partisan Turnout Bias and District
Magnitude’. Electoral Studies, 35:150–158.
Lisi, Marco. 2010. ‘The Democratisation of Party Leadership Selection: The Por-
tuguese Experience’. Portuguese Journal of Social Science, 9(2):127–149.
Moury, Catherine, Daniel Cardoso, and Angie Gago. 2019. ‘When the Lenders Leave
Town: Veto Players, Electoral Calculations and Vested Interests as Determinants
of Policy Reversals in Spain and Portugal’. South European Society and Politics
24(2):177–204.
Nassmacher, Karl-Heinz. 2006. ‘Regulation of Party Finance’. In Richard S. Katz and
William J. Crotty (eds), Handbook of Party Politics. London: Sage, 446–455.
Pinto, António Costa and Pedro Tavares de Almeida. 2008. ‘Portugal: The Primacy
of “Independents”’. In Keith M. Dowding and Patrick Dumont (eds), The Selection
of Ministers in Europe. London: Routledge, 165–176.
Luis Ramiro and María Salvador, Spain. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and
Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Luis Ramiro and María Salvador (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0011
Spain 219
All this relative stability has changed radically since 2015. Until then,
Spain showed some patterns in common with other contemporary West-
ern democracies regarding the state of their political parties, although with
some specificities. Spanish parties had experienced the normal function-
ing of a democratic polity only since the end of the 1970s, without ever
having experienced an extended period of democratic politics and mass
political involvement. Some parties recovered their routine working or were
founded in a political environment dominated by mass media and TV.
They were dependent on state subsidies rapidly established by themselves
Parliament, some Catalan and Basque nationalists (but also Canary Islands
regionalists or nationalists) played a key role in supporting them in Par-
liament and making the formation of single-party minority governments
possible (although the PSOE also counted on the support of the radical-left
IU at certain times during the Zapatero premiership).
Thus, the party system at the time included four state-wide parties of not-
so-unequal electoral weight (PP, 28.7%; PSOE, 22%; Podemos, 20.7%; Cs,
13.9%) and the still surviving nationwide IU (3.7% of the vote) (Vidal 2018).
While Cs had already existed in Catalonia before it decided to expand to the
rest of the country, the rise of Podemos was surely more spectacular: the party
was completely new having been created hardly a year before, at the begin-
ning of 2014 to run the European Parliament Elections of that year. Beyond
these parties, the party system included many non-nationwide peripheral
nationalist and regionalist parties where some electoral changes were also
by representing the newness and the promise of political, social, and eco-
nomic renewal against discredited old, traditional, and established parties
and politicians.
The 2015 elections were key not only because they transformed the party
system by putting an end to the two-party system configuration but also
because the fragmentation of the party system after the elections made gov-
ernment formation, government investiture, and getting a parliamentary
majority in support of a government more challenging tasks than ever. The
PP won the 2015 elections, although in a very weakened position, benefited
However, if the April 2019 elections showed the fragmentation and volatil-
ity reigning over Spanish party politics, the new early elections held in
November 2019 fully confirmed this picture. Again, the electorate showed
notorious levels of volatility. In this case, besides an additional weakening of
Podemos (12.9% of the vote), the elections showed how the other new party
that had entered Parliament in 2015 with astonishing success, Cs, suffered
important losses, receiving only 6.8% of the vote. Four years earlier, Pode-
mos and Cs had challenged the two-party system after entering Parliament
with high levels of support. In November 2019, they were electorally weak-
text was reached in most areas. Regarding the matter at hand, there was abso-
lute agreement that the new political order should be a pluralist democracy
and that political parties would be the leading protagonists. Thus, the Con-
stitution designed a parliamentary model and assigned a central and leading
role to political parties. As a result, they have (almost) a monopoly of political
representation, and there are very few channels of direct democracy partic-
ipation. One of the main goals at the time was to strengthen parties to bring
stability to the new democratic system.
The Constitution includes a provision in its preliminary part specifically
Table 11.1 Larger partiesʼ electoral decline, party system fragmentation, volatility,
and turnout in Spain since 1977
Election year Votes for the two ENEP ENPP Volatility Turnout (%)
largest parties (%)
approved after the Second World War (those of Italy, Germany, and France)
and in the Constitution of Portugal, also approved after a period of dicta-
torship (Blanco 1990; Morodo and Lucas 2001). Thus, Art. 6 means that the
Constitution recognizes the central and crucial role played by parties in a
democracy and assumes the task of guaranteeing certain conditions so that
parties can correctly fulfil this role and, thereby, ensure the proper function-
ing of the democratic system. There are four of these conditions: freedom
from the state, internal democracy, equal opportunities, and transparency
and accountability. The development of these principles, however, has been
from the general principles of the democratic state and the rule of law. Its
legislative development, however, was very limited until recent years, dur-
ing which there have been major reforms in funding and financial-economic
control and regarding parties’ organizational transparency, functioning, and
activities.
At a legal level, the legislator’s activity in the development of these con-
stitutional principles has undergone a significant evolution, from less to
more, and more intensive, regulation. The first Political Parties Act (LPP),
Law 54/1978, was approved by Parliament while the Constitution was being
a) Regarding the creation and existence of parties, the law establishes a reg-
ister system to acquire legal status, which has posed some abstract, but
not practical, problems. Only twice have the application for registration
of a party been rejected (during the early democratic years) but the Con-
stitutional Court ruled that the registrations should take place because
the registry could only perform mere formal control (SSTC 3/1981 &
85/1986).
However, the most significant decision on this matter was the adop-
tion of a dissolution system in 2002 to address the question of parties
Note: data were retrieved for 2017; the reported income share refers to the total
party income.
Source: Political Party Database Round 2 V4 (Scarrow et al. 2022)
d) The rules that regulate parliamentary activity have consolidated the cen-
tral position of parties in the Spanish political system, as all the initiatives
and decisions adopted in Parliament practically refer to the parliamentary
group and not to individual MPs. The MPs are the holders of parliamen-
tary seats; in theory, they are free to act but, in practice, they are subject to
strict party discipline. There have been several cases of MPs’ defection that
parties have faced by signing an anti-defection agreement, which seeks to
limit this practice and penalize individuals and parties who engage in it.
e) Finally, regarding internal democracy, the party law contains some mini-
mum requirements for internal organization and functioning and makes
it obligatory for parties’ statutes to regulate certain areas. This has led
to significant progress, for example, in relation to members’ rights and
parties’ transparency. However, the regulation is not detailed on certain
aspects of party organization, for instance, the internal selection of elec-
toral candidates. In this respect, since 2007, electoral lists must have a
balanced composition of men and women (a minimum of 40% of each
in the list of candidates or, in certain cases, the proportion of men and
women must be as close as possible to numerical balance).12 Nonetheless,
the legal provisions on parties’ internal democracy do not seem to have
been very influential. We will approach this aspect in the next section by
mapping some of the developments in this regard.
organizations. No Spanish party has appeared under any format other than
one of an organization formed by members; all the parties have formally
intended to create membership organizations extended across the territory.
The multi-level nature of Spanish domestic politics (with national, regional,
and local levels, and even other additional levels such as provincial or island
ones) involves the need to recruit thousands of candidates to be part of the
parties’ electoral lists at different levels, and this favours the recruitment
efforts by parties and the creation of territorial sublevels with parties’ local
branches at the base of the parties’ organizational structure. This basic model,
The parties’ weak social roots are also discernible in the absence of clear
linkages between parties and groups or parties and social organizations.
Certainly, they do not exist at a formal level; they are also relatively weak
even at an informal level. The traditional close relationship between con-
servative parties and business organizations, or between centre-right parties
and the Catholic Church, exists only at an informal level of both parties
and social organizations sharing and agreeing on policies and principles.
Something similar can be said regarding the relationship between left-wing
parties and unions or new social movements. Spanish unions have clearly
In this regard, the fragmentation and change of the Spanish party sys-
tem since 2015 has meant changes of relatively modest consequence for
the parties’ organizational models. The rise of Podemos in 2014 certainly
involved very conspicuous innovations including, among others, lower bar-
riers to party membership, many participation procedures for the selection
of party elites and candidates and for manifesto drafting, and the adop-
tion of multiple online procedures for members’ participation (including
internal referendums on political decisions and policy drafting). However,
these important innovations now appear overshadowed by the organiza-
economic and political crises experienced by Spain after the 2008 Great
Recession, the successive party system changes, and the rise of new parties
have somewhat modified this picture. First, the usual intra-party competi-
tion has certainly not generated formal factions as such, but the political
instability meant competitive leadership contests in both the PP and PSOE,
and the latter suffered a particularly conflictual period that included a very
unusual leadership resignation and breaking of party discipline in a key par-
liamentary vote. Second, the new parties—Podemos, Cs, and VOX—have all
experienced serious organizational problems and grave internal conflicts at
The Spanish parties and party system are experiencing an ongoing and
open-ended period of change. The party system has ceased to respond to
a two-party system model and appears now as a multi-party system. The
2008 Great Recession and its consequences contributed to a change in party
preferences that reduced the support received by the larger centre-left and
centre-right parties. The Spanish party system joined the trend of increasing
fragmentation visible in other West European countries. However, Spanish
party politics have also shown high levels of electoral volatility and instabil-
ity that imply that the current party system format cannot be regarded as
definitive. These changes also include an increase in affective polarization
and the successive rise of electorally strong radical-left and radical-right par-
ties whose support, however, given their relative organizational instability,
cannot be considered stable.
Parties’ organizations have also experienced some significant although
uneven changes. The increase in party democracy or of individual mem-
bers’ involvement in decision-making processes—above all, in party leader
selections—is a change that deserves attention. However, apart from that
change, some other important party characteristics (reliance on state
subsidies, overlap between the party in central office and the party in public
office, and party cohesion) remain unaltered.
Some Spanish parties have implemented new approaches to party orga-
nization and have attempted innovative internal procedures closer to
Spain 235
Notes
1. The contribution of M. Salvador is part of the research project ‘El estado de partidos:
raíces intelectuales, rupturas y respuestas jurídicas en el contexto europeo’, PID2021-
124531NB-I00.
2. Party systems including different parties, competition patterns, and government forma-
tion dynamics dissimilar to the national party system exist at the regional level.
3. In this chapter, we focus on the nationwide Spanish party system and its main
changes. However, the multi-level nature of Spanish politics includes specific regional
partysystems in many autonomous communities where peripheral nationalist and
regionalist parties are significant actors. Since the mid-2010s, some important changes
have taken place in several of these party systems, and some non-nationwide parties have
236 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
experienced relevant political changes too. The growth of the nationalist mobilization in
Catalonia that climaxed in 2017 is particularly important due, first, to the changes in the
Catalan party system that this process fostered (notably the strengthening of the ERC’s
role and electoral support) but, second, to its influence on some changes at the national
level (the increased but temporary relevance of Cs and the later rise of VOX).
4. Spain has traditionally shown notable levels of political disaffection (Montero et al. 1997)
and anti-party sentiment (Torcal et al. 2002).
5. Spain has a constructive no confidence vote formula that favours government stability.
6. Until then, Spain remained one of the few West European countries where the radical
right was not represented in parliament (Llamazares and Ramiro 2006).
References
Anduiza, Eva, and Guillem Rico. 2022. ‘Sexism and the Far-right Vote: The Individ-
ual Dynamics of Gender Backlash’. American Journal of Political Science. https://
doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12759.
Bermeo, Nancy and Larry Bartels (eds). 2014. Mass Politics in Tough Times: Opinions,
Votes and Protest in the Great Recession. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bastida, Francisco. 2003. ‘Informe sobre el borrador de la LO de partidos políticos’.
Debates Constitucionales, 5:1–23.
Llamazares, Iván, and Luis Ramiro. 2006. ‘Les espaces politiques restreints de la
droite radicale espagnole’. Pole Sud, 25:137–152.
Medina, Lucía. 2015. From Recession to Long-lasting Political Crisis? Continuities
and Changes in Spanish Politics in Times of Crisis and Austerity. Barcelona: Insti-
tut de Ciènces Polítiques i Socials. https://www.icps.cat/archivos/Workingpapers/
wp334.pdf ?noga=1 (Accessed 13 December 2023).
Montero, José Ramón, Richard Gunther, and Mariano Torcal. 1997. ‘Democ-
racy in Spain: Legitimacy, Discontent and Disaffection’. Studies in Comparative
International Development, 32:124–160.
Scarrow, Susan E., Paul D. Webb, and Thomas Poguntke. 2022. ‘Intra-party Decision-
making in Contemporary Europe: Improving Representation or Ruling with
Empty Shells?’ Irish Political Studies, 37(2):196–217.
Simón, Pablo. 2016. ‘The Challenges of the New Spanish Multipartism: Government
Formation Failure and the 2016 General Election’. South European Society and
Politics, 21(4):493–517.
Tajadura, Javier. 2004. Partidos políticos y constitución. Un estudio de la LO 6/2002,
de partidos políticos y de la STC 48/2003. Madrid: Civitas.
Torcal, Mariano, Richard Gunther, and José Ramón Montero. 2002. ‘Anti-party Sen-
Introduction
The year 2021 marked the 30th anniversary of the first democratic par-
ties in Poland, which had contested the first fully democratic parliamentary
election in 1991. After 45 years of communist centralism and authoritari-
anism, the democratic transformation was expected to stop public apathy,
reduce mistrust of politicians, and increase public activism. However, it was
soon clear that building a functioning democracy with parties competing for
votes based on different programmes would be more difficult than expected.
Since 1991, voter turnout in Poland’s national elections has oscillated around
40–50% (only recently exceeding 60%), and party membership has been
among the lowest in Europe at approximately 1% of the electorate.
Such a picture was presented in the academic literature dating back to the
1990s, when Poland was portrayed as an extremely unstable party system
coupled with feeble party organization (Mair 1996; Millard 2009b). How-
ever, since the early 2000s, the party system has stabilized, the number of
effective parties has decreased, and the number of major parties has remained
(roughly) the same (Walecka 2018). Usual explanations indicate the impact of
electoral rules (most notably, a 5% electoral threshold) and the introduction
of public financing of political parties in 1997, the full effects of which had
been felt since the 2000s (Casal Bértoa and Walecki 2017). While the party
system stabilized and parties received stable public financing, by the 2010s
This work was supported by the Polish National Science Centre (NCN), grant number 2017/26/M/
HS5/00824. The manuscript was finalized by mid-2023.
Wojciech Gagatek, Party Organizational Development in Poland, 2001–2021. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Wojciech Gagatek (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0012
Party Organizational Development in Poland, 2001–2021 241
Table 12.1 Key indicators of the format of the party system in Poland, 1991–2019
Indicators/Election 1991 1993 1997 2001 2005 2007 2011 2015 2019
year
Turnout (% of 43.2 52.08 47.93 46.18 40.57 53.88 48.92 50.92 61.74
active voters)
ENEP 11.62 9.58 4.55 4.45 5.64 3.24 3.68 4.39 3.35
ENPP 10.80 3.88 2.95 4.04 4.26 2.87 3.00 2.75 2.83
Volatility N/A 28.9 19.30 35.20 34.00 23.70 7.70 29.70 7.40
Sum of two biggest 24.31 35.81 60.96 53.72 51.13 73.62 69.07 61.67 70.99
in the parliament. PiS governed from 2005 to 2007 (in coalition with two
junior radical partners), and then, after 2015, in coalition with a group of dif-
ferent parties running for parliament on PiS’s ballot; PO, with PSL as a junior
coalition partner, governed from 2007 to 2015. Table 12.1 presents standard
indicators of the party system in Poland since 1991, documenting its overall
stabilization and consolidation.
But what Table 12.1 does not reveal is that the agendas of PiS and PO have
strongly dominated political competition since 2005, and although nominally
they would be categorized as (centre) right, the ideological distance between
them has always been significant (Kwiatkowska et al. 2016). One can easily
notice this by inspecting various databases and expert surveys, such as the
Chapel Hill Expert Survey or the Comparative Manifesto Project, alongside
the party programmes. For this chapter—and with some simplification—it
suffices to say that, on the one hand, there is PiS, with its emphasis on social
spending and redistribution in the economic field; traditional, conservative
views on moral issues; soft Euro-scepticism regarding European integration;
244 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Table 12.2 Membership figures and party finances in the four largest Polish political
parties
Source: author’s own work regarding collection of membership data; the official election reports by the
Polish Election Committee for other items in the table: www.pkw.gov.pl (Accessed 15 December 2023)
246 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Therefore, juxtaposing PiS and PO, we can ‘control’ the impact of party age,
membership numbers, financial resources, and governing experience. What
clearly emerge as principal differences are their ideologies and origins as
far as personal history is concerned—the impact of this is difficult to show
but worth investigating. Overall, we could argue that these two are the most
similar cases of parties that could be selected.
I will begin the empirical part of this study conventionally, with party
statutes. Analysing the organizational development of the parties, I will high-
light their main differences, which will be contextualized in the subsequent
Political parties and other organizations whose programmes are based upon total-
itarian methods and the modes of activity of Nazism, fascism, and communism, as
well as those whose programmes or activities sanction racial or national hatred,
the application of violence for the purpose of obtaining power or to influence the
State policy, or provide for the secrecy of their own structure or membership, shall
be prohibited. (The Constitution of the Republic of Poland 1997)
The year 2001 saw a spectacular electoral failure of the broad-church post-
solidarity government of the right-wing Electoral Action of Solidarity (AWS)
and the liberal Union for Freedom (UW) that governed from 1997 to 2001;
the post-communist SLD won and governed (in coalition with PSL) from
2001 to 2005. In the same election, PO and PiS contested for the first time,
attaining 12.68% and 9.50% of the vote share, respectively.
PiS, established in 2001, capitalized on the popularity and authority of
Jarosław Kaczyński’s twin brother, Lech, as justice minister in the AWS-
UW government (2000–2001). In the popular imagination, the party and its
leader were inseparable. Lech was the first chair of the party (2001–2003);
after he was elected as Mayor of Warsaw in 2002, his brother Jarosław took
over as party chair and has remained in that role until the time of writ-
ing. However, during the eight years of PiS government, Jarosław Kaczyński
248 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
served as Prime Minister for only one year, favouring the position of party
leader on whom the Prime Ministers from PiS are strongly dependent.
Three politicians—referred to as the three tenors—with significant politi-
cal experience in government and party politics established PO in 2001. Most
party members were drawn from a split in the UW, and others were remnants
of the AWS. The criticism of their former party organizations (portrayed
using oligarchical metaphors and an inability to enthuse members) formed
the basis for a new movement. The term ‘party’ was avoided in its name, and
the organization pictured itself as a (civic) movement that would not only
role. The success of the party had to lie elsewhere—in the ability to have a
smaller, reliable, and tightly controlled membership. To be included on a
candidate list in the 2001 national elections, members had to be thoroughly
cross-checked (Gazeta Wyborcza 2001b, 2001d).
In subsequent years, it became clear that the national leader tightly con-
trolled the party, being surrounded by a small group of the most reliable
members that stood with Kaczyński from the early 1990s. Only the chair
could submit candidacies for major positions of influence, including regional
leaders, and the regional congress of the party could only accept or reject
Party Members in PO
party members plays little or no role. Jacuński et al. (2021) argue that from
this perspective PiS and PO are alike. Based on the 2018 survey of party mem-
bers, these authors showed that when parties ask members for help, they
mostly need it to help collect signatures to support the registration of the
list of candidates for elections (more than a quarter of all cases), but they
hardly ever put their input into the programmatic work and rarely get in
touch directly with voters (Jacuński et al. 2021). Recent studies (Jacuński
et al. 2021; Wincławska et al. 2021) revealed that PiS members are united
in their overall positive view of the role they play within the party, whereas
Conclusions
Based on the above analysis, we can conclude the following. First, in terms
of the organizational development of political parties, the case of PiS shows
a strong overall level of continuity in organizational choices. Although the
party slightly decentralized after the electoral defeat in 2007 and then con-
tinued in this manner until today, it has kept its overall organizational logic
constant. This is an extremely centralized party organization, with national
levels dominating regional levels, a powerful role of the chair, and low levels
of intra-party democracy. Members are mostly needed as potential candi-
dates for elected representatives, but they must be loyal and disciplined and
avoid criticizing the party leader. In contrast, PO has created a sort of circle.
Starting with revolutionary proposals, it gradually centralized many aspects
of party functioning, most notably by increasing the role of the chair. Unable
to control internal party debates, it even considered copying the solutions for
membership policy typical of PiS. However, after Tusk left, the party returned
to a higher level of dispersion of influence. In this sense, this is not a full cir-
cle, but at least a symbolic reference to the early days of the party. At the same
time, and quite systematically, the party introduced participatory mecha-
nisms, first as primaries for presidential elections and then as direct elections
to the party chair. In this sense, the case of PO fits the general description of
the development of some parties in the world today that I presented at the
beginning of this chapter.
256 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Second, while it would not be justified to argue that the different structure
of PO and PiS originated from their different constitutional visions, or even
more to try to prove the impact of the former on the latter, nevertheless, the
link between the two seems visible. PiS as a party, like the state it governs,
must act quickly; so, discussions and deliberations are not a priority. The
leadership should not be limited, checked, or counterbalanced by anything
or anyone, either in the party or in the state, as it draws its legitimacy directly
from the voters (state) or party members (party); internal opposition in the
party or in the parliament is crushed by the power of majority; lower levels
Note
References
Biezen, Ingrid van and Petr Kopecký. 2014. ‘The Cartel Party and the State: Party–
State Linkages in European Democracies’. Party Politics, 20(2):170–182.
Biezen, Ingrid van and Thomas Poguntke. 2014. ‘The Decline of Membership-based
Politics’. Party Politics, 20(2):205–216.
Bolin, Niklas, Nicholas Aylott, Benjamin von dem Berge, and Thomas Poguntke.
2017. ‘Patterns of Intra-party Democracy across the World’. In Susan E Scarrow,
Paul Webb, and Thomas Poguntke (eds), Organizing Political Parties: Representa-
tion, Participation, and Power. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 158–184.
Casal Bértoa, Fernando, and Marcin Walecki. 2017. ‘Party Regulation and the
Reshaping of Party Politics in Poland’. In F. Casal Bértoa and I. van Biezen (eds),
The Regulation of Post-Communist Party Politics. New York: Routledge, 31–55.
Casal Bértoa, Fernando. 2022. Database on WHO governs in Europe and beyond,
PSGO. https://whogoverns.eu/party-systems/electoral-volatility/ (Accessed 14
December 2023).
Cwalina, Wojciech and Milena Drzewiecka. 2019. ‘Poland’. In Otto Eibl and Miloš
Gregor (eds), Thirty Years of Political Campaigning in Central and Eastern Europe.
Springer International Publishing, 131–148.
Döring, Holger, Constantin Huber, and Philip Manow. 2022. Parliaments and Gov-
ernments Database (ParlGov): Information on Parties, Elections and Cabinets
in established Democracies. Development Version. https://www.parlgov.org/data-
info/ (Accessed 14 December 2023).
Elgie, Robert and Gianluca Passarelli. 2020. ‘The Presidentialization of Political
Executives’. In Rudy B. Andeweg, Robert Elgie, Ludger Helms, Juliet Kaarbo and
Ferdinand Müller-Rommel (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Political Executives.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 357–381.
Gazeta Wyborcza. 2001a. Kandydaci 69 tys. Wyborców. https://classic.wyborcza.pl/
archiwumGW/1462736/Kandydaci-69-tys--wyborcow (Accessed 12 May 2023).
258 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Poguntke, Thomas and Paul Webb (eds). 2007. The Presidentialization of Politics.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Rzeczpospolita. 2013. Kaczyński: Biznes często to przystań ludzi PRL. Rzecz-
pospolita. https://www.rp.pl/wydarzenia/art12879901-kaczynski-biznes-czesto-
to-przystan-ludzi-prl (Accessed 14 December 2023).
Rzeczpospolita. 2021. Kaczyński: Łyżka nepotyzmu jest mała w porównaniu z
naszymi sukcesami. https://www.rp.pl/polityka/art53091-kaczynski-lyzka-nepot
yzmu-jest-mala-w-porownaniu-z-naszymi-sukcesami (Accessed 14 December
2023).
Assaf Shapira
Legal background
35
32
30
25 24
20
Seats
15 14
12 11
10
7 6 5 5 4
5
id
as
ism
’am
ur
u
y
’a
rt
ku
ein
At
Sh
Ta
bo
Pa
Ra
on
da
Li
eit
h-
La
sh
ty
Ju
Zi
lB
as
Ye
ni
h
us
ad
ea
lU
ra
io
H
sr
To
na
lig
Yi
d
io
Re
ite
at
Un
N
Intra-party democracy
As mentioned, the Israeli party law does not require parties to be inter-
nally democratic, and thus each party selects its own path. Some Israeli
Political Parties and Democracy 263
However, since the 1970s, and more prominently since the 1990s, Israel’s
parties have radically weakened. In fact, Israel is an extreme example of
this universal phenomenon. Rahat and Kenig found that Israeli parties
experienced the third largest decline—measured as an average of a dozen
indicators—among a group of 26 democracies (Rahat and Kenig 2018). This
decline may have been especially sharp due to the fact that Israel’s starting
point was very high—as noted, it was described as a parties state—but also
due to the adoption of institutional reforms that enhanced political person-
alization and fragmentation. These include the direct elections of mayors in
90
86.9
85
82.8 83.0
81.681.6 81.7
80 79.7 79.3
78.679.278.578.8 78.7
77.4
75
72.3 71.5 70.6
70 69.8
67.8 64.8 68.5 67.4
65 64.7
63.5
60
50
49
51
55
59
19 1
65
69
73
77
81
84
88
92
96
99
03
06
09
13
20 15
20 9–I
I
20
21
22
–I
6
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
19
1
Figure 13.2 Voter turnout in Knesset elections, 1949–2022 (%)
Source: Central Elections Committee, 2022. ʻVoter Turnout in previous Electionsʼ. https://www.gov.il/
he/Departments/Guides/election-committee-history?chapterIndex=4 (Accessed: 14 October 2023)
Israel has always had a multi-party system. This is due to two main factors.
First, Israeli society is extremely heterogeneous, in both social and ideologi-
cal terms. Ideologically speaking, while the disparity between socialist and
capitalist views has faded over recent decades, other divisions—especially
concerning Israel’s relations with its Arab neighbours and the relationship
between state and religion, and more recently also the status of the judi-
cial system—have become more pronounced (Kenig and Tuttnauer 2017;
Shamir et al. 2017). Israeli society is also divided by various cleavages. In addi-
tion to the divide between Arabs and Jews, there are also various politically
relevant divisions, among them the divisions in Jewish society among sec-
ular, religious, and ultra-religious; veterans and newly arrived immigrants;
and Mizrahi and Ashkenazi Jews (immigrants from Asia-Africa or Europe,
respectively, and their descendants). Each of these social groups has been
represented by or through various parties in the Knesset.
Political Parties and Democracy 267
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1949
1951
1955
1959
1961
1965
1969
1973
1977
1981
1984
1988
1992
1996
1999
2003
2006
2009
2013
2015
2019 - I
2019 - II
2020
2021
ENPP ENEP
Figure 13.3 Effective number of parliamentary parties (ENPP) and effective number of
electoral parties (ENEP) in Knesset elections, 1949–2021
Source: Döring et al. 2022, https://www.parlgov.org/data-info/ (Accessed 1.2.2024)
268 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
(a) Until the 1970s, Mapai and its successor party Labour were dominant
parties. They were both ruling parties and the largest parties in the
Knesset from the first elections, held in 1949, to the 1973 elections,
although they never won a majority of seats.
(b) The weakening of Mapai/Labour began as early as the 1960s. Fol-
lowing the 1977 elections, for the first time in the country’s history,
Mapai/Labour was no longer the largest or the ruling party—it was
replaced by the right-wing Likud. From 1981 until the late 1990s, a
competitive bipolar system existed. The two largest parties in each
bloc, Likud and Labour, switched positions as the ruling party (though
as before they never won a majority of seats).
(c) As noted, the power of Likud and Labour greatly weakened in the
1996 and 1999 elections. Although the direct election of the Prime
Minister was abolished before the 2003 elections, the competitive
bipolar system did not reemerge. While Likud eventually managed
to recover and maintain its status as a large party, Labour has been
in a near-continuous process of deterioration since the 1990s, and
no other party replaced it as a stable alternative. Potential candidates
included Kadima (2006 and 2009) and the Blue and White electoral
alliance (2019–2020), but these prematurely disintegrated. These days,
centrist, personalistic, Yesh Atid is the second-largest party, but its
electoral achievements are far behind those of Likud. For some time
it seemed that Likud might become a dominant party. It held power
Political Parties and Democracy 269
35 32.4
30
Electoral Volatility (Pedersen Index)
25.9 25.2
23.9
25
19.8
20 17.6 17.5 17.3
15.6 16.4
14.1 13.7
15 12.6 12.7
10.0 9.2 9.0
10 7.7 7.4 7.3
5.4 5.0
5 2.9
0
21
51
55
59
61
65
69
73
77
81
84
88
92
96
99
03
06
09
13
20 5
20 a
b
20
19
1
19
20
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
in practice before the September 2019 elections; and parties that managed
to emerge and disappear during the 2019–2022 elections, such as Orly
Levi-Abekasis’ Gesher, Moshe Ya’alon’s Telem, and Naftali Bennet’s Yem-
ina. Interestingly, also from a comparative perspective, personal parties are
often characterized by a short lifespan: it is quite unlikely that a personal
party successfully survives after the founder-leader leaves, given his/her
centrality.
In this chapter, I will focus on three prominent parties: Likud, which at the
time of writing is the ruling party and has been the most successful party
in Israel since 1977; Yesh Atid, which is the second-largest party and the
main governing alternative in Israel today; and the Labour Party, which,
together with its predecessors, dominated Israeli politics from the establish-
ment of the state until 1977 and later returned to power three times (1984 in a
unity government, 1992, and 1999). However, since then Labour constitutes
the clearest example of the process of party decline. The changing Knesset
representation of the three parties is shown in Figure 13.5.
50
45 44
40 40
39 38
35 34 35
34
32 31 32
30 30 29
27 Likud
MKs
25 24
22 23
Labor
20 19 20 19
18 18 19
17 Yesh Atid
15 15 15
12 13 13 13
10 11
6 7
5 5
3 4
0
88
92
96
99
03
06
09
13
15
a
b
20
21
22
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Likud
of interest groups such as the unions and right-wing settlers. As noted, these
factors have also damaged the party’s public image. The primaries likewise
imposed a heavy economic and regulatory burden on the party. Moreover,
the party’s democratic and judicial institutions have been embroiled in end-
less internal confrontations and find themselves increasingly occupied with
procedures rather than essence.
Furthermore, Likud has experienced financial difficulties. Like other par-
ties in Israel, most of the party’s revenue comes from party funding (in 2018,
85%; State Comptroller 2021a). The party generates some money from mem-
to YouTube and Facebook. However, Likud’s online activity reflects the per-
sonalization of the party: politicians, first and foremost Netanyahu, are much
more prominent on platforms such as Facebook and Twitter than the party
itself (Rahat 2022).
Labour
before the 2021 elections employed, for the first time, the zipper mechanism
to ensure gender equality. As a result, four of its seven MPs after the 2021 elec-
tions, and three out of four following the 2022 elections, were women. Unlike
Likud, it has had female leaders—Golda Me’ir in 1969, Shelly Yachimovich
in 2013, and Merav Michaeli since 2021.
In stark contrast to Likud, Labour demonstrates little loyalty to its leaders.
Between 1992 and 2022 it had 12 leaders. This indicates high competitive-
ness, a democratic feature. However, such turnover seems to have reached a
damaging level. Like most other parties, Labour has witnessed political per-
communities). Its power gradually decreased, and by the late 1990s it had
almost disappeared from this arena. In 1993, eight mayors among the 30
largest cities were Labour Party representatives, but in 2018 this number
decreased to 1. The proportion of Labour representatives in these cities’
councils decreased from 23% to 2%.
There are several reasons for Labour’s steep decline. First, like Social
Democratic parties in Europe, Labour suffered from the decline and to
some extent disintegration of the working class. Second, the dovish positions
espoused by the party became much less popular with the outbreak of vio-
Yesh Atid
Yair Lapid, a journalist and media celebrity, founded Yesh Atid (‘There Is a
Future’) on the eve of the 2013 elections. The party has won between 11 and
24 seats in each Knesset election since then. In the 2019–2020 elections Yesh
exposure of various aspects connected to its internal affairs) and female rep-
resentation (Rahat and Shapira 2015; Shapira and Freedman 2019). Lapid
determines the gender balance of the party candidate list (it has no gen-
der quotas). Nine out of 24 of the party’s MPs after the 2022 elections were
women (37.5%), of which three were located in the top five positions on the
party list.
However, all these undemocratic characteristics are also found in the other
personal parties. The interesting question is, therefore, what distinguishes
Yesh Atid? Why has it succeeded where other personal parties have failed?
Israeli democracy faces severe challenges. Among them are veteran chal-
lenges such as the occupation of parts of the West Bank, whose residents are
not Israeli citizens; the status of Arab citizens of Israel; and the influence of
the Jewish religion on the public sphere. A newer challenge is the populist and
to some extent anti-liberal and anti-democratic tendencies that have emerged
in recent years.
This last trend culminated in the current government, which was formed
following the 2022 elections, with the participation of Likud, the ultra-
religious parties, and the parties that make up the Religious Zionism electoral
list. The coalition agreements signed before the formation of the govern-
ment include highly problematic clauses from a liberal-democratic point of
view, such as the abolition of some of the bans on discrimination, espe-
cially on an ethnic and gender basis; expanding the influence of religious
institutions and practices on public life; and amendments to the Knesset Elec-
tions Law that will make it easier to disqualify Arab lists and candidates. The
government itself includes ministers such as Itamar Ben-Gvir, chairman of
the far-right Jewish National Front party, who was previously convicted of
incitement to racism and membership in a terrorist organization. At the time
of writing (March 2023), the coalition is rapidly advancing a series of bills
that would severely undermine the independence and power of the Israeli
judicial system—placing the judicial selection process under the control of
the coalition as well as almost cancelling the High Court’s ability to review
bills and government decisions. This legislation has met with a large protest
movement, which includes many of the Israeli (legal, economic, security,
academic) elite, and it is difficult to predict the final result.
Political Parties and Democracy 281
that have made Yesh Atid successful. It seems that parties these days need to
be more professional and less political in their management; to adopt more
flexible models for intra-party participation, especially allowing activists to
choose their preferred forms (e.g. adding the status of ‘supporters’ who are
not official members) and areas of activity; to strengthen ties with society in
various arenas, such as local government; to conduct themselves in a more
responsible manner, including increasing grassroots fundraising efforts; and
to expand and upgrade social media activity in a way that will integrate the
personal and the partisan.
Notes
1. All data concerning the parties’ electoral support in different sectors and localities are
based on: Kenig and Rahat (2023).
2. All data concerning the parties’ achievements in local elections are based on: Kenig and
Rahat (2023).
3. All data concerning party membership are based on: Kenig and Rahat (2023).
4. Yisrael Beiteinu, founded by Avigdor Lieberman in the run-up to the 1999 elections, is
also a successful personal party. Yet it is significantly smaller than Yesh Atid and partially
relies on a sectoral basis of immigrants from the former USSR.
5. For more recommendations, see: Shapira et al. (2021).
References
Akzin, Benjamin. 1955. ‘The Role of Parties in Israel Democracy’. Journal of Democ-
racy, 17(4):507–545.
Ben-Bassat, Avi and Momi Dahan. 2014. Reforms, Politics, and Corruption.
Jerusalem: The Israel Democracy Institute (in Hebrew).
Böhmelt, Tobias, Lawrence Ezrow, and Roni Lehrer. 2022. ‘Populism and Intra-Party
Democracy—Do They Practice What They Preach?’. European Journal of Political
Research, 61(4):1143–1154.
284 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Calise, Mauro. 2015. ‘The Personal Party: An Analytical Framework’. Italian Political
Science Review/Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica, 45(3):301–315.
Central Elections Committee. 2022. ‘Actual Results of the Elections to the 25th
Knesset’. https://votes25.bechirot.gov.il/ (Accessed 14 October 2023).
Dalton, Russel J. and Martin P. Wattenberg. 2000. Parties without Partisans: Political
Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Döring, Holger, Constantin Huber, and Philip Manow. 2022. Parliaments and Gov-
ernments Database (ParlGov): Information on Parties, Elections and Cabinets in
Established Democracies. Development Version. https://www.parlgov.org/data-
Rahat, Gideon and Assaf Shapira. 2015. The Intra-party Democracy Index 2015.
https://www.idi.org.il/articles/3501 (Accessed 31 October 2021) (in Hebrew).
Shamir, Michal, Shira Dvir-Gvirsman, and Rafael Ventura. 2017. ‘Taken Captive by
the Collective Identity Cleavage: Left and Right in the 2015 Elections’. In Michal
Shamir and Gideon Rahat (eds), The Elections in Israel 2015. New York: Routledge,
139–164.
Shapira, Assaf and Avital Freedman. 2019. The Intra-Party Democracy Index 2019,
Available at: https://www.idi.org.il/articles/26503 (Accessed 31 October 2021) (in
Hebew).
Introduction
Until recently, the Mexican party system was one of the most stable and insti-
tutionalized in Latin America. Mexican parties were disciplined and relatively
strong organizations (Greene 2007; Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018a,
2018b; Mainwaring 2018). However, these conditions have changed with the
two recent national elections (presidential elections in 2018 and legislative
elections in 2021)1 revealing a very different outlook (Garrido and Freiden-
berg 2020). The electoral outcomes portray the recently formed National
Regeneration Movement (MORENA hereafter) as unequivocally dominant
over long-standing political parties in Mexico. A dominant party in Mexican
politics is not a new phenomenon; witness the seven-decade rule of the Insti-
tutional Revolutionary Party (PRI hereafter) until the 2000 national election
(Greene 2007).2 But is MORENA’s swift ascendancy the product of the inher-
ent instability that poor governance outcomes and presidential multi-party
systems create in Latin America, or is it the result of some of the factors that
helped the PRI achieve dominance in the past?
I pose that poor governance outcomes are relevant factors that have led to a
weakening of parties in Mexico and instability in the Mexican party system. I
also pose that some factors that contributed to the PRI maintaining power for
seven decades are enabling the current dominance of MORENA. In addition,
the popularity, populist appeals, and electoral strategies of President Andrés
Manuel López Obrador (AMLO hereafter) have played a relevant role in the
rise of MORENA as currently the dominant party in Mexican politics. Fol-
lowing this, I argue that MORENA’s dominance in the future will depend on
the extent to which MORENA continues strengthening its connections with
Aldo F. Ponce, The Weakening of the Mexican Party System. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Aldo F. Ponce (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0014
290 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
society, and on the future success of the populist appeals of its leader, AMLO,
who was elected President of Mexico in 2018.
Before the victory of AMLO and MORENA in the 2018 national elec-
tion, the Mexican party system comprised three major parties—the PRI, the
National Action Party (PAN), and the Party of the Democratic Revolution
(PRD)—and some minor parties with a much lower share of electoral sup-
port. The PAN is a centre-right confessional party founded in 1939 which
remained relatively small during the PRI’s dominance; it won its first guber-
natorial elections and legislative seats in the 1990s (Loaeza 1999). Until 2018,
61
51
41
31
21
1
7
4*
99
00
00
00
00
01
01
01
02
02
–1
–2
–2
–2
–2
–2
–2
–2
–2
–2
–9
94
97
00
03
06
09
12
15
18
21
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) National Action Party (PAN)
Party of the Democratic Revolution (PRD) National Regeneration Movement (MORENA)
Labor Party (PT) Mexican Green Ecologist Party (PVEM)
Citizens’ Movement (MC) New Alliance Party (PANAL)
Social Encounter Party (PES)
Figure 14.1 Evolution of seat shares in the Mexican Chamber of Deputies by party
Source: Authorʼs elaboration based on data from the National Electoral Institute ∗estimated; taken
from Infobae (2021)
4.5
3.5
2.5
2
1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021
ENEP ENLP
Figure 14.2 Evolution of the effective number of electoral parties and the effective
number of legislative parties
ENEP—effective number of electoral parties; ENLP—effective number of legislative parties; figures
for the periods 1991–1994 and 1994–1997 are taken from Garrido and Freidenberg (2020)
Source: Authorʼs elaboration based on data from Gallagher (2023)
Organizational
Organizational capacities
capacities
Membership as a proportion of the electorate + 0.38% 7.62% 0.45% 6.29%
Number of party members 923,861 9,934,820 484,800 2,590,972
Number of party members (updated December 2020) ∗∗ 278,322 1,578,242 234,450 1,250,034
National party income 101,648,192 1,360,270,592∗ 969,531,648 870,428,928
Percentage of income from state funding + 98.4% 97.48% 96.34% 97.78%
Percentage of income from party members + 1.6% 2.52% 3.66% 2.22%
Share direct public subsidies of party’s national income 90% 90% 90% 90%
Subsidy allocation based on Votes Votes Votes Votes
Campaign spending 23,457,274 306,726,482 257,623,465 196,394,734
Full-time employees in national party headquarters 90 132 352 200
∗∗∗
Sub-organizations
Sub-organizations
Women’s sub-organizations Yes Yes Yes Yes
Youth sub-organizations Yes Yes Yes Yes
Senior sub-organizations No Yes No No
Farmer’s sub-organizations Yes Yes No No
Ethnic/linguistic groups Yes Yes No Yes
Continued
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/book/58013 by guest on 17 November 2024
Table 14.1 Continued
Rules
Rules regulating
regulating participation
participation
Voting eligible at party congress All attending All attending All members, All attending
members members attending or not members
Membership must be sponsored No No Yes No
Members must affirm principles Yes Yes Yes Yes
Dues requirement for members Yes Yes Yes Yes
Voting eligible at party congress: All party members in Yes Yes No Yes
attendance∗∗∗∗
Voting eligible: All party members, attending or not∗∗∗∗
Women’s representation at party conferences, party statute rules 50% gender 50% gender 50% gender 50% gender
equality equity equity equity
Women’s share of party’s total candidates in the most recent 50% 42.9% 50% 50%
national elections for the national legislature
Local-level organizations’
Local-level organizations’ prerogatives
prerogatives
Voting eligible: delegates from local or regional parties Yes Yes No Yes
Receives subsidy Yes Yes Yes Yes
success of MORENA. The next section elaborates on the first type of fac-
tors, which are the structural determinants that explain the recent instability
and fragility of the Mexican party system. The following section discusses the
reasons why the Mexican party system appears dislocated, with one relatively
new party currently dominating the others. In doing so, I offer an analysis on
how MORENA has been constructing its swift dominance over other parties.
The last section concludes the discussion and offers suggestions for further
research.
The current literature has identified three possible explanations for the rise
of MORENA. First, voters’ frustration about persisting levels of poverty and
inequality, as well as low economic growth, could have led voters to support
a party advocating change (Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018b; Espinoza
Pedraza 2019; Gegg 2020; Sánchez-Talanquer and Greene 2021). Neither the
PRI nor the PAN offered solutions to these social problems. The Mexican
state falls short in providing sufficient capacities and resources to guarantee
social and citizen rights (Sánchez-Talanquer and Greene 2021). For instance,
its social spending represents only 10.9% of gross domestic product (in 2019),
far below the spending levels of other OECD countries (Hannan et al. 2021;
Sánchez-Talanquer and Greene 2021). It is difficult for the Mexican state to
boost productivity, as it has relatively low taxes and public investment levels
remain low compared to those of other OECD countries (Sánchez-Talanquer
and Greene 2021). The scale of the problem is highlighted by the fact that 51%
of Mexicans prior to the 2018 election were earning less than enough to afford
basic goods and services (Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018b, Sánchez-
Talanquer and Greene 2021). Employing a populist discourse, AMLO has
repeatedly criticized this poor performance to weaken support for his rivals
(Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018b).
The second potential explanation relates to Mexico’s high crime rates
since 2007 (Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018b; Gegg 2020; Prud’Homme
2020; Sánchez-Talanquer and Greene 2021). When former President Felipe
Calderón from the PAN decided to shift policy to a confrontational crack-
down on illegal drug trafficking, the public security forces concentrated on
capturing or killing leaders or lieutenants of criminal organizations (Flores
2009; Chabat 2010; Montero 2012; Ríos 2012; Atuesta and Ponce 2017). This
296 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Toledo and Navarrete Vela 2016).16 The party was born from an alliance of
several groups with diverse ideologies (mostly leftists, but also conservatives
from evangelical organizations) and from different parties and organizations,
the majority from the PRD, but also from the PAN, the PRI, and labour
unions (Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018b; Espinoza Pedraza 2019).
Several reasons could have led AMLO to form this new party. First, he
could have perceived the weakening of the political establishment due to
the economic and societal problems discussed in Section II. In particular,
given the PRD’s weakness, AMLO initially planned that MORENA would be
when AMLO resigned following his electoral defeat in 2012. AMLO stated
that he resigned because the PRD had signed the ‘Pacto for México’, an inter-
party agreement to implement structural reforms in Mexico (Lucca, 2020).
Since the PRD was formed by different leftist groups and parties, the absence
of AMLO as a unifying force prompted the reemergence of differences among
these groups (Prud’Homme 2020). Internal conflicts reached a boiling point
when one faction of the party, ‘Nueva Izquierda’, opposed the resignation
of the governor of the state of Guerrero, Ángel Aguirre, who was somehow
linked to the massacre of 46 students (El Universal 2020). Due to this oppo-
and insulate him from problems arising from these conflicts. Unlike these
skirmishes in MORENA, conflicts in opposition parties have tended to pro-
duce scandals, breaks in their ranks, and difficulties in rapidly adapting to
the overwhelming competition from MORENA.
Third, AMLO has also criticized the functioning of several constitutionally
autonomous institutions, undermining independence from the executive.
This strategy has also contributed to strengthening his reputation as a keen
reformist. Rather than cultivating a typical reputation as a leftist party,
AMLO has aimed to shape MORENA’s image as a reformist and inclu-
It is possible to learn several lessons from this chapter. First, the Mexican
political system is currently under stress. While the first group of factors,
which I call the ‘structural effect’, partially explains the rise of MORENA
and the recent instability of the Mexican party system, it falls well short
of accounting for MORENA’s electoral success in the most recent legisla-
tive election which occurred in 2021. The second group of factors seems
to better explain this outcome. These factors pertain to the strategies and
actions that AMLO and MORENA adopted. MORENA has been increasingly
acquiring more organizational capacity and political power at the expense
of other parties in Mexico. AMLO implemented an aggressive populist dis-
course against opposition parties’ leadership that portrays them as ‘corrupt’.
AMLO’s attacks also targeted governors, high-level public bureaucrats, physi-
cians, and scholars22 that criticize MORENA’s government or hold (or held)
links with opposition parties to weaken them. Simultaneously, AMLO sought
to increase support for his ‘crusade’ against the ‘corrupt’ (Sánchez-Talanquer
and Greene 2021). On many occasions, AMLO complemented his populist
rhetoric with accusations that the Attorney General of Mexico made against
certain troubling rivals or critics.
Second, AMLO’s skill in connecting with voters through these pop-
ulist tactics has contributed to MORENA’s current advantageous position.
MORENA currently holds control of Congress and has been compromising
302 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Notes
1. In Mexico, while presidential and Senate elections occur every six years, the Chamber of
Deputies is renewed every three years.
2. PRI’s dominance was possible thanks to a broad coalition of organizations and soci-
etal sectors such as labour unions, the industrial bourgeoisie, regional elites, government
workers, and the working classes (Greene 2007; Greene and Sánchez-Talanquer 2018a).
3. This figure, like those of the other parties, is likely to be inflated as parties do not
update their membership lists. In order to keep their registration as parties, they
304 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
must demonstrate they have a number of members no less than 0.26% of those
who could have voted in the previous federal election. Recently, the electoral author-
ity, the Instituto Nacional Electoral, asked parties to update their membership lists.
For further information, see https://centralelectoral.ine.mx/2020/02/18/concluye-ine-
procedimiento-actualizacion-padrones-militancia-los-partidos-politicos/
4. The source of these figures is the Political Party Database Project (Poguntke et al.
2020).
5. The PRI inherited its strong party organization from its authoritarian past. The PAN and
the PRD had invested in building strong organizations to put an end to the PRI regime.
Such strategies have been also observed in other countries ruled by dominant parties
14. AMLO was a prior member of the PRI and then of the PRD. When the PRD was formed
in 1989, AMLO decided to join this party, and he repeated the same strategy with
MORENA.
15. This coalition was formed by the PRD, the PT, and Convergencia.
16. AMLO resigned as a member of the PRD on 9 September 2012 (Prud’Homme 2020).
MORENA was then registered as a political party in 2014 (Zepeda 2014).
17. The rate of economic growth was −0.05% in 2019 and −8.24% in 2020 (The World Bank
2021).
18. The alliance of MORENA, the PT, and the PVEM, called Juntos Haremos Historia,
achieved 56% of available seats in the Chamber of Deputies.
References
Atuesta, Laura H. and Aldo F. Ponce. 2017. ‘Meet the Narco: Increased Competition
among Criminal Organisations and the Explosion of Violence in Mexico’. Global
Crime, 18(4):375–402.
Brooks, Daruis. 2020. ‘México: El Inédito Rol del Ejército y la Marina en el Gobierno
de AMLO (Más Allá de la Seguridad Pública)’, BBC News Mundo, December 1.
https://www.bbc.com/mundo/noticias-54850024 (Accessed 15 December 2023).
Bruhn, Kathleen. 1997. ‘The Seven-month Itch: Neoliberal Politics, Popular Move-
ments, and the Left in Mexico’. In Douglas Chalmers, Carlos Vilas, Katherine Hite,
Scott Martin, Kerianne Piester, and Monique Segarra (eds), The New Politics of
Gegg, Madeline. 2020. ‘The Mexican Voter Transformed: MORENA Success in the
Wake of Party System Failure’. Honors Theses, 1401. https://egrove.olemiss.edu/
cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=2406&context=hon_thesis (Accessed 15 December
2023).
Greene, Kenneth F. 2007. Why Dominant Parties Lose: Mexico’s Democratization in
Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Greene, Kenneth F. and Mariano Sánchez-Talanquer, M. 2018a. ‘Authoritarian Lega-
cies and Party System Stability in Mexico’. In Scott Mainwaring (ed.), Party Systems
in Latin America: Institutionalization, Decay, and Collapse. New York: Cambridge
Lucca, Juan Bautista. 2020. ‘Teoría y Política en la Génesis de MORENA como Nuevo
Partido’. Estudios Políticos, 49:37–59.
Lupu, Noam. 2014. ‘Brand Dilution and the Breakdown of Political Parties in Latin
America’. World Politics, 66(4):561–602.
Lupu, Noam. 2018. ‘Party Brands, Partisan Erosion, and Party Breakdown’. In Scott
Mainwaring (ed.), Party Systems in Latin America: Institutionalization, Decay, and
Collapse. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 359–379.
Mainwaring, Scott (ed.) 2018. Party Systems in Latin America: Institutionalization,
Decay, and Collapse. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Reina, Elena. 2021. ‘López Obrador le Otorga más Poder al Ejército: El Tren
Maya será Patrimonio Militar’. El País, March 17. https://elpais.com/mexico/
2021-03-18/lopez-obrador-le-otorga-mas-poder-al-ejercito-el-tren-maya-sera-
patrimonio-militar.html (Accessed 15 December 2023).
Roberts, Kenneth M. 2014. Changing Course: Parties, Populism, and Political Rep-
resentation in Latin America’s Neoliberal Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Rojas, Javier and Aldo F. Ponce. 2021. ‘Lento or Presto? Subnational Government
Capacities and the Pace of Implementation of Contentious Policies’. Education
Introduction
Laura Wills-Otero, The Colombian Party System, 1991–2022. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Laura Wills-Otero (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0015
The Colombian Party System, 1991–2022 311
to survive and have remained key players (Wills-Otero 2014). Other parties
that emerged after the enactment of the 1991 Constitution and the politi-
cal reform of 2003 have become prominent actors in the coalitions of the
different governments, or in the opposition.
Thus, although the high levels of volatility and effective parties explain the
system’s tendency towards deinstitutionalization, they also demonstrate its
flexibility. At critical junctures in particular, flexibility has prevented crises
similar to those that have occurred in some of the region’s other countries
mentioned above. The collapse of party systems in these countries has pro-
the variation in the electoral results. In the next section, I provide a brief
overview of the rules of the electoral system over time (1991–2022) and their
consequences for the party system. I then analyse and compare the electoral
performance of the Centro Democrático (CD) and Comunes and discuss
how these two cases illustrate some of the broader characteristics of the sys-
tem. Finally, I offer a set of conclusions on the prospects for Colombian
democracy in light of its party system.
The political charter enacted in 1991 defined the ground rules that were
intended to open up the political regime, which was classified as a restrictive
two-party system (Botero et al. 2016). Rights, guarantees, and requirements
were established to create new parties and promote their participation in
the country’s political life. As of that year, the number of parties in the sys-
tem increased significantly, with some of these involving dissidents from the
PL and PC. Others emerged as new political alternatives. Among the latter,
the Alianza Democrática M-19 (AD-M-19) emerged from successful negoti-
ations between the National Government and various insurgent groups that
agreed to demobilize in exchange for the possibility of becoming a politi-
cal option (Boudon 2001). The 1991–2002 period saw an explosion of new
political parties and movements, leading to the fragmentation of the multi-
party system. During the same period, the electoral system that had been in
place, which had allowed political parties to register an unlimited number of
lists in the elections to collegiate bodies, promoted internal party fragmenta-
tion. In 2002, about 40 political parties and movements elected seats in the
Congress of the Republic (Wills-Otero 2011). Several of these parties were
dissidents from the two traditional parties, and very few of the new play-
ers managed to consolidate themselves as stable and viable organizations.
The sub-national sphere was also subject to an average increase in parti-
san options. The political decentralization that began at the end of the 1980s
with the popular election of mayors and further consolidated after the 1991
Constitution with the popular election of governors led to the emergence of
new local and regional electoral mechanisms. After the introduction of these
reforms, political competition, and configurations at the national, regional,
and local levels varied significantly (Hoyos 2007; Batlle et al. 2020; Pino
The Colombian Party System, 1991–2022 313
Finally, the signing of the peace agreement in 2016 between the National
Government and FARC-EP established that as of the following elections
and for two consecutive periods (2018–2026), the political party emerging
from the demobilized group would be guaranteed a portion of power in the
Congress of the Republic. The agreement defined 10 seats—5 in the Senate of
the Republic and 5 in the House of Representatives. In addition, an Opposi-
tion Statute was approved as law (Law 1909 of 2018) that provided guarantees
to opposition and independent parties. This includes, for example, rights
such as obtaining state financing, access to the state’s social communication
Alianza Verde (3,7%). When comparing this information with the previous
four-year period (2018–2022), there appear to be changes that account for
the electoral volatility of the party system. Between 2018 and 2022, politi-
cal parties emerged and disappeared. Those that were able to obtain political
representation in both elections increased or decreased their relative power.
This behaviour was repeated in each election and is mainly due to the emer-
gence of new parties and the decline (and eventual disappearance) of existing
ones (Gutiérrez 2007). Table 15.2 presents the political composition of the
legislature between 2018 and 2022.
The negotiations between the Colombian government and the oldest guer-
rilla group in Latin America, the FARC-EP, caused a political split that
resulted in the creation of two new ideologically opposed parties: CD
and Comunes (originally called the Fuerza Alternativa Revolucionaria del
Común, or FARC-EP). The first was created in 2014 under the leadership
of former president Álvaro Uribe, with one of its main objectives being to
oppose the negotiations that the then-government was holding in Havana,
Cuba. The second was a concrete derivation of the agreement that was estab-
lished around the issue of political participation by the former guerrilla
group. Without the certainty of obtaining a share of power in the Congress of
the Republic, as well as rights and guarantees to exercise opposition, FARC-
EP would not have committed itself to moving towards demobilization,
disarmament, and reinsertion into civilian and political life.
Table 15.2 Colombian party system in the legislature, 2018–2022
Continued
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/book/58013 by guest on 17 November 2024
Table 15.2 Continued
Table 15.3 Centro Democrático and Comunes election results, 2014–2020 (% of valid
votes)
suffered by its leader, former President Uribe, who faced a judicial process.
Several prominent militants left the party/retired from politics (Ortiz and
Wills-Otero 2023).
Meanwhile, Comunes’ performance was very poor at each of the three
times it participated following its demobilization and reintegration into polit-
ical and civilian life. In 2018, its presidential candidate, Rodrigo Londoño
(alias Timochenko), withdrew from the campaign due to security concerns,
as he had received several death threats. In the 2018 and 2022 legislative
elections, the party aspired to obtain more seats than it had agreed with
earned the organization 20 Senate seats and made it the second strongest
force in the institution. In the presidential elections, the former president was
also a deciding factor in the newly created party’s victory in the first electoral
round in 2014, and in reaching the presidency in the second round in 2018.
In 2022, the decline of Uribe’s prestige harmed the political party.
In the case of Comunes, Rodrigo Londoño’s leadership and presidential
candidacy were detrimental to the party. During the public events in which
he participated throughout the 2018 campaign, he was the target of aggres-
sive attacks by his detractors. Several threats to his life led him to withdraw
fully complied with, and are even changed during the selection process. In the
case of CD, Uribe centralizes the process and is the one who makes many of
the final decisions concerning the definition of candidacies (Ortiz and Wills-
Otero 2023). For Comunes, in contrast, the party’s internal fragmentation
hinders the selection process.
Political parties in Colombia are still not clear about how many militants
and affiliates are involved in them. Their estimates are made on the basis of
the number of votes they obtain in each election (El Nuevo Siglo 2019). Even
so, the information offered by different media and other sources suggests that
adults over 50 years of age, and people from the highest (6) and lowest
(1) socio-economic strata (Semana 2019).4
The two parties can be differentiated in terms of their ideologies and pro-
grammatic agendas, and it is these characteristics that point to the rupture
that gave rise to their emergence. As mentioned above, the 2012–2016 peace
process involving the national government and the guerrilla group produced
incentives for the formation of these parties. CD was created in 2014 and
participated in the national elections of that year. Its goal at that time was to
gain political power, prevent the re-election of the president, and redefine the
[the] capitalist social order in force in Colombian society…, and the promotion of
an alternative model in which there is social justice; real and advanced democracy;
the overcoming of all exclusion, discrimination or segregation for economic, social,
ethnic or gender reasons; the guarantee of life and dignified existence…, the con-
struction of a new political economy that guarantees the material realization of
human rights. (Art. 5, Estatutos del Partido)
structures, added to its status as an opposition party with little relative power
and weak internal cohesion.
The internal discipline of the two parties and their ability to act cohe-
sively vary both between the two and within each. The early years of CD’s
political activity (2014–2018) were characterized by the high level of disci-
pline that the party recorded in its legislative performance. At the time, CD
defined itself as an opposition party, and its purpose was to delay initiatives
promoted by the coalition parties of the government of Juan Manuel San-
tos, especially those related to the implementation of the peace agreement
been internal fractures, which led some of its members of Congress to request
a split (El Espectador 2021).
Conclusions
after the 1991 Constitution have managed to establish themselves. Among the
latter, left and centre parties that had no place in the system before 1991—
e.g., Polo Democrático, Partido Verde and more recently the PH coalition
(2022)—have become options that revitalize and strengthen the country’s
democracy. Over time, they have gained rights and guarantees that create
favourable conditions for their survival.
Thus, without ignoring the problems arising from the deinstitutionaliza-
tion of the party system, we must also recognize that preventing system
collapse favours the democratic regime, and that the existence of plural-
Notes
1. This chapter was drafted for the ‘Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy’ confer-
ence, organized by the Konrad Adenauer Stiftung Foundation, held in Madrid, Spain,
on 7–8 October 2021. I want to thank the conference participants for their questions
and feedback, and particularly, Wilhelm Hofmeister and Thomas Poguntke for their
comments. Also, I would like to thank Editage (www.editage.com) for English language
editing.
2. Before 1991, the effective number of parties was two. It increased to eight between 1991
and 2002 and decreased to seven in the senate elections after 2003 (Castañeda 2018).
3. For the Senate, the threshold corresponds to 3% of the valid votes. For the lower chamber,
the threshold corresponds to half of the electoral quotient, which is calculated by dividing
the total number of votes in a specific constituency by the total number of seats available
in that constituency.
4. This information needs to be confirmed. In the case of Comunes, there are no sources
that provide any relevant information.
5. During Uribe’s two consecutive administrations, the guerrillas were militarily under-
mined and paramilitary groups were demobilized as a consequence of a law passed by
congress (Law 975 of 2005). The rate of extortive kidnappings and homicides dropped
significantly during this period (Rettberg 2020). This was one of the factors behind the
former president’s popularity and his ability, years later, to lead the creation of the new
party.
The Colombian Party System, 1991–2022 329
References
Rodríguez-Raga, Juan Carlos, and Laura Wills-Otero. 2021. ‘La renovación del
conservadurismo tradicional a través de nuevos partidos: El caso del Centro
Democrático en Colombia, 2014–2018’. Revista Uruguaya de Ciencia Política,
30(1):79–104.
Semana. 2019. ‘¿Quiénes son los duquistas?’, 9 June. https://www.semana.com/
nacion/articulo/quienes-son-los-colombianos-que-apoyan-a-duque/619007/
(Accessed 16 December 2023).
UN Women. 2019. El camino hacia la paridad en el Congreso Colombiano: la
Representación política de las mujeres de las elecciones de 2018. Bogotá: UN Women
Since 1985, Brazil has been going through a process of democratic stabi-
lization while facing a series of challenges: party fragmentation, polarization
between political forces, fluid political careers, corruption, and widespread
distrust of the electorate in relation to the parties. All the factors that led to the
critical 2018 election with the victory of a right-wing populist candidate, Jair
Bolsonaro, mirror this scenario (McKenna, 2020). Elected by a party with-
out wide national representation, Bolsonaro shortly thereafter left that party
and remained two years in government without party affiliation.1 His gov-
ernment, with anti-partisan strategies in Congress, marks a cycle of crises for
traditional parties that began in 2013. These conjunctural aspects are added
to historical and structural aspects that reflect the characteristics and trends
of the new Brazilian democracy.
The development of the Brazilian case allows us to assess to what extent
and in which ways the country’s parties have performed the basic functions
demanded of them in representative democracies: political representation,
selection and recruitment of members, and the elaboration of public policies.
The history of instability and short-lived parties in the country also reveals a
rationale with characteristics that do not always align with classical typolo-
gies such as the emergence of modern parties of ‘cadres and masses’ at the
end of the 19th century (Duverger 1979), or of catch-all parties that arose
from transformations in the European political and electoral market after
1945 (Kirchheimer 1966). Moreover, the changes in organizational models
highlighted in contemporary theories, such as the phenomenon of carteliza-
tion of parties and party systems (Katz and Mair 1995) and the formatting
of the professional–electoral party (Panebianco 2005), are not sufficient to
Silvana Krause and Bruno Marques Schaefer, Political Parties in Brazil. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Silvana Krause and Bruno Marques Schaefer
(2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0016
Political Parties in Brazil 333
accentuated. For example, the voters’ confidence in parties reached its low-
est percentage in 2018 (6.20%), with the most trusted institutions being the
church and the armed forces (Barômetro das Américas 2019)
80
60
40
20
Table 16.1 Sources of the resources for Brazilian general elections, 2002–2022 in
million dollars ($) and proportional (%) values
Source: Elaborated from data by Mancuso (2020) and information available with the Supreme Electoral
Court
∗
The resources were adjusted for inflation as in December 2020. After this procedure, it was further
adjusted considering the dollar quotes for the same period.
338 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
was the sectors most dependent on the state, such as civil construction, which
ended up investing proportionally more in elections. In 2014, companies in
the civil construction sector represented around 6% of the Brazilian GDP
but 27% of total business donations. The manufacturing sector represented
12% of GDP but 35% of total contributions. The distribution of company
resources followed a catch-all pattern for the benefit of the largest Brazilian
parties (and several candidates within them) and without ideological distinc-
tions (Krause et al. 2015). In the case of the 2014 presidential elections, the
three best-placed candidates in electoral polls accounted for 99.7% of the total
In the following sections, we discuss the three main Brazilian parties in terms
of their origins, political representation, resources, ideologies, and internal
dynamics. The weight of these parties has declined. In 1994, the three par-
ties held 42.9% of the seats in the Chamber of Deputies; in 2018 this figure
fell to 22.8%. Figure 16.3 illustrates membership development in relation to
total number of voters who are members of a party and to data on party pref-
erence.7 There was a trend of decreasing membership in all parties and a
decrease in preference, apart from the Worker’s Party (PT), which in 2018
had a significant recovery.
20,00
15,00
10,00
5,00
0,00
2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
Figure 16.3 Party preference and membership as a proportion of the electorate (M/E)
Source: Brazilian Electoral Studies (ESEB) and TSE
340 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
MDB-PMDB
Funding
First, the financing profile of MDB reveals the insignificance of the party
members in sustaining its operation and their dependence on public
resources (in 2018, practically 100% of the budget). Second, the most sig-
nificant impact of corporate financing in election years (2008, 2010, 2014)
challenge. Its loyalty ties with the electorate were tenuous and sustained by
regional leaders, which also explains its electoral downfall in recent years and
difficulties in controlling the country’s executive seat.
PSDB
PT
Funding
Resources from members represented, on average, more than 10% of the
party’s budget, considering the period 2007–2018, unlike the profile from
other parties. In recent years, however, the party has focused almost exclu-
sively on state resources for its maintenance.
Conclusion
In Brazil, political parties were held responsible for the low quality, or incom-
pleteness, of the new democracy during the 1990s and the beginning of
The rise of a right-wing populist government without stable party ties and
the deterioration of democracy19 was related to this scenario regarding the
main parties. These parties have been challenged to answer for their grow-
ing dependence on public resources, diminishing representation, difficulty
in mobilizing members and recruiting new leaders, and lack of cohesive
action in the face of a government that disrupted the country’s political
institutions.
The main leaders of the two centrist parties supported Bolsonaro’s right-
wing populist candidacy in the 2018 runoff. They also later failed to lead a
The 2022 election presented distinct challenges and outcomes for the
two centrist parties. PSDB, for the first time, did not present a presidential
candidate and has since faced internal conflicts between leaders who have
positioned themselves for leadership in the organization. The party was the
one that lost the most representation in the legislature, and in the second
round it did not have a cohesive position on which candidate to support, leav-
ing the regional directorates free to decide for either Lula or Bolsonaro. MDB
had a recovery of representation in the legislature and presented a woman
as a candidate for the presidency: Simone Tebet. Her support grew during
Notes
References
Ignazi, Piero. 2020. ‘The Four Knights of Intra-party Democracy: A Rescue for Party
Delegitimation’. Party Politics, 26(1):9–20.
Katz, Richard S. and Peter Mair. 1995. ‘Changing Models of Party Organization and
Party Democracy: The Emergence of the Cartel Party’. Party Politics, 1(1):5–28.
Kinzo, Maria D’A lva. 2004. ‘Partidos, eleições e democracia no Brasil pós-1985’.
Revista Brasileira de ciências sociais, 19(54):23–40.
Kirchheimer, Otto. 1966. ‘The Transformation of the Western European Party Sys-
tems’. In Joseph La Palombara and Myron Weiner (eds), Political Parties and
Political Development. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 177–200.
Argentina began to have more structured political parties towards the end of
the 19th century with the emergence of parties representing the middle- and
low-income sectors of society.1 From 1912, with the Saenz Peña law legis-
lation establishing universal, secret, and compulsory suffrage, free elections
began to be held. The first President to be elected in a transparent manner
was brought in under this law in 1916. Primarily, four parties came into being
on that occasion: the Unión Cívica Radical (‘Radical Civic Union’; UCR—
Radicals), the Conservative Party, the Progressive Democratic Party, and the
Socialist Party. The UCR was to dominate party politics until the 1930 coup,
which sparked off a period of electoral fraud.
With the 1943 coup, Peronism/Partido Justicialista (‘Justicialist Party’; PJ)
appeared on the scene. This was to become one of the major political forces
right up to the present day, and it triumphed in the 1946 elections as well, only
to be overthrown by a military coup in 1955. From then until 1973, there were
two stages of elected governments, with the exclusion of Peronism. That year
there were free elections in which the Justicialists won again. However, in
1976, another military coup installed a dictatorship until 1983. Since then,
Argentina has experienced the longest democratic period in its history, with
the holding of regular free elections along the lines established by the national
constitution.
The 1994 constitutional reform enshrined political parties as fundamen-
tal institutions of the democratic system (Zovatto 2006), establishing that
only they can present candidates for public office. The state contributes to
the financial support of their activities and the training of their leaders.
The 1994 constitutional reform also solidified a presidential political system,
Carlos Fara and José Emilio Graglia, Democracy and Political Parties in the Argentine Republic. In: Political Parties and the
Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Carlos Fara and
José Emilio Graglia (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0017
358 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
where the head of state and government is a directly elected President who
holds significant executive powers and serves as the chief executive of the
country.
An important detail incorporated in this constitutional reform is the mech-
anism of the ballot, with an unusual system for electing the President. The
incoming President is elected in one of the following three ways: 1) if a can-
didate’s party or alliance obtains more than 45% of the votes in the first round,
it is automatically the winner without the need for a second round; 2) if the
party or alliance that obtains most votes receives between 40% and 45% of
During the first stage of democracy from 1983 until the mid-1990s, a classic
two-party system prevailed. Peronism and Radicalism predominated, alter-
nating in power. During the 1980s, a centre-right party appeared—the Union
of the Democratic Centre (UCeDe)—promoting the concept of a market
economy. In the 1983 presidential election, it won just 0.17% of the vote,
while in the subsequent presidential election six years later it took 7%. This
was the beginning of a progressive fragmentation of the party system due to
the presentation of political personnel who could reach the mass electorate.
Unlike Peronism and Radicalism, it was not a big bureaucratic party but
was, primarily, a party based on public opinion, in line with contemporary
politics.
Apart from the historical parties and the successful experiences of the
FrePaSo and the PRO, presidential and legislative elections saw competition
among forces that were mainly associated with a specific person, with their
legitimacy always depending on the electoral success of such personality-
centred leadership and on favourable circumstances. These forces are what
60 54.11
51.75 51.34
49.94 48.37 48.66
47.49 48.24
50 45.29
40.16 40.28
37.1 38.27
40
29.3
30 27.05
22.25
20 17.27 16.81
10
3
3
19
15
9
7
5
01
99
00
98
98
00
99
20
20
-2
-1
-2
-1
-1
-2
-1
z-
i-
ez
úa
er
ín
em
ez
m
cr
de
nd
hn
ns
R
e
nd
a
en
en
án
M
fo
la
ná
irc
ná
sM
sM
rn
Al
io
de
er
rK
er
Fe
ric
úl
aF
rlo
aF
rlo
do
to
Ra
au
rto
in
Ca
an
és
Ca
in
M
ist
be
N
ist
rn
Cr
Al
Cr
Fe
Party Organization
Given the successive institutional interruptions that took place between 1930
and 1983, together with fraudulent practices (1930–1943) and the proscrip-
tion of Peronism (1955–1973), this chapter will focus on the description of
the party system from 1973 to the present day.
When analysing political parties in Argentina, it must be understood that
they do not correspond to European political party type that is commonly
used as a model. In Latin America, because of several variables, among them
the repeated interruption of democratic processes and the military coups that
undermine the democratic regime and its consolidation, parties have devel-
oped around various practices that were not contemplated in their founding
statutes. Hence, we must talk of parties with medium-to-low institutionaliza-
tion in that their internal life does not always follow their institutional canons,
despite them being formally organized and registered.
Historically, two parties in Argentina have been protagonists of the system:
the UCR and the PJ. The former is a middle-class party which is organized
and federal in scope. It emerged in 1891 and since then has sought to be
the opposition to the national oligarchy. It was only with the first free, secret,
compulsory, and universal elections under the Sáenz Peña Law that they won,
with Hipólito Yrigoyen as their candidate for President in 1916.
Democracy and Political Parties in the Argentine Republic 363
The membership figures of the most important parties in the country give
an insight into their organizational reach. In 2014, according to the National
Electoral Chamber, the PJ had 3,531,445 members, and the UCR, 2,136,955.2
The PRO Party had 107,944 members.
The party system in Argentina has traditionally been divided between those
As already mentioned above, the state has contributed to the economic sup-
port of parties’ activities and the training of their leaders since the 1994
constitutional reform; however, state funding also existed prior to the imple-
mentation of the reform. In national elections—given that Argentina is a
federal country—advertising in electronic media (radio and television) that
depends on a state concession is paid for by the state, thus offloading a large
proportion of the expenses involved. Funding comes from a mixture of public
and private sources.
a) Presidential elections
Among the lists presented, 50% of the amount allocated by the budget is
shared equally. For example, in the last PASO elections the public sector
gave 3,753,560.88 Argentine pesos (18,674.43 USD) to Cambiemos, to be
from the public sector was only $10 million. On the other hand, Frente para
la Victoria had received equal amounts coming from private and public sec-
tors. It is important to highlight that the public contribution depends on the
number of candidates and lists that the parties present.
In spite of these regulations, it is clear that the different political forces
always resort to some kind of extra funding, whether monetary or in kind,
which is outside the law. Moreover, those in executive positions always have
some resources from the executive that they can apply to campaigns, thus
unbalancing the competition. The main informal sources of funding are usu-
Party Communication
as the open data that was shared by its government or its communications
strategy, working intensely with social media and young people. Radicalism,
despite showing more institutional and traditional behaviour, considering
its 130-year history, has also been modernizing its communication system.
The PJ is the party with the least institutionalized behaviour, and this has an
impact on its communication policy. However, like any force with a strong
vocation for power, after its 1983 defeat it quickly incorporated the tools of
up-to-date political communication, and its leadership has been adapting
rapidly over the last 40 years.
PRO, as described above, which was born in 2001 out of the economic and
political crisis, in the context of the demand for the renewal of the political
class (‘Let’s get rid of them all’).
In view of this description, it could be said that the two historical parties
emerged out of two processes of social and economic transformation—
typical of the 19th and 20th centuries—and that the other two forces that
have appeared in the last 30 years were born out of processes of social and
political crisis that generated realignments of the representation that existed
before. As already noted, all the other political projects were more of the ‘flash
who can effectively project their message in the media. The era of mass
bureaucratic parties appears to be over.4
A successful party model would combine an extensive territorial presence
in the geographically and culturally diverse territory of a federal country with
ongoing adaptation to the use of new information technologies, taking on
board as far as possible any changes in public opinion. However, it seems
unlikely that a single force would be able to combine both factors, because
Argentina faces a major challenge with a lack of political federalization.
Argentina has had 40 years of uninterrupted democratic life with free, regular
elections. Though the system is imperfect, there have been no complaints of
fraud in national elections, and it can be said that there is a majority commit-
ment to this situation among the different parties (Ibarreche, 2017). There
are, however, many anomalous situations that distort the functioning of the
republican system through autocratic behaviour. One of them is the lack of
autonomy of the judiciary in several areas that affect the functioning of the
state and of politics.
The various pressures faced by Argentina’s democracy are similar to those
prevalent in the rest of the region:
Notes
References
Barry, Carolina. 2011. ‘Eva Perón y la Organización Política de las Mujeres’. Serie
Documentos de Trabajo, 453. Buenos Aires: Universidad del Centro de Estudios
Macroeconómicos de Argentina.
Cámara Nacional Electoral. 2014. ‘Estadística de Afiliados del segundo semestre
2014’. Registro Nacional de Agrupaciones Políticas. https://www.electoral.gov.ar/
pdf/estadistica_afiliados_2do_semestre_2014.pdf (Accessed 18 December 2023).
Cámara Nacional Electoral. 2015. Cámara Nacional Electoral Poder Judicial
De La Nación. https://www.electoral.gob.ar/pdf/cantidad_minima_de_afiliados_
requeridos_2015.pdf (Accessed 18 December 2023).
(CIPPEC), C. d. 2016. El Financiamiento de la Política Argentina. Informe del Obser-
vatorio Electoral Argentino 2016 Buenos Aires: Centro de implementación de
Políticas Públicas para la Equidad y el Crecimiento.
Corporación Latinobarómetro. 2016. Informe 2016. Santiago de Chile:
Latinobarómetro.
Financiamiento de los partidos políticos para las elecciones nacionales. (s.f.). Obtenido
de https://www.sitiosargentina.com.ar/elecciones-2011/financiamiento-partidos-
politicos.htm#:~:text=El%20sistema%20de%20financiamiento%20de%20los
%20partidos%20pol%C3%ADticos,electoral%20y%20para%20el%20sosteni
miento%20de%20sus%20actividades (Accessed 7 December 2023).
Democracy and Political Parties in the Argentine Republic 377
Alexander C. Tan
Prior to 1986, Taiwan was a one-party authoritarian state with the Kuom-
intang (KMT or Nationalist Party) having dominated the island’s politics
since 1949. Since Taiwan was technically still in a civil war with mainland
China, Taiwan’s National Assembly enacted a ‘Temporary Provisions against
the Communist Rebellion’ as a constitutional amendment that formed the
basis of the martial law which was in effect from 1949 until its repeal in
1987. Under martial law, the KMT maintained its authoritarian rule of Tai-
wan though other approved parties, such as the Chinese Youth Party and
China Democratic Socialist Party, which existed under the ‘guidance’ of the
KMT. Opposition to the KMT’s rule and the regime was not allowed to exist
(at least legally) in the form of organized political parties during this period
of martial law. However, an informal organization called the Tangwai, which
literally means ‘outside of the party’ represented the loose coalition of regime
opponents (Chao and Myers 1998; Rigger 1999).
KMT authoritarian rule affected and defined the development of Taiwan’s
eventual party system in more ways than one (Yu 2005; Tan 2021). First,
the KMT’s authoritarian regime unwittingly created the ‘mainlander versus
islander’ cleavage in Taiwan. With the defeat of the KMT in the Chinese
Civil War, the KMT established a rival government-in-exile on the island
of Taiwan, and in so doing transferred its governmental structure, party
structure, and people to Taiwan. This large, exiled group of Chinese people
(or mainlanders) made up the upper echelons of government, the mili-
tary, state-owned enterprises, and the political party apparatus, automatically
making them the political and societal elites in Taiwan. The ‘islanders’—
mostly descended from the waves of Han Chinese migration throughout
the centuries—had lived under Japanese colonization of the island and were
Alexander C. Tan, Taiwan. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm
Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Alexander C. Tan (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0018
382 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
largely kept out of national politics. One serious ramification of the whole-
sale imposition of the KMT governmental and party apparatus on Taiwan is
the unwitting creation of a ‘them’ versus ‘us’ environment that pitted main-
landers, who benefited from the system and became core of Taiwan society,
against the islanders, who remained largely in the periphery (Chao and
Myers 1998; Hsieh 1999).
Secondly, as the KMT set up its government-in-exile—the Republic of
China—on Taiwan, its politics and the unfinished civil war between the
KMT and the Chinese communists on the mainland dominated the political
are well organized and well resourced are advantaged by the SNTV electoral
rules (Hsieh 1999). The KMT, with its extensive organization and assets, is
definitely a huge beneficiary of this system. While much smaller organiza-
tionally and not as well-resourced, the DPP also benefits to some extent as it
is able to capture seats in the multi-seat electoral districts.
In 2008 Taiwan changed to the mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) sys-
tem in its legislative elections and at the same time reduced the number
of legislative seats from 225 to 113 (Hsieh 2009; Batto et al. 2016). Of the
113 legislative seats, 73 are elected single-member districts elected under the
In 2016, the opposition DPP won the presidential election and, for the first
time in Taiwan’s political history, gained a majority in the Legislative Yuan
(Taiwan’s parliament). Despite the several turnovers of the executive control
between the KMT and the DPP since 1996, Taiwan’s first true democratic
consolidation did not occur until the 2016 election, when the DPP for the
first time controlled both the executive and legislative branches and was
able to enact its own agenda. From 2000 to 2008, Taiwan’s government had
Taiwan: Party System of a Young Consolidated Democracy 385
been divided, with the DPP controlling the executive branch while the KMT
controlled the legislative majority.
After the DPP’s comprehensive victory in 2016, it was finally in a posi-
tion to enact drastic reforms to a political system designed by the KMT. The
first reform that the DPP government promulgated was to address political
party financing and party-owned assets. This had previously been a very con-
tentious issue as the KMT had a huge electoral advantage vis-à-vis the other
political parties because of its extensive party businesses and assets that easily
made it one of the richest political parties in the world.
The KMT or the Nationalist Party is one of the two major political parties
in Taiwan’s multi-party electoral democracy. Established as a revolutionary
386 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
party during the waning years of the Qing Dynasty in China, the KMT was
exiled to Taiwan and established a rival government—Republic of China
(ROC)—after it lost the Chinese Civil War in 1949 to the Chinese Commu-
nist Party that established the People’s Republic of China (PRC). Organized
as a Leninist party, the KMT imposed itself as a hegemonic and authoritarian
party that firmly established control of all aspects of political life in Taiwan
until the end of martial law in 1987 and eventual full democratization in
1996.
The KMT’s dominance of Taiwan’s politics is supported by an intensive
was pushing for a party chairperson separate from the nation’s President
(as had pertained in the past). This seemingly uncontroversial proposal was
mired in the fact that Lee Teng-hui, if elected, would have been the first
islander party chairperson and could have threatened the dominance of the
mainlanders, and that the party chairperson has control over the huge party
organization and resources, which could change the balance of power in
Taiwan.
While conflict between the mainstream and non-mainstream factions
ended with Lee Teng-hui winning the party chairmanship, the non-
Taiwan’s governing party at the time of writing, the DPP, has come a long
way from the ragtag band of opposition activists that formed in 1986, later
to become one of Taiwan’s major parties (Rigger 2001). Within 14 years, the
DPP managed to win the presidency, and by 2004 had become the largest
single party in the Legislative Yuan, effectively ending the 50-year dominance
of the KMT in Taiwan politics.
The DPP’s party manifesto espouses a Taiwan that is distinct and inde-
mogul Lin Kun-hai of the SET media empire, and the Taiwan Normal Coun-
try Promotion Association led by Speaker of the Legislative Yuan You Si-kun.
The existence of these factions does not necessarily mean that the DPP has
a low level of party unity. On the contrary, the factions have learned to co-
exist within the party and have managed to be able to maintain party unity
by sharing power between them. Key power-sharing mechanisms include
the appointment to key governmental positions and statutory boards, agen-
cies, and state-owned enterprises. Clear power sharing is evidenced by Tsai
Ing-wen as state President, Su Tseng-chang, a leading figure of the Social Wel-
Summary Evaluation
Taiwan’s party system has transformed and evolved since 1949. From 1949
to 1987, Taiwan was a one-party authoritarian state. With the political liber-
alization that began in 1987 and the subsequent death of Chiang Ching-kuo,
the political opening accelerated even further (Chao and Myers 1998). By the
first direct presidential election in 1996, Taiwan was a system with one large
dominant party—the KMT. The DPP was a competitive opposition party
but was unable to gain control of the Executive Yuan and Legislative Yuan
(Chao and Myers 1998; Tan et al. 2000; Clark and Tan 2012a). In 2000, the
DPP finally captured the state presidency and the Executive Yuan, as well as a
plurality in the Legislative Yuan. However, between 2000 and 2008 the KMT
managed to maintain control of the Legislative Yuan through the support of
the pan-Blue alliance parties. During that period, Taiwan’s party system saw
new additions to the party systems (e.g. NP, PFP, TSU), but these smaller
parties were not able to make significant inroads to wrest voter support away
from the DPP and the KMT.
From 2008 to 2016, Taiwan’s party system did not deviate from the two-
party system dominated by the KMT and the DPP (Tsai et al. 2007). During
this period, the KMT regained control of the state presidency and the Exec-
utive Yuan as well as continued control of the Legislative Yuan. The DPP
remained the most credible opposition party while the other minor parties
remained present but not significant. It was during this period that several
minor parties, such as the NP and the TSU, weakened substantially.
The 2008–2016 period in Taiwan’s history also marked closer relations
with the PRC as the KMT government was seeking a less confrontational
relations to jump-start Taiwan’s otherwise lacklustre economic performance
Taiwan: Party System of a Young Consolidated Democracy 393
under the DPP government of the prior eight years. For various reasons, the
economic rapprochement and the quickened pace of economic interaction
with the PRC caused concerns in Taiwanese society and further deep-
ened political polarization along the unification–independence cleavage
(Clark and Tan 2016; Tan 2020).9 Several new parties were established
in the period leading up to the 2016 general elections, such as the NPP,
which offers a contending approach but competes primarily along the
unification–independence dimension. The NPP advocates Taiwan’s de jure
independence and is progressive in its policy positions. It espouses positions
pan-Green parties, there is a high likelihood that new issue dimensions will
be introduced to invigorate Taiwan’s young democracy.
On the imbalance of party financial strength as an internal threat to democ-
racy, the Political Parties Act of 2017 was enacted to clearly address the huge
inequalities between the KMT and the other political parties in Taiwan’s elec-
toral politics. The Act’s financial transparency requirement has clarified the
huge disparity in assets and revenues between the KMT and the DPP. Inter-
estingly, it has also highlighted the wealth disparity between the two major
parties (KMT and DPP) versus the other minor parties in the legislature,
Notes
1. See Lipset and Rokkan (1967) on the relationship between social cleavages and political
parties and party system.
2. KMT standing committees include policy, party discipline, culture and communications,
administration, organizational development, and revolutionary practice.
3. The financial statements are available from the Ministry of Interior’s website: https://
party.moi.gov.tw/PartyFinancialChecklist.aspx?n=16101&sms=13073
4. In Taiwan’s presidential election there is no second-round voting; elections are decided
by plurality rule, i.e. a simple first-past-the-post rule.
5. In studies of complex organizations, the population ecology model argues that the
environment where organizations operate affects their organizational forms; over time
organization learning occurs as they copy successful models.
6. The financial statements are available from the Ministry of Interior’s website: https://
party.moi.gov.tw/PartyFinancialChecklist.aspx?n=16101&sms=13073
Taiwan: Party System of a Young Consolidated Democracy 397
7. Party subvention is largely in the form of state funding when a political party receives at
least 3% of the votes in a legislative election. Political parties receive US$1.79 per vote.
Prior to the enactment of the Political Party Act in December 2017, political parties
receive state funding when they receive a minimum of 3.5% of the votes in a legislative
election.
8. The comparative figures for the KMT are 15% for state subvention and 10% for political
donations.
9. A direct result of this societal anxiety of closer relations with the PRC is the Sunflower
Movement that occurred in March–April 2014. Pro-Taiwanese independence student
activists supported by pro-Taiwanese independence politicians occupied the Legislative
References
Batto, Nathan and Gary Cox. 2016. ‘Legislature-centric and Executive-centric The-
ories of Party Systems and Factional Systems’. In Nathan Batto, Gary Cox, Chi
Huang, and Alexander C. Tan (eds), Elections in Taiwan and Japan under Mixed
Member Electoral Systems and its Consequences. Ann Arbor, MI: University of
Michigan Press, 1–22.
Batto, Nathan, Gary Cox, Chi Huang, and Alexander C. Tan. (eds), 2016. Elections
in Taiwan and Japan under Mixed Member Electoral Systems and its Consequences.
Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press.
Chao, Linda and Ramon H. Myers. 1998. The First Chinese Democracy: Political Life
in the Republic of China. Baltimore: John’s Hopkins University Press.
Chung, Li-Hua and Jason Pan. 2014. “KMT is again the world’s richest party.”
Taipei Times https://www.taipeitimes.com/News/taiwan/archives/2014/07/24/
2003595820 (Accessed 16 March 2024).
Clark, Cal. 2002. ‘Democratization and the Evolving Nature of Parties, Issues, and
Constituencies in the ROC’. In Peter C. Y. Chow (ed.), Taiwan’s Modernization in
Global Perspective. Westport, CT: Praeger, 135–159.
Clark, Cal. 2006. ‘Taiwan Enters Troubled Waters: The Elective Presidencies of Lee
Teng-hui and Chen Shui-bian’. In Murray A. Rubinstein (ed.), Taiwan: A New
History, revised edn. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 496–535.
398 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Clark, Cal and Alexander C. Tan. 2012a. Taiwan’s Political Economy: Meeting
Challenges, Pursuing Progress. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Clark, Cal and Alexander C. Tan. 2012b. ‘Partisan Polarization in Taiwan: A Chal-
lenge to Catch-all Parties’. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs, 41(3):7–31.
Clark, Cal. and Alexander C. Tan. 2016. ‘Identity and Integration as Conflicting
Forces Stimulating the Sunflower Movement and the Kuomintang’s Loss in the
2014 Elections’. Contemporary Chinese Political Economy and Strategic Relations:
An International Journal, 2(1):313–349.
Clark, Cal, Alexander C. Tan, and Karl Ho. 2020. ‘Was 2016 a Realigning Election in
Tsai, Chia-Hung, Yung-Ming Hsu, and Hsiu-Tin Huang. 2007. ‘Bi-polarizing the
Politics: Explaining the 2004 Presidential Election in Taiwan’. Journal of Electoral
Studies, 14(1):1–31.
Tsai, Chung-Min. 2018. ‘Taiwan in 2017: The End of a Honeymoon’. Asian Survey,
58(1):73–79.
Wang, T. Y. and G. Andy Chang. 2005. ‘Ethnicity and Politics in Taiwan: An Analysis
of Mainlanders’ Identity and Policy Preferences’. Issues & Studies, 41(4):35–66.
Yu, Ching-Hsin. 2005. ‘The Evolution of Party System in Taiwan, 1995–2004’. Journal
of Asian and African Studies, 40(1/2):105–129.
Introduction
Yeaji Kim, The Development of Party Organizations in New Democracies. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Yeaji Kim (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0019
402 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
and Kruszewska 2018; Han 2019). Given the longevity of political elites and
candidates standing for elections, the changes in the Korean party system
arrangement are not significant (Hellmann 2014).
Lastly, the weakly institutionalized party system in Korea is exacerbated
by a lack of robust organizational structure among Korean political parties.
The parties’ increasing organizational capacities are impeded by elite-driven
party formation and management, as well as two institutional reforms. Dur-
ing the ‘three Kims’ era, politicians directed and controlled parties by treating
them as personal property. The leaders were ‘feudal lords’ who consolidated
groups of legislators who are members of political parties, those parties can
obtain 50% of the total state subsidies. Moreover, parties with more than five
seats are entitled to 5% of the total subsidies, while those with no seat or
fewer than five seats receive only 2% of the total subsidies. It is not surpris-
ing, then, that these parties receive virtually no state funding, despite having
been elected with public support. The current system of distributing state
subsidies is unfair to small and new parties and can contribute to the for-
mation of cartels between parties and the state (Kwak 2003). The collusion
among major political parties to maintain power becomes easier with this
Although the Korean party system consists of three political party families—
progressive, liberal, and conservative—it has traditionally been dominated
by a two-party system in which the liberal and conservative parties play a
central role. However, since the 2004 electoral system change, new progres-
sive parties have emerged, albeit with a minor political impact in terms of
strongholds and the size of their representation in congress when compared
to the other two parties.10
The Development of Party Organizations in New Democracies 407
Two dominant political parties stand out within this system: the DP, which
falls under the liberal party family, and the PPP, which belongs to the conser-
vative party family. The parties are long-standing rivals. Figure 19.1 depicts
how the labels of the DP and the PPP have evolved. The PPP has changed
labels five times since 1988, demonstrating a more consistent evolution over
time than the DP’s history of label changes (Han, 2020). From 1997 to 2011,
the DP changed its name numerous times due to various merges and splits,
while the PPP ultimately kept the same name, the Grand National Party. In
2000, the Millennium Democratic Party (MDP) was split into two parties:
Figure 19.1 The history of the two main political parties in Korea
Note: This figure was created based on the National Election Commission's (NEC) annual reports of
parties from 1988 to 2019 and the People Power Partyʼs (PPP) party statutes since 2020.
408 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
pointed out, the retirement of the ‘three Kims’ from politics has led to a reduc-
tion in clientelistic traits within Korean party institutions. The membership
data shows that the main political parties in Korea have been more success-
ful in recent years in enrolling citizens as members, contrary to common
expectations.
Figure 19.2 presents the DP’s and the PPP’s party memberships as percent-
ages of the national electorate (M/E) in Korea from 1988 to 2019. The data
overall reveal a U-shape curve. From 1988 to 2004, the number of members
in the PPP was significantly higher than the number of members in the DP;
15
Party Membership as Percentage of Electorate (%)
10
Party
DP
PPP
1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
Year
identification with the parties, they are more likely to pay the dues. Therefore,
it would be meaningful to delve into the percentage of party members who
pay membership dues to assess the extent to which they are engaged in their
parties.
Furthermore, Korean parties have been notorious for having ‘paper
members’, referring to ‘those who register for party membership but do
not often pay their membership fees’ (Han 2020: 14). In the early 2000s,
individuals or factions in parties tried to increase the number of party
members by voluntarily buying party memberships for other individuals or
100
Party Membership Who Pay Membership Fees (%)
75
25
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019
Year
Figure 19.3 Percentage of party members who pay the membership fee
Notes: This figure was created based on the National Election Commission's (NEC) annual reports of
parties from 1997 to 2019; DP—Democratic Party; PPP—People Power Party
who were registered by others. The parties may have reported the number of
party members by including the paper members or those members who had
once enrolled but were no longer active. Lastly, when the local branches were
abolished by the revision of the Political Parties Act in 2004, Korean parties
likely lost enormous numbers of party members who did not pay the dues
but were managed by the local branches.
In Korea, the state subsidies for political parties are categorized by two types:
(a) ordinary subsidies and (b) election subsidies. The NEC distributes the
The Development of Party Organizations in New Democracies 413
ordinary subsidies to political parties in each quarter of every year. For the
ordinary subsidies, the state provides ‘an amount obtained by multiplying the
unit price for appropriation of subsidies by the total number of eligible voters
in an election for National Assembly members recently held at the expiration
of their term of office’ (the Political Funds Act, Article 25, Clauses 1 and 3).
The election subsidies are paid to political parties in a year of presidential,
National Assembly, and local elections. The election subsidies are added to
the amount of the ordinary subsidies, considering ‘the unit price for appro-
priation of subsidies per eligible voter for each election’ (the Political Funds
Elections No Elections
90000
State Subsidy (One Million KRW)
30000
1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 2020 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 2020
Year
Figure 19.4 The total amount of state subventions for political parties
Notes: This figure was created based on the National Election Commission's (NEC) annual reports of
parties from 1988 to 2019; Elections were held in 1988, 1992, 1995, 1996, 1997, 1998, 2000, 2002,
2004, 2006, 2007, 2008, 2010, 2012, 2014, 2016, 2017, and 2018.
The PPP’s share of income derived from membership dues has averaged 15%
over time. From 1988 to 1995, the DP gained the largest share of income
from party membership dues, but from 1996 to 2001, the party member-
ship dues were a minor income source. Since 2002, the DP has gained an
average of 37% of its revenue through membership fees. In general, the
percentage of the parties’ income that comes from state subsidies has been
significant.
Second, the current financial system for political parties creates a hostile
environment for new or minor parties’ survival. This results from the con-
ditions that they need to qualify to get paid state subsidies by creating a
negotiating group in the National Assembly. Figure 19.6 presents how much
Membership Fee Membership Fee
75 75
Party Income (%)
Party
50 50
DP
PPP
25 25
0 0
1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 2020 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 2020
Year
100
75
Two Parties’ Portion of State Subsidy (%)
25
1988 1900 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
Year
Figure 19.6 The two established political partiesʼ portion of state subventions
Notes: This figure shows the Democratic Party and the People Power Partyʼs portion of the total state
subventions for political parties in Korea. The figure was created based on the National Election
Commission's (NEC) annual reports of parties from 1988 to 2019.
the DP and the PPP have prevailed in the total amount of state subsidies
over time. The two parties combined have received an average of 78% of the
state subsidies from 1988 to 2019, except for 1995, when the DP and the PPP
received less than 50% of the total state subsidies.
Even though Korea democratized in 1987, its political parties were not
internally democratic until recently. Specifically, the parties excluded party
members from selecting their candidates until the early 2000s, and only a few
The Development of Party Organizations in New Democracies 417
Note: PDP = Party for Peace and Democracy; DP = Democratic Party; NCNP = National Congress for New Politics; MDP = Millennium Democratic Party; GUDNP = Grand
United Democratic New Party; DUP = Democratic United Party
Sources: Park (2016); Jhee and Shin (2018); Chung and Kim (2022)
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/book/58013 by guest on 17 November 2024
Table 19.3 Changes in presidential candidate selection rules of the People Power Party, 1987–2022
Election year 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007 2012 2017 2022
Party name DLP DLP GNP GNP GNP NFP LKP PPP
Type of Closed Closed Closed Quasi-open Quasi-open Quasi-open Quasi-open Quasi-open
primaries
Methods of Selectorate Selectorate Selectorate Selectorates Selectorate voting Selectorate Selectorate Selectorate
primaries voting voting voting voting (80%) + Public voting (80%) + voting (50%) + voting (50%) +
survey results Public survey Public survey Public survey
(20%) results (20%) results (50%) results (50%)
Ratio of Party Party Party Party delegates Party delegates Party delegates Party delegates Party delegates
selectorates delegates delegates delegates (30%) + Party (20%) + Party (20%) + Party and party and party
(100%) (100%) (100%) members (20%) members (30%)+ members members (50%) members (50%)
+ Non-party (30%)+
Non-party members (30%) Non-party
members (50%) members (30%)
Ratio of - - - - Non-party Non-party Non-party Non-party
public survey members (20%) members (20%) members (50%) members (50%)
Number of 7,309 6,882 12,430 48,391 163,617 103,118 39,856 569,059
selectorate
Number of - - - - 6,000 6,000 Not available Not Available
survey
respondents
Note: DLP—Democratic Liberal Party; GNP—Grand National Party; NFP—New Frontier Party; LKP—Liberty Korea Party; PPP—People Power Party
Sources: The data for the period between 1987 and 2017 were obtained from Park (2016) and Jhee and Shin (2018); the author generated the 2022 data; the sample sizes and
methods of survey sampling used for selecting presidential candidates in 2017 and 2022 are not publicly available; the PPP staff has indicated that this information is
confidential
420 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Finally, the parties have adopted different methods to conduct the pri-
maries. The DP has operated a series of regional conventions to choose a
presidential candidate from 2002 to the present. The PPP held a series of
regional conventions in 2002 and has also implemented simultaneous pri-
mary elections held nationwide since then. Moreover, the DP introduced
an electronic voting system at regional conventions in 2002, online voting
in 2002, mobile phone voting in 2007, online voting for Korean nationals
living abroad in 2012, and automatic response system (ARS) voting meth-
ods in 2017. The PPP kept their voting system to ballot voting from 2002 to
Conclusion
Democratic development in Korea has been in the slow lane due to the
weakly institutionalized party system. Political parties, characterized instead
by clientelistic and cartelistic organizational elements, were powerless with-
out strong party organizational capacities. From 1988 to present, the DP and
the PPP have departed from the clientelistic party organizational charac-
teristics by recruiting individuals as party members and democratizing the
candidate selection rules. However, the party system is still marked by its
cartelistic organizational capacity stemming from its heavy dependence on
state subsidies that favour the major parties.
The organizational development of Korean political parties raises impor-
tant questions regarding the development of democracy in Korea. First, not
all party members are active or have strong party affiliations. The parties
422 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Notes
1. The three organizational features follow the suggestions in Scarrow et al. (2017) in
focusing on parties’ organizational capacities, including structure, resources, and rep-
resentative strategies.
2. The highest effective number of electoral parties in 2008 was derived from the change in
the electoral system from a single-member district system to a mixed system in 2004.
3. The regional background includes the areas where political figures were born and where
they resided (Moon 2005; Kang 2008; Kang and Bae 2018; Han 2020).
4. The ‘three Kims’ are Kim Young-sam, who was born in Yeongnam in the east region of
Korea; Kim Dae-jung, who was born in Honam in the southwestern region; and Kim
Jong-pil, who was born in Chungcheong in the southwestern region. Kim Young-sam
and Kim Dae-jung were elected as presidents in 1992 and 1997, respectively.
5. Chungcheong became the ‘swing-vote’ province in the party competition (Wang 2012).
The Development of Party Organizations in New Democracies 423
6. The third-party alternatives (i.e. new parties) entered the party system after a change in
the electoral system from a single-member district system to a mixed system in 2004.
Under the single-member district electoral system, voters had the principle of ‘one man
one vote’, and seats in the assembly were distributed to parties based on the share of votes
that candidates received in local districts. However, the Constitutional Court found this
system to be unconstitutional. In 2004, the electoral system was changed to the inde-
pendent mixed system, which includes both single-member districts and a proportional
system. Under the mixed system, people have two votes: one for a candidate in their local
districts and another for a party on the national list. The majority of seats in the assembly
are allocated to the candidates who win in each electoral district, while the remaining
18. In this chapter, selectorates are used to refer to the groups of people who are eligible to
participate in the presidential candidate selection process in each party.
19. The survey, which included 6,000 eligible voters, was conducted in accordance with the
rules and dates decided by the NEC.
References
Biezen, Ingrid van and Thomas Poguntke. 2014. ‘The Decline of Membership-based
Politics’. Party Politics, 20(2):205–216.
Kang, Won-Taek. 2008. ‘How Ideology Divides Generations: The 2002 and
2004 South Korean Elections’. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 41(2):
461–480.
Kang, Woo Jin. 2017. ‘Income and Voting Behavior in Korean Politics: Why Do the
Poor Support Conservative Political Parties?’. Journal of International and Area
Studies, 24(2):15–33.
Kang, WooJin and Jin Seok Bae. 2018. ‘Regionalism and Party System Change at
the Sub-national Level: The 2016 Korean National Assembly Election’. Journal of
International and Area Studies, 25(1):93–112.
Nemoto, Kuniaki. 2009. ‘Committing to the Party: The Costs of Governance in East
Asian Democracies. (PhD Dissertation). San Diego: University of California, San
Diego.
Park, Chan Pyo. 2016. ‘국민참여경선제의 제도 차이의 발생 배경에 대한 연구 :
16~18대 대선후보 경선제도 비교’. Journal of Future Politics, 6(1): 65–87.
Ponce, Aldo F. and Susan E. Scarrow. 2016. ‘Which Members? Using Cross-national
Surveys to Study Party Membership’. Party Politics, 22(6):679–690.
Scarrow, Susan E. 2017. The Changing Nature of Political Party Membership
in Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics. https://oxfordre.com/view/10.1093/
Since Japan is notorious for its unwillingness to accept refugees,1 it has been
spared from political turmoil comparable to the European migrant crisis:
xenophobic political parties could hardly expand their support and occupy
positions in the existing party system.2
However, the country faces other problems. As the Japanese economy
entered troubled waters after the burst of the asset price bubble in the early
1990s and its population aged at the fastest pace in the world, the fiscal deficit
ballooned. The end of the Cold War and tensions with neighbouring coun-
tries such as China and North Korea also urged Japan to reconsider its role on
the world stage. To deal with these issues, Japan decided to make its political
system more accountable and to strengthen the positions of political leaders.
In 1994, Japan abolished its familiar electoral formula, the single non-
transferable vote (SNTV ), for the lower house and then adopted the
mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) system, which elected 300 seats from
single-seat constituencies and 200 seats from 11 proportional representation
(PR) constituencies according to the d’Hondt method. At the same time, pub-
lic funding for political parties was introduced. The initial focus of this reform
was to drive out the money-ridden politics that prevailed under the long-
ruling conservatives, the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP). The new electoral
system was expected to switch the party system from one of single-party dom-
inance to a more competitive system by consolidating opposition forces and
then ousting the LDP-led government. Furthermore, by taking power away
from the factions inside the LDP and concentrating it in the hands of the
party leadership, it was thought that Japanese politics would become more
effective.
Takayoshi Uekami and Junpei Yamaguchi, Japan. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas
Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Takayoshi Uekami and Junpei Yamaguchi (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0020
428 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
The LDP have successfully adapted themselves to the new electoral system.
They converted themselves to a more programmatic, conservative-oriented,
and less corrupt party by centralizing intra-party relations and increasing
cohesiveness (Uekami and Tsutsumi 2019). On the other hand, the oppo-
sition parties remain fragmented as they are composed of old left-wingers,
centrists, and conservative reformists. Since their extra-parliamentary orga-
nizations are shallowly rooted in society and divided along the lines of their
predecessor parties, they have repeatedly failed to promote a single candidate
running for the single-member districts (SMDs). Furthermore, they have
Defeated and occupied by the Allied powers in 1945, Japan went through
a sweeping demilitarization and democratization. The parliamentary sys-
tem was retained, but the ultimate authority of selecting a prime minister
was transferred from the Emperor to the lower house of the Diet. Universal
suffrage was guaranteed by the newly established Japanese constitution.
Since then, many political parties have appeared and tried to fill the politi-
cal vacuum. As the left-wing parties except for the Communists converged to
Japan 429
form the Japan Socialist Party (JSP), the conservatives merged to establish the
LDP in 1955. Post-war Japanese party politics was built upon the competition
between the conservatives and the progressives, but the LDP won more than
half the seats in national elections most of the time until 1993. Since it suc-
cessfully controlled the government, the party system of that period could be
categorized as one-party dominant (Pempel 1990). Figure 20.1 shows the seat
shares of major political parties since the 1958 general election. In addition
to voter turnout rates, Figure 20.2 displays the effective numbers of electoral
and parliamentary parties (ENEP and ENPP, respectively).
400
300
200
100
0
76
79
80
83
86
90
93
96
00
03
05
09
12
14
17
21
58
60
63
67
69
72
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
19
LDP JSP(SDP) JCP DSP KOMEITO NFP DPJ JRP(JIP) POH CDP DPFP others
Figure 20.1 Seat share of major parties since 1955 (number of seats)
Source: Election results reports, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications
100 7
90
6
80
70 5
60 4
60
40 3
30 2
20
1
10
0 0
58
60
63
67
69
72
76
79
80
83
86
90
93
96
00
03
05
09
12
14
21
17
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Figure 20.2 Core party system indicators: Voter turnout rates (left-side scale, %),
effective numbers of electoral party and of parliamentary party (right-side scale)
Source: Election results reports, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications
430 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Post-war Japanese party politics was shaken badly after the collapse of the
Soviet Union as it was predicated on a domestic version of the Cold War. The
pro-capitalist LDP was pitted against the pro-socialist JSP, both of which took
sides with their ideological friends within and outside the country. This was
also reflected in their international views and foreign policies. However, the
end of the Cold War stripped away the programmatic appeal not only from
the JSP but also the LDP in that the latter’s role as the sole defender of the
market economy was discredited. To put it simply, the cost of overlooking
the misconduct associated with the long-ruling LDP began to outweigh the
benefit of supporting the party.
At that time, several political scandals hit the incumbent LDP hard. From
the late 1980s to the early 1990s, a series of corruption cases came to light
wherein private companies had bribed top LDP politicians. These scandals
outraged the Japanese public and impressed upon them the need to change
Japan 431
the conventional way of conducting politics. In the ensuing 1993 lower house
election, the LDP could not secure a majority of seats. Except for the LDP
and the JCP, eight political parties formed a coalition government headed by
the leader of the Japan New Party (JNP). As the LDP had monopolized the
government ever since 1955, it was a historic moment. In 1994, the new non-
LDP coalition government successfully changed the electoral system for the
lower house from the SNTV to the MMM system, which was composed of
300 SMD seats and 200 PR seats. Public funding for political parties was also
introduced.
members. When the party broke from its coalition partners, the Liberals fell
into internal conflict. In the end, they merged with the DPJ just before the
2003 lower house election. It was not until this merger that the opposition
parties provided voters with a viable alternative to the LDP-led coalition
(Uekami and Tsutsumi 2011).
Although the LDP and Komeito succeeded in remaining in office, they
were finally defeated by the DPJ-led coalition in the 2009 lower house elec-
tion. This does not mean that the LDP just sat idle as the DPJ rose. On the
contrary, the LDP sought to realize a ‘structural reform’ policy based on
Why did the LDP succeed in adapting to the new electoral environment?
Why did the opposition parties fail to do so? We answer these questions by
focusing on party organization under a particular set of electoral systems.
With the introduction of the SMD system in lower house elections,
candidates were required to garner a majority of votes to be elected. They
have come to emphasize policy appeal because it is impossible to buy off
many voters with selective goods. In this context, party organizations play
the chapter, the organization of the LDP remains huge but became more
consolidated.
On the other hand, the difficulties faced by Japanese opposition parties can
be traced backed to the fact that they only have thin and divided organiza-
tions across a wide political spectrum (Uekami and Tsutsumi 2011). In sum,
they face problems of collective choice and collective action even if they share
common goals such as winning elections. The party organizations often hes-
itate to unite their campaigning efforts for a single candidate. However, this
does not mean that mergers of opposition parties always fail. It all depends
In this section, we examine the responses of the LDP and the DPJ to the
electoral environment by measuring the degree to which they maintain and
consolidate their respective organizations.
First, let us compare the size of party organizations for the two major parties.
Since the government’s report on political funds provides the only avail-
able data that allow us to examine the magnitude of membership and party
finance systematically, we have no choice but to describe the situation based
on these data. However, the membership figures reported are the sum of for-
mal members and party friends. As with the multi-speed model (Scarrow
2015), the LDP, the DPJ, and its successor parties have reduced forms of party
membership.
According to Figure 20.3, LDP membership accounts for a much larger
share of the Japanese electorate than that of the DPJ. Even after the DPJ
defeated the LDP by a landslide in the 2009 lower house election, the LDP
managed to keep its member numbers well above those of the DPJ, though
the margin narrowed. After the 2012 election, the LDP kept 800,000 members
whereas the DPJ stayed around 200,000, or only a quarter the membership
of the LDP.
Turning to party finance, the percentage of state subsidies of the total
income of the DPJ headquarters has surpassed that of the LDP (Figure 20.4).
Japan 435
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
LDP DDJ/DP
Figure 20.3 Party membership/electorate ratio (%): The LDP and the DPJ (DP since
2016)
Source: Political funds reports, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
LDP DPJ/DP
Figure 20.4 Share of state funding in party headquartersʼ income (%): The LDP and the
DPJ (DP since 2016)
Source: Political funds reports, Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications
According to the Political Party Subsidies Act that stipulates the amount
of money a political party receives from public coffers each year, subsidy
amounts vary depending on the number of a party’s affiliated members of
parliament (MPs) and the vote share in elections.
The two major Japanese parties relied heavily on public funding to cover
their expenses. Subsidies from the national treasury accounted for almost
436 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
90% of the DPJ’s HQ revenue in its later years. The higher percentage on the
part of the DPJ suggests that they had a hard time receiving monetary sup-
port from party members and auxiliary organizations such as labour unions.
Although the LDP was less dependent on taxpayers, the proportion has grad-
ually risen to nearly 70% in recent years. When comparing the LDP and the
DPJ with this in mind, it can be said that the latter is less rooted in society
(cf. Katz and Mair 1995).
The LDP and the DPJ also performed differently in terms of plebiscitary
intra-party democracy (Poguntke et al. 2016)8 . According to LDP statutes,
each party member and party friend has a right to vote in the party leader-
ship election together with the MPs. But, in the case of an emergency where
the party leader resigns before their term ends, MPs and the delegates from
prefectural organizations have the exclusive right to select the next party
leader. Even in this case, the prefectural organizations are not prohibited
from holding primaries to nominate their preferred candidate(s) for whom
the delegates can cast their votes.
Since the introduction of membership voting in 1977, the LDP has not
always allowed its members to participate in the leadership selection. How-
ever, after the 2001 leadership election, the LDP has almost always let party
members and friends vote (Uekami 2008). Among the 16 leadership elec-
tions since 1997, 4 cases were uncompetitive. Out of the 12 remaining races,
the LDP allowed party members and friends to participate in 11.
The DPJ also adopted membership voting in its leadership election, but
the details of collecting and counting votes were a bit different from those
of the LDP. The eligible voters were stipulated as the following: MPs, candi-
dates for the next national elections, local assembly members, ordinary party
members, and registered supporters. The most striking difference, however,
is how often they held membership votes. From its establishment in 1996 to
its breakup in 2017, the party allowed its members and supporters to vote in
only 6 out of 15 races (The total number of elections during this time was 24,
nine of which were without contenders). Although it had the same emergency
clause as the LDP, the DPJ limited eligibility to MPs; it repeatedly decided to
skip the normal procedure.
In sum, besides being comparatively small, the DPJ organization per-
formed poorly in mobilizing financial resources and encouraging members
to participate.
Japan 437
In terms of ‘the party in the electorate’, the two major parties display clear
contrasts in the composition of voters. We utilized Japanese election survey
data and sorted the LDP and DPJ voters according to their previous voting
on recall (Table 20.1). As we paid special attention to the voting behaviour of
Japanese electorate precipitated by party change, we picked those elections
held just after the DPJ’s formation and its mergers with other parties.
Just before the 1996 lower house election, the DPJ was established at the
Table 20.1 Voter support in national elections for the LDP and the DPJ (DP since
2016) (%)
Source: JES II data for the 1996 lower house election and the 1998 upper house election, JES III data for
the 2003 lower house election, and the post-election survey for the 2016 upper house election conducted
by the Association for Promoting Fair Elections; the data for the secondary analyses of the 2003 and the
2016 elections were provided by the Social Science Japan Data Archive, Center for Social Research and
Data Archives, Institute of Social Science, The University of Tokyo
438 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Despite the merger of the DPJ with the Liberal Party in 2003 and with the
JIP in 2016, the results of the election surveys suggest that the DPJ (DP) was
no longer able to expand its support. The alchemy had ended at last.
In sum, the DPJ in the electorate became fragmented on its way to becom-
ing a major party. Next, we turn to the backgrounds of MPs to examine the
organizational divisions that the LDP and the DPJ have faced. As shown in
Table 20.2a and 20.2b, both the LDP and the DPJ are internally divided by
factions and groups.
To put it bluntly, there have been three major factions—Seiwa, Heisei, and
Seiwa 26 45 54 14 56 54
Heisei 43 27 37 10 27 33
Kochi 37 38 45 12 27 27
Others 64 58 81 23 71 102
Non-affiliated 19 20 41 46 87 46
Total 189 188 258 105 268 262
Ex-JSP (SDP) 15 15 11 12 5 5
ex-DSP 11 11 4 5 2 2
ex-LDP 12 12 9 7 2 1
ex-JNP 14 14 5 9 5 4
ex-JIP 2 16
DPJ 50 103 72 159 39 58
As we have seen, there are several differences between the LDP and the DPJ in
terms of the scale and cohesiveness of party organization. This leads us to the
following questions: Do the organizational features affect the other dimen-
sions of party politics, say policy preference? How much policy variance is
there in the first place? It is important to remember that a majoritarian elec-
toral system gives a winning party extra seats to ensure that it can declare a
mandate from voters. To make its mandate clearer, it is a prerequisite that a
political party must attain policy coherence to some extent.
To answer the questions presented above, we analysed survey data on the
policy positions taken by the candidates for the national elections9 .
Policy coherence
By applying a factor analysis to the data for all candidates since 2003, we
found two dimensions: national security and social issues,10 and economic
issues. The policy items used are those which appear in all waves from 2003
to 2017. Then we calculated the factor scores for the MPs who belong to
the LDP and the DPJ (DP) (Figure 20.5a, 20.5b). Although the DP was dis-
solved just before the 2017 election, we treat successor parties as the DP for
the convenience of the reader. A higher score indicates a more hawkish and
conservative posture for the first dimension and a more fiscal interventionist
stance for the second.
The box plots in Figure 20.5a show that LDP MPs lean more toward a
hawkish and conservative position, while DPJ MPs position themselves just
440 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
(a)
3 3
National security and social issues
2 2
1 1
0 0
–1 –1
–2 –2
–3 –3
03 LDP 05 LDP 09 LDP 12 LDP 14 LDP 17 LDP 03 DPJ 05 DPJ 09 DPJ 12 DPJ 14 DPJ 17 DP
Figure 20.5a Distribution of policy positions on national security and social issues:
LDP and DPJ (DP since 2016)
Source: UTokyo-Asahi Survey
(b)
3 3
2 2
Economic issues
1 1
0 0
–1 –1
–2 –2
–3 –3
03 LDP 05 LDP 09 LDP 12 LDP 14 LDP 17 LDP 03 DPJ 05 DPJ 09 DPJ 12 DPJ 14 DPJ 17 DP
Figure 20.5b Distribution of policy positions on economic issues: LDP and DPJ (DP
since 2016)
Source: UTokyo-Asahi Survey
around the middle. When we look inside of each party, however, the policy
positions of the Democrats are more widely dispersed than those of the
Liberal Democrats.
Figure 20.5b displays the box plots generated for the second dimension.
The left-hand side shows the overall positions and inner variances of the
LDP. It reflects the tendency towards the neoliberal, market-oriented eco-
nomic policy advocated by the party leader in 2003 and 2005, as well as the
more expansionist turn after the financial crisis in 2009. It is interesting to
see that the DPJ follows almost the same pattern as the LDP, but the boxes
are posted in the lower half of the area. As in the case of national security and
social issues, the DPJ was incohesive. The blurred policy positions certainly
Japan 441
discredited its electoral manifestos, making them something the voters could
not count on. To put it simply, the DPJ has not been well positioned in the
electoral contests since the 1994 political reforms.
–4 –2 0 2 –4 –2 0 2
–4 –2 0 2 –4 –2 0 2
LDP Heisei
LDP Heisei LDP Kochi
LDP Kochi LDP Others
LDP Others LDP Non-affiliated
LDP Non-affiliated
2012
–4 –2 0 2 –4 –2 0 2
DP ex-JSP(SDP) DP ex-JSP(SDP)
DP ex-LDP DP ex-LDP
DP ex-JNP DP ex-JNP
DP ex-JIP DP ex-JIP
–4 –2 0 2 –4 –2 0 2
Figure 20.6 Estimated effects of intra-party groups (confidence interval (CI) at 95%)
Source: UTokyo-Asahi Survey
Japan 443
Conclusion
Notes
1. Out of 7,586 asylum seekers, only 125 were given protection by Japanese authorities in
2015, in the midst of the migrant crisis in Europe. By contrast, the number of foreign
residents in Japan is 2.8 million as of 2020.
2. This work was supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers 17H02481 and 18H00813.
3. The JSP changed its name to the Social Democratic Party (SDP) in 1996.
4. Just before the 2017 lower house election, they decided to form the Party of Hope (POH).
The dissidents split and established the Constitutional Democratic Party of Japan (CDP).
5. The LDP garnered support from only a quarter of all voters in the 2017 general elec-
tion (turnout rate (53.68%) multiplied by the party’s share of valid votes (47.82%)). Its
narrower, rather conservative support base chose to elect MPs whose composition was
444 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
heavily distorted by gender inequality: only one out of 10 LDP MPs was female as of
2021.
6. Krauss and Pekkanen (2011) insists that the changes in the LDP organization should be
understood as multi-faceted. The leadership was strengthened the most, the factions and
the decentralised decision-making were weakened somewhat, and the personal campaign
organization was affected modestly.
7. See also Poguntke and Webb (2005).
8. Apart from membership vote, there are almost no other measures usually categorised as
intra-party democracy.
9. The UTokyo-Asahi Survey is available courtesy of Professor Masaki Taniguchi and
References
Aldrich, John H. 1995. Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Political
Parties in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Carey, John M. and Matthew S. Shugart. 1995. ‘Incentives to Cultivate a Personal
Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas’. Electoral Studies, 14(4):417–439.
Catalinac, Amy. 2016. Electoral Reform and National Security in Japan: From Pork
to Foreign Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Katz, Richard S. and Peter Mair. 1995. ‘Changing Models of Party Organization and
Party Democracy: The Emergence of the Cartel Party’. Party Politics, 1(1):5–28.
Kitschelt, Herbert. 2000. ‘Linkages between Citizens and Politicians in Democratic
Polities’. Comparative Political Studies, 33(6/7):845–879.
Kohno, Masaru. 1997. Japan’s Postwar Party Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Krauss, Ellis S. and Benjamin Nyblade. 2005. ‘“Presidentialization” in Japan? The
Prime Minister, Media and Elections in Japan’. British Journal of Political Science,
35(2):357–368.
Krauss, Ellis S. and Robert J. Pekkanen. 2011. The Rise and Fall of Japan’s LDP: Polit-
ical Party Organizations as Historical Institutions. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
Press.
Japan 445
Kushida, Kenji E. and Phillip Y. Lipscy (eds). 2013. Japan under the DPJ: The Politics
of Transformation and Governance. Stanford, CA: The Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-
Pacific Research Center.
Maeda, Yukio and Hidenori Tsutsumi (eds). 2015. Tōchi no jyōken: Minshutō ni miru
seiken unnei to tōnai tōchi. Tokyo: Chikura Shobō
(Maeda, Yukio and Hidenori Tsutsumi (eds). 2015. Party Government and Party
Governance: The Case of the Democratic Party of Japan. Tokyo: Chikura Shobō).
Nakakita, Kōji. 2014. Jimintō seiji no henyō. Tokyo: NHK Shuppan
(Nakakita, Kōji. 2014. The Transformation of LDP politics. Tokyo: NHK Publishing,
(Uekami, Takayoshi and Hidenori Tsutsumi (eds). 2011. Organization and Policies
of Democratic Party of Japan: From its Formation to Acquisition of Power. Tokyo:
Tōyō Keizai Shinpōsha).
Uekami, Takayoshi and Hidenori Tsutsumi. 2019. ‘Inverse Relationship between
Party Institutionalisation and Party System Competitiveness: The Transformation
of Postwar Japanese Party Politics’. In Robert Harmel and Lars G. Svåsand (eds),
Institutionalisation of Political Parties: Comparative Cases. London: Rowman &
Littlefield International, in partnership with ECPR Press, 111–131.
Eswaran Sridharan
Eswaran Sridharan, The Challenges to Democracy in India. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Eswaran Sridharan (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0021
448 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Freedom House also gave India a poor and declined rating in 2020 on inter-
net freedom (from 51/100 to 49/100) as well as communication privacy, and
noted the following:
The report also noted that civil society organizations, particularly those
involved in the investigation of human rights abuses, continue to face threats,
legal harassment, excessive police force, and occasionally lethal violence’
(Freedom House 2021: section E-2) and how the Foreign Contribution
Regulation Act (FCRA) has been amended to target non-governmental orga-
nizations (NGOs) perceived to be political opponents, including the shutting
down of the operations of Amnesty International. The report also noted that
while the judiciary is formally independent, the courts have shown increas-
ing signs of politicization in favour of the ruling BJP, including due process
rights that have not been consistently upheld.
The Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU), in its report Democracy Index 2020
(EIU 2021), also downgrades India under Prime Minister Narendra Modi,
from 2014 to 2020, from a historic high score of 7.92 in 2014 to 6.61 in 2020,
which should be seen as part of a general downward slide in the quality of
democracy worldwide since 2006. India is downgraded to a ‘Flawed Democ-
racy’ in 2020 from a ‘Full Democracy’ earlier, its global ranking falling from
450 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
27th in 2014 to 53rd in 2020. The report noted ‘the increasing influence of
religion under the Modi premiership, whose policies have fomented anti-
Muslim feeling and religious strife, has damaged the political fabric of the
country’, also noting the Citizenship Amendment Act of 2019 ‘undermining
the secular basis of the Indian state’ and the Delhi riots in February 2020, as
well as a general erosion of civil liberties, including the way the corona virus
pandemic was handled (EIU 2021: 31). According to the EIU report, India’s
slide in rank and type to ‘Flawed Democracy’ was primarily due to its sharp
decline in political culture and civil liberties while maintaining a high rank
I largely agree with the three reports on the decline in the quality of India’s
democracy, although I would not go as far as V-Dem in classifying it as
an electoral autocracy. The BJP has lost state elections in major states in
The Challenges to Democracy in India 451
India’s federal system despite campaigns led by Modi and the BJP top brass.
However, while it is still a democracy, I would agree with considering it
an electoral democracy or an illiberal democracy rather than still a liberal
democracy. In the next few paragraphs I will outline the laws which have
been used to weaken civil liberties and give the government intrusive powers
that threaten traditional constitutional freedoms. After that, I will give a brief
recapitulation of the evolution of the Indian political and party system and
the types of political parties to set the context for a discussion of the decline
of the quality of democracy since 2014, the ideology and strategy of the BJP
These laws and agencies allow a ruling party, whichever it might be, to
threaten dissenters and critics and infringe on civil liberties if it wants to. To
be fair to the BJP, it should be noted that it was not under BJP majority rule
that these laws or agencies were created. Some of them date back to the colo-
nial era, and the others were enacted in the years of the relatively liberal and
secular regime of the Congress party. Their misuse is enabled by their sweep-
ing wording, but it is not inevitable. For example, between 2011 and 2014,
when the Congress-led United Progressive Alliance (UPA) government was
voted out, the bulk of the press and most TV channels turned vocally against
BJP, and to the role of the long-hegemonic Congress party under whose gov-
ernments many of the above laws and agencies were created, a brief account
of the nature and evolution of the Indian political system and the types and
nature of political parties is necessary as background.
central government but are allotted to state governments, under whom they
serve for a large part of their careers, alternating between state and central
governments. There are also the Indian Foreign Service and various cen-
tral services like the tax collection services, the audit and accounts service,
the postal services, the railway services, and others, whose officers can be
transferred around the country.
India’s constitution was revolutionary given that despite the country’s
deeply unequal and hierarchical society—largely rural, agrarian, illiterate,
and poor—India adopted a universal adult franchise, something that had
Political Parties
We now turn to a brief overview of the main players in the Indian politi-
cal landscape (for more detailed accounts, see Sridharan and Varshney 2001;
Sridharan 2002, 2010, 2014a, 2014b; Gowda and Sridharan 2007, all of
which this and the following sections draw on). Historically, Congress dom-
inated the party landscape, building on its legacy as the all-encompassing
movement that led India’s struggle for independence from the British. Post-
independence, Congress won seven of the first eight general elections from
1952 to 1984, except 1977, and has governed India for 54 of 74 years. It had an
unbroken domination for the first 30 years of free India and won pluralities
of the vote of 40% and above against a fragmented and regionalized opposi-
tion. Even since 1989 it has remained the single largest party by vote share,
though not seats, in each of the seven elections from 1989 to 2014, losing
that status in 2014 and 2019. Congress is a secular party that believes in a lin-
guistically and culturally diverse notion of Indian nationhood and remains
broadly acceptable to all segments of the population.
There are four other major categories of parties (though these groups of
parties do not necessarily constitute a coalition, by any means). These are,
first, the Hindu-nationalist parties (the BJP and the Shiv Sena); second, the
communist parties, also termed the Left Front (including the Communist
Party of India Marxist [CPI(M)] and the Communist Party of India [CPI]),
and the various Communist Party of India [Marxist-Leninist] splinters);
456 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
third, the agrarian/middle and lower-caste populist parties (the Janata Party,
the Janata Dal, and its offshoots like the Samajwadi Party, Rashtriya Janata
Dal, Rashtriya Lok Dal, Biju Janata Dal, Janata Dal [Secular], and Janata
Dal [United]); and fourth, the ethno-regional or ethnic parties based on
particular regional linguistic groups or lower-caste blocs or tribes (in the
north-eastern states in particular). Let me now outline the four phases of
evolution of the party system up to the present before discussing the role
of political parties in the current state of India’s democracy.
Lok Sabha elections. This has been called the bi-polarization of state party
systems for both assembly and parliamentary elections, but it is a system
of multiple bi-polarities, not the same two parties in each state. That is, the
bipolar consolidations state-wise were between Congress and several vary-
ing opposition parties, for example, Congress vs Left, Congress vs. Bharatiya
Jana Sangh (BJS, formed in 1951, the precursor of the BJP, which was formed
in 1980), and Congress vs a regional party, each in some states. With these
trends the Index of Opposition Unity, or the fraction constituted by the lead-
ing opposition party of the opposition vote as a whole, rose in state after state
(1952) to 5.83 (1996) to 6.53 (2004), the latter two elections marking high
points in the era of coalition and/or minority governments (1989–2014),
before declining to 3.04 (2019) when the BJP returned with an enhanced
majority. Voter participation increased fairly steadily, from 45.4% (1952) to
62% (1998), before slightly dipping and then rising again to an all-time high
of 67.4% (2019).
Prime Minister V. P. Singh after the fall of his government in 1990. Some were
the older regional parties that rose to prominence during1967–1989, such as
those of Tamil Nadu, Andhra Pradesh, and Assam. Most of them had formed
governments in their states at least onceduring1989–2014.
to identify and credit the level of government, central or state, for economic
outcomes.
The BJP
Among these non-Congress parties, the BJP, in power since 2014 with a
majority, merits some discussion. The BJP is among the most ideological
parties of India. It was founded in 1980, but its precursor the BJS, sharing
The BJP, after winning with a majority in 2014 and again in 2019, has become
other parties. The same was achieved in the major state of Karnataka, ruled by
a Congress coalition in 2019, and in another major state, Madhya Pradesh,
ruled by Congress in 2020. Attempts at engineering crossovers from other
parties were successful in West Bengal in 2021 although the BJP lost the elec-
tion. Expansion of its footprint by engineering defections from other parties
has become a mainstream strategy in the BJP.
The modus operandi for this appears to be the systematic use of tax-
enforcement agencies, particularly the Enforcement Directorate, to raid
opposition politicians and then strike secret deals for defection to the BJP.
Conclusion
References
Sridharan, Eswaran. 2002. ‘The Fragmentation of the Indian Party System 1952–
1999: Seven Competing Explanations’. In Zoya Hasan (ed.), Parties and Party
Politics in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 475–503.
Sridharan, Eswaran. 2010. ‘The Party System’. In Niraja Gopal Jayal and Pratap
Bhanu Mehta (eds), Oxford Companion to Indian Politics. New Delhi: Oxford
University Press, 117-135.
Sridharan, Eswaran. 2014a. ‘India’s Watershed Vote: Behind Modi’s Victory’. Journal
of Democracy, 25(4):20–33.
Sridharan, Eswaran. 2014b. ‘Class Voting in the 2014 Lok Sabha Elections: The
Julio C. Teehankee
Despite a long and rich history of democratic practices, party politics, and
elections, the Philippines has institutionalized a clientelistic and patronage-
based democracy within an underdeveloped economy.1 Since the first party,
the Partido Federalista, was founded in 1900 during the American colo-
nial regime, political parties have existed in some form or another. Soon
afterward, from 1907 to 1941, the Nacionalista Party (NP) became the
ruling party. Between 1946 and 1972, a formal two-party system devel-
oped, with the NP and its breakaway faction, the Liberal Party (LP),
alternating in power. Under his Kilusang Bagong Lipunan (KBL; New
Society Movement), Ferdinand Marcos destroyed this party system and
replaced it with a one-party dictatorship from 1972 to 1986. In 1986, a fluid
multi-party system emerged following the restoration of formal democracy
(Teehankee, 2020a).
While the country reverted to the pre-authoritarian presidential form of
government, a multi-party system emerged during the democratic transi-
tion. The shift to a multi-party system with a plurality-based electoral system
runs counter to the classic tenet of Duverger’s Law that argues that plurality-
based elections tend to produce two-party systems (Choi, 2001). However,
the post-authoritarian period saw the rise of ‘an anarchy of parties’ in
which inter-party competition became more fluid and fragmented, especially
under Rodrigo Duterte’s populist presidency. This chapter will delineate
the pitfalls of the post-authoritarian presidential-based party system in the
Philippines.
Julio C. Teehankee, An Anarchy of Parties. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and
Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Julio C. Teehankee (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0022
468 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Table 22.1 Party composition of the Senate, 2016, 2019, and 2022
Lakas CMD 0 0 1 4 1 4
Liberal Party 4 17 3 13 0 0
Nacionalista Party 4 17 4 17 4 17
Nationalist People’s Coalition 4 17 3 13 5 21
National Unity Party 0 0 0 0 0 0
PDP-Laban 2 8 4 17 5 21
Independents 5 21 4 17 5 21
Others 5 21 5 21 4 17
Total 24 100 24 100 24 100
Lakas CMD 5 2 9 4 26 10
Liberal Party 117 50 18 7 10 4
Nacionalista Party 22 9 41 17 36 14
Nationalist People’s Coalition 41 18 35 15 35 14
National Unity Party 23 10 24 10 33 13
List PR-Niemeyer electoral formula in which ‘the number of seats a party (or
organization) is entitled to is calculated based on the proportion by divid-
ing the votes obtained by a party or organization over the total number of all
votes cast for all qualified parties and organizations’ (Agra 1997: 3).
However, unlike the German model, the Philippine party-list elections
are non-compensatory. Only political parties registered for the list system
can field candidates for the PR seats, while the major parties competing for
single-member districts are prohibited from fielding list candidates. Hence,
the majority of the seats in the House are elected through a plurality-based
electoral system. The party-list election in the Philippines is peculiar, given its
low threshold of 2% and a three-seat cap for winning parties that goes against
the principles of PR. As shown in Table 22.3, between 1998 and 2022, an aver-
age of 115 party-list organizations participated in the party-list elections, and
the average number of winning parties exceeded 28. This underperformance
can be directly traced to basic deficiencies in the system brought about by
the three-seat limit and the unclear minimum electoral threshold (Teehankee
2019). The proliferation of small and fragmented party-list organizations has
largely contributed to the country’s ‘anarchy of parties’.
1998 52 14 13 122
2001 52 20 12 46
2004 53 24 16 66
2007 55 23 17 92
2010 57 41 31 150
each’ (Batto and Cox 2016: 3). For a long time, the Philippines was cited along
with the United States as the ‘purest two-party system’ (Shugart and Carey
1992: 222). However, several scholars have noted the role of the presidency
and the introduction of new electoral rules in relation to the fragmentation
of the party system in the post-authoritarian period.
Kasuya (2009) observes that parties are formed around the incumbent or
viable presidential candidates during and after elections. Politicians usually
switch to the incumbents or viable presidential candidates to pursue pork
barrel and other patronage supporters—a form of ‘presidential bandwago-
ning’. On the other hand, Choi (2001) argues that the party fragmentation
in the post-authoritarian period resulted from the adoption of a single-term
limit for presidents in the 1987 Constitution. Including such a restriction
nullifies or mitigates the Duvergerian effect of the plurality rule, resulting
in a multi-party system. Hicken (2016) agrees with the observation that the
term limit was responsible for multi-partyism. The ban lowered the entry
hurdles for presidential candidates and undercut the incumbent president’s
incentives to invest in party formation.
Throughout the years, the Philippines’ post-authoritarian election pro-
cesses have revealed distinct political pathologies. These include the con-
tinued dominance of political families and clans (commonly referred to
as ‘political dynasties’); the existence of weak parties, as evidenced by the
constant and regular practice of party switching among elected officials
(colourfully dubbed ‘political turncoatism’ by the mass media); and the use of
patronage, such as pork barrel, for political mobilization under the country’s
presidential system (Kasuya, 2009; Teehankee, 2013, 2018).
An Anarchy of Parties 471
In 2022, Ferdinand ‘Bongbong’ Marcos, Jr, the sole son and namesake of
the late dictator, won the presidency by a large margin 36 years after his fam-
ily was forced out of the palace by a military-backed people-power uprising.
Former president Gloria Macapagal Arroyo brokered an alliance between
Marcos and Davao Mayor Sara Duterte, the equally feisty daughter of the
populist president Rodrigo Duterte.
An Anarchy of Parties
Party factionalism
The Philippine political party system evolved from elite factions. On the
other hand, intra-elite competition was historically primarily driven by local
land-based political clans that served as the bedrock of Philippine party
politics. Later, changes in the country’s political economy influenced the
nature of factional leadership within the major parties. Under Ferdinand
Marcos’ dictatorship, the authoritarian period disrupted the factional com-
petitions within parties, allowing non-landed politicians to mobilize their
political machines both within and outside the dictator’s dominant party.
Since then, many parties have been formed due to the splits and mergers of
elite-based political factions that shaped the post-authoritarian multi-party
system (Teehankee 2020a).
Every governing party in the post-authoritarian period was driven by
intense factionalism. During the presidency of Duterte, the ruling polit-
ical party—the PDP-Laban—was split into a faction supporting Senator
Aquilino ‘Koko’ Pimentel III and Senator Emmanuel ‘Manny’ Pacquiao and
one loyal to the populist strongman. Meanwhile, the second Marcos pres-
idency is already facing intense factional rivalries between the supporters
of Marcos, Jr. and those loyal to Vice President Sara Duterte (daughter
of former president Duterte). Lakas Christian-Muslim Democrats (Lakas
CMD; the de facto ruling party)—headed by Marcos, Jr’s cousin, House
472 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Party switching
According to Quimpo (2008: 128), ‘[f ]ar from being stable, programmatic
entities, [Philippine political parties] have in practice proven to be not much
From 2010 to 2016, being endorsed by the president’s party was a popular
choice for politicians seeking a House seat: up to 70% of districts had a can-
didate affiliated with the president’s party. In the 2019 midterm elections, just
53% of House districts had at least one candidate from the dominant presi-
dential party (see Figure 22.1). The election of populist strongman Rodrigo
Duterte in 2016 exacerbated the country’s already fractured party system.
He eschewed patronage-based political party building in favour of pop-
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
2010 2013 2016 2019 2022
Congress Governor Mayor
Figure 22.1 Percentage of districts that included a nominee from the presidentʼs
party
Source: Updated from Kasuya and Teehankee (2020)
An Anarchy of Parties 475
From 1946 to 1969, the effective number of national parties in the Philip-
Based on the 2016, 2019, and 2022 election results, only six political parties
are considered competitive at the national and local levels of government.
These major parties are (1) Nacionalista Party (NP), (2) Liberal Party
(LP), (3) Partido Demokratikong Pilipino-Lakas ng Bayan (PDP-Laban),
(4) Lakas Christian-Muslim Democrats (Lakas CMD), (5) Nationalist Peo-
ple’s Coalition (NPC), and (6) National Unity Party (NUP).
The NP is the country’s oldest party. It was founded in 1907 as a merger of Fil-
ipino nationalist parties advocating immediate independence from American
colonial rule. The NP dominated electoral politics throughout the colonial
period. It continued its dominance from the inauguration of the Common-
wealth government in 1935 until the establishment of the Third Philippine
Republic in 1946. However, the party’s structure followed the elitist electoral
process and was therefore elitist.
In 1946, a major faction split from the NP to form the LP. The rivalry
between the two parties dominated Philippine politics from 1946 until 1972.
Both took turns capturing the presidency, controlling both chambers of
Congress, and winning local government seats. Ferdinand Marcos, who had
formerly been affiliated with the LP, was elected president as a member of
the NP. Marcos’ new party absorbed the bulk of the membership of both
parties—the Kilusang Bagong Lipunan (KBL; New Society Movement) after
he placed the country under martial law. A faction of the NP stayed with the
political opposition.
The party was revived after the fall of the Marcos dictatorship. Under the
leadership of billionaire politician Manuel Villar, the party has grown in
size and influence and is currently the second-largest party in the country.
Aside from serving as House Speaker and Senate President, Villar is presently
the wealthiest man in the Philippines. In the 2019 midterm elections, the
party won 3 national positions (senators) and 2,682 local positions (district
representatives, governors, vice governors, mayors, vice mayors, and local
legislators).
two-party system that dominated the post-war period. Locked out of power
upon the declaration of martial law, the remaining leaders of the party who
were not co-opted by the Marcos dictatorship became staunch defenders of
democracy. The party embraced mass-movement politics and played a sig-
nificant role in unifying the political opposition around the candidacy of
Corazon C. Aquino in 1986. After the EDSA revolution (named after the loca-
tion of the largest demonstrations) that ousted the dictator, the LP played an
active role in the democratic transition and consolidation in the country.
After entering into coalition with successive post-Marcos administrations,
The PDP-Laban was forged in the struggle against the Marcos dictatorship.
Its earlier incarnation was a promising progressive political party rooted in
social democratic ideology and organized by a cadre of seasoned activists. It
was the first electoral party to require ideological training before accepting
members. It was the de facto political party of Corazon Aquino during the
1986 snap presidential election and was the majority party in the early part
of the Cory administration (1986–1992). It suffered its first major setback in
1991 when a major faction split to form a new party—the LDP.
The party was weakened for decades and became a minor player in Philip-
pine politics until it successfully fielded Rodrigo Duterte to the presidency
in the 2016 election. As in previous administrations, droves of national and
478 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Speaker under the second Marcos presidency. Since 2022, Lakas CMD bene-
fitted the most from massive party switching to regain its position as the most
dominant party in the country.
There were several attempts to revive the moribund NP in the early post-
Marcos period. The post-Marcos NP was divided into four factions. Attempts
Citizen–Party Linkage
Party Financing
Rodrigo Duterte was the first to successfully utilize social media in a presi-
dential campaign in the Philippines. Given the initial weakness of his political
party, the PDP-Laban, his campaign depended on social media to boost his
candidacy. Among the presidential candidates who used social media cam-
paigning, Duterte’s online presence was the most aggressive and intense, even
using trolls and fake accounts. Moreover, Duterte’s supporters were not only
committed to their candidate online but also offline. They were consistently
part of the huge crowds who attended his political campaigns and rallies.
(Sinpeng et al. 2020).
Halfway into the second Marcos presidency, the various political parties
in the Philippines began their ritual of splitting and merging in anticipa-
tion of the 2025 midterm elections. Already, the de facto ruling party Lakas
CMD has been shaken by a leadership struggle between House Speaker
Romualdez and former president Arroyo. The feud resulted in the sudden
resignation of the party chair, Vice President Sara Duterte, who is a known
close Arroyo ally. On the other hand, the president’s original party in the
2022 election—the PFP—has actively been recruiting party switchers into its
ranks. Unfortunately, these political realignments reinforce the continuing
Note
1. The author acknowledges the research assistance of Ivan Harris Tanyag and Davijay
Leighton Engay for this chapter.
References
Agra, Alberto C. 1997. The Philippine Party-list System: A List Proportional Represen-
tation Scheme of Electing One-fifth of the Members of the House of Representatives.
Manila: Rex Book Store.
Batto, Nathan F. and Gary W. Cox. 2016. ‘Introduction: Legislature-centric and
Executive-centric Theories of Party Systems and Faction Systems’. In Nathan F.
Batto, Chi Huang, Alexander C. Tan, and Gary W. Cox (eds), Mixed-member Elec-
toral Systems in Constitutional Contexts: Taiwan, Japan and Beyond. Ann Arbor,
MI: University of Michigan Press, 1–24.
Choi, Jungug. 2001. ‘Philippine Democracies Old and New: Elections, Term Limits,
and Party System’. Asian Survey, 41(3):488–501.
Galvez, Daphne. 2023. ‘Sara Duterte Resigns from Lakas-CMD’. Inquirer.net, 19 May.
https://newsinfo.inquirer.net/1771350/fwd-sara-duterte-resigns-from-lakas-
cmd#:~:text=MANILA%2C%20Philippines%20%E2%80%94%20Vice%20
President%20and,her%20leaving%20the%20political%20party (Accessed 20
December 2023).
Hicken, Allen. 2016. ‘Thailand and the Philippines under MMM’. In Nathan F. Batto,
Chi Huang, Alexander C. Tan, and Gary W. Cox (eds), Mixed-member Electoral
Systems in Constitutional Contexts: Taiwan, Japan and Beyond. Ann Arbor, MI:
University of Michigan Press, 229–246.
IDEA. 2022. Voter Turnout Database. https://www.idea.int/data-tools/data/voter-
turnout (Accessed 20 December 2023).
484 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
While a sustained wave of mass opposition eventually washed away the for-
mal edifice of South Africa’s apartheid regime, ordinary South Africans have
yet to develop high levels of positive commitment to the institutions of liberal
democracy (Mattes 2019). Instead, the survival of liberal democracy in South
Africa has been based, thus far, on the actions of individual elite ‘gatekeepers’
(Levitsky and Ziblatt 2018) located largely in the country’s courts, parlia-
ment, and civil society organizations, and, sometimes, in political parties.
While some individuals have worked to defend democratic practices within
their parties, and some opposition parties have taken formal steps to counter
specific acts of democratic erosion through legal action, we argue that South
Africa’s parties have, collectively, weakened the country’s democratic experi-
ment by failing to commit fully to all aspects of liberal democracy, engaging
with voters, or offering voters a competitive electoral arena that provides
them with effective choices. South Africa thus has a supply-side problem in
its democracy, a problem exemplified by four important characteristics of the
country’s political party system, which in turn have their roots in a series of
structural and contingent factors.
Two and a half decades after its transition to democracy, South Africa’s politi-
cal party system is characterized by four striking features, none of which bode
well for the sustainability of high levels of representative democracy. The first
and most prominent characteristic is its 25-year dominance by the African
National Congress (ANC), which led resistance to the previous apartheid
regime, culminating in the country’s first democratic, non-racial election in
Robert Mattes, Matthias Krönke, and Sarah Lockwood, Political Parties and Democracy in South Africa. In: Political
Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press.
© Robert Mattes, Matthias Krönke, and Sarah Lockwood (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0023
490 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
1994. The ANC won that election with a resounding 62% of the vote and saw
its support rise even further in subsequent years, peaking at 69% in 2004
(Table 23.1). While its electoral support has receded somewhat in recent
years, the ANC still dominates the political arena, gaining 58% of the vote
in the most recent 2019 national election. This dominance raises concerns
about the accountability of the South African government, as well as reducing
the competitiveness of the electoral arena in problematic ways.
The second key feature of the country’s party system is that it is dominated
by organizations rooted in the pre-democratic, apartheid era, many of whom
parties in the old white parliament (the Democratic Party, and before that the
Progressive Federal Party). From this time, it maintains a worldview based
in the experience of the middle-class, white electorate, which often prevents
it from seeing the world through the eyes of the majority of South Africa’s
citizens today. This reduces its ability to engage with voters and limits the
role the DA can play as a truly competitive opposition party. Similarly, a sec-
ond significant opposition party, the Inkatha Freedom Party (IFP), which
governed the KwaZulu Bantustan during the apartheid era, continues to pri-
oritize issues related to the preservation of Zulu culture and interests and has
In the remainder of this chapter, we will argue that these four characteris-
tics (a still-dominant but declining governing party; the lingering shadow of
apartheid; a plethora of smaller, weak opposition parties; and declining lev-
els of voter turnout) have their roots in a series of structural and contingent
factors, resulting in a supply-side issue for democracy—in which South
African voters lack a truly competitive electoral arena, populated by engaged
parties offering genuine alternatives. We turn first to the structural factors.
In their classic volume, Seymour Martin Lipset and Stein Rokkan (1967)
demonstrated that a country’s current electoral cleavages reflect various
political, economic, or social ‘revolutions’. Such cleavages often ‘freeze’ and
continue as the dominant electoral dividing line years after the underly-
ing conflict has ceased to be important in and of itself. In South Africa,
the apartheid regime created a stark and enduring division between the
interests and values of the black, African majority and white, European
minority (who constituted the subordinate and superordinate groups in
South Africa’s ‘ranked’ society) (Horowitz 1985). Given the relative size of
those populations, moreover, it also created a vastly numerically imbalanced
cleavage, with roughly two-thirds of eligible voters on one side versus approx-
imately one-fifth on the other (with the balance comprising what Donald
Horowitz (1985) called ‘middle groups’ consisting of ‘coloured’ and ‘Indian’
voters).
Because the proportion of voters previously oppressed under the apartheid
system (plus their descendants) is so large, any political party linked to the
apartheid government (or symbolically connected to it in some way) faces a
huge challenge in gaining any sort of legitimacy among the wider electorate.
On the other side of the coin, the ANC has profited from a massive reserve
of credit from its successful opposition to apartheid but has worked hard to
maintain its position as the champion of the previously oppressed and to
position all opposition parties on the other side of the apartheid divide (see
Ferree 2010).
The result is a stark racial cleavage in party support bases; a dominant
ANC and a fractured, weak opposition struggling to capture the wider elec-
torate; and the continued importance of apartheid-era legacies to modern
party success. While actual votes cannot be broken down by race, and survey
Political Parties and Democracy in South Africa 493
results vary somewhat, the general trend is clear. Black voters have given
and continue to give the lion’s share of their votes to the ANC and to a few
other parties whose leaders came out of the ANC (the United Democratic
Movement, COPE, and EFF). In contrast, only a few black South Africans
vote for any political party that has historical connections to the old white
political system, and completely new parties have often struggled to gain
legitimacy without liberation-era credentials. Conversely, white voters have
largely voted for parties that worked within the apartheid system (albeit often
in opposition), with the bulk of votes going initially to the National Party
Electoral system
Public financial support for South Africa’s political parties takes two distinct
forms. First, public funds have been available direct to parties since 1997.
But while public funding is ideally intended to level the playing field and
provide all significant parties with the means to put their case before the
voters, South Africa’s system does the opposite. Until very recently, the vast
share of available funds (90%) was allotted to parties based on their national
and provincial legislative representation. Only 10% was given out equally,
(International IDEA 2021), for more than two decades the ANC and DA
were able to take advantage of undisclosed private donations, an advan-
tage that will take many years to erase. Certainly, only the ANC and DA
are able to employ substantial professional, permanent staff for activities like
fundraising, market research, policy development, and publicity.
Third, the ANC’s campaign spending has increased rapidly over the past
few elections, making it more and more difficult for smaller parties to level
the playing field. The ANC spent an estimated R300 million (approximately
US$44.7 million at the time) on its campaign activities in 2004, rising to
paign strategists will have the necessary organizational capacity and skill to
develop coherent campaigns across new and old media channels that would
in any realistic way close the gap with the dominant and better-resourced
ANC.
Contingent Factors
Beyond these structural factors, South Africa’s political parties are character-
ized by a range of organizational, performance, and strategic shortcomings
Party organization
The ANC
By any standard, the ANC is a highly structured organization with a long
pedigree. First organized by a small group of prominent Africans in 1912 (as
the South African Native National Congress), the ANC as a mass organiza-
tion dates back at least to the late 1940s (Butler 2012). Since its unbanning
as an organization in 1990, the ANC has had four party presidents (Nelson
Mandela, Thabo Mbeki, Jacob Zuma, and Cyril Ramaphosa), with none serv-
ing more than two five-year terms, each (re)elected at quinquennial party
conferences, at which several thousand delegates also elect the rest of the
party office bearers and National Executive Committee. The fact that the
party conference of the governing party takes place about 16 months ahead of
the national election, however, introduces the possibility of prolonged peri-
ods where the party leader differs from the state president. Indeed, this has
occurred on three separate occasions, with two of these instances creating
considerable political tension and organizational paralysis within the party.9
The party has a relatively high degree of internal complexity, with func-
tional subdivisions at the national level, nine provincial subdivisions, and
thousands of local branches (African National Congress 2017). However,
while South Africa is a federal system, the party’s provincial structures are
seen as co-equal in status to other functional subdivisions (e.g. Women’s,
Youth, and Veterans’ Leagues) and have no special role in party decision-
making. Rather party policies and key decisions are made by the National
Executive Committee (which consists of 80 members elected at large and
498 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
six key office holders), and on a daily basis by a smaller National Working
Committee. The ANC also has a set of policy bodies that shadow gov-
ernment ministries. Concerning the level of internal democracy, the ANC
scores well in measures of intra-party democracy developed by the Political
Party Database Project (see Figure 23.1), reflecting the involvement of local
branches in both candidate selection and manifesto development.10
Yet despite being an organizationally complex, geographically widespread,
and internally democratic organization, the ANC has not avoided episodes
of excessive personal control of the party, and it has failed to rein in the
1.0
0.8 0.7
0.7
0.6 0.5
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
BOT_BCP
UGA_FDC
MLW_UTM
KEN_Jubilee
SAF_ANC
BOT_BDP
NAM_SWAPO
NIG_PDP
MLW_MCP
KEN_ODM
MLW_UDF
NIG_APC
ZAM_UPND
SAF_EFE
BFO_MPP
GHA_NPP
AVERAGE
GHA_NDC
MLW_DPP
NAM_PDM/DTM
MAU_MMM
BFO_UPC
ZIM_Zanu-PF
ZIM_MDC
ZAM_PF
TAN_CCM
BOT_UDC
MLI_URD
NGR_PNDS-Tarayya
NGR_MNSD-Nassara
CAM_SDF
UGA_NRM
CAM_RDPC
SAF_DA
TAN_CHADEMA
SEN_APR
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
1994 1999 2004 2009 2014 2019
Despite grumblings from many in the ANC as this took place, old habits
developed during its years in exile (including secrecy, strict discipline, and
the privileging of loyalty above all else) meant that ANC caucus members
were unwilling to support successive votes of no confidence in Zuma until
the casting of a secret ballot became an option.
In addition to its failure to rein in autocratic tendencies, the geographi-
cally widespread organizational structure of the ANC has not prevented it
from isolating itself from interactions with civil society and their associated
accountability demands. In terms of its linkages with civil society, the ANC
has strong and long-standing relationships with the trade union and local
civic association movements. Yet it also has a strong degree of autonomy from
civil society. Indeed, many question whether allied civil society organizations
have retained sufficient autonomy from the ANC and, thus, space to criti-
cize and hold it accountable. Reflecting its historic drive to present a broad
united front against apartheid, the ANC has been the leading force in a tripar-
tite alliance with the South African Communist Party (SACP) and Congress
of South African Trade Unions (COSATU), and, more informally, with the
South African Civics Movement (SANCO)—linkages that provide the ANC
with tremendous advantages during election campaign periods. In return for
their work holding campaign rallies and canvassing and mobilizing voters,
and their pledge not to run their own slate of candidates, the ANC has placed
SACP and COSATU officials on the ANC list, who then take up their seats
as ANC MPs. The number of such seats is probably much larger than either
organization could win if they ran on their own, creating a disincentive for
500 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
these members to criticize ANC policy. For many years, for example, trade
unions and grassroots civic organizations were strongly opposed to ANC eco-
nomic policy, yet their MPs remained loyal to the party. In general, when
COSATU and its allied organizations have publicly criticized ANC policy,
the party has simply responded by condemning them as ‘ultra left’ rather
than engaging with the critique and justifying its own economic policy.
At the citizen level, moreover, while the ANC has a large number of local
branches, evidence suggests that those branches have a relatively limited
presence in their communities. In the 2019 election, for example, the ANC
Opposition Parties
Of South Africa’s three main opposition parties, only the DA has an
organization that is both relatively internally complex and geographically
widespread. Born from a 1989 merger of the liberal, anti-apartheid Pro-
gressive Federal Party with two factions that had broken from the ruling
NP, it then became the DA in 2003 when it joined forces with the remnants
of the NP and the small Federal Alliance. Currently, the DA controls the
government of the Western Cape province and the majority of local councils
in that province, as well as participating in executive coalitions in three
large metropolitan municipal councils outside the province (Tshwane,
Ekurhuleni, Johannesburg).
In contrast to the ANC, the DA is organized federally into nine provin-
cial structures (as well as a youth and women’s league) and led by a federal
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/book/58013 by guest on 17 November 2024
Figure 23.3 Party Presence Index, 35 countries, 2014–2015
Note: Scale represents the proportion of citizens who engaged with a political party in any one of four ways: attend rally, attend meeting,
worked for party during last campaign, contacted party official
Source: Krönke et al. (2022)
502 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
council. Since 1994, the party has experienced regular turnover of leadership,
with five party presidents (Zach De Beer, Tony Leon, Helen Zille, Mmusi
Maimane, and John Steenhuisen) elected at quinquennial federal party con-
gresses. As Figure 23.1 shows, moreover, the party has relatively high levels
of internal party democracy (though lower than the ANC).
While the party is organizationally strong on paper, however, like the ANC
it has relatively weak linkages with citizens. Compared to the ANC, the DA
engages a far smaller share of the electorate in person during the campaign
season. Nevertheless, the party has learned to contact voters virtually, which
given this, the party’s main societal linkage is with the traditional Zulu royal
household. Despite trying to appeal to a broader constituency, the party’s
social and economic conservatism, combined with a continued focus on
traditional leadership and close relations with the Zulu royal family, has
continued to appeal primarily to Zulu-speaking South Africans, limiting its
appeal as an opposition party. Organizationally, the party has relatively little
presence outside of KwaZulu-Natal and the city of Johannesburg; however,
within KwaZulu-Natal the IFP is relatively successful, controlling 9 out of 44
councils and representing the plurality of councillors in a further 16 councils.
Finally, we turn to consider the performance of the ruling party and the asso-
ciated strategies of the major opposition parties. Over the past quarter of a
504 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
For many years, the ANC played its role about as well might be expected. It
entered the post-apartheid dispensation with a deep reservoir of goodwill.
And given the numerically imbalanced cleavages stemming from the social
and economic divisions created by the apartheid regime, and other struc-
tural advantages created by the electoral system and the party funding and
campaign broadcasting rules, the ANC was rewarded handsomely at the bal-
lot box. As Lord Acton might have predicted, however, the size of the ANC’s
electoral victories and legislative majorities generated arrogance at the high-
est levels of party leadership, leading to hesitance and a fear of questioning
eccentric and misguided policies at all levels, and subsequently, malevolence
and corruption spanning the entire breadth of the party. Predictably, public
opinion surveys tracked consistent declines in citizen satisfaction with the
performance of the ANC government and identification with the ANC as
a party. But while the ANC has lost substantial voter support over the last
several elections, it remains the predominant party.
506 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
As for the country’s opposition parties, they have failed to play their role
effectively. The evidence reviewed in this chapter shows that the growing
ranks of dissatisfied South Africans feel they have nowhere to turn for a better
alternative. While the chief opposition party (the DA) has improved its image
in some respects, it—along with the rest of the opposition—has failed to con-
vince a sufficiently sizeable share of the electorate that they are competent
to govern, are inclusive, focused on the issues that matter, and trustworthy.
Most dissatisfied voters thus face the choice of holding their noses and taking
another chance with the governing party or staying home on election day—a
Notes
1. Ethnicity also plays an important role within racial groups in some areas. For instance,
the support that the Inkatha Freedom Party receives comes overwhelmingly from Zulu-
speaking black South Africans, and the votes for the Freedom Front Plus come over-
whelmingly from Afrikaans-speaking whites. Even allowing for this, however, the general
trend still applies.
2. Coloured and Indian voters have been more likely to cross these historical dividing
lines—splitting their votes over time, as a group, between the ANC, NP, and DA. They
form a relatively small part of the South African electorate, however (9% and 3%,
respectively), leaving the dominant trends as above (Statistics South Africa 2016).
Political Parties and Democracy in South Africa 507
3. Voters are also able to cast a second ballot for representatives to their provincial assem-
blies.
4. The ANC briefly changed the constitution in 2002 to allow members to switch parties
during specific periods and according to a complex set of rules. However, the mea-
sure proved to be highly unpopular and was abolished by a subsequent constitutional
amendment in 2009.
5. While the ANC’s vote share fell under 50% in the 2021 local council elections, it has so
far maintained a dominant majority at the national level.
6. This figure falls well below the 34-country average (38%) for Round 8 (2019/2021) of the
Afrobarometer survey.
References
Africa, Cherrel. 2019. ‘Do Election Campaigns Matter in South Africa? An Exam-
ination of Fluctuations in Support for the ANC, DA, IFP and NNP 1994–2019’.
Politikon, 46(4):371–389.
African National Congress. 2017. ANC 54th National Conference Report and Res-
olutions. 54th National Conference of the African National Congress, Johannes-
burg. https://cisp.cachefly.net/assets/articles/attachments/73640_54th_national_
conference_report.pdf (Accessed 20 December 2023).
Ferree, Karen E. 2010. Framing the Race in South Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Fölscher, Marine, Nicola de Jager, and Robert Nyenhuis. 2021. ‘Populist Parties Shift-
ing the Political Discourse? A Case Study of the Economic Freedom Fighters in
South Africa’. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 59(4):535–558.
Horowitz, Donald L. 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press.
Horowitz, Donald L. 1991. A Democratic South Africa? Constitutional Engineering in
a Divided Society. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Lührmann, Anna, Nils Düpont, Masaaki Higashijima et al. 2020. Codebook Vari-
eties of Party Identity and Organization (V-Party) V1. Varieties of Democracy
(V-Dem) Project. https://doi.org/10.23696/vpartydsv1 (Accessed 20 December
2023).
Mattes, Robert. 2019. ‘Democracy in Africa: Demand, Supply, and the “Dissatisfied
Democrat”’. Afrobarometer Policy Paper 54.
Mattes, Robert. 2002. ‘South Africa: Democracy without the People?’. Journal of
Democracy, 13(1):22–36.
Ndamase, Siphesihle. 2020. Policy Brief on Party and Campaign Finance in South
South African History Online. 2019. EFF 2019 Election Manifesto. https://www.
sahistory.org.za/archive/eff-2019-election-manifesto (Accessed 20 May 2022).
Southall, Roger. 2014. ‘Democracy at Risk? Politics and Governance under the ANC’.
The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 652(1):48–69.
Southall, Roger. 2016. Liberation Movements in Power: Party and State in Southern
Africa. London: James Currey.
Statistics South Africa. 2016. Community Survey 2016, Statistical Release P0301.
Statistics South Africa.
Thuynsma, Heather. 2017. ‘Securing their Future: Using Election Campaigns to Safe-
The health and resilience of a country’s democracy are often gauged by the
strength of its democratic institutions, including its political parties (IDEA
2017). In addition to their traditional functions, namely, ‘electoral struc-
turation’, ‘symbolic integration’, and aggregation of the interests of citizens,
political parties also contribute to ensuring political accountability, demo-
cratic stability, and national unity (Mainwaring and Scully 1995). To be
effective, however, political parties are expected to be inclusive and trans-
parent in their operations and maintain democratic principles, especially as
they pertain to their internal processes (Morton 2017).
Political party systems can be one-party, two-party, or multi-party. The
greater the number, the greater the likelihood that the electorate will be
presented with alternative platforms. Over the last six decades, Nigeria has
experimented with various systems. The one-party system has been touted in
pluralistic societies, such as Nigeria, to promote national unity and manage
religious and ethnic diversity (Hamalai et al. 2017). Regardless of its antici-
pated merits, it has been contested that the one-party system is more likely
to result in authoritarianism and political exclusion. Alternatively, the two-
party system, in which parties have distinct ideological postures, such as in
the USA and the UK, is said to have the advantage of engendering polit-
ical information to the electorate in a simplified and understandable way,
political stability and balance, and fewer voting choices. On the reverse side,
however, others have pointed out the challenges associated with the two-
party system, such as the exclusion of minority views, limited choice (and
hence voter apathy), and in some instances negative partisanship, or what has
been described as affective polarization (Iyengar et al. 2012; Hetherington
Jake D. Dan-Azumi, Political Parties in Nigeria’s Fourth Republic, 1999–2019. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Jake D. Dan-Azumi (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0024
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 513
and Rudolph 2015). This system has a long history in Nigeria and was tested
between 1992 and 1993 (the so-called aborted Third Republic) (Oyediran
and Agbaje 1991; Lewis 1996; Adejumobi 1997). As with the one-party sys-
tem, this also failed because the two parties were not ideologically different
(Yaqub 2002).
Since 1999, Nigeria has had a multi-party system with several polit-
ical parties contesting general elections. It is considered more suited to
pluralistic societies and contexts and is more likely to offer a political
platform for varied and diverse interests, including political, religious, cul-
1959 148 89 - 75
1964 189 109 5 -
a
NPC—Northern People’s Congress; NNA—Nigerian
National Alliance, a coalition of parties that contested the
1964 federal elections; NCNC—National Council of
Nigeria and Cameroons; AG—Action Group; and
ZCP—Zamfara Commoner’s Party.
Source: Hamalai (2014: 47) and Independent National
Electoral Commission
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 515
1979 36 28 16 8 7
1983 60 6 12 1 5
a
NPN—National Party of Nigeria; UPN—Unity Party
of Nigeria; NPP—Nierian People Party; GNPP—Great
Nigeria Peoples Party; PRP—People’s Redemption
Party.
Source: Hamalai (2014: 47) and Independent National
Electoral Commission
516 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
1999 to 2019
In the first 16 years of the Fourth Republic (1999–present), the PDP was
among three parties successfully registered out of the initial nine that applied,
and it was granted provisional registration on 5 December 1998. The six other
parties failed to meet the requirement that parties score at least 5% of the total
votes cast in a minimum of 24 states across Nigeria as a precondition for final
registration (Momoh and Thovoethin 2001).
The emergence of the PDP has been characterized as top-down rather
than bottom-up. A national coalition of 34 ex-military officers, politicians,
and other elites formed G34. This group, led by Nigeria’s former vice pres-
ident in the Second Republic (1979–1983), Alex Ekwueme, was a pressure
group opposed to attempts by General Sani Abacha to transform from a
military head of state to a civilian president. In the aftermath of Abacha’s
death on 8 June 1998, General Abdulsalam Abubakar took over and imme-
diately announced a timetable for returning the country to civilian rule by
May 1999. Elections for governors were scheduled for December 1998, while
those for the president were slated for February 1999, with an official han-
dover date of 29 May 1999. In addition, Abubakar released political prisoners,
embarked on substantial political, economic, and social reforms, and estab-
lished an independent election-monitoring body, the INEC, under Decree 17
of 1998 (Dagne 2006). Against the background of these developments, G34
was transformed into the PDP in August 1998.
Owing to its origins as a pressure group comprising various actors across
the broad spectrum of Nigerian society, the PDP was ab initio elitist driven.
This became evident in the processes leading to the emergence of the
party’s flagbearer for the presidential election. The founding chairman, Alex
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 519
Ekwueme, was pushed aside, and the ticket was given to the former mili-
tary head of state, Olusegun Obasanjo. This was done with the backing of
powerful and wealthy members of the party, who considered him a more
predictable and reliable option.
From the onset, the PDP lacked an ideological core to distinguish it from
others and determine its policy goals. Founders of the PDP portrayed the
party as a natural successor to the National Republic Convention, which was
established in 1993 by the military-led government of Ibrahim Babangida
and the NPN. However, this is highly debatable and difficult to establish given
As stated above, the PDP became the dominant political party in Nigeria in
1999, with considerable government control at both the national and state
levels. For 16 years, the party won all presidential elections and maintained
a majority in the Senate and House of Representatives.
Presidential
The results of the first four general elections (1999, 2003, 2007, and 2011)
clearly show the PDP’s dominance (Figure 24.1). The percentage of votes
secured by PDP candidates in 1999 and 2003 was 62%. This increased to
69.60% in 2007 but dropped to 58.87% in 2011.
520 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
80
69.6
70 62.7
53.95
60 58.87
61.94 57.42
50
40 37.29 32.19 42.57
44.96
30 31.96
18.91
20
3.28 7.45 5.44
10
2.39 0.1
While the party’s victory remained impressive over the period, voter sup-
port declined steadily. Nevertheless, given its dominance in all six geopoliti-
cal zones of Nigeria, the PDP can be described as Nigeria’s first pan-national
political party that was largely successful in transcending ethnic and religious
identities. This is evidenced by the party’s performance in the 2011 presi-
dential and National Assembly elections across all six zones, averaging 64%
(EUEOM 2015).
However, 2015 was a watershed moment in Nigerian political history.
For the first time, an opposition party won the presidential elections. It
swept away the ruling party and established solid control at the national
level and across the Federation. This peaceful transition of power consoli-
dated Nigeria’s position as a growing democracy. The candidate of the APC,
Muhammadu Buhari, won the presidential elections with 15,424,921 votes
(53.95%), while the incumbent, Goodluck Jonathan of the PDP, received
12,853,162 votes (44.96%). In the 2019 elections, the APC maintained its con-
trol at the centre with a victory in the presidential and National Assembly
polls. President Buhari was re-elected with 15,191,847 votes (57.42%), beat-
ing the PDP’s closest opponent, Atiku Abubakar (who received 11,262,978
votes), by over three million votes. Simultaneously, three other political par-
ties (PCP, ADC, and APGA) received 309,481 votes. Buhari won in 19 of the
36 states, whereas Abubakar won in 17 states.
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 521
National Assembly
The dominance of the PDP between 1999 and 2011 in both chambers of the
National Assembly (the Senate and House of Representatives) was extensive,
as shown in Figure 24.2. In the 20 February 1999 election, the PDP won 62
out of 109 seats (56.88%) in the Senate and 214 out of 360 seats (59.44%) in
the House. The APP secured 24 seats (22.02%) in the Senate and 77 (21.39%)
in the House. On the other hand, AD won 23 (21.1%) seats in the Senate and
68 (18.89%) in the House.
In 2003, the PDP increased its majority in the Senate, with 76 out of the 109
90
80 78.9
70 69.72 66.1 55.05
60 56.88 58.72
50
40 40.37
22.02 24.77 13.76 44.95
30
16.5
20 5.5
21.1 5.5 5.5
10 6.4
0 1.84
1999 2003 2007 2011 2015 2019
PDP APP/ANPP AD/AC/CAN LP
CPC APGA APC Others
80
73.06
70 59.44 61.67 63
60 58.89
56.4
50
40 35
35.28
30 21.39 26.94
20 19.2
17.22
18.89 9.44
10 7.5
8.89
0
Thus, between 1999 and 2011, the PDP held a majority position in the
House. Although it never won the two-thirds majority (72 in the Senate and
240 in the House) needed for major legislative actions (such as constitutional
amendments and the impeachment of the executive or presiding officers), it
nonetheless had a comfortable majority for most legislative decision mak-
ing. However, in general, there was a gradual weakening of the position of
the PDP in the National Assembly and a steady, even if minimal, rise in the
number of seats won by other parties in the opposition. This trend has been
explained by improvements in the conduct of elections and overall election
management (Akhaine 2011; Gberie 2011; Omotola 2011), growing disillu-
sionment with the ruling party, growing recognition of opposition parties,
and internal conflicts within the ruling party, among others.
Suffice it to say that the erosion of the dominance of the PDP began in
2011 when its hold in the Senate was reduced from 86 seats in 2007 to 72.
By 2015, the party had lost 24 seats. A similar development occurred in the
House of Representatives, where the PDP lost 140 seats between 2007 and
2011—a trend that continued until 2015.
At the sub-national level, the PDP maintained an equal lead in both the
governorship and State Houses of Assembly elections from 1999 to 2011, as
Figures 24.4 and 24.5 show. There was a progressive increase in the number
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 523
90.0
77.8 75.7
80.0 77.8
70.0 61.1
58.3 63.9
60.0 51.5
50.0
40.0 48.5
36.1
30.0 25.0
19.4
16.7
20.0 16.7 13.5 8.3
8.3 8.3 5.6
10.0 2.8
2.8 2.7
80 70.9 68.98
70 63.53
55.15 56.36
60 54.34
50
40
27.07 3.13 39.49
30 21.91 36.86
16.76 16.66
20 2.42
17.37 1.01
5.25 1.81 7.57 1.61 2.72
10 10 3.13 2.62 4.14
3.23
0 0.4 0.2
1999 2003 2007 2011 2015 2019
Figure 24.5 Seats won in State Houses of Assembly by political parties (%)
Source: INECʼs Report of 1999, 2003, 2007, 2011, 2015, and 2019 General Elections
However, in the 2019 general elections, the APC saw a decline in control,
winning 17 states, while the PDP won 16. The APC subsequently won over
more states through court decisions and defections.
At the sub-national level (Figure 24.5), the PDP maintained firm con-
trol between 1999 and 2011. In the 1999 elections, the PDP won 546 seats
(55.15%) out of 990 in the various State Houses of Assembly in the country,
compared to AP’s 268 seats (27.07%) and AD’s 172 seats (17.37%). The PDP’s
share of seats in the State Houses of Assembly rose to its highest in 2003, when
the party won 702 seats (70.90%), while AP and AD won 217 (21.91%) and
Several arguments have been advanced to explain the PDP’s dominance over
the 16 years since it won four successive elections (1999, 2003, 2007, and
2011). This is even more surprising considering the party’s deficient per-
formance in ensuring security, economic growth, and development. Figures
from the National Bureau of Statistics show a steady rise in poverty levels
in Nigeria between 1980 and 2010. For instance, its report shows that in
2010, 60.9% of Nigerians lived in absolute poverty, as against 54.7% in 2004
(NBS 2010).
Some reasons for the prolonged dominance of the PDP include its plural-
istic outlook and success in forming coalitions among divergent stakeholders
and positions. This is exemplified by the composition of its founding mem-
bers, who include politicians and retired military officers. The latter has
been described as a reason for the success and dominance of the PDP. The
military ruled Nigeria for decades and established control and extensive
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 525
member of the Senate or the House of Representatives shall vacate his seat
if he ‘becomes a member of another political party’. However, the Constitu-
tion further lays out the conditions for defection, that is, it can only be done
‘provided that his membership of the latter political party is not as a result of
a division in the political party of which he was previously a member or of
a merger of two or more political parties or factions by one of which he was
previously sponsored’ (Section 68(g)). This latter provision has been used to
justify defection, particularly because it is obscure and does not define what
‘division’ means. As such, any internal disagreement within a party has been
in most parts of the country and the seeming incapacity of the government to
stem the tide probably pushed the people to revolt against the PDP. The most
prominent challenge was the rise of Islamic militancy in north-east Nigeria.
A terrorist sect called Boko Haram, founded in 2002 but rising in promi-
nence in 2009, grew and expanded rapidly, seizing control of several local
governments in the country’s north-east. Its activities disrupted the social
and economic livelihoods of people in the region and caused the deaths of
thousands.
Changes in electoral management by the INEC and innovations that
elections. Some issues that confronted the parties included the imposition of
candidates by political godfathers, opaque and non-competitive primaries,
violations of party guidelines on the conduct of primaries, and the moneti-
zation of the whole process. The Electoral Act 2010 requires political parties
to hold direct or indirect primaries for aspirants in all elective positions. The
bigger parties (the PDP and APC) have often relied more on indirect pri-
maries to nominate candidates. As a result, the party primaries process is
usually controlled by powerful politicians holding public offices, especially
governors of the respective states, in the case of the ruling party, or wealthy
Regardless of the political party in power, the number of women at all lev-
els of government has not changed significantly since 1999. From 1999 to
2019, women’s representation in the Nigerian legislature (109 Senate seats,
360 House of Representatives seats, and 997 State Houses of Assembly seats)
has never reached 10%. In the Senate, the highest was 8.3% (9 seats) between
2007 and 2011; in the House, it peaked at 7.2% (26 seats) between 2011
and 2015. It is worse at the sub-national level, where women’s representa-
tion peaked at 6.9% (68) between 2011 and 2015. This is despite the policy
documents of successive governments subscribing to more seats for women
in elective and appointive positions.
Many reasons have been advanced for the low level of women’s participa-
tion in elective politics, including an unfavourable political system that makes
it difficult for women to participate fully. Additionally, women face cultural
and socio-economic barriers, lower levels of employment and education,
corrupt and patronage-based political systems, and electoral violence (Dan-
Azumi and Asan 2021). Historically, there have been fewer female candidates
in the north than in the south, mainly because of a fusion of religious and
cultural factors that disapprove of women’s political involvement. Despite
this, there was no significant difference in the number of women elected
from the two parts of the country into political positions. Women’s ability
to seek and win political office is further limited by their relatively weaker
economic status in Nigeria. Data from the National Bureau of Statistics, the
World Bank, and the International Monetary Fund have consistently shown
that women constitute the bulk of Nigeria’s poorest population (World Bank
532 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Conclusion
Since Nigeria gained its independence in 1960, political parties in the coun-
try have struggled to establish themselves as genuine national and unifying
platforms. The political parties in the first two Republics were predominantly
ethnically based. This reflects the pluralistic and heterogeneous nature of the
country with multiple ethnic groups and religions. Reform attempts have
sought to establish parties that transcend these limitations, with minimal
success. Since the return to democratic rule in 1999, dominant parties have
made significant strides towards building national appeal. Legal and statu-
tory frameworks now require political parties to have a nationwide presence.
This has resulted in the building of consensus and coalitions as strategies for
winning elections. Consequently, two political parties dominated the Fourth
Republic: the PDP, which dominated between 1999 and 2011, and the APC,
which gained supremacy in 2015 and became the first opposition party in
Nigeria’s history to unseat a ruling party.
As mentioned above, the characteristics of the major political parties in
Nigeria are not easily discernible. They are essentially a loose amalgam
of powerful interest groups desirous of obtaining and holding power. The
multi-party system adopted in 1999 gave rise to numerous political parties
lacking ideological bases. Subsequent reforms have attempted to rationalize
the number of parties. Ninety-one registered political parties contested the
2019 general elections.
Overall, political parties in Nigeria have faced similar challenges, including
the lack of internal party democracy, which has resulted in litigation, defec-
tion, fragmentation, and conflict on numerous occasions. Whichever party
is in power sustains itself mainly through reliance on state resources and
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 533
There is little doubt that Nigeria’s democracy has grown significantly since
1999, and political parties have played a significant role in this regard. Multi-
party systems remain the dominant model. However, this requires significant
modification, particularly given the proliferation of political parties, many of
which are not viable. Thus, the political landscape will likely be dominated
by two parties despite the constitutional recognition of multiple parties. The
major parties can be expected to continue to dominate, but membership in
both will remain fluid as members transfer allegiance in pursuit of political
power. This is enabled by a weak regulatory framework that fails to hinder
Note
1. An honorific title that is the equivalent of the commander-in-chief of the royal army of
the Sultan and leader of Muslims in northern Nigeria.
References
Adejumobi, Said. 1997. ‘The Two Political Parties and the Electoral Process in Nige-
ria, 1989–1993’. In George Nzongola Ntalaja and M. C. Lee (eds), The State and
Democracy in Africa. Harare: AAPS Books, 126–140.
Adekanye, J. Bayo. 1999. The Retired Military as Emergent Power Factor in Nigeria.
Ibadan: Heinemann Educational Books Nigeria plc.
Adetula, Victor A. O. (ed.). 2008. Money and Politics in Nigeria. Abuja: Petra Digital
Press.
Akhaine, Sylvester Odion. 2011. ‘Nigeria’s 2011 Elections: The “Crippled Giant”
Learns to Walk?’ African Affairs, 110(441):649–655.
Dagne, Ted. 2006. Nigeria in Political Transition, report, 1 June https://digital.library.
unt.edu/ark:/67531/metacrs10499 (Accessed 27 September 2021).
Dan-Azumi, Jake Dabang and Caroline Asan. 2021. ‘Women and Legislative Repre-
sentation in Nigeria’s National Assembly: A Detailed Appraisal of the 8th Assembly
(2015–2019)’. Journal of Public Administration and Governance, 11(2):86–109.
Diamond, Larry and Rotimi T. Suberu. 2002. ‘Institutional Design, Ethnic Conflict
Management, and Democracy in Nigeria’. In Andrew Reynolds (ed.), The Architec-
ture of Democracy: Constitutional Design, Conflict Management, and Democracy.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 400–428.
Diamond, Larry. 1988. Class, Ethnicity, and Democracy in Nigeria: The Failure of the
First Republic. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press.
Political Parties in Nigeriaʼs Fourth Republic, 1999–2019 535
Kuenzi, Michelle and Gina Lambright. 2005. ‘Party Systems and Democratic Con-
solidation in Africa’s Electoral Regimes’. Party Politics, 11(2):423–446.
Lewis, Peter. 1996. ‘From Prebendalism to Predation: Political Economy of Decline
in Nigeria’. Journal of Modern African Studies, 34(1):79–103.
Lindberg, Staffan I., Nils Düpont, Masaaki Higashijima, et al. 2022. Varieties of
Party Identity and Organization (V{Party) Dataset; https://v-dem.net/data/v-
party-dataset/country-party-date-v2/ (Accessed 2 February 2024).
Mainwaring, Scott and Timothy Scully. 1995. Building Democratic Institutions: Party
Systems in Latin America. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Isaac Owusu-Mensah et al., The State of Political Party Development in Ghana. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Isaac Owusu-Mensah et al. (2024).
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0025
538 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
30.00%
10.00%
7.29%
2.95% 1.75%
2.92% 1... 1.32%
0.00%
2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 2020
today, the parties’ platforms are the only legitimate arenas to confer political
power on national leaders as well as ensure their removal. Leaning on their
particularistic ideologies, the parties have intermediated and created oppor-
tunities to aid upward social and political mobility through elite consensus,
which, albeit limited, can help to sustain the new democratic order.
the regional and national levels. The parties’ organizations at the national,
regional, and constituency levels are run by the office of their respective sec-
retaries, or general secretaries in the case of the national party, who assist
their chairpersons in the day-to-day running of the parties and traditionally
act as the parties’ spokespersons.
Salient among their structures are the youth and women’s wings. In recog-
nition of the special role women and the youth play in the party organization,
Ghanaian parties have assigned a special place to these groups. The women’s
wings are noted for their caucus activities, including advocating for quotas
Party Membership
NDC and NPP have incorporated biometric registration into their registra-
tion systems.) The parties’ constitutions have many rules related to loyalty
and procedures for punishment for disloyalty. When the applicant’s mem-
bership registration is accepted, the member is strictly obliged to conform to
the party’s discipline and rules of conduct. The most undisciplined members
who brought the name of the parties into disrepute have been expelled. Since
2000, some members of both the NDC and NPP have faced expulsion orders
on grounds of indiscipline and ‘flirting’ with opponents (Debrah 2014).
However, parties in Ghana have not been able to provide an ‘organizational
Party Financing
programmes and appeal to the electorate. The parties are more concerned
about the practical ways of improving the lot of the people—protecting the
vulnerable, providing basic amenities, providing employment, and expand-
ing the market base for socio-economic development—rather than about
the left–right ideological continuum, even though on paper they maintain
their ideological leanings. For instance, the NDC and NPP are aligned with
the global coalitions of ideological parties with their corresponding regional
and sub-regional parliamentary groups (the NDC and NPP belong to the
Conservative and Socialist Parliamentary international groups, respectively).
influence. Besides being nebulous and with cumbersome utility, the pro-
cesses of channelling members’ grievances and resolutions from the bottom
up remain exercises in futility. Moreover, the amount of information emanat-
ing from the national executives to sub-national executives rarely gets to the
ordinary members. The latter’s reliance on information about their parties
through a few activists and rumour mills demonstrates the extent to which the
rank and file are alienated from their parties. It is commonplace for Ghana-
ian politicians to go to their parties and supporters every four years when
they need them to renew their mandates to national offices. After manipu-
Inter-party Conflicts
been particularly marked since 1992. Many factions within the parties have
developed strategies consisting of efforts to undermine other nominees to
ensure the rival faction gains a slate of sensitive positions with a view to turn-
ing the recruitment fortune in favour of their own candidate(s) and to carry
out political engineering where powerful groups sponsor the disqualification
of the candidacy of arch-rivals who pose a severe threat to their electoral
victory.
Ghana has enjoyed a stable democracy for the past three decades, earning the
admiration of both domestic elites and the international community. Political
parties have remained a principal pivot around which the current democ-
racy revolves. Without their involvement, the democratic system would have
suffered irreversible setbacks. Thus, the parties can be described as the soul
that has kept democracy in Ghana flourishing. Their platforms continue to
serve as grounds for political participation by the citizens. The active involve-
ment of women and youths in the political process is the direct result of their
mobilization by the parties: these groups have been at the centre of political
recruitment. After every election, the parties have provided human resources
capable of filling the legions of vacant political office positions. Similarly,
they have contributed to policymaking through manifesto drafting, which
has served as a framework to develop post-election public policy instruments
that direct national development. While partisanship has produced tenden-
cies that have engendered inter-party conflicts and acrimonies, the activism
of the parties’ foot soldiers has kept democracy alive not only by stimulating
high voter attendance but also by encouraging opposition oversight of the
ruling government’s activities.
Given the synergy between active participation and democratic institu-
tionalization, the vibrant party politics that political parties’ engagements
have engendered among the populace points towards an optimistic outlook
552 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Note
1. They have splintered into the National Independent Party, Peoples’ Heritage Party,
References
Achury, Susan, Susan E. Scarrow, Karina Kosiara-Pedersen, and Emilie van Haute.
2020. ‘The Consequences of Membership Incentives: Do Greater Political Benefits
Attract Different Kinds of Members?’ Party Politics, 26(1):56–68.
Debrah, Emmanuel. 2014. ‘Intra-party Democracy in Ghana’s Fourth Republic: The
Case of the New Patriotic Party and National Democratic Congress’. Journal of
Power, Politics & Governance, 2(3):57–75.
Gyimah-Boadi, Emmanuel and Emmanuel Debrah. 2008. ‘Political Parties and
Party Politics’. In Baffour Agyeman-Dua (ed.), Ghana: Governance in the Fourth
Republic. Tema: Digibooks Ghana Ltd, 126–154.
Hoffman, Barak D., and James D. Long. 2013. ‘Ethnicity and Voting in African
Elections’. Comparative Politics, 45(2):127–146.
IDEA. 2022. Voter Turnout Database. https://www.idea.int/data-tools/data/voter-
turnout (Accessed 21 December 2023).
International Foundation for Electoral Systems. 2022. https://www.electionguide.
org/countries/id/158/ (Accessed 21 December 2023).
Kosiara-Pedersen, Karina, Susan E. Scarrow, and Emilie van Haute, 2017. ‘Rules
of Engagement? Party Membership Costs, New Forms of Party Affiliation, and
Partisan Participation’. In Susan E. Scarrow, Paul D. Webb, and Thomas Pogun-
tke (eds), Organizing Political Parties: Representation, Participation, and Power.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 234–258.
NDC (National Democratic Congress). 1992. Elections Party Manifestos—
Continuity and Stability.
NPP (New Patriotic Party). 1992. Development in Freedom, 1992 Presidential and
Parliamentary Elections Manifestos.
The State of Political Party Development in Ghana 553
Poletti, Monica, Paul D. Webb, and Tim Bale. 2019. ‘Why Do Only Some People
Who Support Parties Actually Join Them? Evidence from Britain’. West European
Politics, 42(1):156–172. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2018.1479921
Republic of Ghana. 1992. 1992 Constitution. Accra: Assembly Press.
Republic of Ghana. 2000. Political Parties Act, Act 574. Accra: Assembly Press.
Saffu, Yaw. 2003. ‘The Funding of Political Parties and Election Campaigns in Africa’.
In Reginald Austin and Maja Tjernstrom (eds), Funding of Political Parties and
Election Campaigns: Handbook Series. Stockholm: IDEA, 21–29.
Strøm, Kaare. 1990. ‘A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties’. American
Wilhelm Hofmeister
As the chapters in this volume have underscored, many political parties face
serious difficulties effectively fulfilling the functions commonly ascribed to
them.1 So, the question is whether and how the parties can be helped to per-
form better and whether international party assistance can contribute to this
aim? In this chapter, I try to provide an answer in relation to this question.
My remarks are very much shaped by my own experiences of international
cooperation with political parties as an employee of the Konrad Adenauer
Foundation (KAF). After a few brief comments about the basic problems of
party assistance, some of these practical experiences will be presented, which
are not paradigmatic but nonetheless may illustrate the possibilities and lim-
its of party assistance. In a subsequent section, an overview of the sponsors
and instruments of international party assistance will be provided, which is
followed by a discussion of criticisms regarding the ineffectiveness of party
sponsorship. Finally, a few recommendations will be formulated on how to
make international party assistance more coherent and efficient.
Party assistance can be defined as ‘the organizational effort to support
democratic political parties, to promote a peaceful interaction between par-
ties, and to strengthen the democratic political and legal environment for
political parties’ (Burnell and Gerrits 2012: 4). Its purpose is to strengthen
one or more parties, thereby indirectly promoting democracy. Party assis-
tance is thus a specific part of promoting democracy and is therefore
characterized by the same possibilities and limitations.
Even more than other approaches to promoting democracy, such as
strengthening civil society organizations or the free press, party assistance
affects a central area of politics: the struggle for political power, because that
is a main objective of political parties. It is for this reason that party assistance
Wilhelm Hofmeister, Can the Parties be Helped?. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy. Edited by: Thomas Poguntke
and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Wilhelm Hofmeister (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0026
558 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
KAF also funded a training institute for trade unions that advised, among
others, the most important union leader of that time, Manuel Bustos, also
a Christian Democrat. In rural areas, an agrarian aid institution and two
cooperative unions were KAF partners that had been closely associated with
the PDC since the land reforms of the first Christian Democratic President
Eduardo Frei (1964–1970), thereby strengthening the party’s link to the rural
population. In the poor neighbourhoods of the larger cities, or poblaciónes,
KAF supported a self-help organization for the pobladores, also led by PDC
members. A very important part of the foundation’s work was the granting
strongest party in the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate. It won the pres-
idency again in 1994 with Eduardo Frei.2 This was a success for KAF not
only because the foundation had been working continuously with the PDC
since 1963, which had even been possible during the military dictatorship
with restrictions, but also because many members of the government formed
in 1994, and many members of Congress, had worked in one way or another
at institutions and projects funded by KAF.
Essential for the foundation’s work was the close contact between the party
leadership of the PDC and the German Christian Democratic Union (CDU)
At the time, KAF’s party assistance programme in other countries was also
characterized by ideological affinity and the partisan approach, although the
parties it was assisting did not always conquer top political positions, and
some only managed to do so temporarily. A decade prior to its success in
Can the Parties be Helped? 561
Many of those parties were accepted into the European party families. But
by no means were all parties able to succeed politically.
In Asia, the recent experience in Myanmar indicates how difficult it is
to promote democracy and parties. KAF was one of the first international
organizations that was able to support civil society organizations through
a local partner after the devastation of Cyclone Nargis in 2008. During the
preparations for the 2010 parliamentary elections, which were still subject
to significant restrictions, the first training activities with representatives
of many newly founded parties became possible, especially regional par-
into the political camp within the Soviet sphere of influence. The German
foundations benefited from the fact that there were already parties in Latin
America that had an ideological affinity with the two major parties in Ger-
many, the CDU and the SPD. Christian Democrats and Socialists were the
first partners of German party assistance. As the foundations’ work expanded
geographically, it became difficult to identify partners with the same political
and ideological affinities. Nevertheless, the foundations clung to one element
of their party assistance: exclusively working with just one party. However,
they were increasingly pragmatic when choosing these partners. They estab-
Austria
Dr.-Karl-Renner-Institut Social Democratic Party of Austria 0.9 (2017)
Politische Akademie Austrian People’s Party 0.9 (2017)
FPÖ–Bildungsinstitut Freedom Party of Austria 0.7 (2017)
Grüne Bildungswerkstatt Austrian Green Party—The Green Alternative 0.4 (2017)
NEOS Lab NEOS—The New Austria and Liberal Forum 0.14 (2017)
Team Stronach Akademie Team Stronach Party 0.1 (2017)
Czech Republic
CEVRO Non-partisan Not specified
Denmark
Danish Institute for Parties and Democracy (DIPD) Supported by nine parties represented in the Danish parliament 3.2 (2018)
c
Germany
Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung (KAS) Christian Democratic Union (CDU) 116.4 (2021)
Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung (FES) Social Democratic Party (SPD) 110.7 (2021)
Friedrich-Naumann-Stiftung (FNS) Free Democratic Party (FDP) 41.2 (2019)
Heinrich-Böll-Stiftung (HBS) The Green Party 40.5 (2021)
Hanns-Seidel-Stiftung (HSS) Christian Social Union (CSU) 37.4 (2018)
Rosa-Luxemburg-Stiftung (RLS) The Left Party 47.6 (2021)
Finland
Political Parties of Finland for Democracy (Demo Finland) Supported by nine parties in the Finnish parliament 2.3 (2021)
United Kingdom
Westminster Foundation for Democracy (WFD) Joint leadership by members of the Conservative and Labour 11.3 (2020/21)
Party
Netherlands
Eduardo Frei Foundation (EFF) Christian Democratic Appeal (CDA) No information
Continued
Table 26.1 Continued
Australia
Centre for Democratic Institutions (CDI) Non-partisan, affiliated with the Australian National University No information
(ANU)
Multilateral Organizations:
European Endowment for Democracy 25.0 (2021)
European Partnership for Democracy Association of various organizations, including DIPD, Demo, No information
NIMD, WFD
International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance Non-partisan institution supported by 34 countries around the 28.3 (2021)
(IDEA) world
foundations and the two US institutes NDI and IRI have by far the highest
budgets for cooperation with parties, but like most other institutions, party
assistance is part of broader support for democracy, which includes other
areas of activity. The share of their budgets that goes to party assistance is not
itemized separately, but it should be approximately 20–25%. Some political
institutions in other countries spend a higher percentage on party assistance,
but in many cases this is limited to a few activities each year due to their
relatively small budgets.
Regarding the international promotion of democracy, the share of party
Forms of cooperation
Topics of cooperation
The specific activities of the individual institutions cover the entire range of
issues relevant to political parties:
The education and training of younger party members and women plays
a very important role for virtually all sponsors. The matter of intra-party
democracy is also dealt with very intensively by some sponsors, although
the extent of intra-party participation has little significance for the voting
behaviour of citizens, and there is no unanimous opinion in political sci-
ence as to whether parties must be democratically organized to contribute
to democracy in their respective countries. The fact that Michels’ iron law of
oligarchy is also still in force in Western democracies is overlooked by some
of those involved in party assistance, whose habitus has been described as
The effectiveness of political party assistance has repeatedly been called into
question (Carothers 2006; Erdmann 2008: 244ff; Burnell and Gerrits 2012:
4ff; Burnell 2017 and various country assessments of the book; Svåsand 2014:
46 ff.; Weissenbach 2016: 343ff ). In view of the decline of democracy in
many countries, questions regarding the purpose and effectiveness of party
assistance have become more pressing.
Peter Burnell and André Gerrits have noted that those involved in party
assistance set goals in a very ambitious but general way and normally seek
570 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
effects’ (Carothers 2006: 12). Considering the state of the party systems in
individual countries, that may be true. However, before we can condemn
party assistance, we must consider its different levels.
The first level concerns the underlying political conditions. These largely
determine which role parties play and how they (can) perform these roles.
The system of government, the formal constitution, and the role of other
political and social institutions (parliament, system of checks and balances,
media, civil society, etc.) are important. However, there are other factors
that play a major role: the historic moment of a country, i.e. how long has
Party leaders can be made aware of issues, and we can present them with
alternatives to certain regulations. However, restraint must be used when
assessing the chances that political engineering will successfully influence
the underlying conditions. What may seem desirable or necessary from an
academic or foreign perspective is often difficult to implement politically or
may only be possible at best over the very long term.
At another level, there has also been criticism of the approach to and
methods of party assistance, in which sponsors are accused of putting the
focus of cooperation too heavily on an ‘idealized or mythical’ political party
long term. The presence of their own country representatives, who maintain
continuous contacts with the partner parties on the ground, is a key instru-
ment whereby the foundations acquire direct knowledge and a feel for the
political situation of a country, allowing them to implement and adapt their
cooperation strategies in a differentiated and context-sensitive manner.
However, the limits of this partisan approach become more and more evi-
dent, especially when parties that have been assisted for many years become
less relevant, perhaps because they lack success in governance, are paralysed
by internal conflicts, have important representatives involved in corruption
Notes
1. The author is a Fellow at the Düsseldorf Party Research Institute (PRuF) and has worked
for the Konrad Adenauer Foundation in Latin America, Asia, Spain and Germany.
2. He was the son of the Eduardo Frei who was President from 1964 to 1970.
References
Angell, Alan. 1996. ‘International Support for the Chilean Opposition, 1973–1989:
Political Parties and the Role of Exiles’. In Lawrence Whitehead (ed.), The
Can the Parties be Helped? 579
Krumwiede, Heinrich W., Detlef Nolte, and Renate Rott. 1995. Evaluierung
der Aktivitäten der politischen Stiftungen in Chile. Bundeministerium für
wirtschaftliche Zusammenarbeit und Entwicklung, Referat 201, Bonn, October.
Krastev, Ivan and Stephen Holmes. 2019. Das Licht, das erlosch. Eine Abrechnung.
Berlin: Ullstein.
Pogorelskaja, Swetlana W. 2006. Die Bedeutung der deutschen parteinahen Stiftun-
gen für die EU-Politik gegenüber den MOE- und GUS-Staaten. ZEI Discussion
Paper, C163, 2006. https://www.hintergrund.de/wp-content/uploads/2014/10/
dp_c163Pogorelskaja.pdf (Accessed 20 July 2021).
Parties are essential for democracy because they represent and they govern. It
is widely accepted that these two tasks are not easy to reconcile, as one tends
to be stronger at the expense of the other. Depending on a given country’s
developmental trajectory, institutional arrangements will either strengthen
the representative or the governing function (Mair and Thomassen 2010).
However, the performance of parties is not moulded solely by their institu-
tional environment. On the contrary, it depends also to a considerable degree
on their own ideology, organization, and social anchorage—three factors that
covary with each other. In other words, how parties link to society, how
strong their leaders are, whether or not they are committed to a coherent set
of policies and can hence expect their parliamentary representatives to toe
the party line—all these are also the result of the party’s own choices and the
societal conditions of their country. Clearly, all these aspects also influence
how well parties represent and govern.
It is tempting to generalize across regions when we try to gauge the per-
formance of parties and party systems in democratic governance. This might
read as follows:
Thomas Poguntke, Paul Webb, and Susan E. Scarrow, Parties and Democracy. In: Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy.
Edited by: Thomas Poguntke and Wilhelm Hofmeister, Oxford University Press. © Thomas Poguntke, Paul Webb, and Susan E.
Scarrow (2024). DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198888734.003.0027
582 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
parties had little to attach themselves to and party systems remained in a state
of flux. African parties have long been stereotyped as being dominated by ethni-
cization, often in a clientelist manner. In contrast to that view, however, one must
bear in mind that almost all African countries with multiparty systems banned
ethnic and other particularistic political parties. Latin American parties, on the
other hand, are now strongly moulded by the logic of presidentialism, where par-
ties are increasingly turned into instruments at the disposal of leaders aspiring
to the highest elective office in the country. Asian party systems differ consider-
ably in their degree of institutionalization, and the development of party systems
What do we learn from the country studies concerning the major aspects of
party analysis introduced in Chapter 2? When we look at parties in a changing
environment, it is evident that this is often associated with a decline of social
anchorage in Western Europe, while parties tended to be a lot less socially
entrenched in other parts of the world, except where strongly rooted in tribal
or ethnic loyalties. In some cases, their lack of social anchorage is (partially)
induced by the prevalence of presidentialism, which creates incentives for
by a unified leadership (Mair 1994: 16; Scarrow et al. 2022). However, the
expansion of the selectorates has the potential to weaken the coherence of
the party as a purposive actor. Instead, it may turn the party into an instru-
ment of competing leaders who base their political power on a personalized
mandate rather than on the support of the dominant coalition within their
party (Poguntke and Webb 2005).
The literature on parties as organizations again has a European bias which
is strongly influenced by the analysis of parties and their linkage to society.
Much of the substance of the cadre, mass, catch-all, or cartel ideal-types can
Party Finance
State subsidies to political parties are an aspect that is largely uniform across
all our cases. Only 5 of our 23 countries do not have public funding of polit-
ical parties (the most notable exceptions are the US and the UK). Individual
586 Political Parties and the Crisis of Democracy
Parties as Legislators
where parties fail to generate parliamentary groups that vote cohesively or—
even more problematically—stay together. In countries such as Brazil and
Italy, defection is endemic. This touches upon one of the cornerstones of
democratic party government in parliamentary and presidential systems
alike, in that parties can only link to voters in a meaningful way if their par-
liamentary representatives are also accountable to their party and, via the
party, to the electorate (Müller 2000; Strøm 2000). If those who are elected
to parliament (also) as a representative of a specific party switch their party
allegiance in considerable numbers over the course of a legislative term, the
Parties as Communicators
Conclusion
To conclude, this volume has assembled ample evidence that democratic par-
ties are struggling with several challenges. The challenges are far from being
uniform: similar problems, such as low membership and party instability,
can have different causes. In many respects, an important common denomi-
nator in many countries is a lack of stable linkage between parties and society.
While this is a sign of erosion in many established democracies, parties in
newer democracies are still struggling to build up stronger societal roots.
While the trajectories are different, the results are similar: strong linkages
can help to provide sufficient stability of the supply side of party politics
without preventing representative innovation through new parties. After all,
the growth of populism around the globe is also related to the lack of a sta-
ble and attractive supply by moderate parties. If the market is in flux, radical
challengers always find it easier to gain traction.
One quite common denominator is the trend towards a more personalized
leadership, which often goes hand in hand with a trend toward plebisci-
tary leadership selection. In a way, the formerly well-entrenched (Western)
Parties and Democracy 589
European parties in the tradition of mass parties with clearly defined mem-
bership roles and organizational boundaries are coming to resemble the more
fluid parties in other parts of the world. As presidentalism tends to be partic-
ularly prevalent in Africa and Latin America, it is probably no surprise that
a trend towards a more presidentialized mode of governance has also been
diagnosed for modern democracies (Poguntke and Webb 2005).
What does this mean for parties and their role in democratic governance?
In the first instance, it means that parties as collective entities with a clear
vision of where society should go are increasingly becoming a relic of the past.
References
Biezen, Ingrid van, Peter Mair, and Thomas Poguntke. 2012. ‘Going, Going, . . .
Gone? The Decline of Party Membership in Contemporary Europe’. European
Journal of Political Research, 51(1):24–56.
Biezen, Ingrid van and Thomas Poguntke. 2014. The Decline of Membership-based
Politics. Party Politics, 20:205–226.
Gauja, Anika. 2015. ‘The Construction of Party Membership’. European Journal of
Political Research, 54:232–248.
Hallin, Daniel C. and Paolo Mancini. 2004. Comparing Media Systems: Three Models
of Media and Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Poguntke, Thomas and Susan E. Scarrow. 2020. ‘Intra-party Democracy and Rep-
resentation: Necessity, Complement, or Challenge?’. In: Robert Rohrschneider
and Jacques Thomassen (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Political Representation
in Liberal Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 323–339.
Poguntke, Thomas and Paul D. Webb. 2005. ‘The Presidentialization of Politics in
Democratic Societies. A Framework for Analysis’. In: Thomas Poguntke and Paul
D. Webb (eds), The Presidentialization of Politics: A Comparative Studies of Modern
Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–25.
Sartori, Giovanni. 1991. ‘Comparing and Miscomparing’. Journal of Theoretical
For the benefit of digital users, indexed terms that span two pages (e.g., 52–53) may, on occasion,
appear on only one of those pages.
BJS (Bharatiya Jana Sangh), India 456–457 social groups, connection with 333
Blair, Tony 45–47 volatility 334
Blue and White alliance, Israel 277 Worker’s Party see PT (Worker’s Party),
Boko Haram 527–528 Brazil
Bolsonaro, Jair 303, 332, 351–352, 587–588 Buhari, Muhammadu 520, 524–525, 528
Bossi, Umberto 136–137, 141–142 Burke, Edmund 49
Brazil Burnell, Peter 569–570
Chamber of Deputies 335–336, 340–341, business firm parties 12
343, 344, 347 Buthelezi, Mangosuthu 502–503
Constitution 335 cadre (elite) parties 585
Free Electoral Propaganda in Argentina 366–367
Schedule 335–336 in Brazil 332–333
inclusive cartelization 129 CHES (Chapel Hill Expert Survey) data 200,
in Italy 129, 148–149 212–213, 243–244
in Portugal 206–207 Chiang Ching-kuo 388–389, 392
in South Korea 401–406, 413, 421–422 Chiang Kai-shek 388
in Spain 233 Chile
thesis 13, 72, 95–97, 190, 586 Chamber of Deputies 559–560
in Turkey 187, 190 Christian Democratic Party see PDC
catch-all parties 585 (Partido Demócrata
in Argentina 363 Cristiano—Christian Democratic
in Brazil 332–333, 337–338 Party), Chile
classical model 11–13 party system 296–297
in Germany 82–88, 91–93, 100, 101–102 China Democratic Socialist Party 381
Mapai see Mapai Party, Israel Partito Democratico della Sinistra see PDS
mass parties 272–273, 275 (Partito Democratico della
national parties 264 Sinistra—Democratic Party of the
non-democratic parties 263 Left), Italy
personalization 269–270, 278, 282 Partito Popolare Italiano see PPI (Partito
religious/ultra-religious parties 263, 268 Populare Italiano—Italian People’s
since the 1990s 266–270 Party)
State Comptroller 262, 265–266 party system change 128
weakening of aggregative democratic People of Freedom see PDL (Popolo della
parties 281 Libertà—People of Freedom), Italy
Yesh Atid see Yesh Atid Party, Israel public funding 129
Italian party systems 128–149 relevance of selected parties 132–133
Communist Party see JCP (Japanese Justice and Development Party, Turkey see
Communist Party) AKP (Adalet ve Kalkınma
Democratic Party see DP (Democratic Partisi—Justice and Development
Party), Japan Party), Turkey
Democratic Party of Japan see DPJ Justice Party, Nigeria 517–518
(Democratic Party of Japan)
Democratic Socialist Party see DSP Kaczyński, Jarosław 244–245, 247–248,
(Democratic Socialist Party), Japan 251–252, 254–255
determinants of policy positions 441–443 Kaczyński, Lech 247–248
effective number of electoral parties Kadima 272
(ENEP) 428–429, 432 KAF see Konrad Adenauer Foundation (KAF)
effective number of parliamentary parties Kahlon, Moshe 269–270
National Executive Committee 516–517 Obrador, Andrés Manuel López (AMLO) see
National Gender Policy 532 AMLO (Andrés Manuel López),
National Party of Nigeria see NPN (National Mexico
Party of Nigeria) ODA (Civic Democratic Alliance), Czech
National Republic Convention 519 Republic 111–112, 120
Nigerian People’s Party see NPP (Nigerian ODS (Civil Social Democratic Party), Czech
People’s Party) Republic 108, 111–112, 114, 115–117,
Northern People’s Congress see NPC 119–120, 123–124
(Northern People’s Congress) party financing 121
People’s Redemption Party see PRP (People’s OLAF (European Anti-Fraud Office) 118–119
Redemption Party), Nigeria ONNED (Youth Organization of New
Democracy) 161–162
PFP (People’s First Party), Taiwan 383, 389 Partido Demokratiko Pilipino-Lakas ng
Philippe, Edouard 73–74 Bayan see PDP-Laban (Partido
Philippine party system 467–483 Demokratiko Pilipino-Lakas ng
Aksyon Demokratiko see Aksyon (Aksyon Bayan), Philippines
Demokratiko—Democratic Action), Partido Federal ng Pilipinas see PFP
the Philippines (Partido Federal ng Pilipinas), the
anarchy of parties 467, 469, 471–475 Philippines
citizen–party linkage 480 Partner of the Free Pilipino see Kampi
dictatorship 467, 471, 476–477 (Kabalikat ng Malayang
elections 467–470, 480–482 Pilipino—Partner of the Free Pilipino),
local 468 the Philippines
midterm 474–479, 483 party financing 480–481
Radicalism, Argentina 360–361, 363, 364–367, Sartori, Giovanni 18, 83, 85–86, 99–100
370, 371–372 Savarkar, V. D. 460
see also Peronism, Argentina (1955–1973) Scarrow, Susan E. 3, 68–69
and democracy 364 Schlein, Elly 149
Partido Intransigente 370 Scholz, Olaf 86–87
social groups, connection with 365–367 Schröder, Gerhard 85
Radio Padania Libera, Italy 144 Scotland 38–39
Rafi. Mapai/Labour party, Israel 274 see also United Kingdom party system
Rainbow group, European and Labour Party 39, 45, 53
Parliament 136–137 Scottish National Party (SNP) 39–40,
Rajya Sabha (upper house), India 454 42–43, 45–46
Ramaphosa, Cyril 497, 504 SDP (Social Democratic Party), United
SPOLU alliance (ODS, KDU-ČSL, and TOP effective number of electoral parties
09), Czech Republic 113–114, (ENEP) 384
123–124 effective number of parliamentary parties
Stability and Growth Pact 209 (ENPP) 384
STAN (Starostové a nezávislí—Mayors and elections 382–384, 387–388, 390, 392–396
Independents), Czech legislative 384, 386, 390–391, 394
Republic 112–113, 116–118, 123–124 local 385, 388, 394
Starmer, Keir 40, 48 national 385
state subsidies 585–586 presidential 386, 388
in Czech Republic 111 Green Party 394
distribution of 16–17 mass parties 386
in France 70–72 Nationalist Party see KMT