0% found this document useful (0 votes)
80 views63 pages

Differential Calculus

1) The document provides definitions for key concepts in quantitative methods including limit, continuous function, slope, average rate of change, instantaneous rate of change, and derivative. 2) It outlines 8 rules of differentiation: the constant function rule, power function rule, constant times a function rule, sums of functions rule, product rule, quotient rule, power of a function rule, and chain rule. 3) Examples are provided to demonstrate finding the derivative of both linear and non-linear functions using the various rules of differentiation.

Uploaded by

Rhi Lloyd-Jones
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
80 views63 pages

Differential Calculus

1) The document provides definitions for key concepts in quantitative methods including limit, continuous function, slope, average rate of change, instantaneous rate of change, and derivative. 2) It outlines 8 rules of differentiation: the constant function rule, power function rule, constant times a function rule, sums of functions rule, product rule, quotient rule, power of a function rule, and chain rule. 3) Examples are provided to demonstrate finding the derivative of both linear and non-linear functions using the various rules of differentiation.

Uploaded by

Rhi Lloyd-Jones
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 63

MSc Induction:

Introduction to Quantitative Methods

Differentiation
Dr Ioannis Moutzouris
Academic year: 2018-2019

1
1. Definitions

Definition: Limit
The limit of f(x) as x approaches a equals L if we can make the values of f(x) arbitrarily
close to L (as close to L as we like) by taking x to be sufficiently close to a (on either
side of a) but not equal to a. We write

lim f x   L
x a

Definition: Continuous function


A function f is continuous at a number a if
lim f x   f a 
xa

2
Definition: Slope of a line
The slope of a line is defined as the amount by which its vertical co-ordinate changes
for a unit increase along the horizontal axis, i.e.

change in the dependent variable


slope 
unit change in the indep. variable

Geometrically, the slope of a line is just the tangent of the angle created by the
intersection of the line and the horizontal axis.

Definition: Average rate of change


The average rate of change of y=f(x) with respect to x over the interval [x1,x2] is the
difference quotient
y f x2   f x1 

x x2  x1 ,
and can be interpreted as the slope of the secant line through the points P(x1,f(x1)) and
Q(x2,f(x2)) .

3
Definition: Instantaneous rate of change
The instantaneous rate of change of y=f(x) with respect to x at x=x1, which is
interpreted as the slope of the tangent to the curve y=f(x) at P(x1,f(x1)), is define as

y f x2   f x1 
lim  lim
x 2  x1 x x 2  x1 x2  x1

Definition: The derivative


The derivative of a function f at a number a, is

f x   f a  f a  h   f a 
f ' a   lim  lim
x a xa h0 h

provided this limit exists.

4
Continuity is a necessary condition for differentiability but it is not sufficient. That is,
although differentiability implies continuity, the converse it is not true.

Continuity at a point only rules out the presence of a gap, whereas differentiability
rules out “sharpness” as well. Therefore, differentiability calls for “smoothness” of the
function as well as its continuity.

Example:
The function
y  f ( x) | x  2 | 1
is continuous at x=2,but it is not differentiable at x=2.

Observations:
The tangent line to the curve y=f(x) at P(a,f(a)) is the line through P whose slope is
f’(a) , the derivative of f at a.
The derivative f’(a) is the instantaneous rate of change of y=f(x) with respect to x
when x=a.

5
The derivative f’(x) is itself a function
If y=f(x) is a linear function of x, the concepts of average rate of change and the
instantaneous rate of change (the derivative) are equivalent. In other words, the tangent
line to a straight line is the line itself. Also the slope of a line is constant.

35

30

25

20

15

10

0
1 3 5 7 9
-5

The tangent line as limit of secant lines


It can be seen that as x gets smaller and smaller the secant lines becomes the tangent
line to the curve at point A.

6
Example: rate of change of linear function
The production function of a company has the following form:

y  3x  2
Where, y is the output and x is the input, find change in the production for a unit
change in input.

Choose two points on the domain, and find the respective function values
y  f ( x)  3 x  2 x1 = 1 y1  3(1)  2  5
x2 = 2 y 2  3(2)  2  8
Compute the slope:

y y2  y1 8  5 3
m    3
x x2  x1 2  1 1

The rate of change in the company’s production function is 3. This means that if the
input for this company increase by one unit the production will increase three times.

7
Example: rate of change of non linear function
The revenue of a company is given by the non-linear form:

y  5  10 x  x 2
Where x represents the units of output (for example, cars).

35

30

25

20

15

10
1 3 5 7

8
The rate of change in the revenue (slope of the tangent to the curve) is not the same at
different levels of output. It increases in the beginning and reaches a maximum, and
declines after the maximum. If we plot the graph of the different values taken by the
tangent on the curve, we find:

15

10

0
-1 1 3 5 7 9 11

-5

-10

Plot of the derivative function of the revenue

The plot shows that the rate of change of the function is positive for values of output
lower than 5 and negative for values of output bigger than 5.

9
2. Rules of Differentiation
1) The Constant Function Rule
Derivative of a constant is zero, f ( x )  c

y'  f ' ( x )  0

e.g. y  f ( x)  4 y '  f '( x)  0

2) The Power Function Rule


Derivative of an exponent, f ( x )  x n
, is:

y'  f ' ( x )  nx n1

e.g. a) y  f ( x)  2 x 2 y '  f '( x)  4 x


b) y  f ( x)  3x 6 y '  f '( x)  18x 5

10
3) Constant times a Function Rule
f ( x)  c. g( x)
Derivative of a constant times a function is equal to the constant times the
derivative of that function:
y'  f ' ( x )  c. g' ( x )

4) The Sums of Functions Rule


Derivative of sums and differences of two functions f ( x)  g( x)  h( x) , is:

y '  f '( x)  g '( x)  h'( x)

e.g. a) y  f ( x)  2 x 2  3x 5 y '  f '( x)  4 x  15x 4


1 3
b) y  f ( x )  3x 6
 x y '  f '( x)  18x 5  x 2
3

11
5) Product Rule
Derivative of product of two functions f ( x)  g( x). h( x) , is:

y'  f ' ( x)  g' ( x). h( x)  g( x). h' ( x)

e.g. a) y  f ( x)  2 x 2 (1  3x)
y '  4 x(1  3x)  ( 3)( 2 x 2 )  4 x  12 x 2  6x 2  4 x  18x 2

1 3
b) y  f ( x )  ( 2  3x 2 ) x
3
1
y '  6x ( x 3 )  ( 2  3x 2 ) x 2  2 x 4  2 x 2  3x 4  5x 4 2 x 2
3

12
6) Quotient Rule
The derivative of the ratio of two functions, f(x)= g(x) / h(x) is:

g ' ( x ) h( x )  h ' ( x ) g ( x )
y '  f ' ( x) 
[h( x)]2
Where g(x) is a differentiable function

3x 2  x  3
e.g y
x3 1
( x 3  1)(6 x  1)  (3x 2  x  3)(3x 2 )
y' f' (x) 
(x 3 - 1) 2
[6 x 4  x 3  6 x  1]  [9 x 4  3x 3  9 x 2 ]
y' f' (x) 
( x 3  1) 2

13
7) The Power of a Function Rule
The derivative of a function raised into the power of n, f ( x)  [g( x)] is:
n

y '  f '( x)  n[g( x)]n1 g '( x)

Where g(x) is a differentiable function

e.g. a) y  f ( x)  (1  3x 2 ) 3
g( x)  1  3x 2 g '( x)  6x
y '  3(1  3x 2 ) 2 (6 x)  18 x(1  3x 2 ) 2
 (18 x)(1  6 x 2  9 x 4 )
= -162x 5  108 x 3  18 x

14
8) If, y  f ( u) and u = g( x) , where g(x) and f(u) are both differentiable
functions, then the chain rule of derivatives can be applied as follows:
dy dy du
y'   
dx du dx
e.g.
a) y  ( x 2  3x  1) 3 let us assume y = u 3 and u = x 2  3x  1
dy dy du d (u 3 ) d ( x 2  3x  1)
   
dx du dx du dx

= 3u 2  (2 x  3) = 3( x 2  3x  1) 2 (2 x  3)

b) y  ( x 3  3) 2 let us assume y = u 2 and u = x 3  3


dy dy du d (u 2 ) d ( x 3  3)
   
dx du dx du dx
= 2u  (3x 2 ) = 2( x 3  3)(3x 2 ) = 6 x 5  18 x 2

15
2.1. Derivatives of Exponential and logarithmic functions
1) The Natural Exponential Function Rule

i) f ( x)  e x f'(x)  e x
ii) f(x)  e g(x) f'(x)  g'(x)e g(x)
iii) f(x)  keg(x) f'(x)  kg'(x)eg(x)
iv ) f(x)  a g(x) f'(x)  g'(x)a g(x) . ln a

e.g. a) y  e2 x y'  2e 2 x
x3  x 2 x3  x 2
b) ye y'  ( 3x  2 x)e
2

3(x 2 1 ) 3(x 2 1 )
c) ye y'  6 xe

16
2) The Natural Logarithmic Function Rule
1
i) f(x)  ln x f'(x) 
x
g ' ( x)
ii) f(x)  ln g ( x ) f'(x) 
g ( x)
iii) f(x)  log a g ( x )
ln g ( x ) g ' ( x)
 f'(x) 
ln a g ( x) ln a

36 x 2 3
e.g. a) y  ln 12 x 3
 y'  3

12 x x
2x  1
b) y  ln( x 2  x  1)  y' 
x2  x  1
5 1
c) y  ln(5 x)  y'  
5x x
2x 1
d) y  log( x 2  4)  y'  *
x 2  4 ln 10

17
2.2. Higher order derivatives
It is possible to find the derivative of a derivative of a function. This is called the
second derivative of a function and measures the slope and the rate of change of the
first derivative.

The notation for the second derivative is y’’ or f’’(x). Similarly, the third derivative of
a function, f’’’(x), measures the slope and the rate of change of the second derivative
and so on and so forth.

The rules for taking the second and higher derivatives are the same as before.

Example:
a) y  f ( x)  2 x 2  3x 5 y '  f '( x)  4 x  15x 4
y ' '  f ' '( x)  4  60x 3
y' ' '  f ' ' ' ( x)  180 x 2

18
3. Applications of Derivatives
So far we learned how to find the derivative of a function. Now we study the use of
these derivatives in applications such as plotting functions, finding maximum,
minimum, point of inflection and curvature of a function. We also study some
economic applications of derivatives.

19
3.1. Increasing and decreasing functions
Definition:
A function f(x) is said to be increasing (or monotonically increasing), if successively
larger values of the independent variable x always lead to successively larger values of
f(x), that is if

x1>x2  f(x1)>f(x2)

On the other hand, if successive increase in x always lead to successive decrease in


f(x), that is,
x1>x2  f(x1)<f(x2)

then the function is said to be decreasing (or monotonically decreasing) .

20
Proposition:If a function is differentiable and decreasing at an interval, its first
derivative is negative, f’(x)<0 at this interval.

This indicates that the slope of the curve at any point, within that interval, is negative.
The figure below illustrates a decreasing function, which has a negative first derivative
at point A and within the chosen interval.

x 0.8

0.7

0.6

y 0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
-1 -0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2

[Decreasing function]

21
Proposition:By the same token, a function with a positive first derivative within an
interval is an increasing function. The slope or value of the tangent to any point on an
increasing function is positive. The following figure shows an increasing function

0.8

0.7

0.6

y 0.5

0.4
x 0.3

0.2

0.1

0
-1.8 -1.6 -1.4 -1.2 -1

[Increasing function]

22
3.2. Concavity and Convexity
Definition:
A function is said to be concave at x=a, if at some small region close to the tangent to
the line at point [x=a, f(a)], the graph of the function lies below the tangent line.

On the other hand a function is said to be convex at x=a, if at some small region
around the point [x=a,f(a)], the graph of the function lies completely above the
tangent line. The figures below show the graphs of two concave and convex functions.

-0.1 0.8
1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2
-0.2 0.7
0.6
-0.3
0.5
-0.4
0.4
-0.5 0.3
0.2
-0.6
0.1
-0.7
0
-0.8 -1.8 -1.6 -1.4 -1.2 -1

a) A convex function b) A concave function

23
The first derivative measures the rate of change of a function. The second derivative is
the measure of the rate of change of the first derivative.
We can distinguish the following cases (see the figures):

1. If f ' x0   0 and f '' x0   0

then the value of the function at x0 is increasing at an increasing rate.

2. If f ' x0   0 and f '' x0   0

then the value of the function at x0 is increasing at a decreasing rate.

3. If f ' x0   0 and f '' x0   0

then the slope at x0 is negative and increasing.

4. If f ' x0   0 and f '' x0   0


then the slope at x0 is negative and decreasing.

24
The first derivative a function f tells us about its slope. The second derivative of a
function informs us about the curvature of its graph.

We can find whether a function is concave or convex at a point by finding the value of
its second derivative at that point.

Proposition:
If at x= a y''=f''(a)>0 then f(x) is convex at x=a

If at x= a y''=f''(a)<0 then f(x) is concav e at x=a

25
a) f’(x)>0 b) f’(x)<0
f’’(x)>0 f’’(x)>0

c) f’(x)>0 d) f’(x)<0
f’’(x)<0 f’’(x)<0

26
Examples:
Find the slope and curvature of following functions at x=3;
a) y  x 2  1
y '  f ' ( x)  2 x f ' (3) = -6  0
y ' '  f ' ' ( x)  2 f'' (3) = -2 < 0

Therefore, the function has a negative slope and is concave at x=3.

b) y  x3  x
y '  f ' ( x)  3 x 2 + 1 f ' (3) = 28 > 0
y''  f''(x)  6 x f''( 3 )=18>0

Therefore, the function has a positive slope and is convex at x=3.

27
3.3. First derivative test for relative extremum
At a relative maximum or minimum point the function is neither decreasing nor
increasing. Therefore if a relative extremum occurs, either the first derivative does not
exist or if it does is zero. We restrict ourselves to continuous and differentiable
function. Thus
f ' x0   0

it is a necessary condition for a relative extremum. However it is not a sufficient


condition.

The points of the domain at which the first derivative of the function is zero, are
called critical values.

For example, in the figure below, the slope of the tangent lines at x= -1 and x=1 are
zero and at these two point there are a relative maximum and a relative minimum,
respectively.

28
3.3.1. Second derivative test for relative extremum
If x=x0 is a critical value of f(x), then f(x0) will be

1. A relative maximum if f’(x) changes its sign from positive to negative from the
immediate left of the point x0 to its immediate right. Equivalently,

If f’’(x0)<0, then the point [x=x0, f(x0 )] is a maximum

2. A relative minimum if f’ (x) changes its sign from negative to positive from the
immediate left of the point x0 to its immediate right. Equivalently,

If f’’(x0)>0, then the point [x=x0, f(x0 )] is a minimum

29
Note: In order to find maximum and minimum points on a curve (function), we follow
two steps;

i) Take the first derivative of the function, f’(x), set it equal to zero and solve for the
critical point(s), x=x1 , x=x2 , etc. This step is known as the first-order condition,
FOC.

ii) Take the second derivative of the function, f’’(x), and evaluate it at the critical
point(s). This step is known as second-order condition, SOC.

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
-2 -1 0 1 2
-0.2

-0.4

-0.6

-0.8

[Relative maximum and minimum]

30
Example: Find relative maximum and minimum points of the following functions;

a) y  x 2  1
FOC : y '  f ' ( x)  2 x  2x  0  x0

SOC : y ' '  f ' ' ( x)  2 f ' ' ( x)  2 < 0

Therefore, the function has a relative maximum at [x=0 , y=1].

b) y  2 x 3  6 x  12
FOC : y '  f ' ( x)  6 x 2 - 6 6x 2  6  0  x1  1 , x 2  1

SOC : y ' '  f ' ' ( x)  12 x f ' ' (1)  12 > 0


f ' ' (1)  12 < 0
Therefore, the function has a relative maximum at [x=-1, y=16] and a relative
minimum at [x=1, y=8].

31
3.3.2. The Nth-derivative test
If f’(x0)=0 and f’’(x0)=0 then f(x0) can be either a relative maximum or minimum, or
an inflectional value (an inflectional value is a point of the graph in which the
curvature changes from concave to convex or vice-versa).

In this case we proceed with the n-th derivative test. If

f ' ( x0 )  0, f '' ( x0 )  0,...., f n1 ( x0 )  0, f n x0   0

then the critical value f(x0) will be


 A relative maximum if n is an even number and fn(x0)<0
 A relative minimum if n is an even number and fn(x0)>0
 An inflection point if n is an odd number.

32
3.4. Economic applications of derivatives
3.4.1. Relationship between total, marginal, and average concepts

 The sum of money that flows into a firm is referred to as revenue.


 The sum of money, which flows out of a firm is known as costs.
There are different ways to define revenue and costs.

3.4.1.1. Marginal and Average Revenue


 Total Revenue, TR, is defined as the revenue derived from all sales of particular
goods and is the product of the total number of unit sold, Q, and the unit price of the
goods, P. Mathematically,
TR  P  Q

 Marginal Revenue, MR, is defined as the change in the Total Revenue caused by a
unit increase in production. Therefore, using derivative notation

MR  d(TR)
d(Q)

33
 Average revenue, AR, is defined as the revenue from the sale of each unit, and can
be obtained by dividing the total revenue by the number of units sold as follows;

TR PQ
AR   P
Q Q
Find the average and marginal revenues for the following total revenue function and
evaluate them at Q=10 and Q=5.

TR  200Q  3Q 2

d (TR) TR 200Q  3Q 2
MR   200  6Q AR =   200  3Q
dQ Q Q

If Q = 10 M R = -6(10) + 200 = 140 If Q = 10 AR = -3(10) + 200 = 170


If Q = 5 M R = -6(5) + 200 = 170 If Q = 5 AR = -3(5) + 200 = 185

34
3.4.1.2. Marginal and Average Cost (cost minimisation)

 Total Cost, TC, is defined as the total cost of all factors of production involved in
the production of a certain level of output. Total cost consists of two parts, Total
Fixed Cost (TFC) and Total variable Cost (TVC). Where, Fixed costs are those
which are constant and do not vary with the output level, while, the variable cost are
those which vary with different levels of output. Therefore we can write;

TC=f(Q)=TVC+TFC
 Marginal Cost, MC, can be defined as the change in the total cost caused by
producing an additional unit of output.
d(TC)
MC  f ' ( Q) 
d(Q)

 Average Cost, AC, is the cost of production of one unit which can be obtained by
dividing the total cost by the number of units produced in the following form;
TC F ( Q )
AC  
Q Q

35
Example 1: Find the average cost, AC, and marginal cost, MC, for the following total
cost, TC, function and evaluate them at Q=10 and Q=5.

TC  Q3  10Q 2  30Q  20

d (TC ) TC Q 3  10Q 2  30Q  20


MC   3Q 2  20Q  30 AC =   Q 2  10Q  30  (20 / Q)
dQ Q Q

If Q = 10 MC = 3(10) 2 - 20(10)  30 = 130 If Q = 10 AC = (10) 2 - 10(10) + 30  (20/10) = 32

If Q = 5 MC = 3(5) 2 - 20(5)  30 = 5 If Q = 5 AC = (5) 2 - 10(5) + 30  (20/5) = 9

Now, if we sketch the graphs of total and marginal cost curves, we see that;

36
1) Total cost first rises until reaches a maximum and then falls until reaches its
minimum and then rises again.

2) Marginal cost curve is positive until the total cost reaches its maximum, at this
point marginal cost becomes negative indicating that total cost is falling. Marginal
costs stays at the negative region until total cost reaches its minimum. At this point,
marginal cost will become positive indicating that the total cost is rising again.

75

65

55

45
Cost

35

25

15

-5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity

TC MC

37
Now let us find the minimum and maximum of the total cost function. This is
equivalent to setting the MC to zero and solve it to find where the MC cuts the
horizontal axis.

20  400  4 * 3 * 30
MC  3Q 2  20Q  30  0  Q1 , Q2 
6
20  40 20  40
 Q1   4.38 and Q 2   2.79
6 6

3.4.2. Profit Maximization

Profit, , of an organisation is the total revenue less total cost and can be shown as;


TC  4Q  12Q  10
2

  TR  TC Where 

TR  3Q  8Q  5
2

Therefore, using the cost and revenue functions above, the profit function will be;

38
  TR  TC
  f (Q)  (3Q 2  8Q  5)  (4Q 2  12Q  10)  Q 2  20Q  5

Having the firm’s total cost and revenue functions (above examples), it is possible to
find the output level, which maximises its profit.

Profit can be maximised by optimising the profit function, as follows;

FOC : f ' (Q) = -2Q + 20 = 0  Q  10


SOC : f ' ' (Q) = -2 < 0

M aximum Profit  (10) 2  20(10)  5  95


Total cost  4(10) 2  12(10)  10  290
TotalRevenue  3(10) 2  8(10)  5  385
Therefore at Q=10, the firm will have the maximum Revenue.

39
3.4.3. Inventory Management

Inventory costs is a combination of the cost of purchasing, owning and maintaining


inventory. These vary with the order size.

Example 1: A bicycle retailer examined past data and estimated the following
inventory cost function as a function of the order size (the number of bicycles).

C  4,860 Q -1  15 Q  750,000

The order size, which minimises annual inventory costs may be found by optimising
the above function with respect to Q.

FOC : C'  - 4,860 Q -2  15  0

Q 2  324 Q   18

40
The turning point is at q=18 bicycles.

SOC : C ' '  9,720 q -3


C ' ' (18)  1.67  0  a minimum

Therefore the optimal order size which minimises annual inventory costs is 18
bicycles.

Minimum costs are at C(18) = £750,540.

41
3.4.4. Elasticities

In economics, price elasticity  of demand (supply) is defined as the percentage change


in quantity demanded (supplied) divided by the percentage change in price.
Mathematically,
Q
 100
Percentage change in quantity Q
 
Percentage change in price P
 100
P
This is equivalent to:
dQ
dQ P Q dQ P
  or  or  
Q dP dP dP Q
P

42
Therefore, it is the shape of the demand (supply) curve that defines the elasticity of
demand (supply).

For example, if the demand for a commodity does not change with the changes in the
price of that commodity, the demand for the commodity is said to be perfectly
inelastic, figure (b) below.

The price elasticity of demand is unitless and negative, and in practice, we are
interested in the absolute value of this number. Therefore, the higher the number, the
more elastic is the demand curve. Following figure shows three special cases of
demand curve;

a) A horizontal demand curve, which is perfectly elastic,


b) A vertical demand curve, which is perfectly inelastic,
c) A demand curve with a negative slope, which is elastic

43
P P P
Ed>1

Ed+ Ed=0 P1 Ed =1
Ed<1

Q Q Q
(a) (b) (c)

44
Example 1: Find the price elasticity of demand at prices, P=£100, P=£300, for the
following demand function

Q  1000  2P

i) Find the first derivative of the demand equation with respect to price

dQ d (1000  2 P)
  2
dP dP

ii) Find the demand when P=£100

P=£100 Q=1000-2*100=800

iii) Multiply the price-demand ratio by the value of derivative found in stage (i).

 100  1 1
Ed  (2)     (-1/4)  1  inelastic demand
 800  4 4

45
ii) Now we must find the price elasticity of demand when P=300

P=£300 Q=1000-2*300=400

iii) Multiply the new price-demand ratio by the value of derivative found in stage
(i).

 300  3
Ed  (2)    then  (-3/2)  1.5  1  elastic demand
 400  2

Next, we need to find the quantity and price at which the elasticity is equal to one, i.e.
the demand curve is unit elastic. For this purpose, we need to set the elasticity equal to
one (note that it should be -1), and solve for value of Q in terms of P as follows.

dQ P P
Ed  1  *  1  - 2 *  1  - 2P  -Q  Q  2P
dP Q Q

46
Substituting the value of Q in terms of P in the demand equation will result in the price
at which the price elasticity of demand is equal to one.

Q  1000  2 P
  2P  1000 - 2P  4P  1000  P  250
Q  2P 

Therefore, at P=250 the price elasticity of demand is equal to one.

It has is also been proved that the price elasticity of demand of a linear demand curve
with a negative slope depends on the level of the price.

47
The summary of different forms of price elasticity

Elasticity of Types of elasticity


Demand
Ed =0  Perfectly Inelastic Demand is not sensitive to changes in price.
0< Ed <1  Inelastic Demand is relatively insensitive to changes in
price.
Ed =1  Unit elasticity Changes in demand are equal to changes in price.
1< Ed <  Elastic Demand is relatively sensitive to the changes in
price.
Ed   Perfectly Elastic Demand is sensitive to the change in price.

48
Example 3: Find the elasticity of demand for the following logarithmic demand
function at P=2 and p=5.

ln Q  20  3ln P

dQ dP
E
we need to find d   (1)
Q P

d ln Q 1 dQ
we know that if dQ  d ln Q 
Q , then Q

d ln P 1 dP
also we know that if dP  d ln P 
P , then P

49
Substitute the values of dlnQ and dlnP in (1), will result in the elasticity of demand.

dQ
Q d ln Q
Ed    3
dP d ln p  Ed=3
p

It can be seen that whatever value assigned for P and Q the price elasticity of demand
for a logarithmic demand function of the form lnQ=a-b*lnP would be constant, which
is (-b).

50
3.4.4.1. Use of price elasticity of demand for producers
We know that the revenue of a producer depends on the price of products and the
demand for the products. Therefore the total revenue of the producer, TR, can be
obtained by multiplying the price, P, by the demand for that good, Q.

TR = P*Q

We also know that the marginal revenue of the producer is equal to;

d (TR) 
MR   d(P  Q) dQ dP  dP 
dQ  MR   MR  P Q  M R  P  Q *  
TR  PQ 
dQ dQ dQ  dQ 

 Q dP   1 
 M R  P1  *   M R  P1  
 P dQ   Ed 

51
Now, it can be seen that if the price elasticity of demand is equal to one, then the MR
will be zero and revenue will be at maximum level.

If Ed   , M R  0 and M R  P
If Ed  1, MR  0
If Ed  1, MR  0
If 0  Ed  1, MR 
If Ed  0 , M R  0 and M R  

52
3.4.4.2. Income elasticity of demand
The income elasticity of demand can be defined as the percentage change in the
demand due to a percentage change in income. Mathematically;
Q
 100
Percentage change in quantity Q
 
Percentage change in price income I
 100
I
This is equivalent to:
dQ
dQ I Q dQ I
  or  or  
Q dI dI dI Q
I

Depending on the type of good under study, the income elasticity of demand can take
different values. For example, if the value of the income elasticity of demand is greater
than zero, the good is a normal good. This means that, a percentage increase in income
result in a percentage increase in demand.

53
If the value of income elasticity of demand for one good found to be less than one,
then the good is an inferior good, i.e. a percentage change in income result in a
percentage decrease in demand for that good.

Finally, if the income elasticity of demand for a good is found to be zero, then the
good is categorised as neutral good, i.e. a percentage change in income will not have
any effect on the demand for that good.

EI >0 for normal goods


EI =0 for neutral goods
EI <0 for inferior goods

54
3.4.4.3. Cross Elasticity of Demand
The Cross Elasticity of Demand is defined as the percentage change in the quantity
demanded of Q with respect to a percentage change in the price of another good
(substitute or complement), Py . Mathematically:
dQ / Q dQ Py
 Qy  
dPy / Py dPy Q

If the Cross Price Elasticity of demand is found to be negative, then a % increase in the
price of the second good will result in a decrease in the demand for the first good.
Such commodities are said to be complements, for example, coffee and sugar.
EQy < 0 when Q, Y are complements
On the other hand, if a percentage increase in the price of the second good increases
the demand of the first good (the good under study), then they are called substitutes,
for example, coffee and tea.
EQy > 0 when Q, Y are substitutes

55
Example: Given the demand function, P  Q  4Q  96 , find the price elasticity of demand
2

at P=51. Also find how much the demand changes if price rises by 2%.

P  Q2  4Q  96
P=51 51  Q 2  4Q  96  -Q 2  4Q  45  0

 (4)  (4) 2  4(1)(45)


Find the roots of the equation using Q1 , Q2  2(1)

This will result in Q=-9 and Q=5. Obviously the first solution does not have an
economic meaning. Therefore, Q=5. Now find the derivative of P with respect to
Q; that is

dP dQ 1
 2Q  4  
dQ dP - 2Q - 4

56
dQ 1 1
we know that P=51 and Q=5, therefore  
dP - 2(5) - 4 - 14

It is easy to find the elasticity of demand using the above value for the derivative
of Q with respect to P.

P dQ 51 1
Ed   *  *  0.73
Q dP 5  14

Knowing that elasticity of demand is the percentage change in demand for a


percentage change in price, we can write

Percentage change in demand PCD


Ed    0.73  -  PCD  -1.46%
Percentage change in price 2

This implies that a 2% increase in price will decrease the demand by 1.46%

57
3.5. Taylor and Maclaurin Series
dy d{f (x)}
Let y = f(x), then   f 1(x)
dx dx
d2y d{f 1(x)}
2
  f 2
(x)
dx dx
d 3 y d{f 2(x)}
3
  f 3
(x), etc .
dx dx

3.5.1. Taylor's Series


A function, f(x), may be approximated at some point, xo , by the following:

1 2
f(x)  f(x 0 )  f 1 (x0 ) (x - x 0 )  f (x0 ) (x - x 0 )2
2!
1 3 1 n
 f (x0 ) (x - x 0 )3    f (x0 ) (x - x 0 )n  Remainder
3! n!

58
where f(x0) is the value of f(x) at the point x0 and n! reads n factorial where

n!  n  (n - 1 )  (n - 2 )  2  1
Note 0! = 1! = 1.

3.5.2. Maclaurin's Series

A special case of the Taylor Series is when x  0 , in which case


0

1 2 1 3 1 n
f(x)  f( 0 )  f 1 ( 0 )x  f ( 0 ) x2  f ( 0 ) x 3   f ( 0 )x n  Remainder
2! 3! n!

59
Examples of Maclaurin series expansion

Example 1:
Let f(X)  ( 1  X)3
We know that ( 1  X)  1  3 X  3 X  X . Use MacLaurin's Series to prove it.
3 2 3

f(X)  ( 1  X)3 f( 0 )  1
f 1(X)  3( 1  X)2 f 1( 0 )  3
f 2(X)  6( 1  X) f 2( 0 )  6
f 3(X)  6 f 3( 0 )  6
f 4 (X)  0 f 4 (0)  0

1 1
 f(X)  1  3 X  6 X2  6 X3
2! 3!
Thus (1  X) 3
 1  3 X  3 X 2
 X 3

60
Example 2: Find the value of e
Let f(X)  e x then f(X)  ex f( 0 )  e 0  1
f 1(X)  e x f 1( 0 )  e 0  1
f 2(X)  e x f 2( 0 )  e 0  1
 

X2 X3 Xn
 e  1 X 
x
     ...
2! 3! n

61
Another example of Taylor Series

Taylor series expansion is used to measure the sensitivity of bond prices with respect
to changes in interest rates. Using the first two terms of a Taylor series expansion to
approximate the price change we can write

dP 1 d 2P
dP  dy  2
(dy) 2
 error
dy 2 dy

Dividing both sides of equation by P to find the percentage price change results in

dP dP 1 1 d 2P 1 error
 dy  2
(dy ) 
2

P dy P 2 dy P P
The duration of the bond is define as
1 dP
D
P dy

62
The convexity of the bond is defined as
d 2P
C 2
dy

Bond Price

Actual
price
increase The line representing slope of the curve

Actual
price fall
Current rate Interest rate
Rate decrease Rate increase

63

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy