ch-1 Accounting Methodes
ch-1 Accounting Methodes
March, 2024
1 Gelgelo B. (MSc.)
Bule Hora, Ethiopia
Assessment Methods
Quizzes 10
Test 20
Assignment with 20
Presentation
Final Exam 50
Total 100
2
CHAPTER ONE. EQUILIBRIUM INCOME DETERMINATION
stock of capital and to replace existing capital as it wears out and households buy new houses, which are also part of
investment.
The quantity of investment goods demanded depends on the interest rate, which measures the cost of the funds used
to finance investment.
Government Purchases: The government sector basically does two major things or national economic activities.
Making expenditure on goods and services, which is denoted by (G)
Government earns income through tax, which is denoted by (T)
These purchases are only one type of government spending. The other type is transfer payments (TR) to households,
such as welfare for the poor and Social Security payments for the elderly.
Transfer payments (TR) do affect the demand for goods and services indirectly.
4
Transfer payments (subsidies) are the opposite of taxes: they increase households’ disposable income,
We can now revise our definition of T to equal taxes minus transfer payments (T-TR).
If government purchases equal taxes minus transfers, G = T-TR, then the government has a balanced
budget.
If G+TR>T, the government runs a budget deficit, which it funds by issuing government debt-that is, by
If G +TR< T, the government runs a budget surplus, which it can use to repay some of its outstanding
debt.
The budget surplus (BS) can be defined as the excess of government revenue, consisting of taxes, over
its total expenditure including transfers and is given by the equation as: BS=T-G-TR
5
1.2. Keynesian Cross and the Economy in Equilibrium
In the simple Keynesian model, there are three ‘fundamental assumptions’. These are:
The flow of output produced by an economy (GDP) in a given time period is identically equal to income (Y) generated.
Output is demanded by three types of agents: consumers, firms, and the government (assume a closed economy)
The price level is constant, i.e., there is no inflation. Therefore, the nominal values of Y, C, I, and G are also their real values.
Derivation of the Keynesian cross is started by drawing a distinction between actual and planned expenditure.
Planned expenditure or aggregate demand is the amount of households, firms and the government plan to spend on
expenditure) AD as the sum of consumption (C), planned investment (I) and government purchase (G) AD = C + I +
G
Individual consumers’ demands for products can be aggregated and represented by a consumption function
6
In other words, consumption is determined by disposable income Note that the two curves differ only in their intercept. The intercept of
(Yd) which is total income (Y) minus taxes (T) i.e. Yd=Y-T. consumption function or curve is ‘a’ whereas it is ‘a+I+G’ for the
aggregate demand since I and G are also constant by assumption.
Then, we can write: C = a + b(Y-T), and 0<b<1, hence, C=a+bYd.
Under these particular assumptions, both aggregate demand and
Where, ‘a’ is the intercept of the consumption function
consumption function have the same slope given by marginal
(sometimes called autonomous consumption) - represents the
propensity to consume (MPC)
level of consumption when income is zero and the ‘b’ is the
This can be proved by taking the first order derivative of both functions
marginal propensity to consume (MPC).
since the first order derivative is the slope of a function.
By substituting the values of consumption functional (C),
7
Equilibrium will be found when the desired amount of output demanded by all the agents in the
The graphical representation of the equilibrium is known as the "Keynesian cross" because of the
8
Illustrative Example
Suppose the consumption function and the investment is given as follows with no government intervention:
Solutions :-
AD=C+IAD=100+0.75Y+150 =250+0.75Y
b) The equilibrium level of income is obtained by equating output or income (Y) to aggregate demand (AD) given as follows:
Y=ADY=250+0.75YY-0.75Y=2500.25Y=250Y=1,000
9
c) The equilibrium level of aggregate demand is again obtained by substituting the equilibrium income level into the
aggregate demand function
AD=250+0.75Y and Y=1,000 substituting this in the aggregate demand function we obtain:
AD=250+0.75Y =250+0.75(1000) =250+ 750 =1000. This answer fulfills the equilibrium condition given by: Y=AD
since the values of both the variables are 1000.
d) Equilibrium level of consumption is also obtained by substituting the equilibrium income into the consumption
function. C=100+0.75Y; but Y=1000(in equilibrium). So, C=100+0.75Y C =100+0.75(1000) =100+ 750 = 850
e) Graph showing the consumption function, the aggregate demand function and the equilibrium values with correct
labeling.
10
QUIZ (10%)
11
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers
Government purchase and government tax revenue are the two major government fiscal policy instruments in
relationship between the changes in the instrument and the effect, are known as multipliers.
A. Government Purchase multiplier
If government purchases rise by ∆G, then the planned aggregate demand schedule shifts upward by ∆G, as shown
12
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
It is easy to compare the change in the government spending (∆G) and the change in output (∆Y).
Since the line ‘Y = AD’ is a 450 line, the triangle ‘ABC’ is an isosceles triangle with side AC and side
BC being equal.
The change in output (∆Y) is equal to the distance BC, since BC is equal to AC. But the change in
Thus, the change in output (∆Y) exceeds the change in government expenditure (∆G) by the distance
DC.
The ratio ∆Y/∆G is called the government purchase multiplier; and it tells us the factor by which
income rises in response to a unit increase in government purchases.
An implication of the Keynesian cross is that the government purchases multiplier given by ∆Y/∆G is
larger than one.
13
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
Why does fiscal policy have a multiplier effect on income?
The reason is that, according to the consumption function, higher income causes higher consumption.
Because an increase in government purchases raises income, it also raises consumption, which further
raises income of producers of the consumption goods, and so on.
The impact affects the income and consumption values of different parties for several times. Therefore,
in this model, an increase in government purchases causes a greater increase in income.
The process of the multiplier begins when expenditure rises by ∆G, which implies that income rises by
∆G, as well. This increase in income in turn raises consumption by MPC times ∆G, where MPC is the
marginal propensity to consume.
This increase in consumption raises aggregate demand and income once again. This second increase in
income of MPC (∆G) again raises consumption by MPC(MPC.∆G), which again raises aggregate
demand and income, and so on. We can, thus, write this process compactly as follows:
14
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
15
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
16
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
B. Tax multiplier
The government uses the tax regulation for two major
purposes or objectives.
The first one is that tax is a major source of government
revenue (by increasing tax).
The second one is used to motivate producers and consumers
(by decreasing tax)
Thus, the government increases the tax to meet the first
objective whereas the government decreases the tax to
meet the second objective
For instance, a decrease in tax by T immediately raises
disposable income (Y-T) by T and, therefore,
consumption by MPCxT. For any level of income Y,
aggregate demand is now higher.
As shown in the figure below, the aggregate demand
schedule shifts upward by MPCxT. The equilibrium of
the economy moves from point A to point B.
17
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
18
1.3. Fiscal policy and Multipliers Cont.…
19
Illustrative Example:
20
Illustrative Example Cont.…
21
Illustrative Example Cont.…
22
Illustrative Example Cont.…
23
Illustrative Example Cont.…
24
END OF CHAPTER ONE
25