Aggregate Volatility Expectations and Threshold CAPM: Yakup Eser Arısoy Aslıhan Altay-Salih Levent Akdeniz
Aggregate Volatility Expectations and Threshold CAPM: Yakup Eser Arısoy Aslıhan Altay-Salih Levent Akdeniz
Abstract
We propose a volatility-based capital asset pricing model (V-CAPM) in which asset betas
change discretely with respect to changes in investors’ expectations regarding near-term
aggregate volatility. Using a novel measure to proxy uncertainty about expected changes in
aggregate volatility, i.e. monthly range of the VIX index (RVIX), we find that portfolio betas
change significantly when uncertainty about aggregate volatility expectations is beyond a certain
threshold level. Due to changes in their market betas, small and value stocks are perceived as
riskier than their big and growth counterparts in bad times, when uncertainty about aggregate
volatility expectations is high. The proposed model yields a positive and significant market risk
premium during periods when investors do not expect significant uncertainty in near-term
aggregate volatility. Our findings support a volatility-based time-varying risk explanation.
* Université Paris-Dauphine, DRM Finance, 75775, Paris Cedex 16, France. Tel: +33 (0)1 44 05
43 60, email: eser.arisoy@dauphine.fr
** Bilkent University Faculty of Business Administration, 06533, Ankara, Turkey, Tel: +90 312
290 2047 email: asalih@bilkent.edu.tr
*** Bilkent University Faculty of Business Administration, 06533, Ankara, Turkey, Tel:
+90 312 290 2202 email: akdeniz@bilkent.edu.tr
1
We would like to thank to seminar participants and discussants at Grenoble Ecole de Management, Lancaster
University Management School, Manchester Business School, Université Paris Dauphine, Université Picardie Jules
Verne, AFFI 2012 Strasbourg Meetings and FMA 2012 Atlanta Meetings.
The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) assumes that a firm's riskiness, which is
captured by its beta, is constant through time. However, changes in business conditions,
technology, and taste might induce shifts in the investment opportunity set and investors'
associated risk-return tradeoffs (Jagannathan and Wang, 1996). Many studies model the variation
in betas using continuous approximation and the theoretical framework of the conditional
CAPM.2 Yet, despite a strong theory and considerable evidence on time variation in betas, there
In this paper, we model asset betas neither as static nor as a continuous approximation
implied by conditional models, instead we assume that asset betas change discretely in time.3
Our approach follows the spirit of regime-switching models, which have been extensively used
in modelling financial time-series.4 More particularly, we posit that investors re-assess firms’
systematic risk with respect to expected changes in aggregate risk conditions based on their
expectations regarding uncertainty about future aggregate volatility. There are several reasons
why we assume betas should change with respect to uncertainty about aggregate volatility
expectations. First, it is well documented that both equity and aggregate volatility is time-
2
See Harvey (1989), Ferson and Harvey (1991, 1993, 1999), Ferson and Korajczyk (1995), Jagannathan and Wang
(1996), and Petkovan and Zhang (2005).
3
The intuition behind discrete changes in betas with respect to two different regimes similar to downside-upside
beta approach in Ang, Cheng, and Xing (2006) who show that asset betas change during downside and upside
markets and downside risk is priced. Methodologically, our approach is also related to Markov chain regime
switching models as in Guidolin and Timmermann (2008), and Chen, Gerlach, and Lin (2011), and optimal
changepoint approach as in Bollen and Whaley (2009), and Patten and Ramadorai (2013).
4
See Hamilton (1989), Hamilton and Lin (2002), Ang and Bekaert (2002), Guidolin and Timmermann (2012), Ho,
Shi, and Zhang (2013), Chuang, Huang, and Lin (2013), Zheng and Zuo (2013), and Bailliu et al. (2014) for details
and applications of regime-switching models in different settings
5
For theoretical background and empirical evidence on stochastic volatility of equity and stock market returns, see
Engle and Bollerslev (1986), French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987), Schwert (1989), Engle and Ng (1993),
Canina and Figlewski (1993), Duffee (1995), Braun, Nelson, and Sunier (1995), Andersen (1996), Bollerslev and
Mikkelsen (1999), and Bekaert and Wu (2000).
risk literature suggests that stocks have different exposures to market risk during recessions and
expansions (Lettau and Ludvigson, 2001; Petkova and Zhang, 2005). Given the fact that change
in aggregate volatility is tightly linked to business cycles, our model is able to capture this link
by the fact that option-implied volatility measures are good forecasts of future volatility, we
investors’ expectations with respect to changes in near-term aggregate volatility.9 Rather than
using macro variables as in previous studies, our approach contributes to the literature by
Covri , rm
i
Var rm , any uncertainty in investors’ aggregate volatility expectations
6
Given the definition of beta, i.e.
(i.e. the denominator) is expected to affect returns in the cross-section through betas on the market portfolio. Hence,
our approach is different from Ang et al. (2006) who condition expected returns directly on aggregate volatility and
who model aggregate volatility as a separate risk factor. Our approach is also different from Wang and Ma (2014)
who examine the effect of excess volatility at the individual stock level. We investigate the implications of
uncertainty about aggregate volatility on betas and on the cross-section of expected returns.
7
Pollet and Wilson (2010) show that increases in market volatility can be due to either increases in average
volatilities or average correlations, or both. Furthermore, Buraschi, Porchia, and Trojani (2010) and Buraschi,
Trojani, Vedolin (2014) show that investors have hedging demands against both stochastic aggregate volatility risk
and stochastic correlation risk. In their model, both risk factors stem as a result of uncertainty (disagreement in
beliefs across agents) in the economy. We do not take a direct stand on the correlation structure in this paper.
However, because our measure RVIX essentially captures uncertainty in expected volatility of the market portfolio,
it is closely linked to both sources of risk.
8
See Hsu and Li (2009) who document counter-cyclicality of volatility across different asset classes.
9
For the predictive ability of option-implied volatility measures ranging from intra-day forecasts to one-year ahead
forecasts, and in different markets such as foreign exchange, stock, and bond markets, see Poon and Granger (2005),
Taylor, Yadav, and Zhang (2010), Busch, Christensen, and Nielsen (2011), Han and Park (2013), and Bianconi,
MacLachlan, and Sammon (2015).
10
Among the most widely used macro conditioning variables in the literature are the dividend yield (Fama and
French (1988)), default spread (Keim and Stambaugh (1988)), term spread (Campbell (1987)), short term treasury
bill rate (Fama and Schwert (1977)) and log consumption-wealth ratio (Lettau and Ludvigson (2001)).
11
Our study is also related to the recent strand of literature showing that the difference in option-implied volatility
measures has significant explanatory power in the cross-section of stock returns. Among them are studies by Bali
and Hovakimian (2009), Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009), Cremers and Weinbaum (2010), and Atilgan, Bali
and Demirtas (2015).
betas change with respect to investors' assessment of aggregate risk conditions, proxied by
contribution of the proposed V-CAPM is fourfold. First, we propose a novel measure to proxy
expected changes in aggregate risk conditions, i.e. range of the VIX index (RVIX). 12 VIX is
investors’ expectations of near term volatility in the market.13 Defined as the difference between
the maximum and minimum level of the VIX index, RVIX essentially captures expected changes
in near-term aggregate volatility, or put differently the degree of uncertainty in future aggregate
volatility. In a recent paper, Baltussen et al. (2014) show that the volatility of volatility (vol-of-
vol) is an important factor in the cross-section of stock returns. Using the volatility of option-
implied volatility as a measure of uncertainty about volatility, they document that stocks with
high vol-of-vol underperform stocks with low vol-of-vol. The authors argue that the volatility of
option-implied volatility is an intuitive measure, which is tightly related to the literature that
measure that captures uncertainty regarding future aggregate volatility. Hence, if investors hold
second order beliefs and care about this uncertainty, then stocks or portfolios with different
sensitivities to changes in uncertainty could have different risk-return dynamics, which could
also imply different market risk premium dynamics at times of increased uncertainty about
12
We examine whether using other conditioning variables documented in the literature (such as one month T-bill
rate, aggregate dividend yield, inflation rate, term spread and credit spread) result in significant regime changes in
portfolio betas as implied by the threshold CAPM model. None of the examined variables yield significant regime
shifts in portfolio betas as strong as RVIX.
13
Often referred to as the “fear” or “market sentiment” index, VIX estimates near-term (roughly next 30-day)
expected volatility by weighted-averaging the prices of puts and calls written on the S&P 500 index over a range of
strike prices.
3
Second contribution is our approach to modelling time variation in betas. In standard
conditional CAPM setting, betas practically change at each point in time, however this approach
might have a tendency to overstate the time variation in betas and result in estimates that are
highly volatile. Our setting differs from the standard conditional CAPM models by allowing
betas to change only when the degree of uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility moves
beyond a certain threshold level, admitting a discrete variation in betas in two distinct regimes.
Third, our model implicitly allows for time variation in aggregate volatility which is not possible
about aggregate volatility in a dynamic way, we allow betas to capture potential shifts in the
investment opportunity set linked to expected changes in aggregate risk conditions.14 Our fourth
between betas and uncertainty about aggregate volatility using Hansen's (2000) threshold
regression methodology, which is intuitive and fully supported by the econometric theory.15 The
proposed model is rich in its predictions and offers a volatility-based explanation to some of the
Using RVIX as proxy for uncertainty about aggregate volatility expectations, and
portfolios sorted with respect to market capitalizations and book-to-market ratios as test assets,
our results can be summarized as follows.16 First, using the modified sup LM test suggested by
14
We also investigate whether the documented regime changes in betas with respect to uncertainty about aggregate
volatility expectations is linked to downside risk as in Ang, Chen and Xing (2006) and Bali, Demirtas and
Levy(2009). Using upside and downside betas of Ang, Chen and Xing (2006), we do not find a strong correlation
between high uncertainty vs. downside betas and low uncertainty vs. upside betas. Furthermore, dividing the sample
period into months that correspond to high vs. low uncertainty about aggregate volatility and months that correspond
to upside and downside markets, we find major differences between the corresponding time periods.
15
See Hansen (2000) for a detailed explanation of the threshold estimation methodology.
16
We also use an orthogonalized version of RVIX (RVIXORTH) in order to ensure that the results are not driven by
potential variables that have been documented to be important in the literature. RVIXORTH is defined as the
residual term obtained from regressing RVIX on aggregate dividend yield, the default spread, the term spread, the
short-term treasury bill rate, and the VIX. The results are robust to use of RVIXORTH as the conditioning variable.
4
Hansen (1996), we document significant time variation in betas. 15 out of 22 test portfolios have
significant bootstrap p-values at 5% level.17 The evidence confirms the existence of aggregate
volatility related changes in betas of most portfolios, most particularly for the extreme size and
book-to-market portfolios as well as SMB and HML portfolios. The initial results support the
hypothesis that asset betas change discretely in time and uncertainty about aggregate volatility
Next, we test whether different size and book-to-market portfolios have different beta
sensitivities with respect to investors’ expectations about uncertainty of aggregate volatility and
risk conditions. The threshold estimates suggest that investors overwhelmingly update their beta
risk assessments when monthly range of the VIX index is beyond 9.33 points.18 What makes the
results further remarkable is the direction of this update. Looking at the changes in portfolio
betas, one can see that stocks in small (and value) portfolios have consistently higher betas at
times when uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility is high (i.e. when RVIX in a given
month is above the threshold level). On the contrary, the portfolio of largest market capitalization
stocks (and the growth portfolio) exhibits lower betas during these uncertain times. The increase
in betas is most pronounced for the smallest decile, highest book-to-market decile, SMB and
HML portfolios.
French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987), and Campbell and Hentschel (1992) document
that periods of high volatility usually coincide with downward market moves. Furthermore, risk-
averse investors are reluctant to lose wealth in periods of high volatility because it represents a
17
9 (17) portfolios exhibit significant change in betas at 1% (10%) level.
18
The threshold estimates (which could practically be any positive real number) are quite stable for portfolios that
exhibit significant beta changes (ranging from 6.07 to 11.10), confirming the robustness of the chosen threshold
variable, RVIX.
5
consumption (recessions).19 The increase in betas of small and value portfolios implies that
stocks with these characteristics are perceived to be riskier at times of increased uncertainty
about expected volatility. This also holds for SMB and HML portfolios whose sensitivities to
market returns become higher during those times. Investors view small and value firms riskier
because their returns correlate strongly with market returns in episodes when uncertainty about
expected aggregate volatility is high. On the other hand, returns on big and growth stocks
correlate less with market returns during those times. Our results are consistent with those of
Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) and Petkova and Zhang (2005) whofind that value and small stocks
correlate more with the consumption growth (market returns) during bad times relative to big and
growth stocks, while the opposite holds during good times. We argue that investors view small
and value stocks riskier than their big and growth counterparts because their returns are much
more sensitive to market risk at times of increased uncertainty about aggregate volatility and
To test the robustness of the above results and to further examine the effect of time
variation in investors’ expectations of near term volatility on asset risk-return dynamics, we next
calculate Jensen’s alphas and Sharpe ratios of our test assets in the full sample as well as in two
different regimes (i.e. high and low uncertainty about volatility) implied by the threshold level of
RVIX estimated via the V-CAPM. It is well-documented that small and value stocks (and the
associated SMB and HML strategies) produce significantly higher average returns than their
large and growth counterparts. Looking at Jensen’s alphas and betas of different size and book-
to-market portfolios, we confirm the previous findings that the static CAPM is unable to offer a
risk-based explanation to SMB and HML return differentials. On the other hand, the analysis of
alphas implied by the proposed V-CAPM helps us uncover an important aspect of size and value
19
Hsu and Li (2009) document that equity market volatility is higher in bear markets and recessions.
6
vs. growth puzzles. In particular, we document that size and value strategies yield significant and
positive risk-adjusted returns during calm times when uncertainty about near-term aggregate
volatility is low. On the other hand, the trade-off for size and value strategies is that they have
extremely bad (significant and negative) risk-adjusted returns at times of high uncertainty about
expected volatility.
Portfolio Sharpe ratios also offer a similar volatility-based time-varying risk explanation
to size and value vs. growth anomalies. In periods when uncertainty about aggregate volatility is
low, the strategy in the smallest (value) decile portfolios command higher reward-to-variability
ratios as opposed to the biggest (growth) decile portfolios. However, in periods of high
ratios for the smallest (value) decile portfolio relative to biggest (growth) decile portfolio. The
results confirm our hypothesis that market’s expectation of uncertainty about aggregate volatility
betas and risk-adjusted returns during periods with different levels of uncertainty about aggregate
volatility expectations contribute to our understanding of why small and value stocks on average
earn higher returns than their big and growth counterparts. We show that investing in small and
value stocks are risky strategies in periods when there is high uncertainty about expected
aggregate volatility, and thus investors get compensated for the risk that they are taking against
this uncertainty.
We finally test the pricing implications of the proposed V-CAPM by dividing the sample
into periods of high and low uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility and by estimating
the betas and the corresponding risk premium in the cross-section. To avoid the problem of
factor structure related biases in the estimation procedure, we estimate the betas and the risk
7
premia at the individual stock level rather than at the portfolio level. We start with examining the
relationship between stocks’ betas and future returns. To that end, we first estimate the beta
loadings via monthly regressions using daily returns as in Ang et al. (2006). Classifying betas as
high uncertainty (RVIX>9.33) vs. low uncertainty (RVIX<9.33) betas, we form decile portfolios
each month by sorting individual stocks according to their betas. We then examine out-of-sample
average decile returns for the following month to investigate whether stocks’ beta exposures
their next-month returns. Univariate portfolio sorts indicate that stocks in the highest uncertainty
(calm) beta decile underperform (outperform) stocks in the lowest uncertainty (calm) beta decile
by 0.72% (0.60%) per month. Furthermore, the differences in risk-adjusted returns (CAPM and
FF 3-factor alphas) of portfolios with highest and lowest exposure to uncertainty betas are also
negative and statistically significant. The results are robust to using value-weighted returns.
We finally estimate the corresponding risk premia for uncertainty and calm betas using
the standard Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regression methodology. Consistent with
the previous studies, we document an insignificant market risk premium throughout the full
sample period, confirming the inability of a static version of CAPM to explain the cross-section
of stock returns. On the other hand, we document a positive and significant market risk premium
during calm times when uncertainty about aggregate volatility is low. This result is robust to the
inclusion of different factor exposures such as SMB beta, HML beta and MOM beta as well as
various firm characteristics such as idiosyncratic volatility, size, book-to-market ratio, and firm-
level momentum. On the contrary, during periods of high uncertainty about aggregate volatility,
the market risk commands a significant and negative premium, however its significance
disappears when different portfolio exposures and firm characteristics are included. The results
8
imply a major improvement over pricing relative to static CAPM by re-establishing a positive
market risk premium during calm periods when uncertainty about aggregate volatility is fairly
low.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the threshold V-
CAPM and the related econometric framework. Section 3 presents data and some stylized facts.
Section 4 documents empirical findings for time-series and cross-sectional tests of the proposed
where ri,t+1 is the excess return on asset i, rm,t+1 is the excess return on the market portfolio and E
is the expectation operator. t captures time-variation in market betas, and Zt is the conditioning
information on investors’ assessment of near-term aggregate volatility risk. Using monthly range
of the VIX index as a proxy for investors’ information set for expected changes in aggregate
where 1{} is the indicator function and is the threshold parameter for aggregate volatility.
Combining equations (1) and (2), we have the following threshold volatility CAPM:
ri ,t 1 11Zt 2 1Zt 11{Zt } 2 1{Zt } rm,t 1 i ,t 1 , 3
20
See Section 2 for details on the construction of the conditioning variable RVIX.
9
where Zt is the monthly range of the VIX index (RVIX) that summarizes investors’ information
The observed sample is {rt+1, rm,t+1, Zt}, t = 1, …, T-1. The random variables rt, rm,t, and
Zt are real-valued. The threshold variable Zt is assumed to have a continuous distribution.21 The
threshold regression has the same format as in equation (3), which can be rewritten as:
The above model can further be generalized to the case where only a subset of parameters
switches between the regimes and to the case where some regressors only enter in one of the two
regimes. Also, takes values in a bounded subset of the real line, . This applies to the case of
our conditioning variable RVIX, which is bounded below by zero by definition. We assume r mt,
in Hansen (1996). We test for the null of H0: = 0 against H1: 0. If the null is rejected, this
implies a significant change in betas with respect to levels above or below threshold RVIX.
For all we have the following LM statistics for the null of no threshold:
21
See Hansen (2000) for detailed explanations related to the assumptions.
22
The -mixing coefficients satisfy m½ < . The -mixing assumption controls the degree of time series
dependence and allows the processes to be autocorrelated and heteroskedastic, and is sufficiently flexible to embrace
many non-linear time series processes, including threshold autoregressions.
10
LMT ( ) T Rˆ( ) RVˆT* ( ) R Rˆ( ) ,
1
where,
R 0, I ,
1
T T
ˆ ( ) ˆ( ) , ˆ( ) xt*1 ( ) xt*1 ( ) xt*1 ( )rt 1 ,
t 1 t 1
x *t 1 ( ) xt 1 , xt 1 ( ) ,
~
V̂T* ( ) M T ( ) 1VT ( ) M T ( ) 1 ,
1 T *
M T ( ) xt 1 ( ) xt*1 ( ) ,
T t 1
~ 1 T *
VT ( ) xt 1 ( ) xt*1 ( ) e~t 1 ,
2
T t 1
and where ~et is obtained from the restricted least squares. One limitation of the LM test is the
large sample limit for the sup-LM, which is not nuisance free because the threshold is not
identified under the null of no-threshold effect. Because of this issue, Hansen (1996) suggests a
bootstrap analog of the sup-LM test and shows that this bootstrap method yields asymptotically
correct p-values. We use the bootstrap analog following the steps outlined in Hansen (1996) and
3. Data
The market and stock return data is from Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP)
value-weighted market index for all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks. The risk-free rate is
the one-month T-Bill rate obtained from Ibbotson Associates. Data on VIX and VXO is obtained
from Chicago Board Options Exchange’s (CBOE). The sample covers the period from January
11
1986 to December 2012, with a total of 324 months.23 The test portfolios consist of stocks sorted
according to their market capitalizations, and book-to-market ratios. More precisely, we use 10
portfolios sorted according to their market capitalizations, 10 portfolios sorted according to their
book-to-market ratios, and 2 factor portfolios SMB and HML.24 For cross-sectional tests
performed in Section 4.3, we use the CRSP universe covering all NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ
volatility, we use the monthly range of the VIX index (RVIX). Similar to Chou (2005), we
where τ denotes trading days in a given month, and t denotes months. Taking the difference
between the maximum and minimum level of VIX index in a given month, RVIX summarizes
Range based volatility measures have gained recent interest, and they fare quite well in
predicting future volatility.25 To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to propose a
range based measure of the VIX index.26 We further tested a battery of volatility measures
23
VIX data is available from January 1990 onwards. In order to have as much data as possible, we use the VXO
index (which is based on S&P 100 index options) from January 1986 to December 1989, and the VIX index from its
introduction in January 1990 onwards. The results remain unaffected when we limit the sample period to 1990-2012
using the VIX index only, or omitting VIX and using VXO throughout the 1986-2012 period.
24
SMB (Small Minus Big) is the average return on the three small portfolios minus the average return on the three
big portfolios, and HML (High Minus Low) is the average return on the two value portfolios minus the average
return on the two growth portfolios.
25
See Alizadeh et al. (2002), Chou (2005), Brandt and Jones (2006), Chou and Liu (2010), Harris et al. (2011),
Bannouh, Martens, and van Dijk (2013), and Asai and Brugal (2013) for articles that motivate the use of range based
volatility measures in different settings.
26
Previous studies such as Garman and Klass (1980) and Parkinson (1980) as well as many others use the
logarithmic transformation of the stock price as a measure of stock volatility. Although the asymptotic properties
and forecasting power of price-based range measures has been extensively documented, as far as the authors are
aware of, this is the first paper that applies the concept of range to implied volatility. To have a better understanding
of the properties of RVIX, we check the predictive ability of RVIX to forecast realized variance (VAR) as defined in
Goyal and Welch (2010). The pairwise correlation between RVIX in month t-and VAR in month t +1 is 0.27.
12
ranging from statistical and historical measures of volatility such as standard deviation of returns,
such as change in the VIX index and S&P 500 straddle returns. 27 The proposed RVIX together
with S&P 500 straddle returns are the most successful in capturing time-variation in betas.
We argue that the success of RVIX in detecting changes in betas is due to its ability to
characterize uncertainty about future aggregate volatility much better than alternative measures.
we have the advantage of first identifying investors’ expectations about the evolution of near-
term aggregate volatility (VIX), and second measuring the degree of uncertainty in expected
aggregate volatility captured by the range of the this forward-looking option-implied aggregate
volatility measure (RVIX). Aggregate volatility risk has been documented to be an important
factor that determines investors’ risk-return tradeoff and time-variation in investment opportunity
28
set. Because RVIX is essentially a proxy for the degree of uncertainty regarding aggregate
uncertainty in investors’ information set regarding aggregate volatility risk, and hence to have
implications regarding asset pricing, portfolio allocation, and stock return predictability as an
We further test whether the chosen conditioning variable RVIX is correlated with other
business cycle measures documented in the literature.29 Towards that end, we are particularly
interested in the dividend yield (DIV) of the S&P 500 index, the default spread (DEF) which the
spread between BAA and AAA rated corporate bond yields, the term spread (TERM) which is
27
The reader is referred to section 4.4 for a detailed discussion of results.
28
See Campbell (1993), Chen (2002), Ang et al. (2006) and Barinov (2012) for papers that document pricing of
aggregate volatility risk.
29
See Ang and Chen (2002) and Ang and Bekaert (2002) for studies that document increase in correlations during
recessions.
13
the spread between 10-year, 1-year U.S. government bond yields and the short-term treasury bill
rate (TB) and the VIX index, all of which have been documented as strong predictors of business
cycles and hence the conditional CAPM information set.30 To check whether our results are not
affected from a potential correlation with the business cycle variables documented in the
RVIX t MKT MKTt SMBDIVt DEF DEFt TERM TERM t TBTBt VIX VIX t t (6)
Table 1 reports the summary statistics of RVIX, the market portfolio, as well as the
orthogonalized version of RVIX (RVIXORTH), and macro variables used in the analysis.
Looking at the mean (6.66), median (4.98), the minimum (0.92) and the maximum (129.04) of
the RVIX, one can say that VIX index (expectations of near-term market volatility) and its range
(expected changes in near-term aggregate volatility) are quite stable and do not move
significantly in most of the months during our sample period. Without much surprise, the
maximum level of RVIX was recorded in October 1987, where the VXO index skyrocketed from
its minimum value on 3rd October 1987 of 21.15 points to its historical maximum of 150.19
points on black Monday. Finally, similar to the negative correlation documented in previous
studies between the VIX index and market returns, the correlation between RVIX and the market
is -0.41.
30
Dividend yield data is from Robert Shiller’s website (http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller/data.htm), government
and corporate bond yields are from St. Louis Fed website (https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/ ), and short-term
Treasury bill rates are from Ken French’s data library, (http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/
data_library.html )
14
3.1. Stylized Facts
This section documents some stylized facts about the chosen threshold parameter, market
returns, and the empirically documented size and value vs. growth anomalies.
First, looking at Figure 1, one can see that the proposed conditioning variable RVIX
indeed tracks significant negative market moves. Given the empirical evidence that negative
market moves are most associated with increases in aggregate volatility, our novel measure
Next, we conduct a simple exercise to examine returns on different size and book-to-
market portfolios in different volatility regimes in more detail. Using threshold estimates of the
RVIX index, we divide the sample into two regimes, where regime 1 (2) represents calm
(uncertain) months in which RVIX is below (above) the estimated threshold level of the
associated portfolio. This way of decomposing returns into calm and uncertain months gives us
volatility and portfolio return dynamics. For example, looking at columns 5 and 10 of Table 2,
one can see that asset classes, regardless of their portfolio characteristics, lose much more when
market volatility is expected to be highly volatile. This is in line with Hsu and Liu (2009) who
document that volatile periods coincide with bear markets. On the other hand, columns 2, 3, 7
and 8 document the typical size and value vs. growth anomalies. More particularly, static CAPM
fails to offer a clear and linear relationship between betas and portfolio returns, i.e. high (low)
returns are not always justified by high (low) CAPM betas. However, looking at columns 4, 5, 9,
15
and 10 of Table 2, one can gain interesting insights. For example, in calm months (when RVIX is
below the estimated threshold), one can see almost a monotonous decrease in returns going from
small and value portfolios through big and growth portfolios. The opposite is true for episodes
when uncertainty about aggregate volatility is high, when small and value portfolios become the
worst performers. Despite their higher average returns relative to big and growth portfolios,
small and value stock portfolios become the worst performers at times of high uncertainty about
expected aggregate volatility when the market is expected to do badly.31 On the other hand, by
losing less than the market portfolio, big and growth portfolios can be seen as relatively safer
asset classes during uncertain periods about aggregate volatility and market conditions.
The preliminary findings informally confirm our hypotheses that size and book-to-market
portfolios have different sensitivities to market risk during periods of different expectations
regarding the evolution of aggregate volatility. Thus, we posit that an asset pricing model that
correctly takes into account this volatility-based time variation in risk and returns is expected to
do better in pricing and in explaining size and value vs. growth anomalies.
4. Tests of V-CAPM
We begin by examining whether there are statistically significant regime shifts in betas
due to changes in investors’ expectations regarding uncertainty about aggregate volatility and
market conditions. Our conditioning variable is range of the VIX index and Table 3 reports the
associated bootstrap p-values for the sup-LM test. The null hypothesis is that there is no
significant regime shift in portfolio betas. According to bootstrap p-values presented in Table 3,
there are significant regime changes in betas of most portfolios. For portfolios sorted with
31
This also holds for the zero-cost SMB and HML portfolios, which earn on average 58 and 71 basis points per
month during calm market conditions, but which become extremely risky strategies and lose 269 and 231 basis
points, respectively, during high expected volatility periods.
16
respect to market capitalizations, eight out of ten experience significant changes in their betas
between uncertain and calm periods about expected aggregate volatility. For portfolios sorted
with respect to book-to-market ratios, the evidence indicates a regime shift in betas of seven out
of ten portfolios. SMB and HML portfolios also exhibit significant regime shifts in betas. The
results are also robust to using the orthogonalized version of RVIX (RVIXORTH). Taking into
account that the threshold parameter RVIX captures investors’ expectations about uncertainty in
important determinant of their assessment of aggregate risk conditions and an asset’s sensitivity
to overall market risk. The results, if persistent, offer new evidence and an alternative
explanation to the empirically observed size and value vs. growth anomalies.
The conditional CAPM models may have a tendency to overstate the time variation, and
as a result, continuous approximations of CAPM produce highly volatile beta estimates. This is
further confirmed with the evidence reported in Braun, Nelson, and Sunier (1995), who use a
bivariate EGARCH model to estimate conditional betas and document weak evidence of time
variation. On the other hand, our threshold methodology using RVIX as a conditioning variable
suggests that portfolio betas are stable during different expected volatility regimes, however
investors update their beta estimates when their expectations regarding the uncertainty about
Having detected significant regime shifts in betas for most of the portfolios, we proceed
to test the magnitude of this change, and estimate asset betas and their associated threshold
17
parameters during uncertain and calm periods about expected aggregate volatility. Table 4
reports the static CAPM betas, betas estimated via the V-CAPM in calm (regime 1) and high
uncertainty (regime 2) regimes, together with the threshold estimate of RVIX, which determines
the change in uncertainty about aggregate volatility expectations, above (or below) which
Before going into detailed analysis of portfolio betas Table 4, looking at the last column
of Panel A, one can see that the estimated threshold level of RVIX is very stable across size
portfolios, which is estimated at 9.33 in 7 of the 11 cases. 32 Given that RVIX can take on any
positive real number, this consistent level of the threshold estimate affirms the robustness of the
threshold estimation procedure, the proposed model, and the chosen threshold parameter, RVIX.
We argue that the stability of RVIX across portfolios signals to the degree of uncertainty that the
market views as critical regarding aggregate volatility expectations. When range of VIX index in
a given month is below 9.33, the uncertainty in the market is tolerable and betas remain
unaffected. However, when RVIX is more than 9.33, this indicates that uncertainty in the market
regarding the evolution of expected aggregate volatility has increased, and hence investors
update their information set and risk-return dynamics with respect to this information, which is
Next, a detailed analysis of columns 3 and 4 of Panel A reveals important insights about
how the riskiness of different size sorted portfolios changes from one volatility regime to the
other. We note significant changes in beta risk of size sorted portfolios. In particular, betas of
small stock portfolios increase considerably at times of high uncertainty about expected
32
The threshold levels of 17.69 and 6.07 for deciles 6 and 8 might seem as big deviations from 9.33 at first sight,
however, note that these are the two portfolios where the sup-LM test was unable to detect significant regime
changes. This is also the case for decile 8 of book-to-market sorted portfolios, which is detected as a portfolio with
insignificant regime shift and has a relatively high threshold estimate of 15.00.
18
aggregate volatility. Furthermore, it is only the biggest decile portfolio, which exhibits a decrease
The above findings imply that investors re-assess the riskiness of size sorted portfolios
when range of the VIX index is above (or below) the threshold level of 9.33. For example, when
aggregate volatility is expected to be volatile significantly (i.e. when RVIX is above the
threshold), investors re-estimate the beta for the smallest decile portfolio, and update it from 0.91
in calm periods to 1.24 in uncertain periods. Similarly, the riskiness of the biggest decile
portfolio changes when the RVIX is above (or below) the threshold level of 9.33. More
specifically, the beta for the biggest portfolio drops from 0.98 in calm volatility periods to 0.92
in uncertain periods. Furthermore, the beta differential between the smallest and biggest
portfolios (SMB) increases from -0.06 in the low expected volatility regime to 0.30 in the high
Our findings imply that the sensitivity of an asset’s return with respect to the level of
riskiness. This has clear implications on pricing and portfolio allocation. For example, by having
a lower covariance with the market at times of high uncertainty about market volatility, biggest
decile portfolio tends to lose less than any other size-based strategy during volatile periods. Also
given that volatile episodes usually coincide with downward market moves and recessions, a
strategy invested in the biggest decile portfolio appears to be relatively less risky for risk-averse
investors, who are reluctant to lose wealth during those times. This implies a demand for big
stocks, thus pushing their prices up and resulting in lower average returns. Similarly, the risk of
small stock portfolios goes up when near-term aggregate volatility is expected to be volatile.
19
Because uncertainty and increases in aggregate volatility are mostly associated with bad market
conditions and deteriorations in investor wealth, by correlating highly with the market at times of
high uncertainty about aggregate volatility, small stocks are viewed as riskier at times when extra
Panel B of Table 4 offers similar results for portfolios sorted with respect to book-to-
market ratios. Value portfolios have consistently higher betas at times of high uncertainty about
expected volatility, whereas it is only the growth portfolio whose beta decreases during those
times. The results indicate significant time variation in the risk assessments of value and growth
volatility. Investors view value stocks much riskier because they have a higher correlation with
the market at times of high uncertainty about aggregate volatility. Similarly, a portfolio strategy
in growth stocks tends to be less risky at those times. The results are in line with Lettau and
Ludvigson (2001) and Petkova and Zhang (2005), who also document time variation in riskiness
and expected returns of value and growth stocks, in conditional CCAPM and conditional CAPM
settings, respectively.
4.2. The Relation Between Aggregate Volatility Expectations and Risk-adjusted Returns
The documented evidence so far indicates that asset betas change significantly between
different volatility regimes, depending on whether investors expect significant uncertainty about
aggregate volatility or not. Furthermore, the proposed V-CAPM reveals a distinctive pattern
regarding change of beta risk among different asset classes. More particularly, small market
capitalization and high book-to-market (value) portfolios become riskier at times of high
uncertainty about aggregate volatility expectations. On the other hand, big market capitalization
20
and low book-to-market (growth) portfolios become less risky at those times. The findings of our
model offer a potential remedy to the static CAPM and its failure in explaining the well
documented size and value vs. growth anomalies. In order to examine the robustness of the
proposed volatility-based time-varying beta risk explanation, and to see whether investors’
expectations about uncertainty in aggregate volatility has a similar time-varying effect on risk-
adjusted returns, we next compare Jensen’s alphas and Sharpe ratios within the full sample, and
in calm and high uncertainty regimes determined by the threshold level of RVIX implied by the
proposed V-CAPM.
It is well-documented that small and value stocks on average produce significantly higher
returns than their large and growth counterparts.33 However, looking at Jensen’s alphas and betas
of different size and book-to-market portfolios in Table 5, we confirm previous studies that static
CAPM is unable to offer a risk-based explanation to these abnormal returns. On the other hand,
alphas implied by different volatility regimes help us uncover an important aspect of size and
We initially document that size and value strategies pay off at times of low expected
volatility yielding significant and positive risk-adjusted returns. However, the trade-off for these
strategies is that they have extremely bad (significant and negative) risk-adjusted returns at times
of high uncertainty about expected volatility. For example, a strategy invested in the smallest
decile portfolio earns an average risk-adjusted return of 56 basis points during calm months,
33
Although excess returns on small stocks over big stocks have been disappearing during the last two decades,
excess returns on value stocks over growth stocks have been significantly persistent over years.
21
whereas the same strategy yields a risk-adjusted return of -211 basis points in months when
uncertainty about volatility is high. Similarly, a strategy invested in the highest book-to-market
(value) portfolio earns an average risk-adjusted return of 59 basis points during calm months, but
yields an average risk-adjusted return of -142 basis points in months when uncertainty about
volatility is high. SMB and HML strategies also yield similar and significant risk-adjusted
returns over calm and uncertainty periods. On the contrary, although strategies in biggest and
lowest book-to-market (growth) portfolios disappoint their investors in calm months with
average risk-adjusted returns of 8 and 24 basis points, respectively, they yield positive and
significant risk-adjusted returns in months when uncertainty about volatility is high (24 and 75
(1966, 1975). Sharpe ratio is a commonly used measure to track the performance of mutual funds
and it can be easily applied to measure the reward-to-variability of any investment asset or
portfolio. By scaling an asset’s excess return to the standard deviation of excess returns on the
sensitivity of returns on an investment class or a trading strategy per unit of risk taken. 34 The
measure is model free, hence it provides an indirect test for the robustness of our chosen
volatility parameter RVIX, as we will compare the Sharpe ratios of test assets within the whole
sample with those obtained in two different volatility regimes determined by RVIX. Analyzing
reward-to-variability ratios in different volatility regimes will give us further insight about the
34
The excess return on the asset can be on any benchmark such as the S&P 500 returns or the risk-free rate. As in
most studies, we choose returns in excess of the risk-free rate to measure an asset’s excess return.
22
risk-return dynamics of the test assets with respect investors’ expectations regarding the
Looking at Panel A of Table 6, one can detect no clear pattern in Sharpe ratios of
portfolios sorted with respect to market capitalizations within the full sample. One can even say
that during the sample period, an investment strategy based on stocks in the smallest size decile
commands a lower reward per unit of risk taken as opposed to a strategy based on stocks in the
highest decile, which is not consistent with a rational risk-based explanation. On the other hand,
when we decompose the sample into two volatility regimes determined by the RVIX, we see
different risk-return dynamics across size sorted portfolios in different volatility regimes. In calm
periods, the strategy in the smallest decile portfolio commands a higher reward-to-variability
ratio compared to the biggest decile portfolio (0.2727 vs. 0.2250), however in periods when
uncertainty about volatility is high, the situation is reversed, investors experience a much worse
reward-to-variability ratio for the smallest decile portfolio against the biggest decile (-0.4513 vs.
-0.1727). This different pattern in Sharpe ratios is also consistent with our previous results
documenting significant differences in betas and Jensen’s alphas of those strategies and explains
why investors would want to be compensated for the extra risk that they are taking by investing
in small stocks.
We observe a similar pattern for the Sharpe ratios of portfolios sorted with respect to
book-to market ratios. Although there is not a significant in Sharpe ratios in the full sample, we
document that value portfolios command higher (lower) reward-to-variability ratios compared to
explanation to the empirically documented value vs. growth anomaly. The results confirm our
23
hypothesis that market’s expectation of uncertainty in aggregate volatility is an important
returns help us uncover why small and value stocks on average earn higher returns than their big
and growth counterparts. By conditioning asset returns using a novel forward-looking volatility
measure (RVIX), which summarizes investors’ expectations about the uncertainty of near-term
The time-series analyses at the portfolio level in the first part indicate distinct exposure of
size and book-to-market ratio sorted portfolios to uncertainty about aggregate volatility
expectations, which manifests itself with significant changes in portfolio betas during low and
high uncertainty periods about aggregate volatility. However, it is important to note that stocks
can exhibit significant cross-sectional variation within each portfolio. Therefore even though
time-series analysis at the portfolio level point towards RVIX being a potentially important
conditioning variable in explaining stock returns, this explanatory power might result from
stocks’ other characteristics. In the next section, we examine whether cross-sectional differences
in beta-return relationship are attributable to RVIX at the individual stock level, and whether
betas implied by high vs. low uncertainty about aggregate volatility is a priced risk factor in the
cross-section.
We start with examining whether stock betas estimated via threshold level of RVIX can
predict the cross-sectional differences in their returns. Following Ang et al. (2006), we estimate
24
Equation (3) using monthly regression windows with daily data. In line with our previous results,
we use the most commonly observed RVIX threshold level to identify low (high) expected
volatility periods. More particularly, we identify months in which the threshold parameter RVIX
is greater (less) than 9.33 as periods of high (low) uncertainty about expected aggregate
volatility. We denote corresponding betas as 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 and 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 , respectively. The sample is the
universe of CRSP stocks covering all NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ common stocks with share codes
10 and 11. The regressions are estimated each month from January 1986 to December 2010 (300
months).
of 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 and 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 . For each month, from February 1986 to December 2010, stocks are sorted
into decile portfolios based on their 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 and 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 . Our portfolio formation exercise uses
information available only as of the formation date. Hence it avoids potential look-ahead bias in
the estimation of betas. Decile 1 (10) contains stocks with the lowest (highest) betas. Next-month
post-ranking portfolio returns are calculated using both equally- and value-weighted weighting
schemes, and the procedure is repeated each month. Table 7 reports next-month returns, CAPM
and Fama and French (1993) 3-factor alphas of 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 and 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 sorted deciles.
Univariate portfolio sorts indicate an almost monotone and negative relationship between
the betas and next-month average returns when uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility is
high. Portfolio of stocks with lowest 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 (portfolio 1) earns 1.72% per month, whereas return
on the portfolio of stocks with highest 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 (portfolio 10) is 1.16% per month. The spread
portfolio which is long in the highest 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 stocks and short in the lowest 𝛽𝑈𝑁𝐶 stocks (10-1)
loses on average 0.72% per month with a t-statistic of –2.92. Next month’s risk-adjusted returns
25
(CAPM and FF 3-factor alphas) as well as value-weighted returns (both raw and risk-adjusted)
also imply a negative beta next-month stock return relationship during periods of high
uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility, with alphas and raw returns of the spread
portfolio ranging from -0.49% to -0.73% with almost all but one being significant at 5% level.
On the other hand, our proposed model is able to establish a positive beta next-month
stock return relationship during periods of low uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility. In
particular, portfolio of stocks with lowest 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 (portfolio 1) earns 1.84% per month, whereas
return on the portfolio of stocks with highest 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 (portfolio 10) is 2.44% per month. The
spread portfolio which is long in the highest 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 stocks and short in the lowest 𝛽𝐶𝐴𝐿𝑀 stocks
earns on average 0.60% per month which is significant at 5% level. Although value-weighted
returns further confirm a positive beta stock return relationship at periods of low uncertainty
about aggregate volatility, next month’s risk-adjusted returns (CAPM and FF 3-factor alphas) of
the spread portfolio are relatively lower and insignificant. Overall, betas implied by the threshold
level of RVIX capture uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility indicating that cross-
section of expected returns are systematically related to the level of uncertainty about aggregate
volatility.
There is now a consensus on time variation in market risk. The conditional CAPM is an
attempt to capture this variation. However, Ghysels (1998) shows that the conditional CAPM is
unable to specify time variation accurately, leading to higher pricing errors compared to the
unconditional CAPM. In view of these findings, we believe that it is crucial to understand the
true dynamics of time variation in beta risk and incorporate this dynamics in the pricing model.
26
Our previous findings establish that beta risk exhibits significant changes triggered by shifts in
investors’ expectations regarding the evolution of near-term aggregate volatility. Hence, the next
natural step would be to analyze whether this risk is priced in the cross-section.
We employ standard Fama and MacBeth (1973) two-pass regression methodology. The
K
ri ,jt t j MKT ,i ,t MKT ,t k ,i ,t k ,t i ,t , j 0 ,1, 2
j j j k j
( 7)
k 1
where λ’s represent unconditional prices of risk for various loadings and characteristics, and j =
0, 1, and 2 represent full sample, low and high uncertainty about expected volatility,
respectively. In line with our previous results, we use the most commonly observed RVIX
threshold level to identify low (high) uncertainty periods. More particularly, we identify months
in which the threshold parameter RVIX is greater (less) than 9.33 as uncertain (calm) periods
In the first pass, beta loadings are estimated at each month using daily observations. In
the second pass, a cross-sectional regression is run each month, with beta loadings obtained from
the first pass regressions and additional firm characteristics. The associated estimates for the
intercept term, α, and the risk premia, λ’s, are given by the average of those cross-sectional
regression estimates. Table 7 summarizes the risk premium estimates of associated models
1 We test 7 different specifications of Equation (7). The first column represents the market
model using the full sample. Consistent with earlier findings, CAPM fails to produce a positive
35
We further tried six other threshold levels of RVIX ranging from 8.42 to 11.10, which coincide with the next
commonly observed RVIX threshold levels in our tests after 9.33. The results are robust to different threshold levels
found in portfolio level analyses.
27
and significant risk premium. The second column estimates the price of market risk in low
volatility regime. One can see that, for months where RVIX is less than 9.33 (257 months)
market risk premium is positive and significant, hence the proposed V-CAPM is successful in
establishing a significant sign regarding the price of market risk in periods when market
volatility is not expected to change significantly. Column 3 estimates the price of market risk in
high volatility periods, which corresponds to 43 months in our sample estimation period. We
document a negative and significant market risk premium when the market is expected to exhibit
high volatility.
A negative and significant market risk premium might seem counter-intuitive at first, and
at odds with theoretical predictions of CAPM and relevant risk-based asset pricing theories
where investors should be compensated with a positive risk premium for holding risky assets
such as the market portfolio. However, from an empirical point of view, average realized returns
can be negative in narrowly defined periods in which the reward for taking risk does not
materialize. For example, according to data compiled by Shiller (2013), equity risk premium has
been negative around 75% of the time during the period starting with Nifty Fifty of the 1970’s to
the end of 2007 just before the crisis. Our explanation for the negative risk premium is flight to
safety during episodes when uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility is high. For
uncertainty averse investors, these episodes reflect increase in ambiguity of expected returns
where it becomes extremely difficult to assess which direction the market will go. These
episodes are characterized as periods of unknown unknowns as argued by Baltussen et al. (2014),
i.e. periods when investors don’t know what they don’t know about expected market volatility.
One natural implication to avoid this ambiguity would be to fly to safe heavens such as bonds,
which provide payoffs that are more known and certain. A second order implication for the
28
cross-section of stocks is that there will also be a flight to safety from small and value stocks to
big and growth stock because small and value stocks have higher sensitivities to overall market
To see whether the above results are robust and to make sure the cross-sectional tests are
not suffering from an omitted variables bias, we test the proposed V-CAPM in the presence of
different factor loadings as well as several firm characteristics that have been documented as
important in asset pricing literature. The estimation in specification IV includes market loading
as well as SMB, HML, and MOM loadings, all estimated in monthly windows using daily data.
We see that market risk premium is still significant and positive, confirming the robustness of a
significant and positive market risk premium in calm months. Furthermore, column V shows that
the significance of negative market risk premium disappears when SMB, HML, and MOM
factors are included in high uncertainty regime estimations. Finally, columns VI and VII include
three firm characteristics, which are idiosyncratic volatility, market capitalization and book-to-
market ratio. Idiosyncratic volatility puzzle (the fact that stocks with low (high) idiosyncratic
volatility earn higher (lower) returns) has received considerable interest since it has been first
documented by Ang et al. (2006). We would like to explore whether idiosyncratic volatility is a
priced risk factor or not using the implications of our threshold V-CAPM and the threshold
RVIX variable.36 We further incorporate firm size and B/M ratio as additional firm
characteristics.
36
We measure idiosyncratic volatility as outlined in Ang et al. (2006). More particularly, first on a daily basis we
estimate the regression residual from the Fama and French (1993) three-factor mode; i.e.
ri ,t i i , MKT MKTt i , SMBSMBt i , HML HMLt i ,t .
The idiosyncratic volatility is expressed as,
1
1 T 2 2
IDIOVOLi ,t i,t ,
T 1 t 1
where T is the number of trading days within a calendar month.
29
Column VI confirms our previous finding that market risk premium is positive and
significant in the presence of further additional variables. Specification VII confirms a negative
but insignificant market risk premium in high uncertainty regime. We further document that
idiosyncratic risk is also priced in both regimes. More interestingly, we document a positive
relationship between idiosyncratic risk and returns in calm periods when uncertainty about
aggregate volatility expectations is low, and a negative relationship only in high expected
uncertainty periods. Idiosyncratic volatility risk is priced positively as in Malkiel and Xu (2006)
during periods when expected aggregate volatility does not change significantly. On the others
side, the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle (stocks with high idiosyncratic risk earn lower returns) is
uncertainty about near-term aggregate volatility. Our results offer a partial uncertainty-based
Overall, the proposed V-CAPM does a good job in establishing a positive risk-return
relationship based on market risk. During low uncertainty months, the price of market risk is
positive and significant, which confirms our hypothesis that investors’ expectation about the
risk-return tradeoff. Furthermore, during high uncertainty months, the price of market risk is
negative and significant, but the significance of negative market risk premium disappears and is
subsumed by the HML strategy and idiosyncratic volatility during those months. CAPM has
been much criticized due to its failure in establishing a positive risk-return relationship and its
silence regarding several anomalies. The pricing tests in this section confirm that CAPM is still
alive but need to be modified by taking into account investors’ expectations regarding
30
uncertainty about near-term volatility, and the proposed threshold V-CAPM is a step in this
direction. The findings also offer interesting insights regarding the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle.
One limitation of using RVIX as a conditioning variable is obviously its time span. The
data regarding VIX index can be traced back to January 1986. On the other hand, using statistical
measures of volatility has the advantage of covering much longer time horizons. To test the
previous sections using several historical, statistical and option-based measures as a proxy for
aggregate volatility. These include the standard deviation of market returns, squared returns,
monthly range of the market index (given by the maximum and minimum level of the market
index in a given month), GARCH (1, 1) volatility, change in VIX index (ΔVIX), and monthly
returns on at-the-money straddles written on the S&P 500 index. Neither of the four backward-
looking statistical measures, nor the forward-looking option-based measure (ΔVIX) proved to
On the other hand, monthly ATM S&P 500 straddle returns produce very similar results
to those obtained by range of the VIX index.38 The results using monthly returns on ATM S&P
500 straddles as the conditioning variable can be summarized as follows.39 Similar to previous
findings, most portfolios exhibit significant bootstrap p-values indicating a significant change in
37
This confirms our argument that forward-looking volatility measures do a better job in capturing investors’
expectations on aggregate market risk compared to statistical measures. The results also lend indirect support to Ang
et al. (2006) who find that statistical measures of aggregate volatility, such as sample volatility, extreme value
volatility estimates, and realized volatility estimates, do not produce enough spread in the cross-section.
38
The significance of ATM straddle returns over ΔVIX supports Cremers et al. (2012) who document that ΔVIX
loses its significance in capturing volatility risk premium in the presence of measures constructed using ATM
straddle returns.
39
The results in detail related to ATM straddle returns are available upon request.
31
beta risk due to changes in returns on ATM straddles. Second, the direction of change in betas is
very similar to results obtained using RVIX. We observe an increase in beta risk for small and
value portfolios and a decrease in the risk of big and growth portfolios at times of high volatility,
confirming our explanation that investors see small and value stocks much riskier in volatile
market episodes, which usually coincides with deteriorations in investment opportunities and
reductions in wealth.
We further examine Jensen’s alphas, Sharpe ratios and the pricing performance of the
proposed V-CAPM using ATM straddle returns as the conditioning variable and confirm that our
volatility-based time-varying risk explanation to the observed size and value vs. growth
anomalies is robust to the use of an alternative forward-looking market based volatility measure.
Finally, looking at the cross-sectional price of risk, using individual stock level data, we find that
market risk is priced in the cross-section especially at times of low expected aggregate volatility,
5. Conclusion
We propose an asset pricing model where betas change discretely at different points in
time. This change is due to investors’ assessment of uncertainty about near-term aggregate
volatility. Proxying investors’ expectations regarding the uncertainty about near-term aggregate
volatility with the range of the VIX index, RVIX, we document the following.
First we find that there exists significant time variation in market betas with respect to
uncertainty in expected aggregate volatility. In particular, small market capitalization and value
portfolios have consistently higher betas compared to big market capitalization and growth
portfolios at times of high uncertainty about expected volatility. Moreover, the beta dispersions
32
between small-big and value-growth portfolios are negative (positive) during calm (uncertain)
periods about expected volatility. Because they correlate more with the market at times when
investors expect significant uncertainty in aggregate volatility, small and value portfolios are
viewed as riskier than big and growth portfolios in bad times when uncertainty about aggregate
confirmed by the risk-adjusted returns implied by the V-CAPM. During calm periods when
uncertainty about expected aggregate volatility is low, small and value portfolios earn on average
higher risk-adjusted returns than big and growth portfolios, however they become extremely
risky strategies at times of increased uncertainty regarding expected volatility exhibiting negative
and significant risk-adjusted returns. Finally, the proposed V-CAPM is able to establish a
positive market risk premium during calm periods when uncertainty about expected aggregate
volatility is low.
CAPM has been much criticized due to its failure in establishing a positive risk-return
relationship and its silence regarding several pricing anomalies. There is now a consensus on
time-variation in betas, but not on how this variation should be modelled. By using a novel
in a dynamic way. The proposed model and the related empirical results support the view of a
risk-based rational asset pricing theory and offers a volatility-based explanation of risk-return
dynamics where asset return sensitivities to market risk change discretely in time with respect to
33
References
Alizadeh, S., M. Brandt, and F. Diebold, 2002, “Range-based Estimation of Stochastic Volatility
Models,” Journal of Finance 57, 1047-1092.
Andersen, T. G., 1996, “Return Volatility and Trading Volume: An Information Flow
Interpretation of Stochastic Volatility,” Journal of Finance 51, 169-204.
Ang, A., and G. Bekaert, 2002, “International Asset Allocation with Regime Shifts,” Review of
Financial Studies 15, 1137-1187.
Ang, A., and J. Chen, 2002, “Asymmetric Correlations of Equity Portfolios,” Journal of
Financial Economics 63, 443-494.
Ang, A., J. Chen, and Y. Xing, 2006, “Downside Risk,” Review of Financial Studies 19, 1191-
1239.
Ang, A., R. J. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang, 2006 “The Cross Section of Volatility and
Expected Returns,” Journal of Finance 61, 259-299.
Arnott, R. D., and P. L. Bernstein, 2002, “What Risk Premium is "Normal”?,” Financial
Analysts Journal 58, 64-85.
Asai, M. and I. Brugal, 2013, “Forecasting Volatility via Stock Return, Range, Trading Volume
and Spillover Effects: The Case of Brazil”, North American Journal of Economics and
Finance 25, 202-213.
Atilgan, Y., Bali, T., and K. O. Demirtas, 2015, “Implied Volatility Spreads and Expected
Market Returns”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 33, 87-101.
Bailliu, J., A. Dib, T. Kano, and L. Schembri, 2014, “Multilateral Adjustment, Regime Switching
and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics”, North American Journal of Economics and Finance
27, 68-87.
Bali, T., Demirtas, K. O., and H. Levy, 2009, “Is There an Intertemporal Relation Between
Downside Risk and Expected Returns?”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
44, 883-909.
Bali, T., and A. Hovakimian, 2010, “Volatility Spreads and Expected Stock Returns”,
Management Science 55, 1797-1812.
34
Bannouh, K., M. Martens, and D. van Dijk, 2013, “Forecasting Volatility with the Realized
Range in the Presence of Noise and Non-trading”, North American Journal of Economics
and Finance 26, 535-551.
Barinov, A., 2012 “Aggregate Volatility Risk: Explaining the Small Growth Anomaly and the
New Issues Puzzle,” Journal of Corporate Finance 18, 763-781.
Bekaert, G., and G. Wu, 2000, “Asymmetric Volatility and Risk in Equity Markets,” Review of
Financial Studies 13, 1-42.
Bianconi, M, S. MacLachlan, and M. Sammon, 2015, “Implied Volatility and the Risk-free Rate
of Return in Options Markets”, North American Journal of Economics and Finance 31,
1-26.
Bollen, N. P., and R. E. Whaley, 2009 “Hedge Fund Risk Dynamics: Implications for
Performance Appraisal,” Journal of Finance 64, 987-1037.
Bollerslev, T., and H. O. Mikkelsen, 1999, “Long-term Equity Anticipation Securities and Stock
Market Volatility Dynamics,” Journal of Econometrics 92, 75-99.
Bollerslev, T., Tauchen, G., and H. Zhou, 2009, “Expected Stock Returns and Variance Risk
Premia”, Review of Financial Studies 22, 4463-4492.
Brandt, M., and C. Jones, 2006, “Volatility Forecasting with Range-based EGARCH Models,”
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 79, 61-74.
Braun, P. A., D. B. Nelson, and A. M. Sunier, 1995 “Good News, Bad News, Volatility and
Betas,” Journal of Finance 50, 1575-1603.
Buraschi A., Porchia P., and F. Trojani, 2010 “Correlation Risk and Optimal Portfolio Choice”,
Journal of Finance 65, 393-420.
Buraschi, A., Trojani, F., and A. Vedolin, 2014 “When Uncertainty Blows in the Orchard:
Comovement and Equilibrium Volatility Risk Premia”, Journal of Finance 69, 101-137.
Busch, T., B. J. Christensen, and M. O. Nielsen, 2011, “The Role of Implied Volatility in
Forecasting Future Realized Volatility and Jumps in Foreign Exchange, Stock, and Bond
Markets,” Journal of Econometrics 160, 48–57.
Campbell, J. Y., 1987, “Stock Returns and the Term Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics
18, 373–399.
Campbell, J. Y., 1993, “Intertemporal Asset Pricing without Consumption Data,” American
Economic Review 83, 487–512.
Campbell, J. Y., 2007, “Estimating the Equity Premium,” NBER Working Paper No. 13423.
35
Campbell, J. Y., and L. Hentschel, 1992, “No News is Good News: An Asymmetric Model of
Changing Volatility in Stock Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics 31, 281-318.
Campbell, J. Y., and R. J. Shiller, 1998, “Valuation Ratios and the Long-run Stock Market
Outlook,” Journal of Portfolio Management 24, 11-26.
Canina, L., and S. Figlewski, 1993, “The Informational Content of Implied Volatility,” Review of
Financial Studies 6, 659–681.
Chen, J., 2002, “Intertemporal CAPM and the Cross-section of Stock Returns,” Working paper,
University of Southern California.
Chen, C., R. Gerlach, and A. Lin, 2011, “Multi-regime Nonlinear Capital Asset Pricing Models,”
Quantitative Finance 11, 1421-1438.
Chou, R. Y., 2005, “Forecasting Financial Volatilities with Extreme Values: The Conditional
Autoregressive Range (CARR) Model,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37, 561-
582.
Chou, R. Y. and N. Liu, 2010, “The Economic Value of Volatility Timing Using a Range-based
Volatility Model,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34, 2288-2301.
Cremers, M., and D. Weinbaum, 2010, “Deviations from Put-Call Parity and Stock Return
Predictability”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45, 335-367.
Cremers, M., M. Halling, and D. Weinbaum, 2014, “In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility
Risk in the Cross-section of Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance, forthcoming.
Damodaran, A., 2012, “Equity Risk Premiums: Determinants, Estimation and Implications,”
Working paper, NYU Stern.
Duffee, G. R., 1995, “Stock Returns and Volatility: A Firm-level Analysis,” Journal of Financial
Economics 37, 399-420.
Engle, R. F., and T. Bollerslev, 1986, “Modelling the Persistence of Conditional Variances,”
Econometric Reviews 5, 1–50.
Engle, R. F., and V. K. Ng, 1993, “Measuring and Testing the Impact of News on Volatility,”
Journal of Finance 48, 1749–1778.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1988, “Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of
Financial Economics 22, 3–25.
Fama, E. F., and J. D. MacBeth, 1973, “Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests,”
Journal of Political Economy 81, 607–636.
36
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1992, “The Cross-section of Expected Returns,” Journal of
Finance 47, 427-465.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1993, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and
Bonds”, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56.
Fama, E. F., and G. W. Schwert, 1977, “Asset Returns and Inflation,” Journal of Financial
Economics 5, 115–146.
Ferson, W. E. and C. R. Harvey, 1991, “The Variation of Economic Risk Premiums,” Journal of
Political Economy 99, 385-415.
Ferson, W. E. and R. A. Korajczyk, 1995, “Do Arbitrage Pricing Models Explain the
Predictability of Stock Returns?,” Journal of Business 68, 309-349.
Ferson, W. E. and C. R. Harvey, 1999, “Conditioning Variables and the Cross Section of Stock
Returns,” Journal of Finance 54, 1325-1360.
French, K., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh, 1987, “Expected Stock Returns and
Volatility,” Journal of Financial Economics 19, 3 –29.
Garman, M. B., and M. J. Klass, 1980, “On the Estimation of Security Price Volatilities from
Historical Data”, Journal of Business 53, 67–78.
Ghysels, E., 1998, “On Stable Factor Structures in the Pricing of Risk: Do Time Varying Betas
Help or Hurt?,” Journal of Finance 53, 549-573.
Guidolin, M., and A. Timmermann, 2008, “Size and Value Anomalies Under Regime Shifts,”
Journal of Financial Econometrics 6, 1-48.
Hamilton, J. D., 1989, “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time
Series and the Business Cycle,” Econometrica 57, 357-384.
Hamilton, J. D., and G. Lin, 1996, “Stock Market Volatility and the Business Cycle,” Journal of
Applied Econometrics 11, 573-593.
Han, H., and M. D. Park, 2013, “Comparison of Realized Measure and Implied Volatility in
Forecasting Volatility,” Journal of Forecasting 32, 522-533.
Hansen, B. E., 1996, “Inference When a Nuisance Parameter is not Identified Under the Null
Hypothesis,” Econometrica 64, 413-430.
Hansen, B. E., 2000, “Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation,” Econometrica 68, 575-605.
Harris, R. D., E. Stoja, and F. Yilmaz, 2011, “A Cyclical Model of Exchange Rate Volatility,”
Journal of Banking and Finance 35, 3055-3064.
37
Harvey, C. R., 1989, “Time-varying Conditional Covariances in Tests of Asset Pricing Models,”
Journal of Financial Economics 24, 289-317.
Ho, K. Y., Y. Shi, and Z. Zhang, 2013, “How Does News Sentiment Impact Asset Volatility?
Evidence from Long Memory and Regime-switching Approaches”, North American
Journal of Economics and Finance 26, 436-456.
Hsu, J., and F. Li, 2009, “Cyclicality in Stock Market Volatility and Optimal Portfolio
Allocation.” In: G.N. Gregoriou (Ed.), Stock Market Volatility, 195-207. Boca Raton, FL:
Chapman & Hall.
Jagannathan, R., and Z. Wang, 1996, “The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-section of
Expected Returns,” Journal of Finance 51, 3-53.
Keim, D. B., and R. F. Stambaugh, 1986, “Predicting Returns in the Stock and Bond Markets,”
Journal of Financial Economics 17, 357–390.
Lettau, M., and S. Ludvigson, 2001, “Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A Cross-sectional Test When
Risk Premia are Time-varying,” Journal of Political Economy 109, 1238-1287.
Lewellen, J. W., S. Nagel, and J. Shanken, 2010, “A Skeptical Appraisal of Asset Pricing Tests,”
Journal of Financial Economics 96, 175-194.
Malkiel, B., and Y. Xu, 2006, “Idiosyncratic Risk and Security Returns,” Working paper,
University of Texas at Dallas.
Moise, C. E., 2008, “Stochastic Volatility Risk and the Size Anomaly,” Working Paper, Case
Western Reserve University.
Parkinson, M., 1980, “The Extreme Value Method for Estimating the Variance of the Rate of
Return”, Journal of Business 53, 61-65.
Patten, A., and T. Ramadorai, 2013, “On the High-frequency Dynamics of Hedge Fund Risk
Exposures,” Journal of Finance 68, 597-635.
Petkova, R., and L. Zhang, 2005, “Is Value Riskier than Growth?,” Journal of Financial
Economics 78, 187-202.
Pollet, J. M., and M. Wilson, 2010, “Average Correlation and Stock Market Returns”, Journal of
Financial Economics 96, 364-380.
Poon, S., and C., Granger, 2005, “Practical Issues in Forecasting Volatility,” Financial Analysts
Journal, 61, 45-56.
Schwert, W. G., 1989, “Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time?,” Journal of
Finance 44, 1115-1153.
38
Shanken, J., 1992, “On the Estimation of Beta-pricing Models,” Review of Financial Studies 1,
1-33.
Sharpe, W. F., 1966, “Mutual Fund Performance,” Journal of Business 39, 119-138.
Sharpe, W. F., 1975, “Adjusting For Risk in Portfolio Performance Measurement,” Journal of
Portfolio Management 1, 29-34.
Shiller, R. J., 2005, Irrational Exuberance, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.
Wang, Y., and J. Ma, 2014, “Excess Volatility and the Cross-section of Stock Returns”, North
American Journal of Economics and Finance 27, 1-16.
Welch, I. and A. Goyal, 2008, “A Comprehensive Look at The Empirical Performance of Equity
Premium Prediction”, Review of Financial Studies 21, 1455-1508.
Zheng, T., and H. Zuo, 2013, “Reexamining the Time-varying Volatility Spillover Effects: A
Markov Switching Causality Approach”, North American Journal of Economics and
Finance 26, 643-662.
39
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics
This table reports the descriptive statistics for monthly returns on the market portfolio (MKT), and monthly range of
the VIX index (RVIX), as well as orthogonalized measure of RVIX (RVIXORTH), and 4 business cycle related
measures. The market portfolio is the CRSP value-weighted index for all NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks.
RVIX is the difference between maximum and minimum level of VIX in a given month, i.e. RVIX t = Max{VIXτ} -
Min{VIXτ}, τ = 1,2, … , T, where τ denotes trading days in a given month, and t denotes months. . DIV is the
dividend yield of the S&P 500 index. DEF is defined as the spread between BAA and AAA rated corporate bond
yield and TERM is the spread between 10-year and 1-year U.S. government bond yields. TB is the one-month
Treasury Bill rate. RVIXORTH is the residual term from the following regression:
RVIX t MKT MKTt SMBDIVt DEF DEFt TERM TERM t TBTBt VIX VIX t t
The sample covers the period from January 1986 to December 2012 (324 months). For the period covering January
1986 to December 1989, VIX is replaced by VXO which is based on S&P 100 index options. All return figures are
in percentages.
40
Figure 1. Time-series of RVIX and Market Returns
120 .15
.10
100
.05
80
.00
60 -.05
-.10
40
-.15
20
-.20
0 -.25
86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
MARKET RVIX
41
Table 2. Stylized Facts About Portfolio Returns
This table presents the returns on several portfolios that have been used as test assets in this study and the market
portfolio during the full sample period from January 1986 through December 2012 (324 months) and two different
volatility regimes. Size represents portfolios which contain stocks sorted with respect to their market capitalizations.
B/M represents portfolios which contain stocks sorted with respect to their book-to-market ratios. SMB is a portfolio
that is long in stocks in the smallest decile and short in stocks in the biggest decile. HML is a portfolio that is long in
stocks which are in the highest B/M decile and short in stocks which are in the lowest B/M decile.
Size Beta Full Regime1 Regime2 B/M Beta Full Regime1 Regime2
sample (Calm) (Volatile) sample (Calm) (Volatile)
Small 1.0163 0.0097 0.0176 -0.0365 High 1.0557 0.0115 0.0187 -0.0298
Decile2 1.1604 0.0096 0.0170 -0.0330 Decile2 0.9864 0.0107 0.0160 -0.0203
Decile3 1.1434 0.0104 0.0173 -0.0297 Decile3 0.9716 0.0091 0.0149 -0.0239
Decile4 1.1262 0.0094 0.0158 -0.0271 Decile4 0.9512 0.0102 0.0147 -0.0156
Decile5 1.1380 0.0104 0.0164 -0.0240 Decile5 0.9467 0.0090 0.0135 -0.0167
Decile6 1.0713 0.0104 0.0157 -0.0213 Decile6 0.9029 0.0096 0.0143 -0.0179
Decile7 1.0673 0.0108 0.0164 -0.0205 Decile7 0.8487 0.0098 0.0153 -0.0221
Decile8 1.0795 0.0103 0.0156 -0.0203 Decile8 0.8445 0.0102 0.0141 -0.0124
Decile9 1.0101 0.0101 0.0148 -0.0170 Decile9 0.9228 0.0093 0.0129 -0.0109
Big 0.9449 0.0087 0.0118 -0.0096 Low 1.0501 0.0090 0.0116 -0.0066
SMB 0.0716 0.0010 0.0058 -0.0269 HML 0.0059 0.0026 0.0071 -0.0231
Market 0.0089 0.0129 -0.0143 Market 0.0089 0.0128 -0.0143
42
Table 3. Bootstrap p-values for 10 Size and B/M portfolios
This table reports the bootstrap p-values of the modified sup-LM test suggested by Hansen (1996). We test the null
hypothesis of no significant regime shifts in portfolio betas due to changes in the level of uncertainty regarding
aggregate volatility expectations, captured by RVIX, as well as an orthogonalized measure of RVIX (RVIXORTH).
RVIXORTH is the residual term from the following regression:
RVIX t MKT MKTt SMBDIVt DEF DEFt TERM TERM t TBTBt VIX VIX t t
Size represents portfolios which contain stocks sorted with respect to their market capitalizations, and B/M
represents portfolios which contain stocks sorted with respect to their book-to-market ratios, respectively. The
sample period covers January 1986 to December 2012 (324 months). *, **, *** denote significance levels at 10%, 5%,
and 1%, respectively.
43
Table 4. Threshold Estimates for 10 Size and 10 Book-to-Market Portfolios
This table reports the unconditional CAPM betas, the threshold beta estimates with respect to low and high
volatility regimes, and their associated threshold volatility estimates, proxied by S&P 500 at-the-money straddle
returns. Panels A and B present results for portfolios sorted with respect to market capitalizations, and book-to-
market ratios, respectively. SMB is a portfolio that is long in stocks in the smallest decile and short in stocks in the
biggest decile. HML is a portfolio that is long in stocks which are in the highest B/M decile and short in stocks
which are in the lowest B/M decile. The sample covers the period from January 1986 to December 2012 (324
months). Regime 1 (2) corresponds to low (high) uncertainty about volatility regimes where monthly RVIX is
lower (higher) than the estimated threshold level.
44
Table 5. Comparison of Jensen’s Alphas
This table reports Jensen’s alphas for the unconditional CAPM and for the threshold volatility model (V-CAPM)
with respect to low and high volatility regimes. The sample covers the period from January 1986 to December 2012
(324 months). Regime 1 (2) corresponds to low (high) uncertainty about volatility regimes where monthly RVIX is
lower (higher) than the estimated threshold level. The numbers in parantheses denote the associated t-statistics with
Newey-West corrected standard errors.
Panel A: 10 Size portfolios
α CAPM α V-CAPM, Regime1 α V-CAPM, Regime2
Small 0.0636 0.5601 -2.1113
(0.25) (1.98**) (-4.47***)
Decile2 -0.0221 0.3322 -1.5210
(-0.11) (1.37) (-3.50***)
Decile3 0.0680 0.3908 -1.1887
(0.41) (1.96*) (-2.85***)
Decile4 -0.0177 0.2389 -0.9651
(-0.12) (1.32) (-2.48**)
Decile5 0.1753 0.2750 -0.6550
(0.58) (1.80*) (-2.22**)
Decile6 0.1089 0.2543 -0.4421
(0.94) (2.00) (-1.50)
Decile7 0.1521 0.3319 -0.5203
(1.43) (3.02***) (-1.77*)
Decile8 0.0938 0.2158 -0.4439
(0.92) (1.94*) (-1.86*)
Decile9 0.1147 0.1997 -0.2266
(1.49) (2.35**) (-1.25)
Big 0.0111 -0.0792 0.3373
(0.20) (-1.27) (2.37**)
SMB -0.3088 0.2543 -2.6881
(-0.85) (1.33) (-4.48***)
Panel B: 10 B/M portfolios
α CAPM α V-CAPM, Regime1 α V-CAPM, Regime2
High 0.2306 0.5930 -1.4147
(0.94) (2.26**) (-3.40***)
Decile2 0.2241 0.4556 -0.6294
(1.40) (2.34**) (-2.27**)
Decile3 0.1143 0.4352 -1.1103
(0.61) (2.29**) (-2.54**)
Decile4 0.2190 0.3595 -0.3378
(1.33) (1.75*) (-1.14)
Decile5 0.0443 0.1756 -0.1842
(0.35) (1.16) (-0.63)
Decile6 0.1256 0.3015 -0.4080
(0.89) (1.77*) (-1.21)
Decile7 0.1060 0.3309 -0.7462
(0.73) (1.95*) (-2.50**)
Decile8 0.1566 0.1791 0.1433
(1.58) (1.75*) (0.49)
Decile9 0.0547 0.0167 0.3516
(0.62) (0.15) (1.61)
Low -0.0222 -0.2426 0.7474
(-0.18) (-1.88*) (2.66**)
HML 0.0600 0.4331 -2.4016
(0.17) (2.53**) (-4.10***)
45
Table 6. Comparison of Sharpe Ratios and Volatilities
This table reports portfolio ex-post Sharpe ratios and standard deviations for the full sample and two subsamples
representing two different volatility regimes. Regime 1 (2) corresponds to low (high) uncertainty about volatility
regimes where monthly RVIX is lower (higher) than the estimated threshold level. Panels A and B presents results
for portfolios sorted with respect to market capitalizations, and book-to-market ratios, respectively. SMB is a
portfolio that is long in stocks in the smallest decile and short in stocks in the biggest decile. HML is a portfolio that
is long in stocks which are in the highest B/M decile and short in stocks which are in the lowest B/M decile. The
sample covers the period from January 1986 to December 2012 (324 months).
46
Table 7. Univariate Portfolio Sorts Based on Threshold RVIX Betas
This table reports next-month equally- and value-weighted returns, next-month CAPM alpha, next-month Fama and
French (1993) 3-factor alpha and post-ranking average betas of βUNC and βCALM sorted decile portfolios, where βUNC
corresponds to betas estimated in periods of high uncertainty about aggregate volatility (RVIX > 9.33) and βCALM
corresponds to betas estimated in periods of low uncertainty about aggregate volatility (RVIX < 9.33). Decile 1 (10)
contains stocks with the lowest (highest) betas. The test assets are all NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ common stocks with
share codes 10 and 11. The sample period is from January 1986 to December 2010 (300 months).
47
Table 8. Fama-MacBeth Risk Premium Estimates
This table reports the estimates for the average coefficients from cross-sectional Fama-MacBeth (1973) regressions,
K
ri ,jt t j MKT , i , t MKT , t k , i , t k , t i , t , j 0 ,1, 2
j j j k j
k 1
where λ’s represent unconditional prices of risk for various factor loadings and firm characteristics, and j = 0, 1, and
2 represent full sample, calm (low expected volatility) and volatile (high expected volatility) periods, respectively.
We identify months in which RVIX is less (greater) than threshold level 9.33 as calm (volatile) episodes. The test
assets are all NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ common stocks with share codes 10 and 11. The sample period is from
January 1986 to December 2010 (300 months). Regime 1 (Regime 2) corresponds to months where aggregate
volatility is below (above) the threshold parameter. SMB and HML are portfolio loadings on Fama and French
(1993) factors and MOM is the portfolio loading on the Carhart (1997) momentum factor model, all of which are
measured using monthly data from the end of month t-36 to the end of month t. IDIOVOL is the idiosyncratic
volatility measured each month using daily data as in Ang et al. (2006).SIZE and B/M are the log of market
capitalization and the book-to-market ratio observed at the end of month t, respectively. MOM is firm-level
momentum calculated using the stock return from month t-12 to t-2. The numbers in parentheses are the Newey-
West (1987) corrected t-statistics for each coefficient estimate. The term adjusted R2 denotes the cross-sectional R2
statistic adjusted for the degrees of freedom. ***, **, and *denotes significance at 1%, 5% and 10% level,
respectively.
I II III IV V VI VII
BETA 0.14
(0.68)
BETA-CALM 0.41 0.51 0.77
(2.17**) (2.06**) (3.03***)
BETA-UNC -1.50 -1.00 -0.96
(-1.87*) (-1.02) (-1.10)
SMBBeta 0.31 -0.43 0.22 0.07
(1.68*) (-1.03) (1.29) (0.59)
HMLBeta 0.00 -1.03 -0.09 -0.22
(0.03) (-2.04**) (-0.49) (-2.00**)
MOMBeta 0.05 -0.66 0.13 0.08
(0.16) (-0.80) (0.45) (0.42)
IDIOVOL 0.77 -1.83
(2.91*** ) (-6.50*** )
SIZE -0.27 -0.19
(-5.37***) (-4.47***)
B/M 0.43 0.27
(8.14*** ) (4.44*** )
MOM 0.07 0.14
(5.26*** ) (9.64*** )
CONST 1.11 1.59 -1.81 1.19 -2.18 4.51 2.60
(4.13***) (6.23***) (-1.83*) (7.12***) (-3.34***) (6.74***) (4.57***)
48