0% found this document useful (0 votes)
89 views9 pages

Comp Policy Law An Overview

Competition law is the enactment of that policy and achieves its objectives in three ways. It prohibits anti-competition agreements and practices that harm free trade and competition. It also prevents abuse of dominant position and anti-competitive practices that lead to such a dominant position.

Uploaded by

vik302
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOC, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
89 views9 pages

Comp Policy Law An Overview

Competition law is the enactment of that policy and achieves its objectives in three ways. It prohibits anti-competition agreements and practices that harm free trade and competition. It also prevents abuse of dominant position and anti-competitive practices that lead to such a dominant position.

Uploaded by

vik302
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOC, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 9

Competition Policy and Law – An Overview

Madhav Mehra

The principal objective of competition policy is to foster competition as an instrument for


accelerating growth. The policy is meant to fuel innovation and create market efficiencies that
offers better products and lower prices thus benefitting consumers and maximising welfare. .
Competition law is the enactment of that policy and achieves its objectives in three ways:

(1) prohibiting anti-competition agreements and practices that harm free trade and competition;

(2) preventing abuse of dominant position and anti-competitive practices that lead to such a
dominant position;

(3) regulating mergers and acquisitions.

Competition is irrefutably beneficial for every market participant. Competitive markets give
consumers wider choice and lower prices. It gives sellers stronger incentives to minimize their
costs through innovation and other productivity enhancing techniques. This enables firms to
pass on cost savings to the customers and offer better products and greater choice at lower
prices.

Nonetheless the gap between the assumptions of such theories and the market realities and
practices both in developing and developed countries remains pervasive. While there is a broad
consensus on the competition policy objectives there is considerable divergence in the
application and practice of competition law leading to question marks about its effectiveness .
Even in a mature jurisdiction like United States with over a century of experience, the
application of antitrust laws has not moved beyond semantics. The alternating views on the
reductive and expansive interpretations of the law have led to confusing and apparently
contradictory judgments on antitrust cases that has belied the hopes and aspirations of
lawmakers and the stakeholders.

Competition law poses more a public policy challenge than a legal argument. Indeed US
antitrust decisions in the first half of twentieth century exhibited hostility to large successful
firms. This has since changed. Recent judgments, on the other hand have shown greater
understanding of the social context and market economics. Nonetheless defining monopolies
continues to remain a big challenge. In a seminal case known as the Grinnell Test , the US
Supreme Court distinguished between the willful maintenance of monopoly power as opposed
to power resulting from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product ,
business acumen , or historic accident.

The Supreme Court in United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966), held:

The offense of monopoly under § 2 of the Sherman Act has two elements: (1) the
possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or
maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a
consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.

As Joseph Angland, an eminent authority on competition law, points out, “The Court’s language,
however, provided scant guidance regarding how one could distinguish the type of conduct that
violated Section 2 from that which did not. The Court noted that the mere building of a better
product did not violate Section 2, apparently recognizing that the antitrust laws were designed to
enhance competition and that prohibiting product improvements so as to ensure that firms
offering old, undesirable products could maintain their market position would subvert that
objective. A logical extension of that proposition appeared to be that – at least until some lower
limit was breached – acquiring or maintaining monopoly power by offering low prices did not
offend Section 2. After all, whether a product is “superior” depends to some extent on its price.
It would make little sense to encourage a company to manufacture a light bulb that would last
twice as long, but then to condemn it for not charging double the price. Construing Section 2 to
condone price competition, moreover, was faithful to the origins of the law. The U.S. antitrust
laws, after all, sprang from a concern that the late nineteenth century trusts had burdened
consumers and businesses by charging excessive prices. It was one thing to hold that charging
excessive prices by itself did not violate the antitrust law, but it would be quite another, in all but
the most exceptional circumstances, to use the antitrust laws to require firms to charge high
prices.”

“Business acumen” is a double edged sword. It can be used to develop a more innovative
product that would benefit the consumer or “a complicated scheme to undermine one’s
competitors without offering a better or lower-priced product, and it did not seem that those two
types of conduct should be treated the same. It would be curious indeed if one could defend
against a claim of monopolizing conduct simply by arguing that it was clever monopolizing
conduct.”

Predatory pricing is extreme form of abusive exclusionary pricing, where the dominant firm
charges low prices, with a strategy designed to drive rivals out of the market. Most often, they
are evidence of vigorous competition and beneficial to consumers. Loyalty and bundled
discounts can be used strategically to exclude small rivals. Tying arrangements can be barriers
to entry and innovation, but they may also be a means for achieving manufacturing or
distribution efficiencies. Exclusive dealing agreements can limit distribution channels available
to small manufacturers, but they are also used to achieve efficiencies by aligning the incentives
between a manufacturer and its distributors.

In certain circumstances even pricing above average variable cost can be “predatory” or
“exclusionary”. It can be argued that it can inhibit competition to the detriment of competition
and consumers. Yet, the Supreme Court has created, and probably the majority of
commentators support, a safe harbor for pricing above average variable cost (or some other
cost standard). They arrive at this result by appraising, at least in a qualitative way, the
likelihood of false positives and false negatives, and the consequences of each. The Supreme
Court, for example, recognized that predatory pricing involves incurring losses in the short run
which the predator hopes to recoup in the long run if it succeeds in driving out competition and
being able to charge supracompetitive prices. Comparing the certain short-run loss to the
conjectural long-run gain, and recognizing that one must recoup more than a dollar in the future
to compensate for a lost dollar in the present, the Court noted a consensus among
commentators that predatory pricing is “rarely tried, and even more rarely successful.”

A similar challenge arises with respect to the prohibition of abuse of dominance, the focus of
Article 4 of the Act, says William Blumenthal, former General Counsel of FTC. “It may be
obvious, but an “abuse of dominance” violation requires proof of “abuse” and proof of
“dominance,” and both of those elements present doctrinal complications. Whether a firm is
dominant can be difficult to measure. Market shares alone are ordinarily insufficient to establish
dominance – their predictive power is highly sensitive to accurate determination of the
denominator (the universe, or the “market”), and they fail to account for factors that may defeat
a firm’s ability to exercise market power, such as ease of entry. And whether conduct is abusive
is even more difficult to measure.The practices that provide the basis for a finding of abuse are
usually identical to practices that, in most contexts, are efficiency-enhancing and beneficial to
the public. The market context shifts, but the practices themselves are the same. That is,
depending on market context, a particular practice can be anticompetitive or neutral or
procompetitive. Most often, the practice will be neutral or procompetitive. In a small percentage
of cases, the practice will be anticompetitive. Because the practice itself is ambiguous, policy
makers face great difficulty in framing sensible legal rules. We can’t simply prohibit certain
practices, because we’ll be prohibiting things that we generally want to encourage. Policy
makers have recognized this problem for a long time.

Public restraints are far more effective and efficient at restraining competition. Unlike private
restraints, there is no need to maintain backroom secrecy or to incur the costs of conducting a
covert cartel. Public restraints can be open and notorious. Public restraints are also a more
efficient means of solving the entry problem. Rather than ceaselessly monitoring the
marketplace for new rivals, a firm can simply rely on a public regime that, for example, provides
for only a limited number of licenses. Perhaps the clearest advantage of public restraints is that
they frequently include a built-in cartel enforcement mechanism. While cheating often besets
private cartels, public cartels suffer from no such defect. Cheaters, once identified, can be
sanctioned through government processes.

As a matter of competition advocacy, it is now commonplace for competition authorities to


express concern over the anticompetitive consequences that often flow from regulatory capture
and rent-seeking. Thus, in the United States competition authorities have conducted advocacy
to address governmental restraints that reduce competition in a wide range of industries and
services – physicians, lawyers, funeral homes, and other professional licensing; advertising
claims; sale of wine or real estate using electronic commerce; transportation; and many more.

The problem of governmental restraints may be more pronounced in developing economies, in


which we are more likely to observe recent privatization, former state-owned enterprises, and
significant licensing requirements and other governmental entry barriers. A too-common pattern
is that former state-owned monopolies, now privatized and nominally open to competition, rely
on their regulators to adopt rules that impede entry and discourage the emergence of new
competitors.”

Notwithstanding these arguments, such controversial aspects in the implementation of


competition policy could hardly be thought to outweigh the enormous social and economic
benefits accruing from competition. There is growing empirical evidence that more competition
leads to more innovation and accelerates productivity growth and there is a strong positive
correlation between the effectiveness of competition policy and growth.

The need for competition law becomes even more evident when foreign direct investment is
liberalized. The impact of FDI is not always pro-competitive. Very often foreign direct investment
takes the form of a foreign corporation acquiring a domestic enterprise or establishing a joint
venture with one. By making such an acquisition the foreign investor may substantially lessen
competition and gain a dominant position in the relevant market thus charging higher prices.
Another scenario often encountered in developing and transition economies, is where the
affiliates of two separate multinational companies (MNCs) have been established in competition
with one another in a particular market, following the liberalisation of foreign direct investment in
that country. Subsequently, the parent companies overseas decide to merge. With the affiliates
no longer independent of one another, competition in the host country may be virtually
eliminated and the prices of the products artificially inflated.

The real question that needs to be addressed is not ‘whether or not to have competition policy’
but “how to maximize the expected benefits arising from competition”. In this context , one has
to be careful of not seeking too narrow definition of competition policy objectives which may
harm developing countries. An important paradox is that promoting transparency in market
transactions can harm competition by enabling companies to sell at high prices through tacit
collusion. Likewise, aiming at very high quality standards for products to ensure consumers get
good quality products may act as entry barriers and limit dynamic competition. Excessive
competition also adversely affect the sustainability of small and medium enterprises

Most of these adverse consequences of mergers and acquisitions by MNCs can be


avoided if an effective competition law is in place in the host country. Furthermore an economy
that has implemented an effective competition law is in a better position to attract foreign direct
investment than one that has not. This is not just because most multinational corporations are
expected to be accustomed to the operation of such a law in their home countries and know
how to deal with such concerns but also that multinational corporations expect competition
authorities to ensure a level playing field between domestic and foreign firms, including among
MNCs.
.
During the past decades, many developing countries have instituted
programmes of microeconomic reform, involving greater reliance on markets and
less emphasis on state intervention. Among the more important changes have been a
lowering of tariff barriers, the removal of many quantitative import restrictions, the
reduction of subsidies to domestic producers, the privatisation of government business
enterprises, the easing of foreign exchange controls and the encouragement of foreign
direct investment.

Underlying these reforms is a renewed confidence that market forces and the
individual decisions of consumers and privately owned businesses, can make a greater
contribution to economic and social development than an inward looking centralised
economic system. However, the potential benefits of a shift towards a more market oriented
economy will not be realised unless business firms are prevented from
imposing restrictions on competition. Deregulation of previously regulated sectors,
including state -controlled monopolies such as utilities and “network industries”
considered for the most part to be “natural monopolies,” need to be subject to
competition review by competition authorities or sectoral watchdogs to ensure that
these firms do not abuse their dominant position in the market.

It has to be emphasized that a robust competition policy is central to economic reforms. For
instance price liberalization, if not accompanied by competition laws and policy aimed at
controlling economic behaviour and structures, can result in substantial price increases and
reduced benefits for the overall economy. If monopolistic structures are allowed to continue
unchecked, price liberalization will not be effective. The same can be said of
privatization of state monopolies into private monopolies. Finally, opening of markets
through import competition and FDI liberalization might bring enhanced competition,
but if no safeguards exist, foreign firms might also engage in anticompetitive
practices and abuse dominant market position. Hence the need for a strong and effective
competition law which will ban anti-competitive agreements and encourage conduct where there
are demonstrable net public benefits.

Merger control is emerging as one of the most important area of competition law. The worldwide
Mergers and Acquisitions in the first half of 2008 totaled US$1.6 trillion. Mergers and
Acquisitions in India totaled US$33.1 billion in 2007. The World Investment Report, 2005, by
UNCTAD designated India as the third most attractive research and development centre in the
world. India is the largest foreign investor in the UK outpacing even the US.

India decided to abolish its archaic Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act and passed
the Competition Act 2002 thus shifting its focus from curbing monopolies to promoting
competition. The Act came into force on 20 May 2008. Recognising & realising that the trade
agreements have the potential of preventing, restricting, distorting, discouraging, impeding or
scuttling competition in markets, Section 3 (1) & (2) of the Act declares that ‘No enterprise or
association of enterprises or person or association of persons shall enter into any agreement in
respect of production, supply, distribution, storage, acquisition or control of goods or provision
of services, which causes or is likely to cause an ‘appreciable adverse effect on competition
(AAEC) within India and that such agreement being anti competitive, is void’.

The Act stipulates 5 kinds of vertical agreements. Section 3(4) of the Act provides that

Any agreement amongst enterprises or persons at different stages or levels of the production
chain in different markets, in respect of production, supply, distribution, storage, sale or price of,
or trade in goods or provision of services, including—

a) tie-in arrangement;
b) exclusive supply agreement;
c) exclusive distribution agreement;
d) refusal to deal;
e) resale price maintenance,

shall be an agreement in contravention of sub-section (1 )of Section 3 if such agreement


causes or is likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India.

These vertical restraints are only illustrative (not exhaustive and have been defined inclusively
in the Act. By and large, vertical agreements are not subjected to the rigours of competition law.
However, where a vertical agreement has the character of distorting or preventing competition,
through exclusive distribution, it comes under the anti competitive behaviour.

IPR is an important part of competition law and is designed to give protection to patent holder
with a view to encouraging innovation. Mark Twain’s famous statement that a country without a
patent system is like a crab, destined to move only sideways and never forward speaks of the
importance of patent law and other categories of intellectual property law such as copyright,
trade secrets, trademark, right of publicity, in shaping an open, democratic, market-based
society.

The design of intellectual property rights rests on the recognition of these four baselines and the
choice among them for the particular market environment the legislature seeks to regulate. For
example, the first mover baseline may be appropriate for pioneer innovations while the pro-
consumer baseline may be appropriate for mature inventions of high social value, such as
pharmaceuticals. By recognizing that competition and intellectual property rights inform each
other, policy makers can use these competitive baselines to calibrate intellectual property rights
to the particular market and social context in order to reach the desired policy goals. I am, of
course, not suggesting that this analysis works in a particularly mechanical way. Rather, the
recognition of competitive baselines for intellectual property rights emphasizes the need for a
richer policy debate about the relationship between intellectual property rights and competition.

India’s accession to the World Trade Organization in 1998 occurred as the country suffered a
foreign reserve crisis in the 1990’s that followed a privatization of the economy in the late
1980’s. In March, 1999, the Indian legislature passed emergency measures to comply with
TRIPS agreement and deal with a backlog of over thirty thousand patent applications. The
Indian government established a mailbox where patent applications could be sent and an
administrative structure for the processing of applications with patent offices in Kolkata, New
Delhi, Mumbai, and Chennai. In 2005, the parliament extended patent protection to chemical
compounds amending the 1970 Patent Act that had denied such protection. Despite these
efforts in the area of patent law, as well as concomitant efforts in the areas of copyright, digital
rights, and trademark, India continues, as of this writing, to be on the United States Trade
Representation Priority Watch List under Section 301 of the General Agreement of Tariffs and
Trade. The Indian government’s moves to privatize and to reform its intellectual property laws
is in part the basis for Goldman Sach’s prediction in 2003 that the Indian economy could
surpass that of German, Japan, and the United Kingdom in thirty years.

Jurists in the United States and the European Union have struggled to reconcile the
exclusionary prerogatives of intellectual property law with the goals of antitrust and competition
laws. Whether in the field of licensing practices, parallel importation, or exclusionary
dominance, the laws of the United States and the European Union have attempted to balance
intellectual property and competition law by creating exceptions, safe harbors, and limitations on
rights that allow the two areas of law to progress accordingly.

At the WTO level, agreements on IPR and services are increasingly being assessed from a
competition perspective. In India, though laws against unfair competition and for the protection
of IPR have existed for a long time, the competition policy has been recently put in place by the
enactment of the Competition Act, 2002.1 The Preamble to the Act states its aims thus:

An Act to provide, keeping in view of the economic development of the country, for the
establishment of a Commission to prevent practices having adverse effect on competition, to
promote and sustain competition in markets, to protect the interests of consumers and to ensure
freedom of trade carried on by other participants in markets, in India, and for matters connected
therewith or incidental thereto

Though competition law and IPR have coinciding philosophies, their interface is challenging
because of the dynamic nature of each of them. Competition law uses the elements of markets
and pricing which are continually in flux. IPR is also in flux, with the advent of newer categories
1
of IPR. How the two can be held together in spite of the dynamic scenario that faces us is the
problem that competition policy should seek to solve.

There are currently about 80 developing and transition economies that have competition laws,
but not all of them have adopted a formal merger review system and fewer still are actively
enforcing their merger provisions. Many competition agencies in these countries are receiving
expertise and advice on the design and enforcement of their competition laws from international
organizations such as the OECD, World Bank, UNCTAD, and the recently established
International Competition Network, NGOs such as CUTS International of India and from the
more experienced competition law jurisdictions.

In the words of William Blumenthal “the integrity of competition law in India foreseeably will face
a related challenge: intervention by various political forces to alleviate the pressures that are
imposed by the political process itself. I have just described political intervention in the form of
government-imposed restraints, but there are other forms as well. You should anticipate that
there will be calls for industries to be exempted selectively from the scope of the Competition
Act. And you should anticipate that the Competition Commission from time to time will be
buffeted with demands to grant favor, either by standing down where intervention would be
justified or by intervening where a complainant is complaining of the rigors of the competitive
process itself. Here, too, I hope you will offer CCI the support and encouragement that it
deserves. As we observe in the United States, “Living with competition is hard. Living without it
would be harder.”

Blumenthal continues, “Overcoming these doctrinal, institutional, and administrative challenges


can be difficult. Even in mature competition regimes such as my own, they are sometimes
daunting, and efforts to address them require frequent attention of both public and private
leadership. But the efforts and attention are worthwhile and probably necessary, for a well
structured competition regime can be a source of economic efficiency, consumer welfare,
innovation, and development. If implemented poorly, though, a competition regime can subvert
the goals it was intended to serve; it can leave the public wondering whatever came of the
promised benefits. As you implement the Competition Act, you may feel pressed for speed, but
take the time to get the implementation right. Five or ten years hence, you will be grateful that
you did”.

Competition policy is a complex, cross-cutting policy instrument which is affected by


a number of interconnected factors. Its effective implementation requires a holistic and
integrated mind with ability to hold two opposing views in mind and still have the capacity to
function. Its practitioners, more than anyone, need to be men of “significant learning”, learning
more than a mere accumulation of facts and presentation of a carefully constructed argument
couched in legal rhetoric.

Competition law is essentially an economic law. It is anathema to the purists and doctrinaires.
Its effective implementation would require a cultural change and change in the mind set of legal
practitioners. Legal and political theorists from the time of Plato have wrestled with defining
distinction between law and justice. There is a constant debate whether justice is part of law or
simply a moral judgment. Owen Dixon, Chief Justice of Australia when asked whether it was
part of the duty of a lawyer to contribute towards the progress of society, replied it was not. The
duty of a lawyer, he said was “to keep a hand on and hold steady the framework and foundation
of law”.

We have come a long way since. US Supreme Court judge, Justice Brandeis, the author of
famous Brandeis Brief that has motivated social and economic legislation in US, says, “A lawyer
who has not studied economics is very apt to become a public enemy”. These are harsh words
but as Lord Keynes said “Words have sometimes to be harsh since they represent an assault
on the thought of the unthinking”.

ECS Wade, a Cambridge Professor of law says in “the Aims of Legal Education”: “We should
teach and provide law as a great human institution serving social and economic end and in
relation to the world in which we live.” This world has changed beyond recognition during the 70
years since these words were written. Of the 100 most successful companies listed by Forbes in
1917 not one is making money. The CEO of world’s most powerful country is a black man
whose father came from Africa. In this multi reality, meta-digital world of change, tumult and
turbulence, where the very nature of change is changing by the hour, perceptions of truth
cannot be constant. So each judgment becomes a “work in progress” and learning experience.
We would realise the significance of TS Eliot, in Little Gidding: “And the end of all exploring will
be to arrive where we started and know the place for the first time.”

With these judgments placed on the internet in full view of the millions of Tweeters, users of
Facebook and MySpace, humility and transparency will be best armour. Instead of being driven
by the desire to defend our challenge will be to make it better next time. As Confucius said “Our
greatest glory lies not in never failing but rising each time we fail.”

This would call for a paradigmic shift of the legal process as well as the minds of jurists and
practitioners. Defensiveness would give way to exploration and herald “next level”
jurisprudence which would take into account not only economic but sociological and
environmental goals. An overriding aim of competition law is to promote economic justice. “It is
a hand maiden of modern economics and should be part of laws that reflect societal values
known as sociological jurisprudence”, says Mr Fali Nariman , one of India’s foremost jurists.

We are living in a world of harsh inequalities, inequity and injustice. There appears a widening
disconnect between law and justice. In this interconnected and interdependent world where
human aspirations are rising exponentially, people may be able to stand poverty but will not
stand injustice. India, that has successively recorded the second highest growth in GDP and
ranked third in Mergers and Acquisitions, is 128th on the Human Development Index. From
Bogota to Bangkok our biggest challenge is to bridge the widening inequalities. The legal
fraternity and jurists have a formidable challenge to use law as a driver of change, innovation
and inclusive growth. This would mean bidding good bye to groupthink and capitalising the 5
Ds – disruption of status quo and valuing diversity, dissent, dialogue and disclosure. Lawyers
are heirs to a noble tradition of inventiveness. The most ennobling element of a lawyer’s
profession is that it can ensure justice for its client. Justice is the only weapon that can secure
stability to society and provide sustainability to business. As Pope Paul VI said “If you want
peace, work for justice.” Competition law is essentially an instrument that helps us achieve that
elusive goal.

---------------------

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy