Consumer Demand
Consumer Demand
Rafayal Ahmed
NSU SBE
max u (x )
x ∈RL+
subject to p.x ≤ m
α (p.x ) + (1 − α) p.y ≤ αm + (1 − α) m
p. [αx ] + p. [(1 − α) y ] ≤ m
p. [αx + (1 − α) y ] ≤ m
max u (x )
x ∈B(p,m)
Theorem
(Weierstrass Maximum Theorem) Any continuous function on a
closed and bounded domain achieves its maximum and minimum.
Corollary
Suppose a consumer’s preferences are represented by the
continuous utility function u. Then her UMP has at least one
solution.
▶ Having shown that the UMP has solution(s), let us now focus
on analyzing these solutions.
▶ “If you know something exists, give it a name”.
▶ For given preferences ≿, the solutions(s) to the UMP is a
mapping from (p, m) to X .
▶ Let us call this mapping the demand correspondence,
D : (p, m) ⇒ X .
▶ D maps (p, m) to a subset of X . This subset, denoted as
D (p, m), includes all solutions to the UMP.
▶ Because there may be more than one solution to the UMP, we
are calling D a correspondence.
▶ When the solution is unique, we could call D the demand
function.
Theorem
Suppose the consumer’s preferences are convex. Then, the demand
correspondence D (p, m) is a convex set.
Proof.
Suppose x ∗ , y ∗ ∈ D (p, m). That is, both x ∗ and y ∗ are solutions to the UMP.
That means both of them must also be in the budget set, so x ∗ , y ∗ ∈ B (p, m).
Moreover, we must have u (x ∗ ) = u (y ∗ ) = maxx ∈B(p,m) u (x ), so x ∗ ∼ y ∗ and
thus x ∗ ≿ y ∗ . Now let α ∈ [0, 1] be arbitrary and consider the convex
combination αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ . We have to show αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ∈ D (p, m).
Because B (p, m) is convex, we know αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ∈ B (p, m). Because
preferences are convex, αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ≿ y ∗ , so
u (αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ) ≥ u (y ∗ ) = maxx ∈B(p,m) u (x ). Thusly, αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗
is a solution to the UMP and αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ∈ D (p, m).
Theorem
Suppose the consumer’s preferences are strictly convex. Then, the demand
correspondence D (p, m) is a singleton. That is, there is a unique solution to
the UMP and D (p, m) is a function.
Proof.
Towards a contradiction, assume there are two solutions x ∗ ̸= y ∗ to the UMP.
So x ∗ , y ∗ ∈ B (p, m) and u (x ∗ ) = u (y ∗ ) = maxx ∈B(p,m) u (x ), so x ∗ ≿ y ∗ .
Take α ∈ (0, 1). Because B (p, m) is a convex set,
αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ∈ B (p, m). Because preferences are strictly convex,
αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ≻ y ∗ , so u (αx ∗ + (1 − α) y ∗ ) > u (y ∗ ). Thus, we have
found a bundle in B (p, m) which has a strictly higher utility level than y ∗ . This
contradicts the fact that y ∗ is a solution to the UMP.
Remark
In words, this result means with monotonic preferences, the
consumer’s budget constraint must hold with equality, and thus
the optimal bundle must be on the budget line.
Rafayal Ahmed (NSU) Demand 13 / 20
D (p, m) is Homogenous of Degree Zero
Proof.
Suppose initially the price vector and income were (p, m). Let
λ > 0 be arbitrary. Consider what happens to the budget set when
all prices and income is multiplied by λ.
B (λp, λm) = {x : (λp) .x ≤ λm} = {x : p.x ≤ m} = B (p, m).
The consumer’s preferences are the same as before, and the
consumer has the same budget set to choose from, so clearly
D (λp, λm) = D (p, m). This, by definition, says that the demand
correspondence is homogenous of degree zero.
Definition
At bundle x , the consumer’s marginal utility for good i is:
∂u (x )
MUi =
∂xi
Proposition
Suppose the consumer’s preferences are (strongly) monotonic.
Then for all goods ℓ ∈ {1, ..., L}, the marginal utility MPℓ is
(strictly) positive.
Definition
ϵ
The (positive) ratio ϵji is called the marginal rate of substitution of
good i for good j, and written as MRSi,j .
▶ Let us carefully state all of the constraints for the UMP, and
set it up as a constrained maximization problem (with
inequality constraints):
L L
!
X X
L = u (x1 , ..., xL ) + λ m − pℓ xℓ + µℓ xℓ
ℓ=1 ℓ=1
∂u (x ∗ )
− λpi + µi = 0 (1)
∂xi
∂u (x ∗ )
− λpj + µj = 0 (2)
∂xj
▶ Dividing (1) by (2), we get:
∂u(x ∗ )
∂xi pi
∂u(x ∗ )
=
pj
∂xj