2006 Farida
2006 Farida
2 Definitions
The Latin verb "corrumpere" means to break something. The question to be
answered is what is "broken" by the act of corruption. The obvious answer is that
the law is broken; or that a legal rule is broken; a duty is broken; a moral norm is
broken. But it is important to add that communities and human personalities may
also be broken by the practice of corruption. Communities are disintegrated by
corruption because it undermines predictability and accountability; it reduces
social transparency and erodes social trust. The integrity of the human
personality is broken because corruption involves lying, dissimulation, and living
according to two (contradictory) sets of standards. Social disintegration and the
loss of personal integrity may be the greatest long-term damage done by
corruption (Manchin 2000, P.4). Therefore, defining corruption appears essential
when studying its costs and benefits.
2
Corruption or 'level of corruption' is widely used in public discourse and
usually hold a twofold meaning. Its definitions range between two schools of
thought. On one hand, it stands for those illegal practices, in which citizens or
organisations bribe officials in charge for awarding permissions, contracts, or to
escape punishment or fines for offenses they committed. Simpler: to obtain
privileges against law or against the rules of some bureaucracy (Rose-Ackerman
1999). This is the narrow definition of corruption. Many scholars argue, however,
that corruption is a broader phenomenon, or rather, a hardly definable set of
phenomena, including achieving several advances through personal networking;
paying gratitude money or giving gifts for usual services, what are already
reimbursed from customers or state resources (Kaufman 1998). Viewed most
broadly, corruption is the misuse of office for unofficial ends (Klitgaard 1998, P.
4).
3
research suggests measuring both types of corruption to get a reliable and useful
resource in estimating actual level of corruption in a specific country, even across
counties. Therefore, corruption can be described as the use of power or money
to obtain desired outcomes against the rules and ethics of the community.
Corruption, in all its forms, not only weakens economies, but also has some
economic benefits.
4
gambling, and sexual gratification, as well as economic gain (Miller 2005).
Corruption is usually caused by several procedures and practices.
5
3.2 Consequences of Corruption
There is a growing empirical literature based on comparative country studies,
emphasizing that corruption lowers investment, capital productivity, capital
inflows and many other macroeconomic data (Lambsdorff 1999). Corruption not
only slows economic growth, but it also increases the volatility of business cycle
and affects the human development through enhancing poverty and reducing
social services.
Since rent seeking is often more lucrative than productive work, talents will
be misallocated. Financial incentives may lure the more talented and better
educated to engage in rent seeking rather than productive work, which in turn
results in adverse consequences for the country's economic growth. Ehrilich
(1999) presents a balance growth model to show that in some equilibrium
officials spend a substantial amount of time and effort in seeking and
accumulating political capital, which is not socially productive. Corruption may
entice government officials to allocate public resources less on the basis of social
welfare than according to opportunities for extorting bribes. Large projects,
6
whose performance is difficult to monitor, may provide lucrative opportunities for
rent seeking and bribes. We can expect that it is easier to collect large bribes on
large infrastructure projects or high-tech defense systems than on textbooks or
teachers' salaries. Mauro (1998) concludes that corruption affects the
composition of government expenditure. When corruption is serious, there is
much less government expenditure on education than on large infrastructure and
defense projects. In addition, Mauro finds that corruption also lowers the quality
of infrastructure projects and pubic services. This will result in not only lowering
economic growth, but also affects the human development in these communities.
7
3.2.3 Corruption and Social Welfare
The damaging effects of corruption on investment and economic growth are
widely recognised. But corruption also has adverse effects on human
development. First, corruption reduces the availability and increases the cost of
basic social services. Access to core social services can be easily restricted with
the intention to make corrupt gains (Kaufman 1998, P. 36). Since obtaining
access to basic public services normally requires an illegal cash payment,
corruption also raises the price of these services.
8
and corruption is one of these vital relationships. Corruption is an important
cause of poverty because it promotes unfair distribution of income and inefficient
use of resources.
A similar conclusion can be drawn for a minor case of corrupt misdeed: the
payment of speed money as mentioned by (Douie 1917, P. 545) with respect to
reduced levels of corruption in courts. This implies a tradeoff between
administrative delays and corruption. Given excess demand for public goods and
services, applicants have to line up according to the time of their arrival; files will
be piled and not processed according to the needs of the applicants. The
resulting waiting costs would be reduced if the payment of speed money could
induce bureaucrats to increase their efforts and to process cases according to
urgency, a need which might be measured by the applicants’ willingness to pay.
This argument was opposed (Myrdal (1968), who argued that corrupt officials
might, instead of speeding up, actually cause administrative delays in order to
attract more bribes. A similar proposition is put forward by (Rose-Ackerman
1978, P. 90) arguing that bureaucrats behave like monopolists who profit from
increasing prices by creating scarcity.
9
factor impeding economic development. Corruption hampers economic growth,
disproportionately burdens the poor and undermines the effectiveness of
investment and aid. In addition, the World Bank (1997) is helping countries
develop anti-corruption strategies (World-Bank 1997).
4 Theoretical Considerations
The first theory of corruption that will be discussed is the typology
Heidenheimer (1989), who divided the corruption theories into those which
concentrate on the public official and concern the breaking of the rules of the law
and those according to which corruption is a particular kind of market
phenomenon. Some non-economical formulations of the problem of corruption
will be presented, and thus be placed within the two first categories of
Heidenheimer's typology. In accordance with the perspective adopted in the
research it is an attempt to present non-economic, institutional conditions of
corruption. In successive parts of the chapter corruption will be defined as a
contract referring to the works of Rose-Ackerman (1999) and Banfield (1958),
where they mostly agree that the essential influence on the scale and structure of
corruption is exerted on the one hand by agency structures of the administration
and, on the other hand, cultural conditions.
10
doing certain things is by monetary or other rewards not legally provided for,
induced to take actions which favor whoever provides the rewards and thereby
does damage to the public and its interests (Friedrich 1966, P. 37). Added to
these merely theoretic and loose definitions, researchers need little input
information to make their studies more effective. In each country there are areas,
where traditional corruption is more widespread, where it is virtually unpresent.
Though, the measurement of the narrowly defined corruption has relatively long
tradition and international researches provide sufficient basis to prepare
comparative measurement of the level of these activities. The issue gets even
more complicated, as we try to capture various corruptive activities.
11
fertile ground for corruption to flourish; however they are often not the basis but
themselves a consequence of corruption.
12
which the civil service, far from being a body that exists to implement the rights of
citizens – rights that mirror their duties – is first and foremost perceived as the
least risky way of getting rich quickly. All of which helps to make corruption seem
normal (Stasavage 1998). It is the environment in which public servants and
private actors operate that causes corruption. Public administration in developing
countries is often bureaucratic and inefficient. A large number of complex,
restrictive regulations coupled with inadequate controls are characteristic of
developing countries that corruption helps to get around. But to understand
corruption, institutional analysis is not enough. A political and economic analysis
is important too. Whether it is in Benin, Bolivia, Morocco, Pakistan or the
Philippines – five countries examined in a study by the OECD Development
Centre and the UN Development Programme – corruption is closely linked to the
type of government involved (Hors 2000, P. 5).
The link between political and economic power can be direct. There is
patrimonialism, as in Lebanon, where access to political power ensures access
to economic privileges. The link can be indirect too, as in Turkey, where political
power, such as a privileged position in a patronage-based system, can be bought
and sold. In short, the process of allocating political and administrative posts –
particularly those with powers of decision over the export of natural resources or
import licenses – is influenced by the gains that can be made from them. The
political foundations are cemented as these exchanges of privileges are
reciprocated by political support or loyalty (Kaufman 1998, P. 19). Another
feature common to the countries studied is their underdevelopment, which is
conducive to corruption. In fact, underdevelopment encourages corruption. First
of all, low wages in the civil service encourage petty corruption, and the
imbalance between the supply of, and demand for, public services likewise
creates opportunities for corruption. Also, individuals tend to invest in a career in
the public service, given the shortage of opportunities in the private sector, thus
increasing the likelihood of their involvement in corrupt practices (Gill 1998, P.
85). Another reason is that the low level of education found in underdeveloped
13
countries maintains citizens in a state of ignorance of their rights, barring them
from participating in political life.
14
5 Measuring Corruption
There is a consensus that real volume of corruption cannot be measured or
calculated. However, there are different approaches that indicate the spread of
corruption in societies.
First, general perception can be, and is regularly used as a sensitive core
indicator of the feeling the 'lack of justice' in public transactions. This type of
measure is less stabile over time; it is sensitively reflecting the level how
corruption is displayed in media. Corruption perception in this sense is an indirect
measure related to actual level of corruption, highly depending on how much
space corruption actually has in media agenda. In normal cases, the relative
weight of corruption issues appearing on media must be closely related to what
happens in real life; if there are more corruption cases in the country, there are
more scandals appearing on TV screens as well (Markovits 1988, P. 28).
15
country comparison in certain widely measured areas, and finally we provide the
basis for the longitudinal analysis, which we see more important than cross-
country comparisons. The cross-country analyses in terms of general corruption
practices have serious validity problems. Using perception methods, actual
events surrounding the data collection can significantly influence the results we
get. In proxy measures we cannot control the 'shame-bias' and the 'routine-bias',
that is, we will never know the exact ratio between actual corruption attempts and
the reported number.
16
operationally relevant utilization. One can effectively utilize empirical analysis in
the design and implementation of action programs.
17
contrast to allocative inefficiency, this type of inefficiency is defined as one that
originates from a lack of effort and motivation among the workforce, resulting in
productive units not operating on the production possibility frontier (Button 1994,
P. 91). The original approach to X-inefficiency as developed by (Leibenstein
1973) aimed at explaining the efficiency losses resulting from a lack of
competition in private goods markets. In addition to the allocative losses depicted
by the classical Harberger triangle, Leibenstein argues that monopolistic firms do
not minimise costs for a given production level (Leibenstein 1966, P. 401). In a
competitive environment, inefficient producers are put under pressure from
competing firms, but monopolies can maintain their market position without effort.
The market selects those firms that are able to efficiently use their factor inputs.
But such a selection process does not exist in the case of a monopoly. This
absence of pressure results in a lack of motivation and effort among the
workforce and an inefficient organization of production.
18
Finally, all the three approaches explored scientific methods in the field of
corruption evaluation, and hold value in achieving the goal: that is to estimate the
spread and map the structure of corruption. But, the methods used to measure
corruption based on the World Bank’s frame work may be considered as the
primary tool to use in formulating a comprehensive model to assess and combat
corruption in a specific country. The X-inefficiency model that was used by some
scholars to measure corruption did not proof to be of good use, while doing this
as it was originally formulated for other purposes.
Measuring corruption needs special attention regarding the kind and level of
corruption that determine the appropriate method to be used. A good model
requires a comprehensive understanding for the causes of corruption, business
environment, public administration, institutional structures and the effect of
culture. Moreover, accurate data are a key factor in formulating a sophisticated
model in assessing the level of corruption. Based on literature that has been
reviewed, the model is more likely to use the political patronage, administrative
labyrinth and lack of punishment as the determinants of corruption. As for the
country analysis, the political will, focus group and task forces are the useful
tools.
19
References
20
Huntington, S. P. (1968) "Modernization and Corruption." Yale University Press.
Johnston, B. F. (1984) "The world food equation: Interrelations among
development, employment, and food consumption." Journal of Economic
Literature 22, no. 2: 531-574.
Johnston, M. (1979) "Patrons and Clients, Jobs and Machines: A Case Study of
the Uses of Patronage." American Political Science Review 73, no. 2:
385–98.
Kaufman, D., and Jeffry Sachs. (1998) Determinants of Corruption. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press.
Kaufman, D., Sanjay Pradhan, and Randi Ryterman. (1998) "New Frontiers in
Anti Corruption Empirical Diagnostics." World Bank.
Kaufman, D. a. I. J. (1999) "The Forgotten Rationale for Policy Reform: The
Productivity of Investment Projects." Quarterly Journal of Economics
CXIV: 149-84.
Klaveren, J. v. (1957) "The Concept of Corruption." ierteljahresschrift für Sozial
und Wirtschaftgeschichte 44, no. 4: 44.
Klitgaard, R. (1987) Controlling corruption. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
Klitgaard, R. (1998) "International Cooperation against corruption." Finance and
Development: 3-6.
Lambsdorff, G. (1999) "Corruption in Empirical Research — A Review."
November.
Leff, N. H. (1964) "Economic Development Through Bureaucratic Corruption."
American Behavioural Scientist VIII, no. 3: 8-14.
Leibenstein, H. (1966) "Allocative Efficiency vs. X-Efficiency." The American
Economic Review LVI: 392-415.
Leibenstein, H. (1973) "Competition and X-Efficiency: Reply." Journal of Political
Economy LXXXI: 765-77.
Lewis, A. (1955) The Theory of Economic Growth: Routledge.
Lipset, S. M. a. G. S. L. (1999) Corruption, culture, and markets. Arlington, pp.
24.
Manchin, R. (2000) ASSESSMENT OF THE STATUS OF CORRUPTION:
Discovering a hidden society phenomenon, ed. R. Manchin. Istanbul,
Hungarian Gallup Institute.
Mankiw, N. G. (2000) Principles of Economics. 2. Edition Ed: Harcourt College
Publishers: Fort Worth.
Mauro, P. (1995) "Corruption and Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:
618-712.
Mauro, P. (1998) "Corruption and the Composition of Government Expenditures."
Journal of Public Economic, no. 69: 263-279.
Mauro, P. "The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government
Expenditure: A Cross–Country Analysis." Institute for International
Economics.
Miller, S. (2005) Civil Society, Religion & Global Governance: Paradigms of
Power & Persuasion. Canberra Australia.
21
Morgan, T. (1964) "The Theory of Error in Centrally-Directed Economic
Systems." Quarterly Journal of Economics LXXVIII, no. 3: 395-419.
Nye, J. (1967) "Corruption and Political Development: A Cost-Benefit Analysis."
American Political Science Review 61, no. 2: 417-27.
Ramey, R. a. (1995) "Cross Country Evidence on the Link between Volatility and
Growth." American Economic Review, no. 85: 1138-1151.
Rogerson, R. (2001) "Structural Transformation and Cross-Country Income
Differences." Arizona State University, December.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999) Corruption and Government: Causes,
Consequences, and Reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978) Corruption: a study in political economy. New York:
Academic Press.
Sandholtz, W. a. W. K. (2000) "Accounting for corruption: economic structure,
democracy, and trade." International Studies Quarterly 44: 31-50.
Sik, E. (1999) Some thoughts about the sociology of corruption from an East-
European perspective. Budapest, Princeton University, pp. 10-24.
Solow, R. (1956) "A Contribution to the theory of Economic Growth." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 70: 65-94.
Stasavage, D. a. D. (1998) "Determinants of Customs Fraud and Corruption:
Evidence from Two African Countries." OECD Development Centre,
August.
Stiglitz, E., William, and Roumeen Islam. (2000) "Shaken and Stirred, Explain
Growth Volatility." Annual World Bank Series of Development Economics.
Treisman, D. (2000) "The causes of corruption: a cross-national study." Journal
of Public Economics 76: 399-57.
Vittal, N. (1999) Applying Zero Tolerance to Corruption.
Wei, S. (2000) "Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows, and Currency Crisis."
NBER Working Paper.
Wei, S. (1997) "Why is Corruption So Much More Taxing Than Tax? Arbitrariness
Kills." NBER Working Paper, November.
World-Bank. (1997) "Helping Developing Countries Combat Corruption: The Role
of the World Bank." Oxford University Press.
22