saturation point (1)
saturation point (1)
Consumer Demand
Theory
EXAMPLE 1. The first two columns of Table 4.1 give an individual’s hypothetical total utility (TU) schedule from con-
suming various alternative quantities of commodity X per unit of time. (Utility is here assumed to be measurable in terms of
a fictitious unit called the “util.”) Note that up to a point, as the individual consumes more units of X per unit of time, TUx
increases. Columns (1) and (3) of the table show this individual’s marginal utility (MU) schedule for commodity X. Each
value of column (3) is obtained by subtracting two successive values of column (2). For example, if the individual’s con-
sumption of X goes from zero units to 1 unit, the TUx goes from zero utils to 10 utils, giving a MUx of 10 utils. Similarly,
if the consumption of X rises from 1 unit to 2 units, the TUx rises from 10 to 18, giving a MUx of 8. Notice that as this
individual consumes more and more units of X per unit of time, the MUx falls.
Table 4.1
(1) Q x (2) TUx (3) MUx
0 0 ...
1 10 10
2 18 8
3 24 6
4 28 4
5 30 2
6 30 0
7 28 22
62
Copyright © 2006, 1992, 1983, 1974 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. Click here for terms of use.
CHAP. 4] CONSUMER DEMAND THEORY 63
EXAMPLE 2. If we plot the total and marginal utility schedules of Table 4.1, we get the total and marginal utility curves
of Fig. 4-1. Since marginal utility has been defined as the change in total utility in changing consumption by one unit, each
value of the MUx has been recorded midway between the two levels of consumption, in part (b) of the figure. The saturation
point (MUx ¼ 0) is reached when the individual increases consumption of X from 5 to 6 units. The falling MUx curve
illustrates the principle of diminishing marginal utility.
Fig. 4-1
MUx MUy
¼ ¼
Px Py