Conumer Behavior Old
Conumer Behavior Old
47
LEARNING OUTCOMES
♦ Describe the meaning of indifference curve and the price line and show how these help in explaining
consumer equilibrium.
13. Wants arise from multiple causes such as physical and psychological instincts, social obligations and
individual’s economic and social status
Utility hypothesis forms the basis of the theory of consumer behaviour. From time to time, different theories have
been advanced to explain consumer behaviour and thus to explain consumer’s demand for the product. Two
important theories are (i) Marginal Utility Analysis propounded by Alfred Marshall, and (ii) Indifference Curve Analysis
propounded by J.R. Hicks and R.G.D.Allen.
(1) Rationality: A consumer is rational and attempts to attain maximum satisfaction from his limited money
income.
(2) Cardinal Measurability of Utility: According to the neoclassical economists, utility is a cardinal concept
i.e., utility is a measurable and quantifiable entity. It implies that utility can be measured in cardinal numbers
and may be assigned a cardinal number like 1, 2, 3 etc. Marshall and some other economists used a
psychological unit of measurement of utility called utils.Thus, a person can say that he derives utility equal
to 10 utils from the consumption of 1 unit of commodity A and 5 from the consumption of 1 unit of
commodity B. Since a consumer can quantitatively express his utility, he can easily compare different
commodities and express which commodity gives him greater utility and by how much. Utilities from
different units of the commodity can be added as well.
(3) According to this theory, money is the measuring rod of utility. The amount of money which a person is
prepared to pay for a unit of a good, rather than go without it, is a measure of the utility which he derives
from the good.
(4) The theory also assumes all the other factors ‘constant’ such as price of the commodity, tastes and
preferences, income, habits, temperament and fashion. If any of these changes, the marginal utility may not
decline and thus the law would not hold true.
(5) The theory assumes continuity in consumption and that there is no time gap or interval between
consumption of different units.
(6) The different units of the commodity consumed are assumed to be homogeneous or identical in nature. If
the units show variation or differ in taste, quality or any such similar aspects, then the law may not hold true.
If successive units are of superior quality, diminishing utility may not occur.
(7) The different units consumed should consist of standard units. For instance spoonfuls of juice or spoonfuls
of coffee are too small units and in such cases we could consider the normal units as a glass of juice or a
cup of coffee. Moreover, the commodity which is consumed by the consumer should be divisible in nature.
(8) The assumption of constancy of the marginal utility of money holds that the marginal utility of money
remains constant throughout when the individual is spending money on a good. This assumption, although
not realistic, has been made in order to facilitate the measurement of utility of commodities in terms of
money. If the marginal utility of money changes as income changes, the measuring-rod of utility becomes
unstable and therefore would be inappropriate for measurement.
(9) The hypothesis of independent utility implies that the total utility which a person gets from the whole
collection of goods purchased by him is simply the sum total of the separate utilities of the goods. The
theory ignores complementarity between goods.
point is reached where the consumer no longer wants it. Thus, the greater the amount of a good a consumer has, the
less an additional unit is worth to him or her.
Marshall, who was the exponent of the marginal utility analysis, stated the law as follows:
“The additional benefit which a person derives from a given increase in the stock of a thing diminishes with every
increase in the stock that he already has.”In other words, ‘as a consumer increases the consumption of any one
commodity keeping constant the consumption of all other commodities, the marginal utility of the variable commodity
must eventually decline”.
This law describes a very fundamental tendency of human nature. In simple words, it says that as a consumer
consumes more units of a good, the extra satisfaction that he derives from an extra unit of a good goes on falling. It
is to be noted that it is the marginal utility and not the total utility which declines with the increase in the consumption
of a good.
We may illustrate the law with the help of an example. Consider Table 6, in which we have presented the total utility
and marginal utility derived by a person from chocolate bars consumed per day keeping constant all other factors
that affect utility.
Table 6 : Total and Marginal Utility Schedule
When one chocolate bar is consumed, the total utility derived by the person is 20 utils (unit of utility) and the marginal
utility derived is also 20 utils. With the consumption of 2nd chocolate bar, the total utility rises to 34 and the
corresponding marginal utility is14.With the second chocolate bar the consumer enjoys greater total utility: but the
extra utility derived from the second is smaller than that he derived from the first.
We see that till the consumption of chocolate bars increases to 4, the marginal utility from the additional chocolate
bars goes on diminishing (i.e., the total utility goes on increasing at a diminishing rate). The 5th chocolate bar adds
no utility and therefore, the total utility remains the same at 50. At this level of consumption, the consumer reaches
the ‘satiation’ point and gets no extra satisfaction or utility from consuming more of it. Once this point of satiation is
reached, the consumer would refuse any extra unit of chocolate even if it were free.
However, if the chocolate bars consumed increases to 6, instead of giving positive marginal utility, the sixth
chocolate bar gives negative marginal utility or disutility and it may cause him discomfort. We find that consuming the
6 th chocolate bar actually reduces the consumer’s total utility from 50 to 46.
From table 6, we find that for every one-unit increment in chocolate consumption, the marginal utility is equal to the
change in total utility. Total utility increases every time the consumer consumes more units of chocolate bar till he
reaches the point of satiation, but the additional utility he derives from each successive chocolate bar gets smaller
and smaller as he consumes more. Putting it differently, the rate at which total utility increases gets smaller and
smaller as consumption increases.
From Table 6, we also find that there are some well defined relationships between total utility and marginal utility.
(1) Total utility rises as long as MU is positive, but at a diminishing rate because MU is diminishing
(2) Marginal utility diminishes throughout
(3) When marginal utility is zero, the total utility is maximum. It is the satiation point.
(4) When marginal utility is negative, total utility is diminishing
(5) MU is the rate of change of total utility or it is the slope of TU curve
(6) MU can be positive ,zero or negative
The information in Table 6 above can be graphically presented to show the relationship between total utility and
marginal utility (Fig. 13).
The marginal utility curve shows how marginal utility depends on the quantity of a good or serviceconsumed. As can
be seen from the figure, the marginal utility curve goes on declining throughout.
The principle of diminishing marginal utility is not always true. A few exceptions however, have been pointed out by
some economists. But it is true in large majority of cases, so that it serves as a foundation for the analysis of
consumer behaviour.
the marginal utility of the good becomes equal to the market price. In other words, the consumer will be in equilibrium
(will be deriving maximum satisfaction) in respect of the quantity ofone good when marginal utility of that good is
equal to its price.
In figure 14 , the consumer is in equilibrium at point E with OQ quantity of commodity .We find that at point E, the
marginal utility of the good for the consumer is equal to its price.ie MUx= Px.
What happens when there is a change in the price of the good? The equality between marginal utility and price is
disturbed when the price of the good falls. The consumer will consume more of the good so as to restore the equality
between the marginal utility and price. The marginal utility from the good will fall when he consumes more of the
good. He will continue consuming more till the marginal utility becomes equal to the new lower price. On the other
hand, when price of the good increases, he will buy less so as to equate the marginal utility to the higher price. We
can say that the downward sloping demand curve is directly derived from the marginal utility curve.
Figure14 above illustrates this case. At price P the consumer is at equilibrium at E; MUX = P. When price falls to P1,
the consumer extend his consumption to reach E1 where his MUX = P1.
MUX
The marginal utility of money spent on X MU m = =1
PX
In reality, a consumer spends his income on more than one good. In such cases, consumer equilibrium is
explained with the law of Equi-Marginal utility. According to this law, the consumer will be in equilibrium when
he is spending his money on different goods and services in such a way that the marginal utility of each good is
proportional to its price and the last rupee spent on each commodity yields him equal marginal utility.
The law states that the consumer is said to be at equilibrium, when the following condition is met:
MUx MUy
= = MUM
Px Py
MUx P
Or = x = MUM pure paise khrch hone
MUy Py
chaiye
MUx Px
Or =
MUy Py
3 26 20 6
4 24 20 4
5 22 20 2
6 20 20 0
7 18 20 –
We see from the above table that when the consumer’s consumption increases from 1 to 2 units,
his marginal utility falls from 30 to 28. His marginal utility goes on diminishing as he increases his consumption of
good X. Since marginal utility for a unit of good indicates the price the consumer is willing to pay for that unit, and
since market price is assumed to be at Rs.20, the consumer enjoys a surplus on every unit of purchase till the 6th
unit. Thus, when the consumer is purchasing 1 unit of X, the marginal utility is worth Rs30 and price fixed is Rs 20,
thus he is deriving a surplus of ` 10. Similarly, when he purchases 2 units of X, he enjoys a surplus of 8 [28 – 20].
This continues and he enjoys consumer surplus equal to 6, 4, 2 respectively from 3rd, 4th and 5th unit. When he
buys 6 units, he is in equilibrium because his marginal utility is equal to the market price or he is willing to pay a sum
equal to the actual market price and therefore, he enjoys no surplus. Thus, given the price of Rs 20 per unit, the total
surplus which the consumer will get, is worth 10 + 8 + 6 + 4 + 2 + 0 = 30.
The concept of consumer surplus is closely related to the demand curve for a product. The demand curve reflects
buyer’s willingness to pay; we can also use it to measure consumer surplus. As we know, the height of the demand
curve measures the value buyers place on the good as measured by their willingness to pay for it. We have already
seen above that the difference between the willingness to pay and the market price is each buyer’s consumer
surplus. The difference between his willingness to pay and the price that he actually pays is the net gain to the con-
sumer, the individual consumer surplus.
The total consumer surplus in a market which is the sum of all individual consumer surpluses in a market, is equal to
the area below the market demand curve but above the price. The term consumer surplus is often used to refer to
both individual and total consumer surplus.
Thus, the total area below the demand curve and above the price is the sum of the consumer surplus of all buyers in
the market.
The concept of consumer surplus can be illustrated graphically. Consider figure 15. On the X-axis we measure the
amount of the commodity and on the Y-axis the marginal utility and the price of the commodity. MU is the marginal
utility curve which slopes downwards, indicating that as the consumer buys more units of the commodity, its marginal
utility falls. Marginal utility shows the price which a person is willing to pay for the different units rather than go
without them. If OP is the price that prevails in the market, then the consumer will be in equilibrium when he buys OQ
units of the commodity, since at OQ units, marginal utility is equal to the given price OP. The last unit, i.e., Qth unit
does not yield any consumer surplus because here price paid is equal to the marginal utility of the Qth unit. For all
units before the Qth unit, the marginal utility is greater than price and thus these units fetch consumer surplus to the
consumer.
actually
paid
(b) The consumer surplus now available to the new buyers who started buying the commodity due to lower
prices (the triangle c)
2.4.1 Applications
The concept of consumer surplus has important practical applications. Few such applications are listed below:
(1) Consumer surplus is a measure of the welfare that people gain from consuming goods and services. It is
very important to a business firm to reflect on the amount of consumer surplus enjoyed by different
segments of their customers because consumers who perceive large surplus are more likely to repeat their
purchases.
(2) Understanding the nature and extent of surplus can help business managers make better decisions about
setting prices. If a business can identify groups of consumers with different elasticity of demand within their
market and the market segments which are willing and able to pay higher prices for the same products, then
firms can profitably use price discrimination.
(3) Large scale investment decisions involve cost benefit analysis which takes into account the extent of
consumer surplus which the projects may fetch.
(4) Knowledge of consumer surplus is also important when a firm considers raising its product prices
Customers who enjoyed only a small amount of surplus may no longer be willing to buy products at higher
prices. Firms making such decisions should expect to make fewer sales if they increase prices.
(5) Consumer surplus usually acts as a guide to finance ministers when they decide on the products on which
taxes have to be imposed and the extent to which a commodity tax has to be raised. It is always desirable
to impose taxes or increase the rates of taxes on commodities yielding high consumer surplus because the
loss of welfare to citizens will be minimal.
2.4.2 Limitations
It is often argued that this concept of consumer surplus is hypothetical and illusory. In real life, the surplus
satisfaction cannot be measured accurately.
(1) Consumer surplus cannot be measured precisely - because it is difficult to measure the marginal utilities of
different units of a commodity consumed by a person.
(2) In the case of necessaries, the marginal utilities of the earlier units are infinitely large. In such case the
consumer surplus is always infinite.
(3) The consumer surplus derived from a commodity is affected by the availability of substitutes.
(4) There is no simple rule for deriving the utility scale of articles which are used for their prestige value (e.g.,
diamonds).
(5) Consumer surplus cannot be measured in terms of money because the marginal utility of money changes
as purchases are made and the consumer’s stock of money diminishes. (Marshall assumed that the
marginal utility of money remains constant. But this assumption is unrealistic).
(6) The concept can be accepted only if it is assumed that utility can be measured in terms of money or
otherwise. Many modern economists believe that this cannot be done.
will be prepared to forgo for successive increments in his stock of food so that his level of satisfaction remains
unaltered, we get various combinations as given in table 8:
Table 8 : Indifference Schedule
Now, if we plot the above schedule, we will get the following figure.
In Figure 17, an indifference curve IC is drawn by plotting the various combinations given in the indifference
schedule. The quantity of food is measured on the X axis and the quantity of clothing on the Y axis. As in indifference
schedule, the combinations lying on an indifference curve will give the consumer the same level of satisfaction.
signifies a higher level of satisfaction. Thus, while all combinations of IC1 give him the same satisfaction, all
combinations lying on IC2 give him greater satisfaction than those lying on IC1.
We notice that MRS is falling i.e., as the consumer has more and more units of food, the trade –off or rate of
substitution becomes smaller and smaller; i.e. he is prepared to give up less and less units of clothing.( Refer figure
19). When a consumer moves down his indifference curve, he gains utility from the consumption of additional units of
good X, but loses an equal amount of utility due to reduced consumption of Y. But at each step, the utility levels from
which the consumer begins is different. At point A in figure 19, the consumer consumes only a small quantity of food;
and therefore his marginal utility of food at that point is high. At A, then, an additional unit of food adds a lot to his
total utility. But at A he already consumes a large quantity of clothing; his marginal utility of clothing at that point is
low. This means that it takes a large reduction in the quantity of clothing consumed to counterbalance the increased
utility he gets from the extra unit of food.
On the contrary, consider point C. we find that the consumer consumes a much larger quantity of food and a much
smaller quantity of clothing than at point A. This means that an additional unit of food adds only lesser utility, and a
unit of clothing forgone costs more utility, than at point A. So the consumer is willing to give up less units of clothing
in return for another unit of food at C(he gives up only 2 units of clothing for 1unit of food, whereas he gives up 6
units of clothing at point A for one unit of food).
Moving down the indifference curve—reducing consumption of clothing and increasing food consumption—will
produce two opposing effects on the consumer’s total utility: reduction in total utility due to reduced consumption of
clothing, and increase in total utility due to higher food consumption. In order to keep the levels of satisfaction
constant, these two effects must exactly cancel out as the consumer moves down the indifference curve. The
principle of diminishing marginal rate of substitution thus states that the more of good Y a person consumes in
proportion to good X, the less Y he or she is willing to substitute for another unit of X.
There are two reasons for this.
1. The want for a particular good is satiable so that when a consumer has more of it, his intensity of want for it
decreases. Thus, in our example, when the consumer has more units of food, his intensity of desire for
additional units of food decreases.
2. Most goods are imperfect substitutes of one another. MRS would remain constant if they could substitute
one another perfectly.
We know that along the indifference curve:
(Change in total utility due to lower clothing consumption) = (Change in total utility due to higher food consumption)
Change in total utility due to a change in clothing consumption = MU c × ΔQ c
Change in total utility due to a change in food consumption = MUf × ΔQf
Therefore, along the indifference curve:−MUc × ΔQc = MUf × ΔQf
Note that the left-hand side of the equation has a minus sign as it represents the loss in total utility from decreased
clothing consumption. This must equal the gain in total utility from increased food consumption, represented by the
right-hand side of the equation. Along the indifference curve:
∆Qc – MUf
=
∆Qf MUc
To generalize, the marginal rate of substitution of X for Y (MRSxy) is the slope of the indifference curve.
MUx
MRS xy =
MUy
As the number of units of Y the consumer is willing to sacrifice gets lesser and lesser, the marginal rate of
substitution gets smaller and smaller as we move down and to the right along an indifference curve. That is, the
indifference curve becomes flatter (less sloped) as we move down and to the right.
one exra
cannot be
gain with
sacrifice
The consumer can arrive this choice moving down his budget line starting from point R .While doing this, he will pass
through a variety of indifference curves (To make the diagram simple, we have drawn only a few). Suppose he
chooses R. We see that R lies on a lower indifference curve IC1, when he can very well afford S, Q or T lying on
higher indifference curves. Similar is the case for other combinations on IC1, like H. Again, suppose he chooses
combination S (or T) lying on IC2. But here again we see that the consumer can still reach a higher level of
satisfaction remaining within his budget constraints i.e., he can afford to have combination Q lying on IC3 because it
lies on his budget line. Now, what if he chooses combination Q? We find that this is the best choice because this
combination lies not only on his budget line but also puts him on the highest possible indifference curve i.e., IC3. The
consumer can very well wish to reach IC4 or IC5, but these indifference curves are beyond his reach given his
money income. Thus, the consumer will be at equilibrium at point Q on IC3. What do we notice at point Q? We notice
that at this point, his budget line PL is tangent to the indifference curve IC3. In this equilibrium position (at Q), the
consumer will buy OM of X and ON of Y.
At the tangency point Q, the slopes of the price line PL and the indifference curve IC3 are equal. The slope of the
MUx
indifference curve shows the marginal rate of substitution of X for Y (MRSxy) which is equal to while the slope
MUy
Px
of the price line indicates the ratio between the prices of two goods i.e.,
Py
At equilibrium point Q,
MUx Px
MRS
= xy =
MUy Py
Thus, we can say that the consumer is in equilibrium position when the price line is tangent to the indifference curve
or when the marginal rate of substitution of goods X and Y is equal to the ratio between the prices of the two goods.
We have seen that the consumer attains equilibrium at the point where the budget line is tangent to the indifference
curve and
MUx MUy
=
Px Py
In fact the slope of the indifference curve points to the rate at which the consumer is willing to give up good Y for
good X. The slope of the budget line tells us the rate at which the consumer is actually able to trade good X and
good Y. When both these are equal, he will be maximizing his satisfaction given the constraints.
The indifference curve analysis is superior to utility analysis: (i) it dispenses with the assumption of measurability of
utility (ii) it studies more than one commodity at a time (iii) it does not assume constancy of marginal utility of money
(iv) it segregates income effect from substitution effect.
SUMMARY
• The existence of human wants is the basis for all economic activities in the society. All desires, tastes and
motives of human beings are called wants in Economics.
• In Economics, wants are classified in to necessaries, comforts and luxuries.
• Utility refers to the want satisfying power of goods and services. It is not absolute but relative. It is a
subjective concept and it depends upon the mental attitude of people.
• There are two important theories of utility, the cardinal utility analysis and ordinal utility analysis.
• The law of diminishing marginal utility states that as a consumer increases the consumption of a commodity,
every successive unit of the commodity gives lesser and lesser satisfaction to the consumer.
• Consumer surplus is the difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for a commodity and what he
actually pays for it.
• Consumer surplus is the buyer's net gain from purchasing a good. Graphically, it is the triangular area below
the demand curve and above the price line.
• A rise in the price of a good reduces consumer surplus; a fall in the price increases consumer surplus
• The indifference curve theory, which is an ordinal theory, shows the household’s preference between
alternative bundles of goods by means of indifference curves.
• Marginal rate of substitution is the rate at which the consumer is prepared to exchange goods X and Y.
• The important properties of an Indifference curve are: Indifference curve slopes downwards to the right, it is
always convex to the origin, two ICs never intersect each other, it will never touch the axes and higher the
indifference curve higher is the level of satisfaction.
• When two goods are perfect substitutes of each other, indifference curves for these two goods are straight,
parallel lines with a constant slope along the curve, or the indifference curve has a constant MRS
• Goods are perfect complements when a consumer is interested in consuming only in fixed proportions.. In
such a case, the indifference curve will consist of two straight lines with a right angle bent which is convex
to the origin, or in other words, it will be L shaped.
• Budget line or price line shows all those combinations of two goods which the consumer can buy spending
his given money income on the two goods at their given prices.
• The slope of the budget line is determined by the relative prices of the two goods. It is equal to ‘Price Ratio’
of two goods. i.e. PX /PY i.e. It measures the rate at which the consumer can trade one good for the other .
• The budget line will shift when there is: a change in the prices of one or both products with the nominal
income of the buyer (budget) remaining the same or when there is a change in the level of nominal income
of the consumer with the relative prices of the two goods remaining the same.
• A consumer is said to be in equilibrium when he is deriving maximum possible satisfaction from the goods
and is in no position to rearrange his purchase of goods.
The consumer attains equilibrium at the point where the budget line is tangent to the indifference curve and
MUx / Px =MUy /Py = MUz /Pz