Solutions Chap 16
Solutions Chap 16
171
172 Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems
generations, and these consumers may not care enough about their children to leave
them a bequest to offset this tax liability.
If you hold the Ricardian view, then you believe that the preceding objections are
not important. In particular, you believe that consumers have the foresight to see that
government borrowing today implies future taxes to be levied on them or their descen-
dants. Hence, a debt-financed tax cut gives consumers transitory income that eventual-
ly will be taken back. As a result, consumers will save the extra income they receive in
order to offset that future tax liability.
7. A budget deficit might be good policy for the following reasons. First, it can help stabi-
lize the economy if output is below full employment. Second, it can allow the country to
keep tax rates relatively smooth despite fluctuations in government spending (e.g.,
temporary wars) or in output (namely, in recessions). Third, it can shift a tax burden
from current to future generations. For example, some expenditures might benefit
future generations, and some economists argue that those generations should bear
some of the costs of financing the expenditures.
8. The level of government debt might affect the government’s incentives regarding money
creation because the government debt is specified in nominal terms. A higher price
level reduces the real value of the government’s debt. Hence, a high level of debt might
encourage the government to print money in order to raise the price level and reduce
the real value of its debt.
If national saving did not change, then as pointed out by the prominent economist
you heard from yesterday, the budget deficit would not have the effects I listed. In par-
ticular, output, employment, foreign debt, and interest rates would be unaffected in
both the short run and the long run. The tax cut would have no effect on economic well-
being.
There are several reasons the Ricardian argument may fail. First, consumers
might not be rational and forward-looking: they may not fully comprehend that the cur-
rent tax cut means a future tax increase. Second, some people may face constraints on
their borrowing: in essence, the tax cut would give these taxpayers a loan that they are
unable to obtain now. Third, consumers may expect the implied future taxes to fall not
on them, but on future generations whose consumption they do not care about.
Your committee must decide how you think consumers would behave in response
to this debt-financed tax cut. In particular, would they consume more, or not?
Your faithful servant,
CBO Economist.
3. a. We will assume that the life-cycle model of Chapter 16 holds and that people want
to keep consumption as smooth as possible. This implies that the effect on con-
sumption of a temporary change in income will be spread out over a person’s
entire remaining life. We will also assume for simplicity that the interest rate is
zero.
Consider a simple example. Let T be the amount of the one-time, temporary
tax levied on the young, and let B be the amount of the one-time benefit paid to
the old, where B = T. If a typical elderly person has 10 years left to live, then the
temporary benefit increases the present consumption of the elderly by B/10. If a
typical worker has 30 years left to live, then the increase in taxes decreases their
present consumption by T/30. Aggregate consumption changes by an amount
ΔC = B/10 – T/30
= B/15.
The transfer of wealth to the elderly causes a net increase in consumption
and, therefore, a decrease in saving. This happens because the elderly increase
consumption by more than the workers decrease it, because the elderly have fewer
years left to live and thus have a higher marginal propensity to consume.
b. The answer to part (a) does depend on whether generations are altruistically
linked. If generations are altruistically linked, then the elderly may not feel any
better off because of the Social Security benefit, since the tax and benefit increase
has no effect on a typical family’s permanent income; it simply transfers resources
from one generation of the family to another. If the elderly do not want to take
advantage of this opportunity to consume at their children’s expense, they may try
to offset the effect of the tax increase on the young by giving them a gift or leaving
a bequest. To the extent that this takes place, it mitigates the impact of the tax
change on consumption and saving.
4. A rule requiring a cyclically adjusted balanced budget has the potential to overcome,
at least partially, the first two objections to a balanced-budget rule that were raised
in this chapter. First, this rule allows the government to run countercyclical fiscal
policy in order to stabilize the economy. That is, the government can run deficits dur-
ing recessions, when taxes automatically fall and expenditures automatically rise.
These automatic stabilizers affect the deficit but not the cyclically adjusted deficit.
Second, this rule allows the government to smooth tax rates across years when
income is especially low or high—it is not necessary to raise tax rates in recessions or
to cut them in booms.
On the other hand, this rule only partially overcomes these two objections, since
the government can only run a deficit of a certain size, which might not be big enough.
Also, a cyclically adjusted balanced budget does not allow the government to smooth
tax rates across years when expenditure is especially high or low, as in times of war or
Chapter 16 Government Debt 174
peace. (We might take account of this by allowing an exemption from the balanced bud-
get rule in special circumstances such as war.) This rule does not allow the government
to overcome the third objection raised in the chapter, since the government cannot shift
the burden of expenditure from one generation to another when this is warranted.
Finally, a serious problem with a rule requiring a balanced cyclically adjusted
budget is that we do not directly observe this budget. That is, we need to estimate how
far we are from full employment; then we need to estimate how expenditures and taxes
would differ if we were at this full-employment level. None of these estimates can be
made precisely.
5. The Congressional Budget Office (www.cbo.gov) regularly provides budget forecasts.
One excellent CBO publication that summarizes these forecasts is the “The Budget and
Economic Outlook.” For example, in the March 2009 update of this publication, the
CBO projected that the debt held by the public would rise from 41 percent of GDP at
the end of 2008 to a peak of 62 percent by the end of 2011 and then decline to 56 per-
cent at the end of 2019. Under current rules for producing baseline projections of the
debt, the CBO makes several assumptions.
First, the CBO assumes that so-called discretionary government spending (items
such as defense, administration, and the like, amounting to about one-third of federal
spending) will grow at only the rate of inflation. Since nominal GDP generally grows
faster than inflation, this implies that the CBO builds in a steady decline in discre-
tionary government spending relative to GDP.
Second, the CBO assumes that the growth of both Medicare and Medicaid aver-
ages about 7 percent per year under the rate setting system that constrains fees paid
for physician’s services. But if Congress overrides these limits in the future, as it has
every year since 2003, federal spending on these health programs will be much greater
than projected.
Third, the CBO assumes that the taxes in the future will be whatever legislation
currently says they will be (i.e., the CBO does not take a stand on what changes legis-
lators might pass in the future).
Fourth, the CBO makes educated guesses about future potential economic growth,
now projected at 2.3 percent over the next decade, and other economic indicators. As
discussed in the January 2009 issue of the “Budget and Economic Outlook,” the CBO
justifies these assumptions by noting “CBO’s baseline projections are not intended to be
a forecast of future budgetary outcomes; rather, they serve as a neutral benchmark
that legislators and others can use to assess the potential effects of policy decisions. As
such, CBO’s baseline budget projections, like its economic projections, do not incorpo-
rate potential changes in policy.”
These assumptions, which serve the purpose of providing a neutral benchmark,
are unlikely to hold in practice. Policymakers probably will increase real spending on
discretionary programs as the economy grows over time. They may also change taxes,
although the direction is harder to predict. If the United States experiences a produc-
tivity slowdown, this will reduce output growth and hence growth in tax revenue. As a
consequence, future government debt likely will be somewhat different than currently
projected.