SG09
SG09
1. Introduction
Throughout this guide so far, we have only ever considered ‘the’ interest rate, that is
the one set by the monetary authorities, or that is allowed to change to clear the money
markets if the money supply is the instrument of choice. In reality, there are a large number
of interest rates, from those on debt that mature overnight to interest rates on debt that
mature up to 30 years in the future. This chapter will examine in more detail the links
between short-term and long-term interest rates, explaining why such links are important
and providing theories that explain the short-term–long-term interest rate relationship.
2. Aims
This chapter will introduce the relevance of a rich variety of interest rates in financial
and macroeconomic decisions. We will also discuss different term structure theories.
3. Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities,
you should be able to:
• explain what a yield curve is and why it is important for policy makers
• list and discuss the different empirical regularities of the yield curve
• list and describe the three different theories of the term structure outlined in this
chapter, noting any differences and similarities and stating which theories can explain
which empirical facts
• describe the relationship between rates of return and bond prices and why this is so
important for the absence of arbitrage conditions on which the expectations hypoth-
esis focuses.
125
4. Reading advice
The main readings for this section are the chapters in the textbooks by Goodhart (1989),
Harris (1985) and especially Mishkin (2003). Chapter 7 of Mishkin should be read before
starting this part of the subject as it starts by giving a general introduction to the ideas
behind the term structure and then develops the relevant theory. The two entries in the
New Palgrave Dictionary by Malkiel and Mishkin are very useful but the chapter by Shiller
in the Handbook of Monetary Economics is difficult and should only be read if you feel
comfortable with the material.
5. Essential reading
Goodhart, C.A.E. Money, Information and Uncertainty. (London: Macmillan, 1989)
Chapter 11.
Harris, L. Monetary Theory. (New York; London: McGraw-Hill, 1985) Chapter 17.
Malkiel, B.G. ‘The term structure of interest rates’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate and
J. Eatwell (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London:
Macmillan, 1994).
Mishkin, F.S. The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets. (Boston,
Mass.; London: Addison Wesley, 2003) Chapter 7.
Mishkin, F.S. ‘The yield curve’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate and J. Eatwell (eds) The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London: Macmillan, 1994).
126
6. Further reading
Books
Shiller, R.J. ‘The term structure of interest rates’, in Friedman, B. and F. Hahn (eds)
Handbook of Monetary Economics. (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1990).
Walsh, C.E. Monetary Theory and Policy. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2003)
Chapter 10.
Journal articles
Aksoy, Y. and H. Basso, ‘Liquidity, term spreads and monetary policy’, Economic
Journal, 124, 2014, 1234–1278.
Mankiw, N.G. and L.H. Summers ‘Do long-term interest rates overreact to short-term
interest rates?’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1984) 1, pp.223–247.
McCallum, B.T. ‘Monetary policy and the term structure of interest rates’, National
Bureau of Economic Research working paper, w4938, (1994).
Shiller, R.J. ‘The volatility of long-term interest rates and expectations models of the
term structure’, Journal of Political Economy 87(5, Part 2) 1979, 1190–1219.
Activity (9.1)
127
9%
Yield to maturity
6%
4%
Figure 9.1:
• Coupon bonds. Typically, coupon bonds promise to pay a fixed sum of money, the
coupon, every period, whether it is every month, quarter or year, and also promise to
pay the holder of the bond its face value on maturity. For example, a ten-year bond
may be bought from the government for £100 that promises to pay £5 (the coupon
128
payment) every year for the next ten years. In the final year, both the last £5 coupon
and the maturity value of the bond, £100, are paid.
• Discount bonds. Discount bonds do not offer any interest or coupon payments. In-
stead, they are sold at a ‘discount’ and pay a larger amount on maturity. For example,
a ten-year discount bond may be sold today for £60 that pays no coupons at all but
pays £100 on maturity, ten years from now.
Consider a coupon bond that pays C every year from now to infinity. Such bonds, without
a maturity date, are called perpetuities or Consols (the UK term). The price of this bond,
P, will be the future cash flow, discounted back to today by the interest rate, R, assumed
constant here for convenience.
!
C C C C 1 C
P= + + +··· = = . (9.1)
1 + R (1 + R) 2 (1 + R) 3 1 + R 1 − 1/(1 + R) R
There is then a negative relationship between the price of a bond and the interest rate. This
was discussed in Chapter 3 when examining Keynes individual money demand function.
(For bonds that do have a maturity date, the relationship between bond prices and the
interest rate, although still negative, is not as simple as (9.1). Intuitively, if the interest rate
increased, people would be willing to pay less for a bond that pays a fixed coupon payment
each period. If a perpetuity bond that paid a coupon of £5 had a price of £100, this implies
the market interest rate is 5%. If the market interest rate doubled to 10%, no investor would
be willing to pay more than £50 for the same bond since the £5 coupon on a £50 bond is
10%. Hence the bond price and interest rate are negatively related.
1. Rates of return on short- and long-dated bonds move together over time.
2. When short rates are low, the yield curve is likely to be upward sloping and vice
versa.
129
are perfect substitutes. Consider someone who wishes to save a fixed amount of money
for n periods. She could either buy long-dated bonds now, at date t, that pay t Rt+n per
cent per year. The left-hand subscript denotes the time when the bond is bought and the
right-hand subscript denotes when the bond will mature. Alternatively, she could buy a
bond that matures at date t + 1 (a one-period bond) paying a rate of return t rt+1 . When
this matures she will buy another one-period bond (at date t + 1 that matures at date t + 2)
paying a rate of return t+1 rt+2 and will continue doing this until date t + n. If the return from
a portfolio made up of long-dated bonds is not identically equal to the expected return from
continually rolling over one-period debt, then arbitrage opportunities will be exploited to
bring the two returns together.
Suppose for example that a two-year bond paid a rate of return of 4% per year. If the
rate of return on a one-year bond was 3% today and expected to remain at 3% next year,
investors will rush in to buy the longer-dated bond as it pays a higher rate of return. The
increased demand for the two period bonds will push the price up and, as explained above,
will push the rate of return down from 4%. Also, the reduction in demand for one-period
bonds will push the price down, causing the one-period rate of return to increase from 3%.
In equilibrium, under the expectations hypothesis, the total return from each portfolio must
be equal to avoid arbitrage opportunities. Using the same notation as above, but noting that
at date t when the saving decision is made, all future one-period rates are not known and
have to be estimated, then the discount bond reads:
The left-hand side is the total return from holding n period bonds until they mature. The
right-hand side is the total expected return from holding and continually rolling over one-
period bonds, n times. The rates of return on all bonds bought at date t + 1 onwards are
not known at date t, hence the e (expectation) superscript. Taking logs of (9.2), noting that
ln(1 + X) ≈ X for small X, gives:
n · t Rt+n = t rt+1 + t+1 rt+2 + t+2 rt+3 + . . . + t+n−1 rt+n
e e e
t+n−1
1 X e
⇒ t Rt+n = sr . (9.3)
n s=t s+1
This is one of the main results of the expectations hypothesis; the long-term interest rate is
an average of the current and all future expected short-term interest rates. The expectations
hypothesis does have a number of criticisms, however:
• It cannot explain the empirical fact that the yield curve has a persistent upward slope.
If the long rate is an average of current and expected future short rates, this can only
be explained if the short rate increases through time. This clearly is not the case.
• If the long rate is an average of current and future short rates, the long rate must be a
smoother series (when plotted through time) than the short rate. This is not true; the
long rate is just as volatile.
130
• In order to avoid arbitrage opportunities and keep total returns equal, if the rate of
return on long-term bonds is greater than the return on short bonds, then holding
long-dated bonds must be accompanied by a capital loss (i.e. the price of long-term
bonds must fall). If the price of long-term bonds falls, the rate of return must increase
still further in the next period. Putting this another way: if the long rate is higher than
the short rate, the long rate must increase. This does not happen in reality.
If the long rate is an average of the current and expected future short rates, then an
upward-sloping yield curve suggests that the short rate is expected to increase in the future
(see (9.3)). If the real interest rate is constant then the increase in expected future nominal
interest rates must be associated with an increase in expected future inflation, as per the
Fisher equation. The greater the slope of the yield curve, the more short-term rates are
expected to rise and so the faster is inflation expected to increase.
Activity (9.2)
Why do you think people would prefer to hold short-term, rather than long-term,
debt?
(Hint: think of the desire to lock up money in long-term bonds and the risk of
capital gains or losses when such holdings have to be liquidated.)
131
Despite being able to explain persistent upward-sloping yield curves, the segmenta-
tion hypothesis cannot explain the fact that interest rates move together since the markets
are completely segmented. Also, the theory cannot explain why yield curves are upward
(downward)-sloping when short rates are low (high).
132
• describe the relationship between rates of return and bond prices and why this is so
important for the absence of arbitrage conditions on which the expectations hypoth-
esis focuses.
1. ‘Under the segmentation hypothesis, the slope of the yield curve tells us nothing
about expected inflation.’
Section B
2. Empirical fact: yield curves tend to have an especially steep upward slope when short
rates are low and a downward slope when short-term interest rates are high. Can you
explain this fact with the theories of the term structure analysed in this chapter?
3. Assuming that the expectations hypothesis is the correct theory of the term structure,
calculate the interest rates for one to five year bonds and plot the resulting yield
curves when one year interest rates over the next five years look as follows:
How would your yield curves change if people preferred shorter-term bonds over
longer-term bonds?
4. If the yield curve was steeply upward sloping, what is the market predicting about
the movements of future short-term interest rates? What might the market predict
about the inflation rate in the future?
5. How can the preferred habitat theory explain the appearance of downward-sloping
yield curves if t kn , the term premium, is positive?
133
(a) Using (9.3), we see that:
134