Theme 4
Theme 4
Markets: 1757-1857
Theme IV
Colonial Economy
137
Trade and Markets
COLONIAL ECONOMY
Theme begins with a discussion on British Indian currency policies (Unit 8). Whether
British Indian monetary policies were designed to handle Britain’s ‘severe external liquidity
crisis’? It delves into Indian nationalists’ opinion on the currency and gold standard policy
of the British in Colonial India; whether India was denied the benefits of the gold standard
by reducing her access to gold or else intervention of British interests (by switching
Indian gold asset preferences to sterling) had little significance?
Unit 9 revolves around Dada Bhai Naoroji’s theory of ‘drain of wealth’ from India. Ever
since, the drain of wealth debate has continued to be a heated theme among the economic
historians on British India. Some assert that it drained counrty’s resources; while others
critically questioned the preposition and called it excessively overstated. For some, it was
‘extremely confused and largely coloured by political feelings’. Interestingly, proponents
of conflicting schools of thought are often partially in agreement with each other's findings.
In recent years, the discourse has shifted from an ‘anti-colonial’ theoretical framework to
‘economic theory’.
The contours of economic degradation form the theme of Unit 10. It led to the systematic
destruction of indigenous industries and artisanal classes. British colonial policies completely
brought in the destruction of Indian textile industry, resulting in ‘deindustrialisation’ of
Indian industries and an unfavourable balance of trade between India and England. British
land policies further led to ‘de-agriculturalisation’.
Lastly , the theme (Unit 11) explores whether British imperial policies on account of
drain of Indian resources, money and food exports worsened and triggered famines;
famines became deadly and resulted in enormous loss of lives in the nineteenth century
India or else British rule mitigated famines. Whether it was the British Raj or the geography
responsible for such frequent occurrences of devastating famines; and whether introduction
of railways ended the long eras of deadly famines?
Famine of Bengal
Image Courtesy
Author: Unknown Artist, 1874
Source: https://www.lookandlearn.com/history-images/U233585/The-Famine-in-Bengal; https:/
commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Distressed_Natives_Going_to_the_Relief_Works_
138 _The_Graphic_1874.jpg
Merchants and
UNIT 8 CURRENCY* Markets: 1757-1857
Structure
8.1 Introduction
8.2 Currency on the Eve of Colonial Rule
8.3 Early Phase of Company Coinage
8.4 The Classical Silver Era: 1835-1893
8.5 The Herschell Committee and After
8.6 Council Bills
8.7 Summary
8.8 Glossary
8.9 Exercises
8.8 Suggested Readings
8.1 INTRODUCTION
The modern monetary system of India evolved under conditions of colonialism. The system
was intended to serve colonial interests, initially the interests of the East India Company
(its shareholders and those connected with it), and by the early decades of the nineteenth
century of economically and politically dominant elites of Britain. Currency was closely
linked to the mechanism for extracting wealth from India for the benefit of Britain. The
system was marked by problems from the 1890s, which became increasingly difficult to
resolve due to the stranglehold of British imperialism. Most of these problems were the
outcome of the role which Indian currency was required to play in the economy of Britain.
The East India Company was granted a royal charter in 1600 by queen Elizabeth I
(r. 1558-1603) of the Tudor dynasty, which gave to it a monopoly of the trade between
England and Asia. This implied that no individual or corporate entity in England could legally
engage in this trade. At the same time the charter permitted the Company to take a specified
amount of precious metal (gold or silver) out of the country for its commercial activities.
This was essential because the Company needed precious metal for purchasing commodities
in Asian markets. At this stage, the main commodities it was seeking to purchase for English
and European consumers (a portion of the goods brought to England was re-exported to the
Continent) were Asian spices – mainly pepper, cloves, nutmeg and mace. As the Indonesian
archipelago was the main source for these spices the East India Company sent its first few
commercial expeditions to this region. However, the Dutch East India Company (VOC;
Vereenigde Oost-Indische Compagnie), which had been formed in 1602 and was much
more powerful having far more resources than the East India Company, prevented the
English from getting access to the major producing areas of Southeast Asia.
It may be mentioned that since the end of the 1490s a new oceanic route between Europe
and Asia had been in use for the trade in spices and other commodities, besides the older
land-cum-sea route through West Asia and the eastern Mediterranean. This was an
all-sea route via the Cape of Good Hope. The feasibility of the route had been demonstrated
by the voyage of a fleet of Portuguese ships commanded by Vasco da Gama, which had
successfully traversed this route (from Lisbon to the Malabar coast, and back) in
1497-99. Subsequently, for most of the sixteenth century, the Portuguese had monopolized
this route, violently imposing their control over it with their armed ships. The Portuguese
monopoly came to be challenged by the end of the century by the VOC (and the English
East India Company). Eventually the VOC put an end to the control exercised by the
Portuguese over the all-sea Cape route, establishing its own monopoly by the early decades
of the sixteenth century. The VOC’s monopoly over the route (for most of the seventeenth
century), and control of spice-producing areas, particularly of Southeast Asia, was greatly
superior to that of the Portuguese. As a result the English East India Company only had
8.6 SUMMARY
The monetary system as it evolved during the colonial period was intended to serve colonial
interests and was intricately connected to the economic interests of the colonial power.
Further, problems of British Indian currency were largely related to wealth transfer to
Britain. The primary form of currency of the East India Company’s early trade was
Spanish silver coins, ‘piece of eight’. In the late seventeenth century the East India Company
minted the earliest coins. They received official permission to mint coins locally in 1717
and thus minted coins at Bombay and Madras. In 1766 the East India Company introduced
bimetallic coins in Bengal which in the nineteenth century shifted to monometallic silver
standard rupee as primary currency. In 1835 by Gold and Silver Coinage Act silver rupee
became legal tender in British East India Company territories, though coins issued in the
name of the Mughal emperor also continued to remain in circulation. In 1861, paper
currency was introduced. However, sharp fall in the value of silver from 1870 onwards
prompted the British Indian government to have serious deliberations. Herschell Committee
was first to be constituted to address the issue of declining silver prices, which recommended
closing of private minting of silver coinage. Accordingly exchange rate of rupee was
fixed. Later Fowler Committee suggested adoption of gold standard which was never put
into practice. Instead, Gold Standard Reserve was created which backed Indian rupee 147
Colonial Economy with securities. Further, Council Bills were introduced which allowed for conversion of
pounds into sterling. It had deep ramifications on Indian economy for British importers
made payments in pound sterling and Indian exporters received rupees out of Indian
revenues. After 1926 agricultural prices fell sharply resulting in distress sales of gold
reserves. Indian gold reserves were siphoned to Britain to recover British losses out of
Great Depression. Finally, in 1931 Gold Standard was abandoned resulting in sharp decline
in the value of rupee. Again in the World War II Indian silver balances were used to cover
war expenses, preventing India benefitting from rising value of gold. Independent India's
currency problems were thus legacy of British colonial policies.
8.7 GLOSSARY
Asharfi/Muhr Mughal gold coin
Dam Mughal copper coin; 40 dams = 1 Mughal silver rupee
Diwani Rights Rights to collect taxes; In 1765 diwani rights of Bengal,
Bihar and Orissa were granted to the East India
Company by the Mughal Emperor Shah Alam II after
the defeat of the combined forces of Mir Qasim,
Shujauddaula,, Nawab of Awadh and Shah Alam II in
1764.
Hun/Pagoda Gold coin in circulation in Deccan and South India. It
was modelled on ducat, Venetian gold coin.
Reales A unit of currency in Spain introduced by Pedro I of
Castile (r. 1350-1369) until it was replaced by peseta in
1868.
Sarraf Money-changers
8.8 EXERCISES
1) Discus the currency policy of British Indian government.
2) In what ways did the Herschell Committee transform Indian currency?
3) Examine various committees appointed and currency laws passed by the British Indian
government.
4) ‘Indian currency system was intended to serve the colonial interests’. Comment.
5) British Indian currency problems were largely related to wealth transfer to Britain.
Analyse.
6) ‘Independent India’s currency problems are the legacy of British colonial policies’.
Comment.
7) What role did the Council Bills mechanism play in the transfer of wealth from India to
Britain?
149
Colonial Economy
UNIT 9 DRAIN OF WEALTH DEBATE*
Structure
9.1 Introduction
9.2 Nationalists and the Drain
9.3 Critics of the Drain
9.4 Left Nationalist Views
9.5 Recent Arguments for and Against Drain
9.6 Summary
9.7 Glossary
9.8 Exercises
9.9 Suggested Readings
9.1 INTRODUCTION
In a paper entitled ‘England’s Debt to India’ Dadabhai Naoroji first highlighted in 1867
that Britain was bleeding India by extracting and appropriating more than one-fourth of
India’s revenue. He developed his arguments further in a paper on the ‘Poverty of India’
in 1873 and in 1901 he wrote Poverty and Un-British Rule in India. About the same
point in time Mahadev Ranade and Bholanath Chandra too developed their own ideas of
the drain of wealth from India. These ideas would become the mainstay of the nationalist
critique of British rule in India. Leaders with divergent ideas about India's freedom struggle
agreed on the economic exploitation of India by various means. British spokesmen put up
a stout defense asserting that India only had to pay a small price for the benefits of Pax
Britannica, construction of railways, access to the cheapest money market in the world
and the benefits of modern knowledge and institutions. In recent times the arguments for
and against the drain of wealth from India have been modified and reformulated by radical
and liberal economists and historians.
Note: A plus sign (+) indicates net exports of goods; a minus sign (-) indicates net imports of
goods and net exports of remittances, service charges and other invisibles.
Source: A.K. Banerjee, Aspects of Indo-British Economic Relations, 1818-1898, Bombay,
1982, Tables 34A and 40A.
Source: B.R. Tomlinson, The Economy of Modern India, 1860-1970, III, 3, Cambridge, 1993,
Cambridge online 2008, Table 1.3. p 16.
During the trade boom between 1909-10 and 1912-13 India imported Rs 1,174 million
worth of gold, including Rs 45 million worth of sovereigns which went into circulation.
India’s gold reserves increased by Rs 294 million. It also imported Rs 549 million worth of
silver, only a third of which was used for coinage. [Tomlinson, 2008: 15-17] India was
being paid for its exports but much of the bullion imported was hoarded or not put to
productive use. Morison stated that unrequited transfers were limited to the Home
Charges which were around twenty million rupees a year. This sum was less than two per
cent of the total value of exports at the end of the 19th century and under one per cent in
1913. Morison placed the India drain in 1910-11 at 36% of the Home Charges. This drain
was offset by the services provided by the British.
K.N. Chaudhuri has pointed out that the export surplus was offset by the administrative
expenses incurred outside India, the charges for freight and banking, the remittance of
profits by businessmen, the savings of civil servants and the interest on borrowed capital.
According to Chaudhari’s calculations during 1898-1903 the payment for debt and invisible
expenses amounted to 30 to 35 per cent of exports falling to 23 per cent during 1911-14.
He went on to assert that during this period the sums expended on invisibles and debt
payment in the current account of the balance of payments could not be more than five
percent of the national income. As for the Home Charges they averaged only about 1.8
percent of exports annually between 1898-1901 and declined to an average of 0.8 percent
during 1911-14. Therefore, the drain was not of much significance by the late 19th century.
Several scholars have argued that the drain should refer only to the unproductive debt or
unnecessary expenditure in the annual Home Charges and that it should be assessed in
relation to national income and not public revenue. According to T. Mukerjee (1972: 205)
during 1870-1900, the drain was only between .04 and .07 per cent of India’s national
income. Charlesworth (1982: 54-5) pointed out that even if all Home Charges were
regarded as unproductive, the drain would still ‘barely exceed 0.5 per cent of national
income’. Dasgupta has argued that Ranade recognized that British rule did lead to some
drain of wealth from India but this was neither the root cause of poverty nor the binding
constraint on economic growth in India. Preoccupation with ‘drain’ had the effect of
narrowing the focus of Indian economic thought [Dasgupta, 1993: 86]. 153
Colonial Economy Theodore Morison drew a distinction between economic and political debts but believed
that the 7 million pounds that India had to pay for its ‘political connections with England’
in 1910-11 was in return for maintenance of internal order and protection against external
aggression. Morison and others have argued that India borrowed in England at a lower
rate of interest than other foreign countries did. McLane has pointed out that in the early
years of the twentieth century, Japan paid 4.5 to 5 per cent on its foreign loans while India
paid about 3.5 per cent. The yield to British investors on Indian railways in 1907 was 3.87
per cent; on colonial railways, 4.0 per cent; on American railways, 4.5 per cent; and on other
foreign railways, 4.7 per cent. [McLane, 2003] While the railway or ‘productive’debt was
increasing, the ordinary or ‘unproductive’ debt was decreasing. The ordinary debt had included
the £12,000,000 owed to the stockholders of the old East India Company, the cost of
suppressing the mutiny, and expenses arising out of other wars. The ordinary debt stood at
£96,000,000 in1862; by 1897 it had been reduced to £72,721,161 or by more than 24
per cent. In the same period, the rate of interest paid on the debt declined from 4.543
per cent to 3.393 per cent. In consequence, the annual charge of interest declined by 50 per
cent not including exchange, or by 16 per cent including exchange. By 1909, the ordinary, or
unproductive debt had been reduced still further, to £37,700,000. [McLane, 2003]
Arun Banerji has criticized Chaudhuri for not having a clear concept of the drain and goes
on to argue that it is not of central importance. All the components of the Home Charges
were not objectionable and the calculations were inaccurate. Instead of identifying certain
payments as a drain ‘‘we may look at the entire spectrum of payments abroad out of
incomes generated domestically (and of savings made from them), effected by the owners
of such incomes and savings (or by their nominees) to defray their current or capital
expenses abroad. Varying elements of drain, such as have been discussed, may inhere in
many such payments.’’ [Banerji, 1982: 189]
Table III
Index of exports, imports, and treasure; percentages of imports, invisible and debt payments, and
Home Charges in the total export values; exports as percentages of total estimated agricultural
output, 1898-1914
Year Exports Imports Treasure Percentage of total exports Exports as
(Net Import) of Imports of Invisible of Home % of total
and debt Charges estimated
payment agricultural
output
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
1898-99 100 100 100 56 33 1.9 -
1899-00 97 103 124 59 34 1.8 -
1900-01 95 112 99 61 30 1.7 13.8
1901-02 111 121 87 59 35 0.6 16.6
1902-03 115 116 151 56 30 1.6 14.7
1903-04 136 127 225 50 28 1.1 18.5
1904-05 140 144 219 55 29 1.0 19.3
1905-06 143 169 154 64 33 0.8 20.3
1906-07 157 166 370 60 22 0.9 19.4
1907-08 157 193 351 70 23 1.0 25.6
1908-09 136 179 156 75 25 1.4 18.4
109-1910 166 172 297 59 34 1.0 19.3
1910-11 186 189 310 58 27 1.0 21.8
1911-12 202 201 410 56 24 0.9 25.4
1912-13 218 230 488 60 23 0.8 27.4
1913-14 221 264 346 69 21 0.8 29.7
Col.1: Index number of export value; Col.2: Index number of import value; Col.3: Index number of
net import of treasure; Col.4: Value of imports as percentages of exports; Col.5: Total invisible and
debt charges as percentages exports; Col.6: Home Charges as percentages of exports; Col.7: Value
of exports as percentage of estimated agricultural output in India.
Source: Y.S. Pandit, India's Balance of Indebtedness 1898-1913, Oxford, 1937; K,M. Mukherjee, Levels
of Economic Activity and Public Expenditure in India, Bombay, 1963, Table 3, Col. 6; Chaudhuri, K.N.,
‘India’s International Economy in the Nineteenth Century’, Modern Asian Studies, II, 1 (1968), pp. 31-50.
154 Source: Arun Banerji, Aspects of Indo-British Economic Relations, 1982, Table 37, p 203.
Banerji focuses on the transfer problem – the need for a sustained export surplus to meet Drain of Wealth Debate
remittance requirements over long periods of time. In India during 1858-1898 there was
the rigid compulsion to make transfers when the demand and price of exports was subject
to substantial fluctuations. He argues that if the annual transfers are large in relation to
public revenues, export values or national income and foreign capital is not available to
diminish the burden of transfer, the burden on the poor transfer or country becomes
onerous. [Banerji, 1982: 213-14]. As this was the case in India the transfer problem was
a serious issue. Banerji’s critique of a particular understanding of the drain is not a denial
of a drain since he later criticized both Bayly and Roy for not acknowledging it. [Arun
Banerji, 2005] However, in 2004 Bayly stated – citing Patrick O’Brien – that the transfer
of wealth from the non-European world contributed between 5% and 15% of the total
stock of capital for investment in Britain during the late 18th century. [Bayly, 2004: 174]
Sen argues that the values of the annual sales of Council Bills – after deducting import of
capital – are a credible measure of the financial transfers from India. During 1898-1908
an annual average of 19.8 million pounds was remitted abroad as unilateral transfer. This
amount exceeded the net export earnings from trade and treasure estimated at 17.3 million
pounds as annual average. The unilateral transfer during 1898-1908 constituted 2.3 percent
of India’s national income during this period. [Sen, 1992: 59]
Sen has also discovered a device ‘‘of accounting transfers’’ hidden in the budgetary
practices of the government in India. In 1867 a select committee of the British parliament
had recommended that ‘‘all capital expenditure on productive works supplied from revenue
should be treated in the accounts as if it had been borrowed, that a sum equal to that
which was thus supplied should be transferred from the ordinary debt to the productive 157
Colonial Economy public works debt, and that interest on that sum be charged on the works.’’ Sen has
italicised the word ‘as if it had been borrowed’ [Sen, 1992: 31]. As a result of this practice
the productive debt in India went up from 5.4 million to 159.3 million pounds between
1867 and 1897 and its proportion in the total debt went up from 6.4 per cent to 63.3 per
cent. Therefore, expenditure on servicing productive debt was for unproductive purposes.
The colonial government’s policy was designed to ‘‘camouflage the extent of public
borrowings to finance the politically sensitive and commercially unviable expenditures of
government.’’ [Sen, 1992: 32] Productive debt was ‘‘a surrogate for the amount spent
and borrowed in the past for unproductive purposes.’’ Revenue for financing public works
was used to subsidize unproductive expenditure and to retire unproductive debt. Therefore,
on this ground, the nationalist critique of the Home Charges and the drain from India is
justified.
During the colonial period, the resources of tropical countries were appropriated by the
metropolitan countries at the cost of local foodgrain production and absorption. [Patnaik
& Patnaik, 2017: 100]
It has been estimated that between 1922 and 1938 India had a current account deficit of
382 million pounds since its commodity export surplus was 827 million pounds when the
invisible liabilities were 1209 million pounds. This resulted in a financial gold outflow of
260 million pounds and an additional debt of 122 million pounds. Two-fifths of the gold
inflow into Britain during this period came from India. [Patnaik & Patnaik, 2021: 168]
Utsa and Prabhat Patnaik have argued that Britain derived immense advantages from its
control over the export earnings and finances of India. First, it strengthened the position of
the British pound sterling as the key global currency and a stable medium for holding
wealth. Neither commodities, gold nor any other major currency could undermine the
pound. Second, it led to the long boom of the nineteenth century and the diffusion of
industrial capitalism across the globe, but not the colonies. Third, it kept up the level of
aggregate demand for world capitalism, because of the possibility of triangular trade through
the colonies. [Patnaik & Patnaik, 2017: 126-127]
India had a huge export surplus with Europe and North America from the late 19th century
onwards. Over two-thirds of India’s export surplus came from these regions by the 1920s.
S.B. Saul had pointed out earlier how this export surplus helped Britain manage its balance
of payments difficulties – financing more than two-fifths of Britain’s total deficits
[Patnaik, 2019: 303]. Large capital exports to the USA in particular would not have been
possible without siphoning off the foreign exchange earnings of India. According to Utsa
Patnaik while the revenues of the central and state government doubled between 1900-01
and 1925 – from a hundred crore rupees to two hundred and ten crore rupees the export
surplus more than trebled. She writes, ‘‘A higher share of the budget went to ‘pay’ producers
for their export surplus out of their own taxes, making the income-deflating impact even
more severe.’’ [U. Patnaik, 2019: 306]
As Britain faced economic difficulties after the First World War it sought greater control
over India’s monetary policy. In order to facilitate British economic recovery based on an
expansionary world economy Britain wanted to regulate gold flows to India. According to
Balachandran it was easier to induce deflation in India to prevent the disruption of global
expansion than to urge the USA to promote such an expansion. [Balachandran, 1996:
226] Britain intensified efforts to eliminate any residual use of gold as money in the colony.
162 Keynes had observed that gold flows to India ‘‘were counter-cyclical to the world
economy.’’ Gold flows rose during booms and fell during a slump. British policy in the Drain of Wealth Debate
1920s generated deflationary expectations and reduced gold imports. In the 1930s it
strengthened deflationary trends to boost the outflow of gold. According to Balachandran,
‘‘Indian gold exports eased Britain’s external liquidity pressures and exerted an
expansionary influence on the world economy during the Depression’’ [Balachandran,
2016: 93]. Moreover, the British ensured that there was no default on payment of debt
which necessitated tax increases or cuts in expenditure. The countries that defaulted
during the depression performed better than those that did not. [Balachandran, 2016: 89]
9.6 SUMMARY
To, sum up, there is no doubt that there were considerable unilateral transfers to Britain
during the colonial period. Although the nationalists tended to regard the Home Charges
as the equivalent of the annual drain of wealth from India even the liberals have accepted
that some expenses arose because India was a colony of Britain. Secondly, there is broad
agreement that the Council Bills were used by the exchange banks to pay exporters. In
that sense there were no unrequited exports from India. However, the invisible charges
were high and the exchange banks, shipping and insurance companies earned monopoly
profits. The broader idea of the costs and benefits of colonialism requires empirical evidence
that is difficult to find. And it has to be based on counterfactuals that vary considerably.
Tirthankar Roy and G. Balachandran have different assessments of colonial monetary
policy partly because of differences in assumptions and counterfactuals. Michael Edelstein
has argued that if there had been no trade with the Empire the British GDP would have
declined by 1 to 3 per cent in 1870 and 1913 respectively. Patrick O'Brien has countered
that independent countries need not have withdrawn from trade with Britain. [Gardner
and Roy, 2020: 103]
Thirdly, the need for annual remittance in sterling to pay interest on public debt created a
pressure to maintain a high level of exports which diminished the bargaining power of the
exporters. The problem of the terms of trade between primary commodities and industrial
goods is a more general issue which arises with or without colonial rule. Fourthly, the
British control of India’s monetary policy and the holding of surplus export earnings in
sterling in London limited the sums available for investment in India. This also led to the
contraction of money supply in India and the adoption of pro-cyclical policies during the
period of depression. Fifthly, we have to look at the consequences of the drain for stagnation
and mass poverty in India. Utsa Patnaik has argued that India became poor because
Britain took away 45 trillion dollars from India between 1765 and 1938. Liberals like Roy
have argued that India remained poor because the state was unable to increase taxes for
investments or borrow at home or abroad to increase agricultural output and productivity.
If nearly a quarter to a third of the annual budget of the Indian government had not been
used to pay Indian exporters there would have been no need to raise more taxes or
borrow money for investment. Finally, even if there are disagreements about the estimates
there was a substantial drain of wealth from India. In varying proportions all countries
under colonial rule suffered because of a transfer of surplus to the metropolis.
9.7 GLOSSARY
Home Charges Expenditure incurred in England by the Secretary of
State on behalf of India
Internal Drain Transfer of incomes from peasants to traders and
middlemen
Moral Drain Drain in the form of British civil and military official’s
enormous salaries and pensions
Unrequited Exports/transfers for which there is no reverse flow
Exports/Transfers of goods or Transfers finance in payment; often done
to settle past debts.
163
Colonial Economy
9.8 EXERCISES
1) Discuss briefly nationalist’s ideas on drain of wealth.
2) Provide critique of nationalist’s ideas on drain of wealth.
3) What are leftists’ views on drain of wealth?
4) Critically examine recent arguments pertaining to drain of wealth.
164
Chung, Tan (1986), Triton and Dragon, Studies on Nineteenth Century China and Drain of Wealth Debate
Imperialism, Delhi: Gian Publishing House.
Dasgupta, Ajit K. (1993), A History of Indian Economic Thought, Routledge.
Drummond, I. (1974), Imperial Economic Policy, 1919-1939: Studies in Expansion
and Protection, London.
Esteban, Javier Cuenca (2001), ‘The British Balance of Payments, 1772-1820: India
Transfers and War Finance’, The Economic History Review, Feb., Vol. 54, No. 1 ,
pp. 58-86.
Gardner, Leigh and Tirthankar Roy (2020), The Economic History of Colonialism, Bristol
University Press.
Goldsmith, Raymond W. (1983), The Financial Development of India,1860-1977,
New Haven.
Gupta, P.S. (1987), ‘State and Business in India in the Age of Discriminating Protection’,
in Dwijendra Tripathi (ed), State and Business in India: A Historical Perspective,
Manohar, Delhi, pp. 157-216.
Habib, Irfan (1975),‘Colonialization of the Indian Economy, 1757-1900’, Social Scientist,
March, Vol. 3, No. 8, pp. 23-53.
Habib, Irfan (1985), ‘Studying a Colonial Economy without Perceiving Colonialism’,
Modern Asian Studies, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 355-381.
Harnetty, Peter (1972), Imperialism and Free Trade: Lancashire and India in the
Mid-Nineteenth Century, Vancouver.
Iyer, Vibha (2020), ‘Commodity Export Surplus, Council Bills and Sterling Debt’, Social
Scientist, March-June 2020, Vol. 48, No. 3/6 (562-565), pp. 55-66.
Maddison, Angus (1989), ‘Dutch Income in and from Indonesia, 1700-1938’, Modern
Asian Studies, 23,4, pp. 645-670.
Markovits, Claude (2017), ‘The Indian Economy and the British Empire in the Company
Period: Some additional reflections around an essay by David Washbrook’, Modern Asian
Studies, Vol. 51, No. 2, Special Issue: New Directions in Social and Economic History:
Essays in Honour of David Washbrook, March, pp. 375-398.
McLane, John (2003), ‘The Drain of Wealth and Indian Nationalism at the Turn of the
Century’, in G. Balachandran (ed), India and the World Economy, 1850-1950, Delhi.
Morison, Theodore (1911), The Economic Transition in India, London.
Mukherjee, Aditya (2022), ‘The Great Divergence: How Colonial India Made Modern
Britain’, in Aditya Mukherjee, Political Economy of Colonial and Post-Colonial India,
Delhi: Primus.
Naik, J. V. (2001) ‘Forerunners of Dadabhai Naoroji’s Drain Theory’, Economic and
Political Weekly, Nov. 24-30, Vol. 36, No. 46/47, pp. 4428-4432.
Patnaik, Utsa (1984), ‘Transfer of Tribute and the Balance of Payments in the CEHI’,
Social Scientist, No 12, December, pp 43-55.
Patnaik, Utsa (2000), ‘New Estimates of Eighteenth-Century British Trade and Their
Relation to Transfers from Tropical Colonies’, in K.N. Panikkar, Terence Byres, Utsa
Patnaik (ed), The Making of History: Essays presented to Irfan Habib, Delhi: Tulika,
pp. 359-402.
Patnaik, Utsa (2014), ‘India in the World Economy, 1900 to 1935: The Inter-War Depression
and Britain’s Demise as World Capitalist Leader’, Social Scientist, Vol. 42, No. 1/2
(January-February), pp. 13-35.
Patnaik, Utsa (2018), ‘Profit Inflation, Keynes and the Holocaust in Bengal, 1943-44’,
Economic & Political Weekly, October 20, vol. LIII, no 42, pp. 33-43.
165
Colonial Economy Patnaik, Utsa (2019), ‘Revisiting the ‘‘Drain’’, or Transfers from India to Britain in the
Context of the Global Diffusion of Capitalism’, in Shubhra Chakrabarti and Utsa Patnaik
(eds), Agrarian and Other Histories: Essays for Binay Bhushan Chaudhuri, New
Delhi.
Patnaik, Utsa (ed) (1990), Agrarian Relations and Accumulation: The Mode of
Production Debate in India, Delhi: OUP.
Patnaik, Utsa and Prabhat Patnaik (2017), A Theory of Imperialism, Columbia University
Press.
Patnaik, Utsa and Prabhat Patnaik (2021), Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History
and the Present, Monthly Review Press.
Rothermund, Dietmar (1992), India in the Great Depression, 1929-1939, Delhi.
Roy, Rama Dev (1987), ‘Some Aspects of the Economic Drain from India during the
British Rule’, Social Scientist, Mar., Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 39-47.
Roy, Tirthankar (2019a), How British Rule Changed India’s Economy: The Paradox
of the Raj, Palgrave Macmillan.
Roy, Tirthankar (2019b), ‘State Capacity and the Economic History of Colonial India’,
Australian Economic History Review, Vol. 59, No.1, March, pp. 80-102.
Roy, Tirthankar (2022), ‘Imperialism, Globalization, and Inequality: The Indian Story’, in
Joseph Inikori (ed), British Imperialism and Globalization, c. 1650-1960, Essays in
Honour of Patrick O’Brien, Boydell Press, pp. 241-262.
Roy, Tirthankar (2022), An Economic History of India, 1707-1857, Routledge, second
edition.
Roy, Tirthankar (2020), The Economic History of India, 1857-2010, fourth edition,
Oxford University Press, Delhi.
Sen, Sunanda (1992), Colonies and the Empire, India 1890-1914, Orient Longman.
Sullivan, Dylan and Jason Hickel (2023), ‘Capitalism and extreme poverty: A global analysis
of real wages, human height, and mortality since the long 16th century’, World
Development, 161, 106026.
Tomlinson, B.R. (1975), ‘India and the British Empire, 1880-1935’, Indian Economic
and Social History Review, October, vol. 12: 337-77.
Tomlinson, B.R. (2008), The Economy of Modern India, 1860-1970, III, 3, Cambridge,
1993, Cambridge online.
166
Colonial Economy
UNIT 10 COLONIAL ECONOMY AND ITS and Its Impact
IMPACT*
Structure
10.1 Introduction
10.2 Economic Consequences of the Advent of Colonialism
10.3 Deindustrialization and Industrialization
10.4 Agriculture: Taxation, Land Tenure and Stagnation
10.5 Tribute, Drain of Wealth and Colonial Transfers
10.6 Commercialization of Agriculture and Debt
10.7 Famines
10.8 Money and Finance
10.9 Literacy, Gender and Environment
10.10 Summary
10.11 Glossary
10.12 Exercises
10.13 Suggested Readings
10.1 INTRODUCTION
The debate about the economic impact of British Rule is as controversial today as it was
when Dadabhai Naoroji wrote Poverty and Un-British Rule in India and R.C. Dutt had
a famous dispute with Lord Curzon. While contemporary colonial scholars praised the
benevolent nature of empire the nationalists argued that India had been impoverished
because of British rule. In recent years liberal economists like Tirthankar Roy have criticized
the left-nationalist view of colonialism espoused by Irfan Habib and Amiya Bagchi. By
examining the impact of colonial rule on industry, agriculture, standard of living and different
strata of the population we can get a better idea of what British rule meant for India.
Unadjusted figures are raw census figures. The adjusted figures are calculations by the author.
Source for Tables a&b: Bagchi, Amiya Kumar, ‘De-industrialisation in Gangetic Bihar’, in
Amiya Kumar Bagchi, Essays in Honour of S.C. Sarkar, 1976, Table 4, p. 512.
Between 1794 and 1895, Amiya Bagchi showed that the gross material output of an
average inhabitant of Bengal and Bihar had declined by about 20 per cent. [Bagchi,
2021: 20] By the end of the 19th century Indian textile imports averaged more than
two billion yards a year and were valued at nearly 20 million pounds annually. India
absorbed more than 40% of the total cloth exports of Britain by the end of the century.
However, there were enormous regional variations. In Madras Presidency the number
of handlooms did not decline but rose over the course of the nineteenth century. The
weavers worked the looms for fewer hours and there was a shift towards coarse
cloth. The handlooms survived by adapting to local needs and preferences using
mercerized yarn and artificial silk, producing cotton sarees with silk borders,
handkerchiefs and angavastrams, and finding export markets in Sri Lanka and South
East Asia for the Madras lungis. What is more important, Specker linked the fortunes
of the weavers to fluctuations in the output and relative prices of raw cotton and cloth
as well as grain prices and cloth. [Specker, 1989] In Central India, according to
Harnetty, the handloom industry was able to retain about forty per cent of the domestic
market until the early years of the twentieth century. As the railways began to expand
their network in Rajasthan after the First World War handlooms there began to face
competition, albeit later than other regions. By this time, Indian mills had become
major players and they were competing with handlooms in Rajasthan.
Indrajit Ray argues that there is insufficient data to examine deindustrialization in
terms of inter-sectoral job transfers. He argues that it is easier to empirically examine
deindustrialization in terms of a decline in an industry not compensated by growth of
a modern sector in the same product. Twomey has estimated that employment fell by
300,000 between 1790 and 1830. On the other hand, Indrajit Ray has argued that the
decline in employment in the textile industry of Bengal took place after the mid-1820s
because of setbacks in both the overseas and domestic markets. Slow and steady
decline took place only thereafter. Employment declined by 65,000 in the 1820s, 144,000
in the 1830s, 160,000 in the 1840s and 192,000 in the 1950s. Ray has estimated that
563,000 workers in aggregate lost their jobs between 1810 and 1859. [Ray, 2011: 70]
He concludes that while at least one million gained employment in textiles in Bengal
during the eighteenth century only 563,000 lost jobs in the first half of the nineteenth
century. Although British discriminatory policies affected Bengal textile exports in
the period up to the 1820s the subsequent decline in textile production in Bengal was
due to the technological changes brought about in the nineteenth century.
169
Colonial Economy Table II
Change in Annual Employment Scenario in Bengal, 1815-1859
Year Silk Cotton Salt Ship- Indigo Total Change in
building Employment Employment
1795-9 88,775 179,905 88,020 928 460,080 817,7-8 -
1800-4 84,040 198,931 90,303 4,508 522,478 900,260 (+)82,552
1805-9 97,255 141,798 108,567 2,400 833,419 1,183,439 (+)238,179
1810-14 155,536 126,745 113,639 5,400 868,826 1,270,146 (+)86,707
1815-19 158,109 210,128 114,655 5,589 994,757 1,483,238 (+)213,092
1820-4 202,242 145,589 123,785 2,341 1,040,878 1,514,835 (+)31,597
1825-9 219,267 56,856 121,212 1,429 1,364,060 1,762,824 (+)247,189
1830-4 188,460 -21,616 149,887 1,074 1,230,295 1548,100 (-)565,803
1835-9 237,786 -53,573 93,947 1,626 1,146,199 1,425,985 (-)122,115
1840-4 232,730 -181,250 98,861 2,443 1,387,268 1,539,955 (+)113,970
1845-9 227,670 -221,108 90,504 0 1,054,268 1,151,334 (-)388,621
1850-4 211,227 -317,480 59,044 0 596,865 549,656 (-)601,678
1855-9 233,271 -468,213 57,289 0 526,861 349,208 (-)200,448
Source: Indrajit Ray, Bengal Industries and the British Industrial Revolution, 1757-1857,
2011, Table 8.1, p 252.
Ray has estimated that employment opportunities increased in salt manufacturing,
shipbuilding, indigo dye manufacturing, in raw and wrought silk, and in the export sector of
cotton textiles during the period 1757-1829. Additional employment opportunities came to
1.62 million in aggregate for the early nineteenth century. [Ray, 2011: 247] When Bengal
suffered heavy industrial decay during 1830-59 about 1.21 million industrial workers lost
their jobs. Of these, about 78 per cent represented jobs that had been created during
1795-1829 so that the net loss of employment opportunities comes to 0.27 million for the
period 1795-1859 as a whole. State discrimination led to the demise of salt manufacturing
and shipbuilding while market forces downsized cotton and silk textiles. Both market
forces and discriminatory policies affected deindustrialization. [Ray, 2011: 254]
Tirthankar Roy has highlighted that Indian handlooms began to grow by the early twentieth
century because they responded to challenges and opportunities. The less skilled weavers
declined but high skilled weavers like Momins and Padmasalis were able to survive by
innovating and adapting. There was growing concentration of weavers in towns where
they could avail of the services of specialist dyers and bargain with creditors and merchants
for better terms. The weavers adopted imported yarns, gradually adopted technological
innovations like the fly shuttle and eventually the powerlooms. The handlooms had nearly
one third of the domestic market in textiles by the 1930s in terms of market share. In
terms of the total market value, it was even higher because handlooms had diversified into
higher value products. [Roy, 1993] Also, market forces and technological and organizational
changes affected traditional industries like leather as tanneries emerged and local leather
workers and collectors of hides declined. The railways and imported brass sheets led to
the rise of the brassware industry. [Roy, 1999]
The traditional industries of India declined in the period 1820-1880 in most parts of the
country in varying degrees, but particularly between 1850 and 1880. What is important to
note is that the nationalist critique of British colonial policies was not just – or so much –
that the traditional industries had declined but that there was no compensatory development
of modern industries in India like in Britain. While modern industry emerged in the late
19th century the progress was limited. There are several criticisms. First, that the
development of a vast railway network in India was done in the interests of Britain.
Investors in the railways were guaranteed five per cent on capital regardless of
performance. The network lines were laid and freight rates determined in order to facilitate
manufactured imports into India and to promote agricultural exports. Secondly, railway
wagons and locomotives were imported from Britain and there was no encouragement of
an iron and steel industry in India. Thirdly, a policy of free trade was followed. Tariff
protection would have helped Indian cotton mills compete against Lancashire. India was
170
not able to protect its infant industries ? a strategy that was adopted by late industrializing Colonial Economy
countries like Germany and the USA. Finally, there was neglect of investment in irrigation and Its Impact
that would have increased agricultural output and the purchasing power of the people. As
Rajat Ray has argued had India been independent industrialization would have begun by
the early years of the twentieth century and the pace of industrialization would have been
much higher.
The initial rise of modern industries like cotton and jute in the late 19th century was followed
by the growth of iron and steel, sugar, paper and cement in the post-World War I period
after the introduction of tariff protection. This has been hailed as a positive development
and evidence of change in the nature of colonialism. [Dewey, 1978] Aditya Mukherjee
has argued strongly that these trends were not the result of colonialism but a break with it.
[Mukherjee, 2008: 25] Import substitution industrialization after the 1920s was led by
indigenous capitalists. Britain’s staple industries became less competitive after the First
World War and there was a decline in the volume of world trade and the export of capital.
Industries in India grew during the Depression years while those in the developed capitalist
countries were affected by lack of demand. As there was a huge decline in the demand
and price of agricultural commodities considerable merchant capital deployed in the
movement of agricultural commodities in India moved into industries like sugar and paper
during the 1930s. However, as Bagchi had argued in Private Investment in India the
growth of industries in the interwar period was affected by a demand constraint. As the
entire period of the 1930s was marked by the depression it was not possible to expand the
railway network, invest in irrigation or in heavy industry like steel because of weak demand.
Tomlinson has argued that even European capitalists in India had considered setting up of
a second steel plant to rival that of the Tatas but were deterred by the absence of demand
for steel.
Sources: India, Statistical Abstract Relating to British India (London: HMSC and Calcutta
Government Press, various years); Tirthankar Roy, The Economic History of India,
1857-2010, Fourth Edition, 2020, Table 3.12, p. 83.
Tirthankar Roy acknowledges that per capita food availability declined in the 20th century.
For him this was the outcome of limited taxation, low investment by the state, poor
rainfall, inadequate irrigation and ‘‘water famines.’’ [Roy, 2021, 2022] Irrigation was
confined to areas in Punjab, UP and Madras and private investment in wells was
inadequate. Commercialization of agriculture was limited despite enormous growth in
agricultural exports between 1860 and 1914 as monsoon dependent areas did not
contribute much to agricultural exports. Non-food crops were less than 15 per cent of
net area sown at their peak. In 1914, the agricultural export to agricultural
value-added ratio was about 14 per cent – excluding tea export – and the agricultural
export to agricultural production ratio was about 7-10 per cent. [Chaudhary, Gupta,
Roy & Swamy, 2016f: 108] Even in 1936 only twenty per cent of the cultivated area
was irrigated.
173
Colonial Economy Table VI
Agriculture Acreage Summary
Total Area Net Per net area sown (%)
Acres area Food Rice Wheat Oilseeds Non food Cotton
sown grains total
(as %) total
British India
1895 539093648 36.5 92.4 35.2 11.6 7.1 91.1 4.9
British India
1904 554234736 37.6 89.7 33.4 11.3 7.0 10.2 5.7
British India
1913 618927145 36.2 89.8 35.1 10.6 6.7 11.3 6.3
British India
1920 667361372 34.1 87.9 35.1 11.0 6.9 13.4 6.9
British India
1936(1936-7) 625149442 35.6 89.6 35.3 10.6 5.6 12.8 6.9
Madras 80104239 39.6 81.8 31.2 0.0 16.5 10.9 7.8
Bombay 48721608 57.8 70.8 6.5 5.9 7.6 23.3 13.2
Bengal 49254596 49.7 97.0 89.9 0.6 4.5 10.9 0.2
UP 67848920 53.3 105.4 18.7 21.1 2.8 7.0 1.9
Punjab 61001600 45.7 80.2 3.7 33.7 4.1 28.8 10.4
Bihar 44324194 44.9 101.4 50.0 5.7 7.7 2.0 0.2
CP & Berar 63004800 39.0 82.7 23.1 12.8 9.4 18.8 16.1
Assam 35484800 18.6 85.9 82.3 0.0 6.5 3.1 0.5
Sind 30027932 15.7 84.2 25.1 19.8 4.3 21.8 19.0
Orissa 20594776 31.5 95.2 79.4 0.1 4.8 1.2 0.1
Source: Latika Chaudhary et al. in Latika Chaudhary, Bishnupriya Gupta, Tirthankar Roy and Anand
V. Swamy (eds), A New Economic History of Colonial India, Routledge 2016, Table 7.1, p. 104.
Less than 5 per cent of the total budget was allocated for irrigation although it increased
yields significantly.
Expenditure on railways decreased from 23 per cent in 1894 to 15 per cent in 1935 but
investment in irrigation did not increase. More than 85 per cent of expenditure on productive
works was devoted to railways between 1894 and 1919. The colonial state did not increase
investment in irrigation and agriculture because railway expansion directly helped British
investors and manufacturers but irrigation did not. Most scholars agree that levels of both
public and private investment in India were low.
Table VII
Estimates of Investment, 1901-46
Tirthankar Roy, The Economic History of India, 1857-2010, Fourth Edition, 2020,
Table 3.14, p. 87.
174
What the authors of A New Economic History of Colonial India argue is that the Colonial Economy
colonial state was ‘‘conservative’’ and that it taxed little and spent little. This is asserted and Its Impact
even more emphatically by Tirthankar Roy [2019 a] in How British Rule Changed India’s
Economy. (For details see Table VI, Unit 9 of the present Theme.)
Also, there were ecological and technological constraints which limited irrigation expansion
during the colonial period. Elizabeth Whitcombe pointed out some of the negative
consequences of irrigation but Ian Stone found it led to higher growth rates. Rohan D’Souza
has highlighted the difficulty in controlling the flow of the Mahanadi river in Orissa.
[D’Souza, 2006] After independence, however, the investment in irrigation rose significantly
and produced positive results.
10.7 FAMINES
The average life expectancy in India which was 25 years for 1821-1871, fell to about 20
in 1871-1921 due to the unusual level of famine and influenza deaths, rising to about 35 in
1951[ Roy, 2019a: 3] About thirty to forty million people died during famines in the second
half of the 19th century India. [Sheldon, 2009: 74] Estimates of Sullivan and Hinkel are
even higher. People died not only because of lack of food but due to malaria, cholera or
malnutrition. As the state was more interested in grain exports than in the food requirements
of the people it resulted in mass starvation. Little relief was provided and the railways did
not mitigate the effects of food shortages until the early years of the twentieth century.
As regards the famine of 1876-78 land revenue rates and the process of their revision
before and after the famine ‘‘created an economic shock at a time of extreme vulnerability’’.
[Hall-Mathews, 2005: 214] Although the Famine Commission blamed the Marwaris,‘‘their
exploitation itself was so symbiotic with the revenue system that there is no logic in
attacking one and not the other.’’ Also, individual and local agency was very important.
Temple, who had controlled mortality in Bihar in 1874 by spending six million pounds, only
spent about 1.59 million pounds in Bombay later. [Hall-Mathews, 2005: 177] A uniform
famine policy replaced ‘‘local autonomy with paradigms designed to justify suffering.’’
The 1901 famine in Bombay Presidency saw worse mortality and disruption than
1876-78, despite considerable improvements in organizational efficiency.
The major famines of 1896-97 and 1899-1900 also caused a fodder famine and nearly a
third to a half of the cattle perished in the famine affected regions. The loss of cattle
reduced productivity and income due to the loss of manure and decline in availability of
butter, milk and ghee. There was also a shift to less labour-intensive subsistence crops
like jowar instead of wheat which required several ploughings. Pre-famine level productivity
levels became harder to attain. [Mishra, 2013] Vinita Damodaran has pointed out that
there was also the erosion of traditional means of sustenance and customary patterns of
life that made millions vulnerable to famines. Traditional relationships regarding irrigation
and water-harvesting in south Bihar declined because local zamindars refused to clean
canals and ponds and maintain traditional irrigation systems over the course of the nineteenth 177
Colonial Economy century owing to the decline in their incomes.Agrarian distress, droughts and famines led
to the migration of people to urban industrial centres like Bombay and Calcutta. About 1.5
million people migrated as indentured labour to work on plantations and farms in far flung
areas after the 1830s after slavery was legally banned. [Tinker, 1974; Sen, 1992] An
estimated 29 million people left India for Southeast Asia and lands around the Indian
Ocean and South Pacific between c. 1840 and 1930. [Balachandran, 2016d: 96]
Latika Chaudhary, ‘Caste, Colonialism and Schooling: Education in British India’, in Latika
Chaudhary, Bishnupriya Gupta, Tirthankar Roy and Anand V. Swamy (eds), A New Economic
History of Colonial India, Routledge, 2016, Table 10.1, p 165.
The position of women declined during the colonial period because of a decline in mortality.
Early marriage prevented many women from ‘‘taking up the new wage-earning
opportunities that appeared in towns and cities far away from home. Growing family size
made their economic value smaller and lives at home harder than before.’’ [Roy, 2019a:
112] Fewer women went to school whether at the beginning of the period or at the end.
Between 1881 and 1951, work-participation rate fell from 43% of the population to 39. 179
Colonial Economy The male participation rate fell from 63 to 54%, and women’s participation fell from 31 to
23%. [Roy, 2019a: 124] However, women were well represented in the formal sector
despite the prohibitions of the Factory Acts and restrictions on women working in
underground coal mines. According to Samita Sen women constituted 15-20 per cent of
the workforce in textile mills and a half or more of the workforce in mines and plantations
in the early 1920s.Their numbers began to decline in the 1930s. [Sen, 2008: 95] A process
of excluding women from the modern industrial workforce which began after the 1920s
continued for decades even after independence. [Sen, 2008: 103]
Scholars like Ramchandra Guha and Mahesh Rangarajan have emphasized how the
revenue-maximizing and forest policies of the state led to commercial forestry, decline in
diversity of forest trees, restrictions on the use of forest resources by local communities
and tribes and erosion of customary rights. Pallavi Das has collected data about the rising
demand for wood to make sleepers for the railways averaging 1800 to 2000 sleepers per
mile. It was more economical for the Madras Railway to use locally procured firewood
rather than imported coal. [Das, 2015: 74] Deforestation reduced access to nuts, berries,
firewood, medicinal plants, small game and timber for local communities and aroused
resentment and protests and even arson and rebellion. Over the course of the 19th century
forests were cut to meet the needs of the iron smelters and sugar boilers in Tamilnad
there by reducing the resources available for self-provisioning. [Parthasarathy in Inikori,
2022]. Dalits, Paraiyars specifically, kept goats and sheep and even on occasion cattle
and horses. Any changes restricting the rights of labourers to own animals increased their
vulnerability to poor harvests or bad years. During the Madras famine of 1876 to 1878 a
British official observed that the labouring classes of South India ate fish, snails, frogs,
field-rats, game of every description, fowls, goats, sheep, bullocks and pigs. The bulk of
these animals were likely to have been obtained or maintained through self-provisioning.
Kathleen Morrison has argued that deforestation near Vijaynagar was higher in the early
sixteenth century than in the colonial period. In northern Karnataka Vodda construction
workers were often compelled to work without payment and sacrifices for pre-colonial
reservoirs had to be borne disproportionately by women and depressed caste men. Despite
regional variations it is clear that the process of resource extraction, extension of the
arable and utilization of forest resources intensified during the colonial period. It led to
what Neeladri Bhattacharya has called villagization or more broadly an agrarian conquest
in Punjab. Over time it resulted in sedentarization of the population as pastoralists were
encouraged or compelled to became cultivators. Ajay Skaria has observed the decline in
the status of tribal groups in the Dangs region adjoining Baroda in Gujarat and Benoy
Chaudhuri has noted the reduction of tribals to landless labourers or tenants in North
Bengal.
10.10 SUMMARY
Colonial and liberal economists have a more positive assessment of the economic impact
of colonialism. Goldsmith has argued that countries that remained independent like Turkey
or Ethiopia did not experience much growth. Recent assessments of the railways in India
have argued that they reduced the cost per ton mile, were the largest employer in the
modern sector, achieved productivity increases, reduced the grain price dispersion by at
least twenty per cent between 1860 and 1920 [Andrabi & Kuehlwein, 2010] and increased
real agricultural income by approximately 16 per cent when the railroad network was
extended to the average district. [Donaldson, 2018; Bogart & Chaudhary, 2016e] The
cost benefit analysis done by Davis and Huttenback and Patrick O’Brien focuses on the
rate of return on investments in the colonies. These studies do not assess the use of
colonial export surpluses for Britain’s balance of payments, the advantages of cheap food
and raw materials and transfer of surplus or the benefits of controlling India’s monetary
policy. The Dutch cultivation system of the mid-19th century which forced villagers to
produce sugar and coffee yielded around a third of Dutch – not Javanese-government
revenue. [Gardner & Roy, 2020: 122] The farmers of West Africa got a higher proportion
180 of export revenues than those in settler or plantation economies but they still had to deal
with unequal exchange when marketing their produce. [Austin, 2022: 160-161] Although Colonial Economy
there was an increase in per capita income and the heights of Ghanains rose during the and Its Impact
colonial period the relatively low tax and low expenditure pattern of tropical Africa restricted
possibilities for growth.
There is no doubt that colonialism had a retardative influence on the Indian economy.
That there was a drain of wealth from India, that India could not support domestic industries,
that the country could not default on debts unlike sovereign countries, that it could not
develop a modern banking system are important markers of its subordination and
exploitation. There were constraints imposed by climate and geography given the technology
of the colonial period but low public investment is a major factor for low growth
acknowledged even by liberal economists. The strongest indictment of colonialism is that
it systematically drained India of its resources, distorted India’s growth to make it a valuable
appendage of Britain, neglected investment in India, imposed deflationary policies,
particularly during the depression years and kept India in poverty at a time when the
developed countries were growing rapidly.
10.11 GLOSSARY
Home Charges Expenditure incurred in England by the Secretary of State on
behalf of India.
Unrequited Exports/transfers for which there is no reverse flow ofgoods
Exports/Transfers or finance in payment; often done to settle past debts.
10.12 EXERCISES
1) Assess impact of colonial rule on Indian economy.
2) In what ways did the colonial policies led to the destruction of traditional Indian
industries?
3) Do you agree that colonial policy hindered the growth of modern industries in India?
4) Discuss the recent debates pertaining to impact of colonial rule in India.
5) ‘Western Europe was more advance than India even before the industrial revolution’
and ‘Indian manufactures started showing signs of decline much before the inflow of
manufactured goods into the country’. Comment.
6) Discuss the impact of colonial rule on Indian textile industry.
7) Discuss briefly deindustrialization of Indian industries during the colonial period.
8) ‘Colonial policies hindered the growth of Indian agriculture.’ Comment.
9) In what ways did the revenue settlements were oppressive in nature?
10) ‘Drain of wealth was a small price paid for an efficient civil service and peace
maintained by the British.’ Comment.
11) In what ways did commercialization of agriculture enhanced debt burden?
12) Colonial policies before and after famines created ‘economic shock’. Examine.
13) In what ways did free trade imperialism hindered Indian industrial interests?
14) In what ways did the colonial rule impacted literacy and gender employability?
182 Chaudhary, Latika (2016b), ‘Caste, Colonialism and Schooling: Education in British India’,
in Latika Chaudhary, Bishnupriya Gupta, Tirthankar Roy and Anand V. Swamy (eds), A Colonial Economy
New Economic History of Colonial India, Routledge. and Its Impact
Chaudhuri, Benoy Bhushan (1984), ‘Rural Power Structure and Agricultural Productivity
in Eastern India, 1757-1947’, in Desai, Rudolph and Rudra, (ed), Agrarian Power and
Agricultural Productivity in South Asia, Delhi.
Chaudhuri, K.N. (1968), ‘India’s International Economy in the Nineteenth Century: A
Historical Survey’, Modern Asian Studies, II, 1, 1968.
D’Souza, Rohan (2006), Drowned and Dammed: Colonial Capitalism and Flood
Control in Eastern India, Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Damodaran, Vinita (2015), ‘The East India Company, Famine and Ecological Conditions
in Eighteenth-Century Bengal’, in Vinita Damodaran, Anna Winterbottom & Alan Lester
(eds.), The East India Company and the Natural World, Palgrave Macmillan.
Das, Pallavi (2015), Colonialism, Development, and the Environment: Railways and
Deforestation in British India, 1860-1884, Palgrave Macmillan.
Datta, Rajat (2000), Society, Economy and the Market: Commercialization in Rural
Bengal c.1760-1800, Delhi: Manohar.
Datta, Rajat (2019), ‘Before the great divergence: the early modern South Asian agrarian
economy in a global perspective’, in Sanjay Kumar, Satya P. Mohanty, Archana Kumar
and Raj Kumar (eds), China, India and Alternative Asian Modernities, Routledge.
Davis L.E. and R.A. Huttenback (1986), Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The
Political Economy of British Imperialism, 1860-1912, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Dewey, Clive (1978), ‘The End of Imperialism of Free Trade: The Eclipse of the Lancashire
Lobby and the Commission of Fiscal Autonomy to India’, in Clive Dewey and A.G. Hopkins,
(eds.), Imperial Impact: Studies in the Economic History of Africa and India, London.
Donaldson, Dave (2018), ‘Railroads of the Raj’, The American Economic Review, April,
Vol. 108, Nos. 4-5, pp.899-934.
Gadgil, Madhav and Ramchandra Guha (1992), This Fissured Land: An Ecological
History of India, Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Gardner, Leigh and Tirthankar Roy, (2020), The Economic History of Colonialism, Bristol
University Press.
Ghosh, Shami (2014), ‘The ‘‘Great Divergence’’, Politics, and Capitalism’, Journal of
Early Modern History, pp. 1-43.
Guha, Ranajit (1982), Elementary Aspects of Peasant Insurgency in Colonial India,
Delhi.
Guha, Sumit (ed) (1992), Growth, Stagnation or Decline?: Agricultural Productivity
in British India, Delhi.
Gupta, Bishnupriya (2016d), ‘The Rise of Modern Industry in Colonial India’, in Latika
Chaudhary, Bishnupriya Gupta, Tirthankar Roy and Anand V. Swamy (eds), A New
Economic History of Colonial India, Routledge.
Habib, Irfan (1995), ‘Colonialisation of the Indian Economy, 1757-1900’, in Essays in
Indian History: Towards a Marxist Perspective, New Delhi, 1995.
Hall-Matthews, David (2005), Peasants, Famine and the State in Colonial Western
India, Palgrave Macmillan.
Haruka, Yanagisawa (1993), ‘The Handloom Industry and its Market Structure: The Case
of Madras Presidency in the First Half of the Twentieth Century’, IESHR, 30,1, 1993.
Ian Stone (1984), Canal Irrigation in British India: Perspectives on Technological
Change in a Peasant Economy, Cambridge.
183
Colonial Economy Kling, Blair (1966), The Blue Mutiny: The Indigo Disturbances in Bengal,
1859-1862, Pennsylvania University Press 1966.
Krishnamurty, J. (1985), ‘De-industrialization in Gangetic Bihar: Another Look at the
Evidence’, IESHR, 22, 4.
Kumar, Dharma (ed.) (1983), The Cambridge Economic History of India, Vol. II,
c.1757-c.1970, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mann, Michael (1998), ‘Ecological Change in North India: Deforestation and Agrarian
Distress in the Ganga-Yamuna Doab, 1800-1850,’ in Grove, Damodaran and Sangwan
(eds), Nature and the Orient, Delhi.
Marika, Vicziany (1979), ‘The De-industrialization of India in the Nineteenth Century: A
Methodological Critique of Amiya Kumar Bagchi’, IESHR, 16, 2.
Mishra, Saurabh (2013), ‘Cattle, Dearth, and the Colonial State: Famines and Livestock in
Colonial India, 1896-1900’, Journal of Social History, Summer, Vol. 46, No. 4,
pp. 989-1012.
Morris D, Morris (1968), ‘Towards a Reinterpretation of Nineteenth Century Indian
Economic History’, IESHR, 5,1.
Morrison, Kathleen (2014), ‘Conceiving Ecology and Stopping the Clock: Narratives of
Balance, Loss, and Degradation’, in Mahesh Rangarajan and K. Sivaramakrishnan (eds),
People, Animals, and Mobility in India’s Environmental History, Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Morrison, Kathleen D. (2010), ‘Dharmic Projects, Imperial Reservoirs, and New Temples
of India: An Historical Perspective on Dams in India’, Conservation and Society,
8(3): 182-195.
Mukherjee, Aditya (2002), Imperialism, Nationalism and the Making of the Indian
Capitalist Class, 1920-1947, Delhi.
Mukherjee, Aditya (2008), ‘The Return of the Colonial in Indian Economic History: The
Last Phase of Colonialism in India’, Social Scientist, Vol. 36, No. 3/4 Mach-April,
pp. 3-44.
Mukherjee, Aditya (2022), ‘The Great Divergence: How Colonial India Made Modern
Britain’, in Aditya Mukherjee, Political Economy of Colonial and Post-Colonial India,
Delhi: Primus Books.
Mukherjee, Mridula (2005), Colonializing Agriculture: The Myth of Punjab
Exceptionalism, New Delhi: Sage.
Nadri, Ghulam (2016), The Political Economy of Indigo in India, 1580-1930: A Global
Perspective, Leiden: Brill.
Neal, Larry and Jeffrey Williamson (eds) (2014), The Cambridge History of Capitalism,
Volume II, The Spread of Capitalism: From 1848 to the Present, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Neeladri Bhattacharya, ‘Pastoralists in a Colonial World,’ in Arnold and Guha (eds), Nature,
Culture, Imperialism, Delhi 1995.
O’Brien, P.K. (1988), ‘The Costs and Benefits of British Imperialism, 1846-1914’, Past
and Present, No 120, August, pp. 163-200.
Parthasarathi, Prasannan (2011), Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not: Global
Economic Divergence, 1600-1850, Cambridge University Press.
Prasannan Parthasarathi (2022), ‘Labor and Environment in Nineteenth-Century Tamilnad,
India’, in Joseph E Inikori (ed), British Imperialism and Globalization, c. 1650-1960:
Essays in Honour of Patrick O’Brien, The Boydell Press.
Patnaik, Utsa (2014), ‘India in the World Economy 1900 to 1935: The Inter-War Depression
and Britain’s Demise as World Capitalist Leader’, Social Scientist, Vol. 42, No. 1/2
184 January-February, pp. 13-35.
Patnaik, Utsa (2018), ‘Profit Inflation, Keynes and the Holocaust in Bengal, 1943-44’, Colonial Economy
Economic & Political Weekly, October 20, Vol. LIII, no. 42, pp 33-43. and Its Impact
Patnaik, Utsa (2019), ‘Revisiting the ‘‘Drain’’, or Transfers from India to Britain in the
Context of the Global Diffusion of Capitalism’, in Shubhra Chakrabarti and Utsa Patnaik
(eds), Agrarian and Other Histories: Essays for Binay Bhushan Chaudhuri, New
Delhi.
Patnaik, Utsa and Prabhat Patnaik (2021), Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History
and the Present, Monthly Review Press.
Raj, K.N. et al (eds) (1985, Essays on the Commercialization of Indian Agriculture,
Delhi.
Rangarajan, Mahesh (ed) (2007), Environmental Issues in India: A Reader, Pearson
Delhi.
Ray, Indrajit (2011), Bengal Industries and the British Industrial Revolution,
1757-1857, London: Routledge.
Ray, Rajat (1979), Industrialization in India, Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Ray, Rajat (ed) (1992), Entrepreneurship and Industry in India, 1800-1947, Delhi.
Raychaudhuri, Tapan, (1968), ‘A Re-interpretation of Nineteenth Century Indian Economic
History?’, IESHR, 5,1.
Rothermund, D. (1992), India in the Great Depression, 1929-39, Delhi: Manohar.
Roy, Tirthankar (1993), An Economic History of India, 1707-1857, Routledge, second
edition.
Roy, Tirthankar (2021), ‘Water, Climate, and Economy in India from 1880 to the Present’,
Journal of Interdisciplinary History, Volume 51, Number 4, Spring, pp. 565-594.
Roy, Tirthankar (2022), Monsoon Economies: India's History in a Changing Climate,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Roy, Tirthankar (1993), Artisans and Industrialization. Indian Weaving in the Twentieth
Century, Delhi.
Roy, Tirthankar (1999), Traditional Industry in the Economy of Colonial India,
Cambridge.
Roy, Tirthankar (2010), The Crafts and Capitalism: Handloom Weaving Industry in
Colonial India, Routledge.
Roy, Tirthankar (2014), ‘Capitalism in India in the very long run’, in Larry Neal & Jeffrey
Williamson (eds), The Cambridge History of Capitalism, Volume I, The Rise of
Capitalism: From Ancient Origins to 1848, Cambridge.
Roy, Tirthankar (2019a), How British Rule Changed India’s Economy: The Paradox
of the Raj, Palgrave Macmillan.
Roy, Tirthankar (2019b), ‘State Capacity and the Economic History of Colonial India’,
Australian Economic History Review, Vol. 59, No.1, March, pp. 80-102.
Roy, Tirthankar (2020), The Economic History of India, 1857-2010, Fourth Edition,
Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Roy, Tirthankar (2022), ‘Imperialism, Globalization, and Inequality: The Indian Story’, in
Joseph E Inikori (ed) British Imperialism and Globalization, c. 1650-1960: Essays in
Honour of Patrick O’Brien, The Boydell Press.
Roy, Tirthankar (ed.) (1996), Cloth and Commerce: Textiles in Colonial India, New
Delhi.
Roy, Tirthankar and Anand V. Swamy (2016), Law and the Economy in Colonial India,
University of Chicago Press.
185
Colonial Economy Sen, Samita (2008), ‘Gender and Class: Women in Indian Industry, 1890-1990’, Modern
Asian Studies, Vol. 42, No. 1, Indian Labour (January), pp. 75-116.
Sen, Sunanda (1992), Colonies and the Empire, India 1890-1914, Calcutta.
Sen, Sunanda (2016),‘Indentured Labour from India in the Age of Empire’, Social
Scientist, January-February, Vol. 44, Nos. 1/2, pp. 35-74.
Sheldon, Richard (2009), ‘Development, Poverty & Famines: The Case of British Empire’,
in Mark Duffield & Vernon Hewitt (eds), Empire, Development& Colonialism: The
Past in the Present, New York: James Currey.
Skaria, Ajay (1999), Hybrid Histories: Forests, Frontiers and Wildness in Western
India, Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Specker, Konrad (1989), ‘Madras Handlooms in the Nineteenth Century’, IESHR, 26, 2,
1989.
Stokes, Eric (1986), The Peasant Armed: The Indian Rebellion of 1857, Oxford.
Sullivan, Dylan and Jason Hickel, (2023), ‘Capitalism and Extreme Poverty: A Global
Analysis of Real Wages, Human Height, and Mortality Since the Long 16th Century’,
World Development, 161, 106026.
Swamy, Anand (2011), ‘Land and Law in Colonial India’, in Debin Ma and Jan Luiten van
Zanden (eds.), Long-term Economic Change in Eurasian Perspective, Stanford
University Press, pp. 138 -157.
Thorner, Daniel and Thorner, Alice (1962),‘ ‘‘De-industrialization’’ in India, 1881-1931,’ in
Land and Labour in India, Bombay.
Tinker, Hugh (1974), A New System of Slavery: The Export of Indian Labour Overseas,
1830-1920, London: Oxford University Press.
Tomlinson, B.R. (1978), ‘Foreign Private Investment in India, 1920-1950’, Modern Asian
Studies, Vol. XI.
Tomlinson, B.R. (1981), ‘Colonial Firms and the Decline of Colonialism in Eastern India,
1914-1947’, Modern Asian Studies, Vol. XV.
Twomey, M.J. (1983), ‘Employment in Nineteenth Century Indian Textiles’, Explorations
in Economic History, 20, 3.
Washbrook, David (2020),‘The Cambridge History of Capitalism’, in Kaveh Yazdani and
Dilip M. Menon (eds), Capitalisms: Towards a Global History, Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Whitcombe, Elizabeth (1971), Agrarian Conditions in Northern India, Vol. 1: United
Provinces under British Rule, 1860-1900, University of California Press.
Williamson, Jeffrey G. (2011), Trade and Poverty: When the Third World Fell Behind,
Cambridge: MIT Press.
Wilson, Jon E. (2005), ‘‘‘A Thousand Countries to Go to’’: Peasants and Rulers in Late
Eighteenth-Century Bengal’, Past & Present, No. 189, November, pp. 81-109.
Yazdani, Kaveh and Dilip Menon (eds) (2020), Capitalisms: Towards a Global History,
Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Yazdani, Kaveh (2017), India, Modernity and the Great Divergence: Mysore and
Gujarat (17th-19th Centuries), Leiden: E.J. Brill.
186
Famines and Epidemics
UNIT 11 FAMINES AND EPIDEMICS*
Structure
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Famines
11.2.1 Famines: Causation and Culpability
11.2.2 Impact of the Colonial Political Economy
11.2.3 Reports, Commissions and Relief Measures
11.2.4 Outcome and Analysis: Crime, Altruism and Moral Economy of a Famine
11.3 The Scourge of Epidemics
11.3.1 Malaria, Cholera, Plague and Social Malaise
11.3.2 The Epidemic Diseases Act, 1897
11.4 Famines, Epidemics and Colonial Policies
11.5 Summary
11.6 Glossary
11.7 Exercises
11.8 Suggested Readings
11.9 Instructional Video Recommendations
11.1 INTRODUCTION
The history of disease, epidemics, famine and scarcity has been linked to natural and
human causation. There are very few countries in the world which may actually claim to
have escaped the vagaries of nature or the trail of misery left behind by famines and
epidemics. The political economy also plays a crucial role in determining the response in
such a situation. This Unit will look at the intertwined nature of famines and epidemics,
explore the idea whether famines were caused by dearth of resources or was it a matter
of uneven or skewed distribution of the same. Failure of rains and consequently of crops
was not a new phenomenon and occurred in India in the ancient period as well. There are
hymnal references found in Rig Veda to invoke rain in order to prevent drought from
damaging the crops and produce. In medieval times, the rulers made several provisions
for the affected subjects to deal with the effects of the famine. So the question arises
whether the policies formulated during the colonial period differed in any fundamental
way from the interventions made by the erstwhile rulers? The role played by the British
imperial state in preventing, salvaging or at times perpetuating the situation will be the
subject matter of this Unit.
After reading the Unit, you will be able to understand the co-relation between colonial
political economy and famine; know about the role of the state in perpetuating or preventing
famines; learn about famine commission, reports, codes and relief measures; and understand
the link between famine and epidemics.
11.2 FAMINES
The word ‘famine’ is derived from the Latin word ‘fames’ which implies hunger or a
condition of ‘extreme general scarcity of food’ resulting in excess mortality from starvation
or hunger induced illness. The etymology and meaning of words signifying famine vary by
language. In Italian the word for famine, carestia, is derived from caritas, and signifies
dearness. This alludes to the intensity of a famine. If the price of basic foodstuffs increases
for a prolonged period, then it’s a serious famine. In German, hungersnot connotes hunger
associated with a general scarcity of food. The most common terms for famine in the Irish
language are gorta (starvation) referring to the infamous 1840s drochshaol (the bad
times). In pharaonic Egypt, the standard word for famine (hkr) was derived from ‘‘being
hungry’’ (Srivastava, 2014: 1; Grada, 2009: 4-5).
* Dr. Rachna Mehra, School of Global Affairs, Dr. B.R. Ambedkar University, Delhi 187
Colonial Economy 11.2.1 Famines: Causation and Culpability
According to Morris D Morris, there is no one way to ‘formulate a definition that would be
adequate for all policy purposes’. Famines are also associated with droughts but it is
neither a direct nor an inevitable consequence of drought even though these words are
synonymously used in administrative practice (Morris, 1974:1855). Sanjay Sharma affirms
that in the earlier accounts of colonial state in India terms like ‘drought', ‘scarcity’, ‘distress’,
‘dearth’ and ‘famine’ were used interchangeably but over a period of time ‘their meanings
became more specific and the state evolved a set of criteria’ to ‘comprehend and classify
a situation as a ‘scarcity’ or a ‘famine’ (Sharma, 2001: 6). The causation of famine may
be attributed to natural phenomena like acute shortage of rainfall, attack by pests, etc. or
political and economic factors like wars, economic depression and government policies
resulting in heavy taxation, financial crisis etc.
The famines occurred at frequent intervals in the Indian subcontinent but the policies
implemented to deal with it differed under each political regime. Many texts belonging to
ancient period including Vedas and Jatakas allude to famines occurring during those times.
A severe famine was reported in Bihar in 298 BCE under the reign of Chandra Gupta
Maurya which lasted for 12 years and Kalhan’s Rajatarangini also mentions about a terrible
famine that occurred in Kashmir. One of the most important accounts of dealing with such a
calamity comes from Kautilya’s Arthashastra, a treatise on statecraft composed during the
Mauryan rule. It recommended that in times of famine, the king should provide the subjects
food from his own stores, encourage migration of people to sea shores, banks of rivers or
lakes and levy additional revenue apart from taking contributions from the rich. Kautilya, in
the fourth century BCE also recommended employment creation and redistribution to the
poor as parts of a sound administrative system to defeat famines (Dreze & Sen, 1991: 123).
During the medieval period, there is a reference to a severe famine that occurred during
Alauddin Khalji’s reign (1296-1316) whereby the Sultan and the nobles did whatever was
possible in their capacity to provide relief to the people. Barani, the court chronicler, mentions
that he introduced a new economic policy by establishing grain stores in mohallas of Delhi.
During the reign of Muhammad bin Tughluq, the failure of rains (1326-27) affected several
parts of the Doab and the suffering was worsened due to the enhanced revenue assessment.
Another famine from 1334-35 lasted for seven years and the state advanced loans, encouraged
migration, allowed sinking of wells, etc. Various Indian rulers (such as Muhammad bin Tughluq
in the fourteenth century) made extensive use of work projects and income creation for
rebuilding lost entitlements (Dreze & Sen, 1991: 123). The Mughal rule was also not left
untouched by the famine. Among many incidents of scarcities, the court historian Abul Fazl
mentions one which occurred in 1583-84 during the reign of Akbar. It is believed that the
ruler laid the foundations of an embankment, opened alms houses and free kitchens in cities
and recruited soldiers in the army in order to provide employment to the affected populace.
The other kind of administrative arrangements included dahseri tax of ten seers per bigha
in kind from tilled land as famine insurance (Srivasatva, 2014: 17).
The causation, severity and the strategy of dealing with famines may have varied under
different regimes but the misery associated with it and large scale mortality was quite
pervasive. However, the famines were mostly local in character and not as widespread as
those documented in the nineteenth century. The general cause of famine was often
attributed to failure of rains followed by floods or wars. The suffering from scarcity
intensified under the East India Company (henceforth EIC) owing to the systematic
over-assessment of land revenue and economic exploitation. Initially there were no unified
or well defined rules for famine relief and administration. Although the EIC politically
gained foothold in the Indian subcontinent, yet it largely functioned as a corporate body
focussed on trade and commerce unlike earlier rulers who felt obligated to provide for
their subjects who suffered owing to the natural calamities. The policies followed by the
erstwhile rulers were more sympathetic towards famine relief than the EIC whose primary
aim was to reap economic gains than save people’s lives (Srivastava, 2014: 28, Meena,
2016: 3). The context of famines occurring in nineteenth century was different in scope,
188 incidence and policy outcome from the famines of the earlier times. However, the widespread
changes brought about in the colonial period exacerbated the effects.
11.2.2 Impact of the Colonial Political Economy Famines and Epidemics
The issue of famine cannot be seen in isolation to the changes brought about by the colonial
political economy. In the eighteenth century internecine warfare ensued with the
disintegration of the Mughal Empire resulting in the rise of provincial states. The absence
of paramount power gave East India Company a foothold to interfere in the internal political
scenario. Though it was a trading company, yet its ambitions were not limited to commerce
as they made political alliances to promote their economic interests. The competition from
British machine made goods, destruction of indigenous crafts, exemption or concession
given to foreign merchants from the payment of customs and transit duties, company’s
complete monopoly of Indian trade, heavy duties imposed by the British government on
Indian goods imported to England was a setback to the indigenous textile, carpet making,
fine embroidery and metal work industries. The people employed in these industries had
no option but to fall back upon their land. The weavers, spinners were reduced to penury and
the pressure on agrarian land could not supplement their income (Srivsatava, 2014: 10).
In the domain of foreign trade, India became a supplier of raw materials instead of exporting
finished goods. The peasants were initially engaged as independent contractors and later
as indentured workers cultivating tea, coffee and indigo for European planters. This coercive
exercise reduced the food crop area to make way for cash crops. The land revenue policy
of East India Company and later the British Government of India (Permanent Settlement
of Cornwallis, Zamindari system in North West Provinces, Ryotwari Settlements) were
characterized by excessive assessments, disregarded the occupancy rights of the tenants
and led to insecurity of rents and tenures (Srivsatava, 2014: 11-12). The growing and
widespread penury had a direct co-relation to mounting indebtedness as the peasants
found themselves at the mercy of money lenders who aided by the new laws of registration
could easily dispossess them from their lands. Indian political leaders like Dadabhai Naoroji
and economists like RC Dutt, blamed the British administration and particularly its system
of taxation for the deteriorating condition and widespread poverty among people (Naoroji,
1901: 36). Dutt attributed famines to the constantly soaring land revenue which left no
surplus with the cultivator nor permitted him to invest in agricultural improvement (Dutt,
1909: 2; Srivastava, 2014: vi). Thus, British rule resulted in general impoverishment which
was aggravated by the occurrence of famines. The next Section will discuss the famines
that occurred during the colonial period from eighteenth to mid-twentieth century.
In order to contain the contagion, the government passed a law known as ‘The Epidemic
Diseases Act’ of 1897 which empowered authorities to adopt all measures deemed necessary
to prevent the plague’s spread, including prohibition of pilgrimages to Mecca and emigration
from India, preventing railway bookings, religious gatherings and stocking essential
commodities. The implementation of this Act did not go down well with the subject population.
Soldiers were enlisted to conduct an intrusive door-to-door search, the ‘infected dwellings’
were demolished, caste and religious segregation was practised, arrangements were made
to dispose of dead bodies by sprinkling carbolic powder over the corpse before washing
with a phenyl solution. These stringent yet inconsiderate measures of assaulting, humiliating
the people and destroying their property triggered discontent leading to the assassination
of the plague commissioner WC Rand in Pune (Mehra, 2020).
The Epidemic Diseases Act passed in 1897 was a small legislation consisting of four
sections to prevent the spread of ‘‘Dangerous" Diseases. The concerns included specifying
special measures to control the outbreak, enabling the state governments to take measures
to contain it, spelling out penalty for those who disobeyed and granting protection to those
who implemented it. While the Act was precise in its content, it left much room for
interpretation. The definition of a ‘‘dangerous epidemic disease’’ was not provided in the
Act. There was no clear description of whether an epidemic was ‘‘dangerous’’ on the
basis of the magnitude of the problem or the severity of the disease. It was purely regulatory
in nature and lacked a specific public health focus. Hence it was like a ‘‘policing’’ Act,
intended to control epidemics and not to deal with coordinated and scientific responses to
prevent and tackle the outbreak (Rakesh, 2016; Mehra, 2020).
11.5 SUMMARY
After reading this unit you will be able to understand the linkages between colonial political
economy, famines and epidemics. You will be able to differentiate the policies followed in
197
the pre-colonial period and those implemented under the East India Company and the
Colonial Economy British Crown to deal with famine and epidemics. You will learn about natural and manmade
factors that contributed to ecological changes and worsening of famine situation. The
effects of famine in the form of grain riots and philanthropy have also been laid out. Finally
the role of The Epidemic Diseases Act in dealing with contagious diseases has been discussed
briefly.
11.6 GLOSSARY
Chalisa Chalisa (literally, "of the fortieth’’ in Hindustani)
refers to the Vikram Samvat calendar year 1840
(1783)
Contagionist Etiology The causation for the spread of an infectious
disease
Doji Bara The Doji Bara famine (also Skull Famine) of
1791-1792 was attributed to a major El Nino event
lasting from 1789-1795 and producing prolonged
droughts.
Famine Codes They were guidelines for the local administration
to provide relief measures
11.7 EXERCISES
1. What were the recommendations given by the Famine Commissions?
2. How useful were the Famine Codes?
3. How is crime and philanthropy related to famine relief?
4. Do epidemics always occur in conjunction with famines?
5. How far did the Epidemic Diseases Act respond to the problems created by contagious
diseases?