0% found this document useful (0 votes)
78 views14 pages

Chap 2 U2 A4 PLUS

This document discusses consumer behavior and the theory of demand and supply. It covers: 1) The classification of human wants into necessities, comforts, and luxuries. 2) The definition of utility as the anticipated satisfaction from consuming a good, and the distinction between total utility and marginal utility. 3) Marshall's theory of marginal utility analysis, including the law of diminishing marginal utility which states that the marginal utility of a good decreases as its consumption increases.

Uploaded by

lenovo lenovo
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
78 views14 pages

Chap 2 U2 A4 PLUS

This document discusses consumer behavior and the theory of demand and supply. It covers: 1) The classification of human wants into necessities, comforts, and luxuries. 2) The definition of utility as the anticipated satisfaction from consuming a good, and the distinction between total utility and marginal utility. 3) Marshall's theory of marginal utility analysis, including the law of diminishing marginal utility which states that the marginal utility of a good decreases as its consumption increases.

Uploaded by

lenovo lenovo
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 14

THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Chapter 2 :
UNIT 2: THEORY OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR

NATURE OF HUMAN WANTS


All desires, tastes and motives of human beings are
called wants in Economics. Wants may arise due to
elementary and psychological causes. Since the
resources are limited, we have to choose between the
urgent wants and the not so urgent wants.
All wants of human beings exhibit some characteristic
features.
1. Wants are unlimited in number. They are never
completely satisfied.
2. Wants differ in intensity. Some are urgent, others are
felt less intensely.
3. Each want is satiable.
4. Wants are competitive. They compete each other for satisfaction because resources are scarce tosatisfy
all wants.
5. Wants are complementary. Some wants can be satisfied only by using more than one good or group of
goods.
6. Wants are alternative.
7. Wants are subjective and relative.
8. Wants vary with time, place, and person.
9. Some wants recur again whereas others do not occur again and again.
10. Wants may become habits andcustoms.
11. Wants are affected by income, taste, fashion, advertisements and socialcustoms.
12. Wants arise from multiple causes such as natural instincts, social obligation and individual’s economic and
social status.
Classification of wants
In Economics, wants are classified into three categories, viz., necessaries, comforts and luxuries.

Necessaries
Necessaries are those which are essential for living. Necessaries are further sub-
divided into necessaries for life or existence, necessaries for efficiency and
conventional necessaries. Necessaries for life are things necessary to meet the
minimum physiological needs for the maintenance of life such as minimum
amount of food, clothing and shelter. Man requires something more than the
necessities of life to maintain longevity, energy and efficiency of work, such as
nourishing food, adequate clothing, clean water, comfortable dwelling, education,
recreation etc. These are necessaries for efficiency. Conventional necessaries arise
either due to pressure of habit or due to compelling social customs and
conventions. They are not necessary either for existence or for efficiency.
PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

Comforts
While necessaries make life possible comforts make life comfortable and satisfying. Comforts are less urgent
than necessaries. Tasty and wholesome food, good house, clothes that suit different occasions, audio-visual
and labour saving equipments etc .make life more comfortable.
Luxuries
Luxuries are those wants which are superfluous and expensive.
They are not essential for living. Items such as expensive clothing,
exclusive motor cars, classy furniture, goods used for vanity etc
fall under this category.
The above categorization is not rigid as a thing which is a comfort
or luxury for one person or at one point of time may become a
necessity for another person or at another point of time.
What is Utility?

The concept of utility is used in neo classical Economics to explain the operation of the law of demand. Utility
is the want satisfying power of a commodity. It is the expected satisfaction to a consumer when he is willing
to spend money on a stock of commodity which has the capacity to satisfy his want. Utility is the anticipated
satisfaction by the consumer, and satisfaction is the actual satisfaction derived.
A commodity has utility for a consumer even when it is not consumed .It is a subjective entity and varies from
person to person. A commodity has different utility for the same person at different places or at different
points of time. It should be noted that utility is not the same thing as usefulness. From the economic
standpoint, even harmful things like liquor, may be said to have utility because people want them. Thus, in
Economics, the concept of utility is ethically neutral.
Utility hypothesis forms the basis of the theory of consumer behaviour. From time to time, different theories
have been advanced to
explain consumer
behaviour and thus to
explain his demand for the
product. Two important
theories are (i) Marginal
Utility Analysis
propounded by Marshall,
and (ii) Indifference Curve
Analysis propounded by
Hicks and Allen.

MARGINAL UTILITY ANALYSIS


This theory which is formulated by Alfred Marshall, a British economist, seeks to explain how a consumer
spends his income on different goods and services so as to attain maximum satisfaction. This theory is based
on certain assumptions. But before stating the assumptions, let us understand the meaning of total utility and
marginal utility.
Total utility: Assuming that utility is measurable and additive, total utility may be defined as the sum of
utility derived from different units of a commodity consumed by a consumer. Total utility is the sum of
marginal utilities derived from the consumption of different units i.e.
TU= MU1+MU2+... +MUn
Where MU1, MU2,. ,MUn etc are marginal utilities of the successive units of a commodity.

Marginal utility: It is the addition made to total utility by the consumption of an additional unit of a
commodity. In other words, it is the utility derived from the marginal or one additional unit consumed or
possessed by the individual.
THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Marginal utility = the addition made to the total utility by the addition of consumption of one more unit of a
commodity.

Assumptions of Marginal Utility Analysis


(1) Rationality: A consumer is rational and attempts to attain maximum satisfaction from his limited money
income.
(2) Cardinal Measurability of Utility: According to neoclassical economists, utility is a cardinal concept i.e.,
utility is a measurable and quantifiable entity. It implies that utility can be measured in cardinal numbers
and assigned a cardinal number like 1, 2, 3 etc. Marshall and some other economists used a psychological
unit of measurement of utility called utils. Thus, a person can say that he derives utility equal to 10 utils
from the consumption of 1 unit of commodity A and 5 from the consumption of 1 unit of commodity B.
According to this theory, money is the measuring rod of utility. The amount of money which a person is
prepared to pay for a unit of a good, rather than go without it, is a measure of the utility which he
derives from the good.
(3) Constancy of the Marginal Utility of Money: The marginal utility of money remains constant
throughout when the individual is spending money on a good. This assumption, although not realistic,
has been made in order to facilitate the measurement of utility of commodities in terms of money.
(4) The Hypothesis of Independent Utility: The total utility which a person gets from the whole collection of
goods purchased by him is simply the sum total of the separate utilities of the goods. The theory
ignores complementarity between goods.

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility


One of the important laws under Marginal Utility analysis is the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility.
The law of diminishing marginal utility is based on an important fact that while total wants of a person are
virtually unlimited, each single want is satiable i.e., each want is capable of being satisfied. Since each want is
satiable, as a consumer consumes more and more units of a good, the intensity of his want for the good
goes on decreasing and a point is reached where the consumer no longer wants it. Thus, the greater the
amount of a good a consumer has, the less an additional unit is worth to him or her.
Marshall who was the exponent of the marginal utility analysis, stated the law as follows:
“The additional benefit which a person derives from a given increase in the stock of a thing
diminishes with every increase in the stock that he already has.”
In other words, as a consumer increases the consumption of any one commodity keeping constant the
consumption of all other commodities, the marginal utility of the variable commodity must eventually decline.
This law describes a very fundamental tendency of human nature.

Table 6: Total and marginal utility schedule


Quantity of chocolate bar Total utility Marginal
consumed utility
1 30 30
2 50 20
3 65 15
4 75 10
5 83 8
6 89 6
7 93 4
8 96 3
9 98 2
10 98 0
11 94 –4
PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

Let us illustrate the law with the help of an example. Consider Table 6, in which we have presented the total
utility and marginal utility derived by a person from the chocolate bars consumed. When one chocolate
bar is consumed, the total utility derived by the person is 30 utils (unit of utility) and the marginal utility
derived is also 30 utils. With the consumption of 2nd chocolate bar, the total utility rises to 50 but marginal
utility falls to 20. We see that till the consumption of chocolate bars increases to 9, the marginal utility from
the additional chocolate bars goes on diminishing (i.e., the total utility goes on increasing at a diminishing
rate). The 10th chocolate bar adds no utility and therefore, the total utility remains the same at 98. However,
when the chocolate bars consumed increases to 11, instead of giving positive marginal utility, the eleventh
chocolate bar gives negative marginal utility or disutility as it may cause him discomfort.
From Table 6, we can conclude the following important relationships between total utility and marginal utility
1. Total utility rises as long as MU is positive, but at a diminishing rate because MU is diminishing.
2. Marginal utility diminishes throughout.
3. When marginal utility is zero, total utility is maximum. It is a saturationpoint.
4. When marginal utility is negative, total utility is diminishing.
Graphically we can represent the relationship between total utility and marginal utility (fig. 11).

Fig. 11: Marginal utility of chocolates consumed


As will be seen from the figure, the marginal utility curve goes on declining throughout. The diminishing
marginal utility curve applies to almost all commodities. A few exceptions however, have been pointed out
by some economists. According to them, this law does not apply to money, music and hobbies. While this
may be true in initial stages, beyond a certain limit these will also be subjected to diminishing utility.
The Law of diminishing marginal utility helps us to understand how a consumer reaches equilibrium in case of
a single good. It states that as the quantity of a good with the consumer increases, marginal utility of the
good decreases. In other words, the marginal utility curve is downward sloping. Now, a consumer will go on
buying a good till the marginal utility of the good becomes equal to the market price. In other words, the
consumer will be in equilibrium (will be deriving maximum satisfaction) in respect of the quantity of the good
when marginal utility of the good is equal to its price. Here his satisfaction will be maximum.
In reality, a consumer spends his income on more than one good. In such cases, consumer equilibrium is
explained with the law of Equi-Marginal utility. According to this, the consumer will be in equilibrium when
he is spending his money on goods and services in such a way that the marginal utility of each good is
proportional to its price and the last rupee spent on each commodity yields him equal marginal utility.
The law states that the consumer is said to be at equilibrium, when the following condition is met:
(MUX/PX) = (MUY/PY) or (MUx / MUY) = (Px /PY)

Limitations of the Law


The law of diminishing marginal utility is applicable only under certain assumptions.
(i) Homogenous units: The different units consumed should be identical in all respects. The habit, taste,
temperament and income of the consumer also should remain unchanged.
THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

(ii) Standard units of Consumption: The different units consumed should consist of standard units. If a
thirsty man is given water by successive spoon full, the utility of the second spoonful of water may
conceivably be greater than the utility of the first.
(iii) Continuous Consumption: There should be no time gap or interval between the consumption of one
unit and another unit i.e. there should be continuous consumption.
(iv) The Law fails in the case of prestigious goods: The law may not apply to articles like gold, cash,
diamonds etc. where a greater quantity may increase the utility rather than diminish it. It also fails to
apply in the case of hobbies, alcohol, cigarettes, rare collections etc.
(v) Case of related goods: Utility is not in fact independent. The shape of the utility curve may be affected by
the presence or absence of articles which are substitutes or complements. The utility obtained from tea
may be seriously affected if no sugar is available and the utility of bottled soft drinks will be affected by
the availability of fresh juice.
Based on unrealistic assumptions: The assumptions of cardinal measurability of utility, constancy of
marginal utility of money, continuous consumption and consumer rationality are unrealistic.

Consumer’s Surplus
The concept of consumer’s surplus was propounded by Alfred Marshall.
This concept occupies an important place in economic policies of
government and in decision-making of monopolists.
If a consumer gets more utility from a commodity, he would be willing to
pay a higher price and vice-versa. It has been seen that consumers
generally are ready to pay more for certain goods than what they
actually pay for them. This extra satisfaction which consumers get from
their purchase of a good is called by Marshall as consumer’s surplus.
Marshall defined the concept of consumer’s surplus as the “excess of
the price which a consumer would be willing to pay rather than go
without a thing over that which he actually does pay”, is called
consumer’s surplus.”
Thus consumer’s surplus = what a consumer is ready to pay - what he actually pays.

The concept of consumer’s surplus is derived from the law of diminishing marginal utility. As we purchase
more of a good, its marginal utility goes on diminishing. The consumer is in equilibrium when the marginal
utility of a good is equal to its price i.e., he purchases that many number of units of a good at which
marginal utility is equal to price (It is assumed that perfect competition prevails in the market). Since the
price is the same for all units of the good he purchases, he gets extra utility for all units consumed by him
except for the one at the margin. This extra utility or extra surplus for the consumer is called consumer’s
surplus.
Consider Table 7 in which we have illustrated the measurement of consumer’s surplus in case of
commodity
X. The price of X is assumed to be ` 20.
Tab 7: Measurement of Consumer’s Surplus

No. of units Marginal Utility (worth ) Price (`) Consumer’s Surplus


1 30 20 10
2 28 20 8
3 26 20 6
4 24 20 4
5 22 20 2
6 20 20 0
7 18 20 –
PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

We see from the above table that when consumer’s consumption increases from 1 to 2 units, his
marginal utility falls from ` 30 to ` 28. His marginal utility goes on diminishing as he increases his
consumption of good X. Since marginal utility for a unit of good indicates the price the consumer is willing to
pay for that unit, and since price is assumed to be fixed at ` 20, the consumer enjoys a surplus on every unit
of purchase till the 6th unit. Thus, when the consumer is purchasing 1 unit of X, the marginal utility is
worth ` 30 and price fixed is ` 20, thus he is deriving a surplus of ` 10. Similarly, when he purchases 2 units
of X, he enjoys a surplus of ` 8 [` 28 – ` 20]. This continues and he enjoys consumer’s surplus equal to ` 6, 4,
2 respectively from 3rd, 4th and 5th unit. When he buys 6 units, he is in equilibrium because his marginal
utility is equal to the market price or he is willing to pay a sum equal to the actual market price and therefore,
he enjoys no surplus. Thus, given the price of ` 20 per unit, the total surplus which the consumer will get, is `
10 + 8 + 6 + 4 + 2 + 0 = 30.

The concept of consumer’s surplus can also be illustrated graphically. Consider figure 12. On the X-axis we
measure the amount of the commodity and on the Y-axis the marginal utility and the price of the commodity.
MU is the marginal utility curve which slopes downwards, indicating that as the consumer buys more units of
the commodity, its marginal utility falls. Marginal utility shows the price which a person is willing to pay for the
different units rather than go without them. If OP is the price that prevails in the market, then the consumer
will be in equilibrium when he buys OQ units of the commodity, since at OQ units, marginal utility is equal to
the given price OP. The last unit, i.e., Qth unit does not yield any consumer’s surplus because here price paid is
equal to the marginal utility of the Qth unit. But for units before Qth unit, marginal utility is greater than price
and thus these units fetch consumer’s surplus to the consumer.

Fig. 12: Marshall’s Measure of Consumer’s Surplus

In Figure 12, the total utility is equal to the area under the marginal utility curve up to point Q i.e. ODRQ. But,
given the price equal to OP, the consumer actually pays OPRQ. The consumer derives extra utility equal to DPR
which is nothing but consumer’s surplus.
Limitations:

It is often argued that this concept is hypothetical and illusory. The surplus satisfaction cannot be measured
precisely.
(1) Consumer’s surplus cannot be measured precisely - because it is difficult to measure the marginal utilities
of different units of a commodity consumed by a person.
(2) In the case of necessaries, the marginal utilities of the earlier units are infinitely large. In such case the
consumer’s surplus is always infinite.
(3) The consumer’s surplus derived from a commodity is affected by the availability of substitutes.
(4) There is no simple rule for deriving the utility scale of articles which are used for their prestige value (e.g.,
diamonds).
(5) Consumer’s surplus cannot be measured in terms of money because the marginal utility of money changes
THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

as purchases are made and the consumer’s stock of money diminishes. (Marshall assumed that the
marginal utility of money remains constant. But this assumption is unrealistic).
(6) The concept can be accepted only if it is assumed that utility can be measured in terms of money or
otherwise. Many modern economists believe that this cannot be done.
The concept of consumer surplus has important practical applications. Few such applications are listed below:
 Consumer surplus is a measure of the welfare that people gain from consuming goods and services. It is
very important to a business firm to reflect on the amount of consumer surplus enjoyed by different
segments of their customers because consumers who perceive large surplus are more likely to repeat their
purchases.
 Understanding the nature and extent of surplus can help business managers make better decisions about
setting prices. If a business can identify groups of consumers with different elasticity of demand within
their market and the market segments which are willing and able to pay higher prices for the same
products, then firms can profitably use price discrimination.
 Large scale investment decisions involve cost benefit analysis which takes into account the extent of
consumer surplus which the projects may fetch.
 Knowledge of consumer surplus is also important when a firm considers raising its product prices
Customers who enjoyed only a small amount of surplus may no longer be willing to buy products at higher
prices. Firms making such decisions should expect to make fewer sales if they increase prices.
 Consumer surplus usually acts as a guide to finance ministers when they decide on the products on which
taxes have to be imposed and the extent to which a commodity tax has to be raised. It is always desirable
to impose taxes or increase the rates of taxes on commodities yielding high consumer’s surplus because
the loss of welfare to citizens will be minimal.

INDIFFERENCE CURVE ANALYSIS


In the last section, we have discussed the marginal utility analysis of demand. A very popular alternative and a
more realistic method of explaining consumer’s demand is the ordinal utility approach used a different tool
namely indifference curve to analyse consumer behaviour. This approach to consumer behaviour is based on
consumer preferences. It believes that human satisfaction, being a psychological phenomenon, cannot be
measured quantitatively in monetary terms as was attempted in Marshall’s utility analysis. In this approach, it
is felt that it is much easier and scientifically more sound to order preferences than to measure them in terms
of money.

The consumer preference approach is, therefore, an ordinal concept based on ordering of preferences
compared with Marshall’s approach of cardinality.
Assumptions Underlying Indifference Curve Approach
(i) The consumer is rational and possesses full information about all the relevant aspects of economic
environment in which he lives.
(ii) The indifference curve analysis assumes that utility is only ordinally expressible. The consumer is capable
of ranking all conceivable combinations of goods according to the satisfaction they yield. Thus, if he is
given various combinations say A, B, C, D and E, he can rank them as first preference, second preference
and so on. However, if a consumer happens to prefer A to B, he cannot tell quantitatively how much he
prefers A to B.
(iii) Consumer’s choices are assumed to be transitive. If the consumer prefers combination A to B, and B to C,
then he must prefer combination A to C. In other words, he has a consistent consumption pattern.
(iv) If combination A has more commodities than combination B, then A must be preferred to B.
PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

Indifference Curves
What are Indifference Curves? The ordinal analysis of demand (here we will discuss the one given by Hicks
and Allen) is based on indifference curves. An indifference curve is a curve which represents all those
combinations of two goods which give same satisfaction to the consumer. Since all the combinations
on an indifference curve give equal satisfaction to the consumer, the consumer is indifferent among
them.

If a consumer equally prefers two product bundles, then the consumer is indifferent between the two
bundles. An Indifference curve is also called iso- utility curve or equal utility curve.

Asking the consumer further how much of clothing he will be prepared to forgo for successive
increments in his stock of food so that his level of satisfaction remains unaltered, we get various
combinations as given below:

Table 8: Indifference Schedule

Combination Food Clothing MRS


A 1 12
B 2 6 6
C 3 4 2
D 4 3 1

In Figure 13, an indifference curve IC is drawn by plotting the various combinations given in the indifference
schedule. The quantity of food is measured on the X axis and the quantity of clothing on theY axis.

Fig. 13: A Consumer’s Indifference Curve

Indifference Map

An Indifference map represents a collection of many indifference curves where each curve represents a
certain level of satisfaction. In short, a set of indifference curves is called an indifference map.

An indifference map depicts the complete picture of consumer’s tastes and preferences. In Figure 14, an
indifference map of a consumer is shown which consists of three indifference curves.

We have taken good X on X-axis and good Y on Y-axis. It should be noted that while the consumer is indifferent
among the combinations lying on the same indifference curve, he certainly prefers the
combinations on the higher indifference curve to the combinations lying
on a lower indifference curve because a higher indifference curve signifies a higher
level of satisfaction. Thus, while all combinations of IC1 give him the same
satisfaction, all combinations lying on IC2 give him greater satisfaction than
those lying on IC1.
THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Fig. 14: Indifference Map

Marginal Rate of Substitution

Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a consumer is prepared to exchange goods X and
Y. Consider Table-8. In the beginning the consumer is consuming 1 unit of food and 12 units of clothing.
Subsequently, he gives up 6 units of clothing to get an extra unit of food, his level of satisfaction remaining the
same. The MRS here is 6. Likewise when he moves from B to C and from C to D in his indifference schedule, the
MRS are 2 and 1 respectively. Thus, we can define MRS of X for Y as the amount of Y whose loss can just be
compensated by a unit gain of X in such a manner that the level of satisfaction remains the same.
MUx
The marginal rate of substitution of X for Y (MRSxy) is equal to
MUy

We notice that MRS is falling i.e., as the consumer has more and more units of food, he is prepared to give
up less and less units of clothing. There are two reasons for this.
1. The want for a particular good is satiable so that when a consumer has more of it, his intensity of want for
it decreases. Thus, in our example, when the consumer has more units of food, his intensity of desire for
additional units of food decreases.
2. Most goods are imperfect substitutes of one another. MRS would remain constant if they could substitute
one another perfectly.
Properties of Indifference Curves
The following are the main characteristics or properties of indifference curves:
(i) Indifference curves slope downward to the right: This property implies that the two commodities can
be substituted for each other and when the amount of one good in the combination is increased, the
amount of the other good is reduced. This is essential if the level of satisfaction is to remain the same on
an indifference curve.
(ii) Indifference curves are always convex to the origin: It has been observed that as more and more of one
commodity (X) is substituted for another (Y), the consumer is willing to part with less and less of the
commodity being substituted (i.e. Y). This is called diminishing marginal rate of substitution. Thus, in our
example of food and clothing, as a consumer has more and more units of food, he is prepared to
forego less and less units of clothing. This happens mainly because the want for a particular good is
satiable and as a person has more and more of a good, his intensity of want for that good goes on
diminishing. In other words, the subjective value attached to the additional quantity of a commodity
decreases fast in relation to the other commodity whose total quantity is decreasing. This diminishing
marginal rate of substitution gives convex shape to the indifference curves. However, there are two
extreme situations. When two goods are perfect substitutes of each other, the indifference curve is a
straight line on which MRS is constant. And when two goods are perfect complementary goods (e.g.
printer and cartridge), the indifference curve will consist of two straight lines with a right angle bent
which is convex to the origin, or in other words, it will be L shaped.
PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

(iii) Indifference curves can never intersect each other: No two indifference curves will intersect each other
although it is not necessary that they are parallel to each other. In case of intersection the relationship
becomes logically absurd because it would show that higher and lower levels are equal, which is not
possible. This property will be clear from Figure15.

Fig. 15 : Intersecting Indifference Curves


(iv) A higher indifference curve represents a higher level of satisfaction than the lower indifference
curve: This is because combinations lying on a higher indifference curve contain more of either one or
both goods and more goods are preferred to less of them.
(v) Indifference curve will not touch either axes: Another characteristic feature of indifference curve is that it
will not touch the X axis or Y axis.

The Budget Line

A higher indifference curve shows a higher level of satisfaction than a lower one. Therefore, a consumer, in
his attempt to maximise satisfaction will try to reach the highest possible indifference curve. But in his pursuit
of buying more and more goods and thus obtaining more and more satisfaction, he has to work under two
constraints: first, he has to pay the prices for the goods and, second, he has a limited money income with
which to purchase the goods.
A consumer’s choices are limited by the budget available to him. As we know, his total expenditure for
goods and services can fall short of the budget constraint but may not exceed it.
Algebraically, we can write the budget constraint for two goods X and Y as:

PXQX + PYQY ≤ B

Where
PX and PY are the prices of goods X and Y and QX and QY are the quantities of goods X and Y chosen and B is the
total money available to the consumer.
THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

The budget constraint can be explained by the budget line or price line. In simple words, a budget line
shows all those combinations of two goods which the consumer can buy spending his given money income
on the two goods at their given prices. All those combinations which are within the reach of the consumer

(assuming that he spends all his money income) will lie on the budget line.

Fig. 17: Price Line

It should be noted that any point outside the given price line, say H, will be beyond the reach of the consumer
and any combination lying within the line, say K, shows under spending by the consumer.
This slope of budget line is equal to ‘Price Ratio’ of two goods. i.e. PX /PY

Consumer’s Equilibrium
Having explained indifference curves and budget line, we are in a position to explain how a consumer reaches
equilibrium position. A consumer is in equilibrium when he is deriving maximum possible satisfaction from
the goods and therefore is in no position to rearrange his purchases of goods. We assume that:
(i) Theconsumerhasagivenindifferencemapwhichshowshisscaleofpreferencesforvariouscombinations
of two goods X and Y.
(ii) He has a fixed money income which he has to spend wholly on goods X and Y.
(iii) Prices of goods X and Y are given and are fixed.
All goods are homogeneous and divisible, and The consumer acts ‘rationally’ and maximizes his
satisfaction.

Fig. 18: Consumer’s Equilibrium


PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

`To show which combination of two goods X and Y the consumer will buy to be in equilibrium we bring his
indifference map and budget linetogether.
We know by now, that the indifference map depicts the consumer’s
preference scale between various combinations of two goods and the
budget line shows various combinations which he can afford to buy
with his given money income and prices of the two goods. Consider
Figure 18, in which IC1, IC2, IC3, IC4 and IC5 are shown together with
budget line PL for good X and good Y. Every combination on the budget
line PL costs the same. Thus combinations R, S, Q, T and H cost the same
to the consumer. The consumer’s aim is to maximise his satisfaction and
for this, he will try to reach the highest indifference curve.
Since there is a budget constraint, he will be forced to remain on the given budget line, that is he will have
to choose combinations from among only those which lie on the given price line.
Which combination will our hypothetical consumer choose? Suppose he chooses R. We see that R lies on a
lower indifference curve IC1, when he can very well afford S, Q or T lying on higher indifference curves. Similar
is the case for other combinations on IC1, like H. Again, suppose he chooses combination S (or T) lying on
IC2. But here again we see that the consumer can still reach a higher level of satisfaction remaining within
his budget constraints i.e., he can afford to have combination Q lying on IC3 because it lies on his budget
line. Now, what if he chooses combination Q? We find that this is the best choice because this combination
lies not only on his budget line but also puts him on the highest possible indifference curve i.e., IC3. The
consumer can very well wish to reach IC4 or IC5, but these indifference curves are beyond his reach given his
money income. Thus, the consumer will be at equilibrium at point Q on IC3. What do we notice at point Q?
We notice that at this point, his budget line PL is tangent to the indifference curve IC3. In this equilibrium
position (at Q), the consumer will buy OM of X and ON of Y.
We have seen that the consumer attains equilibrium at the point where the budget line is tangent to the
indifference curve and
MUx / Px = MUy /Py
At the tangency point Q, the slopes of the price line PL and the indifference curve IC3 are equal.
Thus, we can say that the consumer is in equilibrium position when the price line is tangent to the indifference
curve or when the marginal rate of substitution of goods X and Y is equal to the ratio between the prices of
the two goods.
The indifference curve analysis is superior to utility analysis: (i) it dispenses with the assumption of
measurability of utility (ii) it studies more than one commodity at a time (iii) it does not assume constancy of
marginal utility of money (iv) it segregates income effect from substitution effect.

SYNOPSIS:
 Consumer surplus is the difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for a commodity
and what he actually pays forit.
 The indifference curve theory, which is an ordinal theory, shows the household’s preference
between alternative bundles of goods by means of indifference curves.
 Marginal rate of substitution is the rate at which the consumer is prepared to exchange goods X
and Y.
 The important properties of an Indifference curve are: Indifference curve slopes downwards to
the right, it is always convex to the origin, two ICs never intersect each other, it will never touch
the axes and higher the indifference curve higher is the level of satisfaction.
THEORY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY

 Budget line or price line shows all those combinations of two goods which the consumer can buy
spending his given money income on the two goods at their given prices.
 A consumer is said to be in equilibrium when he is deriving maximum possible satisfaction from
the goods and is in no position to rearrange his purchase of goods.
The consumer attains equilibrium at the point where the budget line is tangent to the indifference
curve and MUx / Px =MUy /Py = MUz /Pz

SELF-EVALUATION
1. If the demand for a good is inelastic, an increase in its price will cause the total expenditure of the
consumers of the good to:
(a) remain the same. (b) increase.
(c) decrease. (d) any of these.
2. All of the following are determinants of demand except:
(a) tastes and preferences. (b) quantity supplied.
(c) income of the consumer. (d) price of related goods.
3. If the quantity demanded of mutton increases by 5% when the price of chicken increases by 20%,
the cross-price elasticity of demand between mutton and chicken is :
(a) -0.25 (b) 0.25
(c) -4 (d) 4
4. When the numerical value of cross elasticity between two goods is very high, it means
a) The goods are perfect complements and therefore have to be used together.
b) The goods are perfect substitutes and can be used with ease in place of one another.
c) There is a high degree of substitutability between the two goods.
d) The goods are neutral and therefore cannot be considered as substitutes.
5. Demand for a good will tend to be more elastic if it exhibits which of the following characteristics?
a) It represents a small part of the consumer’s income.
b) The good has many substitutes available.
c) It is a necessity (as opposed to a luxury).
d) There is little time for the consumer to adjust to the price change.
6. What will happen in the rice market if buyers are expecting higher rice prices in the near future?
(a) The demand for rice will increase. (b) The demand for rice will decrease.
(c) The demand for rice will be unauected. (d) None of the above.
7. A vertical supply curve parallel to Y axis implies that the elasticity of supply is:
(a) Zero. (b) Infinity.
(c) Equal to one. (d) Greater than zero but less than infinity.
8. The supply of a good refers to:
(a) actual production of the good. (b) total existing stock of the good.
(c) stock available for sale.
(d) amount of the good ordered for sale at a particular price per unit of time
9. Potato chips and popcorn are substitutes. A rise in the price of potato chips will —————— the
demand for popcorn and the quantity of popcorn will ———————
(a) increase; increase (b) increase; decrease
PROF. AKHILESH DAGA

(c) decrease; decrease (d) decrease; increase


10. If the price of Orange Juice increases, the demand for Apple Juice will .
(a) increase (b) decrease
(c) remain the same. (d) become negative.

Answers:
1. (b) 2 (b) 3 (b) 4. (c) 5. (b)
6. (a) 7. (a) 8. (d) 9. (a) 10. (a)

Student Notes:
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________
__________________________________________________________________________________________

Let them sleep while you grind, let them party while you work. The
difference will show.
- Eric Thomas

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy