0% found this document useful (0 votes)
36 views5 pages

Application Analysis On Internal Rate of Return Rule For Investment Decision

Uploaded by

Andro Hutabarat
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
36 views5 pages

Application Analysis On Internal Rate of Return Rule For Investment Decision

Uploaded by

Andro Hutabarat
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 5

International Conference on Humanity, Education and Social Science (ICHESS 2016)

Application Analysis on Internal Rate of Return Rule for Investment


Decision

Liyang Jiang1,a
1
School of Business management, Tonghua Normal University, Tonghua 134002, China.
a
dbcy9999@163.com

Keywords: net present value rule, capital budgeting decisions, internal rate of return, cash,
investment decision.

Abstract. The net present value (NPV) rule is not the only criterion available to evaluate a capital
investment proposal. You may be familiar with the payback period, the internal rate of return, or
another criterion. This paper examines and explains how to apply to the NPV rule: the
internal-rate-of-return (IRR) rule, the criteria used by a large sample of companies when making
capital budgeting decisions, with the IRR rules being the most popular and the average accounting
return and PI rules being the least popular. We analyze whether the internal-rate-of-return (IRR) rule
satisfy the conditions of a good investment decision rule. Recall that a good investment decision rule
must take into account the timing of a project’s expected cash flows and the project’s risk. In addition,
it should select projects that increase the market value of the firm’s equity. In our analysis of the
alternative rules, we identify a number of cases in which the methods lead to a decision that
contradicts the NPV rule. We explain why these conflicts occur and why some firms still use some of
these techniques to screen investment proposals. We use the projects to illustrate how the alternatives
to the NPV rule are usually applied in making investment decisions and compare their performance
with that of the NPV rule. .

Introduction
The steps involved in applying the NPV [1-3] rule to evaluate an investment proposal are summarized
in this paper. Tow inputs are required to calculate a project's NPV: (1) the expected cash-flow stream
that the project will generate over its useful life and (2) the appropriate cost of capital that reflects the
risk of the expected cash-flows. The cost of capital is the rate at which the project's future cash flows
need to be discounted to compare their present value with the investment cost.
That a good investment decision rule must take into account the timing of a project’s expected
cash flows and the project’s risk. In addition, it should select projects that increase the market value
of the firm’s equity A project’s payback period is the number of periods (usually measured in years)
required for the sum of the project’s expected cash flows to equal its initial cash outlay. In other
words, the payback period is the time it takes for a firm to recover its initial investment. Consider
investment A, whose characteristics are reported in Table 1 and whose expected and cumulative cash
flows are shown in Table 2. The investment’s payback period is the length of time it takes for the firm
to get back its initial cash outlay of $1 million.
Table 1 EXPECTED CASH-FLOW STREAMS, COST OF CAPITAL, AND NET PRESENT
VALUES OF ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENT PROPOSALS (ALL INVESTMENTS ARE FIVE
YEARS LONG AND REQUIRE AN INITIAL CASH OUTLAY OF $1 MILLION)
Investments E and F
End-of-Year Investment E Investment F
1 $ 325,000 $ 325,000
2 325,000 325,000
3 325,000 325,000
4 325,000 325,000
5 325,000 925,000
Total cash flows $1,625,000 $2,275,000
Cost of capital 10% 10%
NPV $ 232,006 $ 635,605

© 2016. The authors - Published by Atlantis Press 497


Table 2 EXPECTED CASH-FLOW S FROM Table 1
End-of-Year Expected Cash Flows Cumulative Cash Flows
1 $ 600,000 $ 600,000
2 $ 300,000 $ 900,000
3 $ 100,000 $ 1000,000
4 $ 200,000 $1200,000
5 $300,000 $1500,000

A project’s internal rate of return (IRR) is the discount rate that makes the NPV [1-3] of the
project equal to zero. For example, to compute the IRR of investment E and F, we set NPV (E and F)
equal to zero and find the discount rate that satisfies this condition. That rate is the investment’s IRR:
Unfortunately, there is no simple way to compute the IRR of a cash-flow stream except for the
trivial case in which the project is a one-period investment or an annuity.
All that is needed to calculate the IRR of an investment is the sequence of cash flows the
investment is expected to generate. In effect, an investment’s IRR summarizes its expected cash-flow
stream with a single rate of return. The rate is called internal because it considers only the expected
cash flows related to the investment and does not depend on rates that can be earned on alternative
investments.

The IRR Rule


Consider investment A. Its IRR is 19.05 percent, and its opportunity cost of capital [4-5] is 10 percent.
Recall that investment A’s opportunity cost of capital is the highest return a firm can get on an
alternative investment with the same risk as A. Should the firm accept investment A? Yes, because
the project’s IRR (19.05 percent) is greater than the highest return the firm can get on another
investment with the same risk (the 10 percent opportunity cost of capital).
Table 3 IRR FOR THE SIX INVESTMENTS IN Table 1.
Investment E F
Internal rate of return 18.7 28.5
2 2
% %

According to the internal rate of return rule, an investment should be accepted if its IRR is higher
than its cost of capital and should be rejected if its IRR is lower. If the investment’s IRR is equal to
the cost of capital, the firm should be indifferent about accepting or rejecting the project. A project’s
IRR can be interpreted as a measure of the profitability of its expected cash flow before considering
the project’s cost of capital. Thus, if a project’s IRR is lower than its cost of capital, the project does
not earn its cost of capital and should be rejected. If it is higher, the project earns more than its cost of
capital and should be accepted. When used in comparison with the IRR, the investment’s opportunity
cost of capital is usually referred to as the hurdle rate, the minimum required rate of return, or, simply,
the investment’s required return. In other words, if a project’s IRR is lower than its required return, it
should be rejected; if it is higher, it should be accepted.

Dose the IRR Rule maximize the firm’s equity value?


A project’s IRR is determined by setting its NPV equal to zero, so we would expect a project’s NPV
to be related to its IRR. To illustrate, we compute the NPV of investment E for various discount rates,
as shown in Table 4.
Table 4 NET PRESENT VALUE OF INVESTMENT E FOR VARIOUS DISCOUNT RATES.
Discount Rate 0% 5% 10%
NPV(E) $625,000 $407,080 $232,006
15% 20% 25% 30%
$89,450 −$28,05 −$125,98 −$208,44
0 4 0
From the figures in Table 4, we can draw a graph that shows the changes in NPV (E) as the
discount rate varies. The graph, known as the project’s NPV profile, is shown in Fig.1 NPV (E) is on
498
the vertical axis and the discount rate is on the horizontal axis. The graph shows an inverse
relationship between NPV (E) and the discount rate. As the discount rate increases, NPV (E)
decreases because its expected cash flows are discounted at increasingly higher rates. The NPV curve
intersects the horizontal axis at the point at which NPV (E) is equal to zero. At this point, the discount
rate used to calculate the NPV of investment E must be equal to the IRR of investment E because the
IRR is the discount rate at which the NPV is equal to zero. This discount rate is 18.72 percent (see
Fig.1).

Fig. 1 The NPV Profile of Investment E. Fig. 2 The NPV Profile of Investment E AND H.

According to the IRR rule, investment E should be accepted if its cost of capital is lower than its
IRR of 18.72 percent and should be rejected if its cost of capital is higher. The graph indicates that for
discount rates (or costs of capital) lower than 18.72 percent, the project’s NPV is positive, and for
discount rates higher than 18.72 percent, the project’s NPV is negative. In other words, the graph
indicates that when the NPV is positive, the IRR is higher than the cost of capital, and when it is
negative, the IRR is lower than the cost of capital. The two rules are thus equivalent. And because the
NPV rule is consistent with the maximization of the firm’s equity value, so is the IRR rule.

The IRR Rule may be unreliable


The IRR rule may sometimes provide the incorrect investment decision [6-7] when (1) the firm is
reviewing two mutually exclusive investments (the firm cannot invest in both; if it accepts one, it
must reject the other), and (2) the project’s cash-flow stream changes signs more than once (the
sequence of future cash flows contains at least one negative cash flow after a positive one).

The case of mutually exclusive investments


When two projects are mutually exclusive, the IRR rule and the NPV rule [8] may, under certain
circumstances, select different investment proposals. They have the same useful life (five years), the
same initial cash outlay ($1 million), and the same cost of capital (10 percent). Investment E has an
IRR of 18.72 percent, and investment H has an IRR of 16.59 percent (see Fig.2). Both investments
have an IRR that exceeds the cost of capital of 10 percent, so they should both be accepted according
to the IRR rule. However, the investments are mutually exclusive, so the firm can accept only one.
Which should it select? Intuition suggests the selection of investment E because it has a higher IRR
than investment H. Unfortunately, intuition does not always lead to the correct decision. According to
the NPV rule, investment H is preferable to investment E: at a cost of capital of 10 percent, the NPV
of investment H is $282,519, whereas that of investment E is only $232,006. The NPV profiles of
investments E and H in Exhibit 7.15 show why the IRR and NPV rules disagree. The graph indicates
that both the NPV and IRR rules favor investment E when the discount rate is higher than 12.94
percent (the rate at which the two NPV curves intersect) and lower than 18.72 percent. For rates
above 18.72 percent, the two projects should be rejected; both have a negative NPV and a discount
rate higher than the IRR. For rates lower than 12.94 percent, the NPV rule favors investment H, but
the IRR rule still favors investment E (it has a higher IRR than H). This situation usually arises when
the cash-flow patterns of two mutually exclusive investments differ widely, as in the case of
investments E and H. Investment E’s cash flows are evenly distributed during the project’s life,

499
whereas those of H are concentrated in the last year of the project’s life. At high discount rates, the
discounting effect (the “shrinking” of cash flows resulting from discounting) on distant cash flows is
more pronounced than when the rate is low. As a consequence, when the discount rate increases, the
NPV of the investment with cash flows concentrated at the end of the project’s life (such as
investment H) decreases more rapidly than the NPV of the investment whose cash flows arise earlier
(such as investment E). The two projects have the same NPV at the point at which their NPV curves
intersect. After that point, the NPV ranking of the two projects changes. With a cost of capital of 10
percent, project H is the better investment because its NPV is larger than that of project E, thus
creating more value to the firm’s owners. Because the IRR approach would lead to the opposite
choice, it would also have the opposite effect. In general, when a firm wants to rank projects
according to their contribution to the value of the firm’s equity, it should use the NPV rule rather than
the IRR rule.

The case of investments with some negative future cash flows


The IRR rule may be unreliable when a project’s stream of expected cash flows includes negative
cash flows. Negative cash flows can occur when an investment requires the construction of several
facilities that are built at different times in the future. During the year when a new unit is built, the
cash flow generated by the previously installed unit might not be large enough to cover the cost of the
new one. The result is that the project’s total cash flow for that year becomes negative. A project can
also have a negative future cash flow if the project’s termination requires a major capital expenditure,
such as for a strip-mining project. Closing the mine and restoring the area’s landscape at the end of
the project’s useful life may make the project’s terminal cash flow negative. When negative cash
flows occur, a project may have more than one IRR or none at all. We illustrate this phenomenon with
a two-year project that has a cost of capital of 20 percent and the pattern of expected cash flows
shown.
The project [9-10] has an IRR of 5 percent and an IRR of 40 percent. (If you check this, you will
find that the project’s NPV is zero at both 5 percent and 40 percent.) If the project has a cost of capital
of 20 percent, it should be rejected if its IRR is 5 percent and accepted if it’s IRR is 40 percent. The
choice is not obvious. What should the firm’s managers do in this case? They should ignore the IRR
rule and use the NPV rule instead. At a cost of capital of 20 percent, the project has a positive NPV of
$20,833 and should be undertaken.

Why do managers usually prefer the IRR Rule to the NPV Rule?
Despite its shortcomings, the IRR rule is popular among managers. One reason may be that the
calculation of a project’s IRR requires a single input, the cash-flow stream that the project is expected
to generate. An estimate of the project’s cost of capital is not necessary, whereas the calculation of a
project’s NPV requires estimates of both the expected cash-flow stream and the cost of capital.
However, the application of the IRR rule requires both inputs. To decide whether to invest, managers
must compare the project’s IRR to its cost of capital. Thus, even though the IRR can be computed
without knowing the project’s cost of capital, the cost of capital is still needed to decide whether to
undertake the project. If both methods require the same inputs to select projects, what is the
advantage of using the IRR rule? The advantage may be that it is easier to estimate a project’s IRR
than its NPV when the project’s cost of capital is uncertain (the computation of the IRR does not
require knowing the cost of capital). Then, the decision whether to accept or reject the project is made
after an appropriate required return is determined.
Our advice: a project’s NPV can be estimated with the same information required to apply the IRR
rule, so you should compute both. When both rules lead to the same recommendation, mention the
project’s IRR instead of its NPV. When the outcome of your analysis indicates a conflict between the
two methods, you should trust the NPV rule.

500
Summary
Our analysis of the alternatives to the net present value (NPV) rule has shown that the NPV rule is the
best criterion for selecting desirable investment proposals (projects that are expected to raise the
market value of a firm’s equity and, thereby, increase the wealth of the firm’s owners). This
conclusion does not imply that the alternative capital budgeting techniques presented in this paper
should be discarded. A project’s profitability index, internal rate of return, payback period, and
average accounting return may provide useful information to managers and are often easier to
interpret and communicate than the NPV. As Table 1shows, companies rarely rely on a single method
to screen investment proposals. Most firms using the NPV rule also use alternative decision criteria.
But this observation should not distract from the facts that all the alternatives to the NPV method
have some shortcomings and that some have serious weaknesses in assessing the value-creating
capacity of a project. We summarizes the properties of the IRR investment evaluation methods. Our
final recommendation: when alternative methods provide conflicting signals, the value-creating
manager should trust the NPV approach.

References
[1] Christian Gollier, Expected net present value, expected net future value, and the Ramsey rule,
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 59 (2010) 2142–2148.
[2] Tsu-Pang Hsieh, Chung-Yuan Dye, Liang-Yuh Ouyang, Determining optimal lot size for a
two-warehouse system with deterioration and shortages using net present value, European Journal of
Operational Research, 191 (2008) 182–192.
[3] Mario Rese, Markus Karger, Wolf-Christian Strotmann, The dynamics of Industrial Product
Service Systems (IPS2) – using the Net Present Value Approach and Real Options Approach to
improve life cycle management, CIRP Journal of Manufacturing Science and Technology, 1(2009)
279–286.
[4] Feroz Kabir Kazia, Joshua A. Fortmana, Robert P. Anexa, David D. Hsub, Andy Aden, Abhijit
Dutta, Geetha Kothandaraman, Techno-economic comparison of process technologies for
biochemical ethanol production from corn stove, Fuel, 189 (2010) S20–S28.
[5] Ming Yang, William Blyth, Richard Bradley, Derek Bunn, Charlie Clarke, Tom Wilson,
Evaluating the power investment options with uncertainty in climate policy, Energy Economics,
30(2008) 1933–1950.
[6] Bartł omiej Igliń ski, Roman Buczkowski, Anna Igliń ska, Marcin Cichosz, Grzegorz Piechota,
Wojciech Kujawski, Agricultural bio-gas plants in Poland: Investment process, economical and
environmental aspects, bio-gas potential, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 16 (2012)
4890–4900.
[7] Kaveh Khalili Damghani, Soheil Sadi-Nezhad, M.B. Aryanezhad, A modular Decision Support
System for optimum investment selection in presence of uncertainty: Combination of fuzzy
mathematical programming and fuzzy rule based system, Expert Systems with Applications, 38
(2011) 824-834.
[8] Peter Miller, Ted O’Leary, Mediating instruments and making markets: Capital budgeting,
science and the economy, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32 (2007) 701-734.
[9] Ethan Ilzetzki, Enrique G. Mendoza, Carlos A. Végh, How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers?
Journal of Monetary Economics, 60 (2013) 239-254.
[10] Matt Croucher, Potential problems and limitations of energy conservation and energy efficiency,
Energy Policy, 39(2011) 5795–5799.

501

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy